Module 3: Covering Business Public-Private Partnerships E.R. Yescombe YCL Consulting Ltd., London U.K. www.yescombe.com 2-4 September 2013 (1) Introduction to PPPs ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (2) Public infrastructure Why is infrastructure different? • public goods – available to all but difficult to get users to pay (e.g. street lighting) ∴ state has to provide • merit goods – services which should be based on need, rather than ability to pay (e.g. hospitals, schools) ∴ state has to provide • externalities – positive and negative – caused by the project but not part of it: e.g. new road reduces congestion in other roads, but users of those roads won’t pay for this benefit ∴ state has to provide But historically state did not provide much infrastructure: • economic infrastructure (roads, canals, railways) provided by local communities or private enterprise, e.g. in 19th century England; • social infrastructure (schools, hospitals) provided by religious organisations or other charities State can provide or facilitate provision of public infrastructure ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (3) What is a PPP? Public-private partnership (PPP, P3) • American origins – no single meaning – political rather than legal term • ‘Policy-based’ or ‘programme-based’ PPPs (PPPs against AIDS / malaria) v. ‘project-based’ or ‘contract based’ PPPs (PPP for a new road) Private finance for construction of new (or upgraded) public infrastructure + long-term service provision (including operation and maintenance) + risk transfer to private sector + remains in public ownership (or returned at end of contract) = ‘partnership’ ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (4) Development of PPPs Concessions …the user pays (tolls, fares, water fees, etc.) • Old concept – 18th century turnpike roads → Franchise / affermage – ‘publicans & sinners’, water in France, rail in U.K.) U.K. development of PFI Model – the public sector pays : • Underinvestment in public infrastructure in the 1970s, incl. maintenance • Thatcher government (1979-1990) - ‘New Public Management’: • the state is an inefficient provider of public services • where possible, role of state should be to facilitate / regulate provision of public services rather than always provide them itself → privatizations of the 1980s (mainly utilities) → new investment • But investment in public infrastructure continued to be inadequate: • development of “self-funding” projects, paid by users (i.e. concessions) → Channel Tunnel (1987), plus two major toll bridges and one toll road • but limited number of possible projects of this type in U.K. • Continued public budget constraints: → Private Finance Initiative (1992), to find other ways of bringing private finance into public infrastructure investment PFI model (renamed PF2 in 2012) widely imitated around the world Also known as the Availability Model because in many cases private sector is paid when the project is available for use ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (5) ‘Boundary lines’ for PPPs U.S. National Council for PPPs defines a PPP as: • ‘a contractual agreement between a public agency (federal, state or local) and a private sector entity. Through this agreement, the skills and assets of each sector (public and private) are shared in delivering a service or facility for the use of the general public. In addition to the sharing of resources, each party shares in the risks and rewards potential in the delivery of the service and/or facility’ ‘Narrow’ versus ‘broad’ definition: • Narrow– only private finance for new or upgraded infrastructure • Broad as above covers other kinds of private-sector involvement in infrastructure, e.g.: • Design & build contracts (no finance or long-term involvement) • Management contracts (no finance) • Franchises / leases (grey area but generally no finance) • Provision of state property (not public infrastructure) • Confusing to call them all PPPs – some elements in common, but structures, especially risk transfer, quite different ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (6) Public procurement / privatisation PPPs v. standard public-sector procurement: • Design & build v. design-bid-build • Contract including operation v. separate and unrelated operation • Finance from general government budget v. private-sector finance PPPs v. privatisation: • No transfer of public ownership • Public sector remains accountable to users • Contract-based not regulator-based • Main overlap with privatisation relates to transfer of staff ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (7) The public → private spectrum PPPs lie between ‘pure’ public- and private-sector projects: Public project ←——————————————————————–→ Private project ←—— Public-Private Partnership Contract Type Public-sector procurement Franchise (Affermage) Construction Operation Ownership Public sector* Public sector Public sector Public sector Private sector Public sector Who pays? Public sector Users n/a Private sector Who is paid? Design-Build FinanceOperate (DBFO) Private sector Private sector Public sector BuildOperateTransfer (BOT) Private sector Private sector Private sector during Contract, then public sector Public sector or users BuildTransferOperate (BTO) Private sector Private sector Private sector during construction, then public sector Public sector or users Private sector Private sector Private sector Public sector or users Build-OwnOperate (BOO)** Private sector Private sector Private sector Private-sector offtaker, public sector, or users Private sector * Public sector normally designs the project and engages private-sector contractors to carry out construction on its behalf (design-bid-build). ** This would be a PPP in the minority of cases where ownership of the project does not revert to the public sector at the end of the PPP contract (e.g. some waste management contracts) N.B.: PPP may be Concession or PFI Model ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (8) ‘Alphabet Soup’ ‘Alphabet soup’: • • • • • • • • • BOT BOOT BTO BLT BLOT BTL DBFO DBFM BOO etc. build-operate-transfer build-own-operate-transfer build-transfer-operate build-lease-transfer build-lease-operate-transfer build-transfer-lease design-build-finance-operate design-build-finance-maintain (or –manage) build-own-operate etc. Complex and overlapping terminology is pointless and confusing The key distinction is between: • ‘Reverting assets’: At the end of the PPP Contract the assets revert to public-sector control (unless a new contract, e.g. franchise, is signed); applies to most PPPs (= all terms above except BOO) • Non-reverting assets’: Private sector retains ownership & control – applies only to minority of cases where assets have some non-public use (= BOO) ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (9) Projects suitable for PPPs What projects are suitable in principle for PPPs? • • • • • • • • • • • the project provides an essential public service; not possible / desirable to privatize the project (e.g. road, hospital) public sector is directly accountable for the public service; the project is self-contained, i.e. it can be built and operated as one or more units, with a separately identifiable cash flow; the project has a long life (if not no point in signing a long-term contract); little risk of technological obsolescence (ditto) risk-transfer to private sector is possible; the project involves significant capital expenditure, and also requires long-term maintenance; the capital cost of the project should be high enough to justify the higher set-up costs for this more complex type of procurement; evidence that similar projects have been procured as PPPs; evidence of private-sector interest in providing the project as a PPP. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (10) Sectors suitable for PPPs Economic infrastructure • usually (but not always) user-paid / concession model (may also have public-sector subsidy) • Concession Model, e.g.: • roads / tunnels / bridges (tolled) • railways / light rail (passenger fares / freight charges) • water / waste water treatment (or could be PFI Model) • ‘Quasi-PFI Model’ • ‘availability-based’ process plant / ‘throughput’ contracts: power generation, power transmission, pipelines, LNG terminals N.B.: may not be PPPs (e.g. privatized electricity industry) • PFI Model, e.g.: • ‘shadow toll’ roads • ‘availability-based’ economic infrastructure: roads, rail, etc. • availability-based ‘accommodation’ projects: schools, hospitals • ‘service-based’, e.g. street lighting Social infrastructure • usually (but not always) public sector-paid / PFI model, e.g.: • ‘availability-based’ ‘accommodation’ projects: hospitals, schools, prisons, training centres, government offices, etc. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (11) PPP Contract – key features Various names: Project Agreement, Concession Agreement, Power Purchase Agreement, etc. Parties: Project Company & public-sector entity (= ‘Contracting Authority’) Objectives: • Specify required outputs from contract • Specify payment and performance régime • Allocate responsibilities and risks • Accommodate change • Penalise failure • Set out termination arrangements Payment only begins on delivery, i.e. end of construction phase (in most cases) Pre-agreed payments either by Contracting Authority or by users (or a combination of the two) calculated to: • repay bank loans or other debt (usually ‘project finance’-style debt) and give investors an acceptable rate of return on their equity investment • cover projected long-term operating costs (allowing for inflation) • so long as project performs as expected ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (12) Output specification PPP contract based on output specification – what has to be done but not how to do it: • Design and construction: • PPP school contract: Contracting Authority will specify, say, number of classrooms of a certain size, but not their layout or how to build them • Road concession: Contracting Authority will specify, say, that the road must have two lanes on each side, and meet normal road standards, but not how the road is to be built to meet these standards. • Service quality: again specify what is required but not how to do it • Key Performance Indicators (KPIs) and performance points (e.g. if the hospital ward is not cleaned on schedule or to the required standard, or if accidents are not cleared from the road within a certain time, deduction for poor service, leading to penalty payments). • Availability – is the project fully available for use? (e.g. if the roof leaks so a school classroom can’t be used, deduction for unavailability of the room). This ensures risk transfer to the private sector, a key aim of a PPP ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (13) Introduction to Project Finance ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (14) What is project finance? PPP lenders (mainly banks) usually use ‘project-finance’ techniques for PPPs. Project finance is a specialised form of finance: • Used for infrastructure with long construction / operation period • Lenders rely on project cash flow, not corporate balance sheet or past profit record; • So lenders carry out detailed due diligence, e.g. examine reality / viability of cash-flow projections. • Lenders rely on project contracts not physical assets as security • Lenders cannot take a mortgage over a school; • ‘Contract-based financial engineering’. • High ratio of debt to equity – main reason for using project finance; • Debt is cheaper than equity, so reduces cost of finance – hence produces a lower-cost project. • Project must be ‘ring-fenced’ (i.e., legally and economically selfcontained). ∴ Special-purpose vehicle (‘SPV’) Project Company as the borrower • No guarantees from investors in Project Company (‘non-recourse’ finance) • Finite project life, so debt must be fully repaid; • Cf. corporate loan, where debt may be rolled over indefinitely. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (15) Why do I need to know about this? Public-sector viewpoint • Surely raising the finance is the private sector’s problem? • Yes but: • Need to understand what is required to make a planned PPP project ‘bankable’ / financially viable, including whether any public-sector support (e.g. revenue guarantee) might be needed • Need to understand how much the project is likely to cost, and whether this is affordable • Forced renegotiation to meet lenders’ requirements, or complete failure to raise finance amongst the commonest reasons for PPPs failing in developing countries. ∴ Public-sector party needs to understand if a financing plan is credible before awarding PPP contract. Private-sector viewpoint • Can’t propose or bid for a PPP project without knowing what financing is available, how it should be structured, and how much it will cost • Non-financial employees (e.g. designers, engineers, maintenance) need to understand what lenders’ requirements are, and how they differ from a normal client in a simple construction / operating & maintenance contract. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (16) Industries using project finance Natural resources: • oil and gas fields • mining • LNG export and import plant • petrochemicals • pipelines Process plant: • power generation (PPAs) & transmission • industrial, e.g. plastics Telecommunications (e.g. mobile phone / satellite networks) Leisure projects (e.g. football stadium) Public infrastructure: • PPP Concessions (payment by user) • PFI-Model PPPs (payment by public sector) All involve major long-term project investments Principles / structures similar whatever type of project ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (17) Power-generation project Investors Equity Lenders Electricity Gridco / Distributor Project-Finance Debt Power-Purchase Agreement Project Funding Project Company Sub-Contracts EPC Contract EPC Contractor ©YCL Consulting Ltd. Fuel-Supply Contract Fuel Supplier Operation & Maintenance Contract O&M Contractor September 2013 (18) Toll-road concession Investors Equity Lenders Project-Finance Debt Concession Agreement Project Funding Project Company Sub-Contracts Contracting Authority Construction Contract Design & Build Contractor ©YCL Consulting Ltd. Operating Contract Toll-Road Operator Tolls Road Users Maintenance Contract Maintenance Company September 2013 (19) PFI Model – social infrastructure Investors Equity Lenders Contracting Authority Project-Finance Debt PPP Contract Project Funding Project Company Sub-Contracts Construction Contract Design & Build Contractor ©YCL Consulting Ltd. Maintenance Contract Maintenance Company Services Contract (e.g. cleaning, catering, security) Services Company September 2013 (20) Equity and debt Equity, provided by ‘sponsors’ / passive investors: • 10-30% of PPP project capital costs • high risk / high return – high return on investment if project does well, low return (or loss) if it does not do well • ‘upside’ and ‘downside’ Project-finance debt, provided by lenders • 70-90% of PPP project capital costs • low risk / fixed return = paid before equity / fixed margin over cost of funds • no ‘upside’ only ‘downside’ • lenders: • banks = private-sector commercial banks prepared to make long-term loans to projects; public-sector development banks, et al. • bonds = public debt issue, usually bought by investors looking for long-term secure cash flow, e.g. insurance companies, pension funds • development finance institutions (DFIs): direct (e.g. IFC) or via funds • export credit agencies (ECAs) – where project imports equipment • infrastructure / PPP funds - invest mainly in equity, but some debt ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (21) What do lenders expect? From public sector: • political commitment • political consensus (between government and opposition) • adequate project preparation • transparent procurement • appropriate risk transfer • project pipeline (& similar requirements from investors) From sponsors: • expertise / track record • arm’s length sub-contracting • reasonable equity investment • financial capacity (but not obligation) to provide support to deal with any financial problems with project • long-term commitment From sub-contractors • Experience in the sector • Credit standing • Appropriate penalties / liquidated damages / bonding ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (22) Why investors use project finance Project finance is complex and slow ∴ expensive, and with a high up-front cost (on top of complexity of PPPs!) Benefits for investors: • Greater leverage, hence higher ROE (return on equity) • Increased borrowing capacity • Long-term finance • Risk spreading / limitation • Partners with different financial strengths and industry skills can work together • Tax benefits (deductibility of loan interest) • [Off-balance sheet] ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (23) Benefit of PF to the public sector Project finance for PPP projects is beneficial to a Contracting Authority: • Lower total funding cost ∴ cheaper projects • Increases investors’ financial capacity ∴ creating more competition for projects • Enables public sector to assess and monitor project-specific data ∴ transparency • Third-party due diligence • Additional inward investment / skills transfer • Financial market development ∴ Public sector should ensure that project finance is available for PPP projects by ensuring ‘bankability’ N.B.: not all PPPs use project finance. • Alternative is corporate finance (usually with smaller projects) • Investors use own funds • Any extra debt is raised by investing company • Lenders do not rely on project cash flow, but investor’s credit ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (24) PPPs — For and Against ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (25) PPPs vs. public procurement Main reason governments around the world are adopting PFI is that it helps to deal with budgetary or borrowing constraints • But PFI Model provides ‘finance’, not ‘funding’ – public sector has to pay for it over time and so it has a fiscal effect (→ ‘Affordability’) • Tariff payments by users of concessions are a form of tax anyway? Main argument by critics of PFI is that the government can borrow money more cheaply • Correct to say that the cost of private-sector equity and loan debt in a PPP project is greater than the government’s cost of borrowing • But the government can borrow money more cheaply because the lender is not taking any risk on the project • Which means that government is taking the risk – needs to be added to cost of public procurement • So value of risk transfer in PPPs needs to be taken into account – but difficult to assess • And can the government actually borrow all the extra funds in lieu of a PPP programme? ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (26) Other arguments for PPPs Other general arguments in favour of PPPs: ‘Additionality’, or acceleration of investment → economic growth • Paying for public infrastructure investment through taxes may reduce the economic growth which the investment is trying to promote? ‘Private capital at risk’ = risk transfer, e.g. construction / maintenance • Even if the investors lose their investment, the lenders are still at risk → Third-party due diligence (banks or bond underwriters) • If the project gets in trouble, lenders will help it, to protect their loan Private-sector innovation, and project-management skills (efficiency) ‘On time and on budget’ – but this can be achieved without PPP (and PPP costs increase during bid stage anyway) Means that maintenance is actually done • Transfer of maintenance / lifecycle risk to private sector • Probably one of the best arguments for PPPs Public-sector benefits: • Improves procurement skills – e.g. London Olympics sites • Forces public-sector into long-term thinking and budgeting • ‘Contestability’ – comparing efficiency of public and private sector ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (27) Other arguments against PPPs • Risk transfer? • Valuation of risk transfer is very subjective • Real risk transfer? • Incomplete contract – can’t think of everything in advance • Over-complex – too difficult for public sector to manage, expensive to procure • Contracting Authority has to ensure the public service continues if PPP fails • ‘Privatising profits while socialising losses’? • Distorts choice of project (e.g. rebuild v. refurbish)? • Lack of long-term flexibility? • PPPs and politics: • Union / labour issues • ‘Public service – private profit’ ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (28) How not to do it – Mexico in the 1990s 1989-94: Private toll-toad programme awarded 53 concessions for 5,500 km Investment of ca. $13bn Miscalculation of costs, revenues, and Mexican currency crisis led to collapse of programme by 1994 → failure to complete additional planned 6,500 km Mexican banks left with non-performing loans of ca. $5bn Large-scale government bail-outs required – only recently have most of these roads been refinanced in the private sector Causes: • Poor tender procedures, mainly for the benefit of local construction companies, little consideration of long-term viability of projects • Inadequate bid competition (too many projects at once) → high construction costs • Government-owned banks lent with little due diligence • Lack of institutional capacity in public sector, banks, construction industry • Cost overruns from inadequate engineering and design work, failures to secure rights of way, change orders, cost-plus contracts, permit delays • Inaccurate traffic projections and unwillingness to pay, especially by trucks • Failure to complete networks / connecting roads • Poor toll collection procedures and poor control of cash flows • O&M costs underestimated • State governments failed to meet financial obligations… etc. etc…. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (29) Process Plant: Offtake Contract ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (30) Power-generation project Investors Equity Lenders Electricity Gridco / Distributor Project-Finance Debt Power-Purchase Agreement Project Funding Project Company Sub-Contracts EPC Contract EPC Contractor ©YCL Consulting Ltd. Fuel-Supply Contract Fuel Supplier Operation & Maintenance Contract O&M Contractor September 2013 (31) Power Purchase Agreement Power Purchase Agreement (‘PPA’), developed in the U.S, in 1980s, provides structure for PPPs in general Role of the PPA: • Long-term power sale to a distribution company (public or private sector – but if public can be considered a PPP) • Security of revenue for Project Company, enabling it to raise PF debt • Security of supply for the offtaker (power purchaser) ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (32) PPA tariff structure Tariff structure / pricing fixed on signature of PPA Capacity / Availability Charge – set at a level to cover: • assumed operating costs • assumed debt service (which follows from assumed construction cost) • return on equity investment (ditto) - paid even if plant is not despatched (“despatch risk”) - provided the plant is capable of producing x MW of power Energy Charge – set at a level to cover • assumed quantity of fuel (e.g. gas) used, based on assumed efficiency • cost of fuel per unit • other variable O&M costs Other Costs • Other ‘one’ off costs which leads, e.g. to greater maintenances costs • E.g. more than x cold start-ups per annum pay y per start-up Indexation against inflation / exchange rates No compensation for inefficiency – higher than expected • debt caused by construction-cost overruns • outages (availability) • fuel consumption • maintenance costs → loss of revenue and / or penalty payments ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (33) PPA - commercial viability Contracts do not substitute for commercial reality Does the project make commercial sense? • Overall supply / demand for power • Role of the project in the country’s power industry • PPA price v. price charged to users • Comparative cost of the power produced Can the offtaker pay? • Affordability v. price of power sold to the individual user • Transmission losses • General financial condition – may be unstable if power users are subsidised • Privatisation of state-owned offtaker? • State guarantee? ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (34) PPA - deductions & penalties Low initial output • Supposed to be 150 MW but only capable of 100 MW • Either cut Availability Payment by 33% • Or ‘buy-down payment’ – NPV of above; may be covered by penalty from EPC contractor High initial heat rate • Ratio of amount of power generated by x amount of fuel • High rate means will have to use more fuel to generate same amount of power • Either offtaker ignores and Energy Charge is not adjusted • Or buy-down payment as above Low availability • If plant is to be available, say, 325 days a year, but is only available 300 days (e.g. due to excess maintenance) • Capacity Charge is adjusted by 300 ÷ 325 ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (35) Fuel supply Fuel supply agreement • Pricing basis to match power sales • Can Project Company assume “take or pay” risk? • Penalties for failure to deliver? Financing issues: • Source of fuel: • If from a dedicated source who takes risk of supply running out? • If from the market who takes price risk? • Credit standing of fuel supplier • Physical connections (pipeline / road / rail) Is a long term fuel supply needed? • Supply risk • Price risk ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (36) O&M Contract Maintenance may be dome by Project Company Often covered by Operation & Maintenance (O&M) Contract Key issue – how much risk can be passed on to O&M Contractor, especially: • Operating costs other than fuel • Unavailability = maintenance downtime (planned and unplanned) • Cost of maintenance (especially replacement parts) Credit strength of O&M Contractor Positions quite variable between different contracts ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (37) Transport PPPs ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (38) Toll-road concession Investors Equity Lenders Project-Finance Debt Concession Agreement Project Funding Project Company Sub-Contracts Contracting Authority Construction Contract Design & Build Contractor ©YCL Consulting Ltd. Operating Contract Toll-Road Operator Tolls Road Users Maintenance Contract Maintenance Company September 2013 (39) Concession Agreement Parties—Public Authority and Project Company Term—typically long-term (25-35 years): • to enable cost + profit recovery • to transfer long-term risks, e.g. maintenance Key contract provisions: • Allocate responsibilities and risks, e.g. land acquisition, connecting roads • Pre-agreed toll régime, e.g. base tolls + inflation on agreed formula • Output specification (public sector says what is required not how to do it): • Penalty régime: • Service provision / “availability” • Service quality incl. maintenance standards • Accommodate change, e.g. extra lanes • ‘Non-compete’ provisions? • Termination arrangements Most risks/obligations passed down to back-to-back sub-contractors Provides a basis for funding by investors and lenders (equity + debt) ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (40) Should traffic risk be transferred? The more risk transfer to the private sector the greater difficulty in financing projects Traffic risk in a PPP toll-road project raises basic risk-assessment issue: • Can traffic (= toll revenue) risk be transferred to private sector? • Issues with data collection • Long-term traffic projections notoriously unreliable • “Willingness to pay” / value of time saved – difficult to estimate • Public sector generally (and prudently) overestimates • “Winner’s curse” • Traffic growth is a factor of: • General growth in the economy • Local development • The local and national transport network • Not under control of private sector investors / lenders • Transferring traffic risk to private sector may inhibit public-sector ability to manage the network as a whole • “Non-compete” obligations Alternatives are: government support [t.b.d.], Availability-Based Contract, Shadow Tolls ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (41) Availability-based Road Contract Availability payments (similar system to Capacity Charge in PPA) based on fixed monthly payments, subject to deductions for: • Lack of availability: e.g. road closed for accident or maintenance • Poor service provision: e.g. road not kept free of rubbish N.B.: • Does not prevent Contracting Authority charging users tolls for the road • Tolls can even be collected by the Project Company on behalf of Contracting Authority • Retains most of the traffic risk in the public sector – but usage does affect long-term maintenance costs, for which risk with private sector This PFI-Model approach deals with the issue of ‘willingness to pay’ by the users, but not affordability issues for public sector (‘fiscal risk’) ‘Shadow tolls’ are an alternative approach – Contracting Authority pays tolls instead of users – but still may cause affordability problems ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (42) PFI Model: Availability-based ‘Accommodation’ Projects ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (43) PFI Model – social infrastructure Investors Equity Lenders Contracting Authority Project-Finance Debt PPP Contract Project Funding Project Company Sub-Contracts Construction Contract Design & Build Contractor ©YCL Consulting Ltd. Maintenance Contract Maintenance Company Services Contract (e.g. cleaning, catering, security) Services Company September 2013 (44) PFI schools projects The British PFI programme is the world’s largest PPP programme: • approx. 700 projects signed, which approx 650 are operational; • total capital value approx. £55 billion (≈ US$80 billion). U.K. Department for Education’s projects (mainly schools) have been a major part of the total PFI programme: • approx. 170 projects signed; • total value approx. £8 billion (≈ US$13 billion). Individual school projects too small to be economic as a PPP: ∴ mostly for ‘grouped’ schools projects: can be 20 or more schools in one project – so U.K. has more individual school projects than any other type of PPP. N.B.: A school is just one type of ‘accommodation’ PPP project in the social infrastructure sector: same principles can apply to, e.g., hospital, prison, offices. And same ‘Availability-based’ Contract can be used for other sectors, e.g. roads (instead of a Concession or ‘Shadow Toll’ contract). ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (45) How to structure a PPP school project? Two basic types of PPP: • usage-based, e.g. toll road • output- and availability-based, e.g. power station. Private sector could take usage risk for public-sector schools, but: • usage depends on general public policies (and could restrict changes in policy; cf. toll roads); • not acceptable in U.K. for private sector to provide teaching in public schools, only school buildings. Or private sector could build a school, hand over to public sector, and then walk away, with public sector making deferred payment? • transfers construction risk but otherwise is just a simple loan; • considered public-sector debt from completion of construction; • has been used in some European countries but not U.K. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (46) Output- / availability-based contract? Typical power-station PPP pays according to: • output: can the power station generate x MW of power? • availability: can the power station produce its full output as and when required (i.e. is it available)? • throughput: payment for fuel use (not relevant for a school!). Investors in a PPP power station are not told how to build or maintain it: • design, construction and operation are at their risk; • just has to be available to produce the agreed output (x MW). Output / availability are easy to measure for a power station • but can they be measured for a school? • output specification cannot be a single measure (e.g. number of megawatts); • availability is not ‘on-off’ like a power station. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (47) Output specification Much more complex than a power station: Construction output – schools must have, e.g.: • x classrooms of a certain size • dining room / assembly hall / sports facilities, etc.; • design is not specified by the public sector (other than requirement to meet building standards, etc.); ∴ design of school is proposed by bidders (and differs between bidders) to meet the output requirements. Service output also needs to be specified: • maintaining what has been built and ‘lifecycle’ replacement; • day-to-day services such as cleaning, catering, security: Equipment may also need to be specified, e.g. desks, IT services. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (48) Benefit of output specification? Without output specification cannot transfer risk from public to private sector: • If public sector designed the school any construction / operation problems could be blamed on design, and claims made as in conventional ‘design-bidbuild’ procurement. • Leaves private sector with long-term maintenance and lifecycle risks; → choices such as more cost now and less maintenance later, because have to budget for whole-life cost of the school. ∴ Stimulates innovation by the private sector. • Risk transfer = off-balance sheet for public sector • e.g. EUROSTAT requirement that must transfer: • construction risk plus • either demand risk • or availability risk. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (49) Payment mechanism Payment begins on completion – construction is funded by private sector. Fixed constant monthly payments – ‘Unitary Charge’ (= service fee: not split as for PPA) • Calculated by bidders to cover: • Operating costs • Debt service • Equity return • Partially indexed for inflation Payment deductions for: • Unavailability • Poor service quality ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (50) The PPP schools experience in U.K. An enormous increase in school building. • Difficult to imagine it could have been achieved in another way. Lengthy procurement periods. Projects generally completed on-time and on-budget. • Exceptions relate to solvency of construction sub-contractors, but problems have been absorbed by investors / lenders, not public sector. • However → delays in delivery of completed schools. ∴ Public sector needs to pay more attention to credit quality of major sub-contractors. Design quality is adequate, but little evidence of major innovation. Good level of performance on availability (very limited deductions) Some concerns on quality of services, e.g. cleaning. Concerns on long-term flexibility and the cost of change. Much adverse publicity in newspapers and TV – poor Government communication of the benefits of the PFI programme. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (51) Risk Analysis, Allocation and Mitigation ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (52) Risk allocation Theory: • Project risks should be allocated to the party • best able to manage them, and • best able to bear the financial consequences Dealing with commercial risks in PPP projects: • PPP contract allocates project risks between the Contracting Authority and the Project Company • Sub-contracts move risks from the Project Company to sub-contractors • Insurance ‘plugs holes’, where no party can take the risk ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (53) Contracting Authority and risk Allocation of risk is a VfM (‘value for money’) question: • Key element of the Public Sector Comparator (PSC) [t.b.d.] • Specifically, is it more cost effective for the Authority to retain a risk or pass it to the private sector, i.e. does the private sector price the risk higher (= retain risk) or lower (= transfer risk) than the Authority would? Contracting Authority’s primary objective is delivery of the service ∴ biggest risk is non-delivery Contract penalties / deductions are a crude instrument for ensuring service delivery Contracting Authority does not normally get any financial guarantees / bonding Contracting Authority’s main risk protections are • due diligence before signature • effective contract monitoring • ultimate ownership of project ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (54) Optimism Bias ‘Optimism bias’ • key issue when considering risk assessment for the public sector = tendency to underestimate costs in a public procurement: • Underestimation of construction / operation costs, time to construct, etc. • Optimism may be needed to get approval for project • Little career sanction if the public-sector official gets it wrong • ‘Gold plating’ is further issue with costs of public procurement Much of the risk of optimism bias → private sector in PPP contract (but some risks will be retained by public sector) And PPP procurement itself is not without optimism bias! ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (55) Investors and risk Investors have: • a relatively small equity investment; • with a relatively high return. Ultimately their equity investment is an ‘option payment’: • payment of a lump sum; • gives a right to future profits; • limits their risk; and • gives them the option to walk away from a failed project and lose no more money. Often willing to leave more risk in the Project Company, but constrained by lenders’ requirements Not in investors’ interests to give guarantees to Contracting Authority or lenders as it destroys the value of their option – loses a main benefit of the projectfinance structure ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (56) Lenders and risk Debt is cheaper than equity, so • High gearing (ratio of debt to equity) produces a lower total cost of funding, but • High gearing creates greater risk for the lender Lenders’ return is limited – fixed return over cost of funds – and has downside but no upside ∴ Project risks must be limited – ‘A banker is a man who lends you an umbrella when it’s not raining.’ Lenders want the Project Company to be an ‘empty box’, with risks transferred to other parties, e.g.: • sub-contractors (construction / operation / maintenance) • insurance • Sponsors • Contracting Authority As lenders are most conservative, their attitude to risks is the lowest common denominator and so determines what goes in the PPP Contract ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (57) Risk matrix Risk analysis (by all parties) based on: • Identifying all possible project risks (however remote) • Measuring effect of these risks on project’s ability to service debt • Looking at what mitigations exist in the project’s contractual structure: e.g. are risks passed through to sub-contractors? • Considering whether residual risks are acceptable N.B.: Lenders concerned about low probability / high impact risks: • may require a disproportionate amount of negotiation / evaluation Analysis in blocks, e.g.: • Site risks • Construction risks • Revenue risks • Operating risks • Legal / regulatory risks • Residual-value risks • Macro-economic risks (interest rates and inflation) • Political risks (other than legal/regulatory) [t.b.d.] • Private (debt) finance (can it be obtained, on expected terms?) The role of insurance also has to be considered: • Insurance for physical damage and consequential loss of revenue • Political risk insurance [t.b.d.] ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (58) Risk-transfer - outline framework Risk transfer under most PPP contracts follows similar general principles: • Site risks to Contracting Authority • So if the Contracting Authority does not make the site available on time it will have to pay compensation for the delay • Design / construction risks to Project Company • So if the school is completed late or over budget no payments are made and the revenue is therefore lost. • Construction sub-contractor will pay penalties to compensate. • Most operating risks to Project Company: • High opex / maintenance / lifecycle, or payment deductions, reduce net revenues • Usage / revenue risk transfer depends on type of project • Some risks / deductions may be passed down to services subcontractor and O&M / building maintenance sub-contractor. • Macro-economic risks may be shared: • High interest rates reduce revenues (unless fixed or hedged). • Payment mechanism may hedge against opex inflation. • Currency exchange-rate risk depends on revenue currency. • Political risks – legal / regulatory or wider political problems • Mainly to Contracting Authority Insurance covers most force majeure (Acts of God). ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (59) Political risks PPPs need strong political support – important that this is from government and opposition, so if there is a change of government, policy does not change. PPPs also very difficult to negotiate if the Contracting Authority’s staff don’t want to enter into the PPP – unless there is firm political direction. Sub-sovereign risk – further issue if Contracting Authority is not central govt. Investors / lenders may want political-risk guarantees – provided by DFIs, ECAs Political risks originally defined as: • currency convertibility and transfer • expropriation of the project by the state • political violence Newer category of ‘creeping expropriation’ – powers of the state are used against the Project Company. So typical political risk guarantee also covers, e.g.: • contractual payment obligations (including termination payments). • Government action or inaction with a material adverse impact on the project • frustration of arbitration (refusal to recognise award). ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (60) Why do projects fail? Triggers for failure: • Sponsors fail to comply with contractual obligations, e.g. further investment; • Sponsors’ inability to raise finance • Construction sub-contractor underestimating costs / relying too much on income from equity share / misunderstanding D&B obligations • Underestimation of operating costs / over-estimation of revenues from concessions • ‘Winner’s curse’ / PPP contract renegotiation • Political interference • Abandonment of project by Project Company and Sponsors Causes • Inexperienced Contracting Authority – poorly drafted contracts • Aggressive ‘low ball’ tendering, with the aim of renegotiation • Inexperienced Sponsors – misunderstanding of what they are taking on • Government / opposition turning PPP into political football ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (61) Public-Sector Support for PPPs ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (62) Reasons for public-sector support PFI-Model / process-plant projects with a Contracting Authority has support simply because payments are coming from public sector Even Concessions create contingent liabilities, e.g. retained risks and termination payments Otherwise public-sector support may be provided for a variety of reasons: • For financial-market reasons: e.g. lack of long-term finance without some support • For financial-viability reasons: support needed because project would not be financially viable if all its finance were raised on market terms. • For cost reasons: i.e. to reduce the cost of private finance and hence reduce payments by Contracting Authority, or by users. • To reduce political risk: need for clear government cover for political risks ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (63) Types of public-sector support Viability-Gap Finance Subsidy Minimum revenue guarantee (MRG) Debt guarantee Mezzanine debt DFI finance ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (64) The Procurement Process ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (65) PPP Project Cycle PPP project cycle can be divided into 7 main stages from Contracting Authority point of view: Inception: set up project governance; appoint advisers Feasibility Study: needs and options analysis, evaluation, procurement plan Preparation for market: prepare request for proposals; draft PPP Contract Procurement: pre-qualification; negotiation → preferred bidder; signing Construction: monitor; deal with any changes* Operation: ditto Handback: ensure handback condition PPP procurement is far more complex than standard public-sector procurement: • Has to consider long-term operation phase, not just construction • Has to take private finance into account • Needs strong governance to get it right ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (66) Feasibility study Benefits: • information about project costs, and whether these can be met from within the Contracting Authority’s budget or by user fees; • identification, quantification, mitigation and allocation of risks; • a basis for considering how the project will be structured; • identification of constraints which may cause the project to be halted; and • ensuring that the project is developed around a proper business plan. Some typical errors: • gaps in the evidence supporting the argument; • insufficient investigation of demand risks; • excessive risk transfer to the private sector; • costings not derived from market-based information; • proposed financial structure is not viable Initial market soundings (including talking to DFIs) are important ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (67) Feasibility study: contents Key topics: • • • • • • • • • • • Needs and options analysis Project scope Output specifications and performance requirements Socio-economic assessment Technical viability Risk identification and analysis Costings Payment mechanism Financial modelling and sensitivities Value for Money Affordability ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (68) Value for Money UK Treasury: ‘…PFI should only be pursued where it delivers value for money (VfM), where VfM is the optimum combination of whole life cost and quality (or fitness for purpose) to meet the user’s requirement, and does not always mean choosing the lowest cost bid. (Value for Money Assessment Guidance, 2004) How can VfM be achieved? • Programme level = Qualitative evaluation • Is this project inherently suitable as a PPP (see slide 9)? • Project level = Is it VfM to procure this particular project as a PPP? • Can this be demonstrated in quantitative terms (i.e. PPP is ‘cheaper’)? → ‘Public-Sector Comparator’ (PSC) • Procurement level • Is this PPP project procurement being run in a way which will produce best VfM? • Primarily achieved by competitive pressure But even if the project stands up in VfM terms, is it ‘Affordable’? ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (69) Quantitative VfM evaluation A PPP appears to be inherently more expensive than a direct public procurement because its cost of finance will usually be lower because: • Government can borrow more cheaply than the private sector • But Government borrowing does not take risk into account • Risk on Government projects is borne by taxpayers, not lenders ∴ To show that a PPP is better VfM than public procurement in quantitative terms, we need to • compare cost of public-sector procurement v. cost of PPP procurement = ‘Public-Sector Comparator’ (PSC). • N.B.: whole-life comparison – construction and operation costs • to show that, when you allow for risk transfer, the PPP route is better VfM • i.e. the ‘true’ net cost of public procurement is greater than the PFI route Issues: • How to value risk transfer? • When should you do the calculations? ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (70) Affordability PPPs provide finance but not funding Someone – either the public sector or the user – has got to pay over time Public object to paying for something ‘the government should provide’ (e.g. a road) or is ‘provided by God’ (e.g. water supply) If payment for existing infrastructure – e.g. toll roads – has not kept pace with costs → difficult to price new infrastructure properly Social infrastructure likely to rely on public-sector payment (PFI model) → fiscal problems: i.e. cannot be properly afforded within overall budget ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (71) Procurement procedure Typical procurement / review stages: • Pre-qualification (pre-qualify say 4) • Request for proposals (cut down to 2) • Negotiation on proposals • Best & final offer (BAFO) from remaining 2 bidders • Bid evaluation • Preferred bidder • Commercial Close / Financial Close • No substantive negotiation after appointment of PB Bid evaluation: Simple price evaluation not appropriate: • “Two envelope” system: bidders have to pass minimum hurdles e.g.: • technical feasibility • deliverability (including finance) • adherence to risk transfer and other aspects of proposed PPP contract; then open second envelope and the best price bid wins • Single evaluation: Different factors are given a percentage, e.g. cost 40%, technical and deliverability 30%, legal (= risk transfer) 20%, design 10%; bidders scored against each factor and the best score wins • Problems of transparency if negotiations take place after contract award ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (72) Relationship with lenders Important to ensure that bidders have appropriate levels of lender support at each stage of procurement process: • Feasibility study: should include evidence that the project is likely to be “bankable”. Direct discussions with potential lenders, including DFIs, is one way to help establish this. • Pre-qualification: Initial letters of support from potential lenders (other than multilateral DFIs, which cannot support any particular bidder): not legal commitment on the lenders’ part, but lenders usually take such letters seriously. • Initial bid: Evidence of bank support, including a term sheet, but subject to further due diligence and final credit approval • Negotiations: Contracting Authority ideally does not deal with lenders but leaves this to bidder, but realistically some negotiation with lenders may be needed to ensure that project remains bankable • Final bid (BAFO): At this stage lenders should confirm that the terms of their loan are agreed, provide a final draft loan agreement, and confirm that they have received the necessary credit approvals. ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (73) Unsolicited bids World Bank (PPP Reference Guide): …there is a place for genuine and innovative [unsolicited] proposals, but these are the exceptional case. The private sector must put up strong independently analyzed cases for unsolicited proposals at an early stage, before governments are sucked in to supporting projects that are financially weak, high risk, will take up significant human resources of the government, and will likely take a longer than normal time to implement because of these difficulties. Undesirable in early stages of a PPP programme Often fail to produce expected benefits / raise finance / keep to schedule Tie up limited public-sector PPP expertise, so hamper programme development Go for ‘low-hanging fruit’ – the obvious easy deals, no added value Private sector feasibility study is not a substitute for public-sector work – seldom saves money or time Difficult to fit within proper competitive procurement procedure: • Can be done by BAFO prequalification, payment of development fee, bid bonus for evaluation, Swiss challenge (= right to match) – but none are ideal Often linked to corruption ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013 (74) Published 2002 Published 2007 Further information: www.yescombe.com ©YCL Consulting Ltd. September 2013