Institutional Selection in International Relations: State Anarchy as Order Author(s): Hendrik Spruyt Source: International Organization, Vol. 48, No. 4 (Autumn, 1994), pp. 527-557 Published by: The MIT Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2706895 . Accessed: 22/09/2011 20:28 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to International Organization. http://www.jstor.org Institutionalselectionin international relations:stateanarchyas order HendrikSpruyt conIn effect, whatthisquestionasks is why,at varioustimesand in differing individualsand groupsbelieveonepoliticalformratherthananotheris texts, bestsuitedto advancetheirinterests. -Robert Gilpin At the end of the feudalera, a dramaticeconomicchangeoccurred.Localized barterexchangestartedto givewayto monetaryexchangeand translocaltrade. forms century, a varietyof new institutional By thebeginningof the fourteenth had emergedfororganizingpoliticaland economiclife.Sovereignterritorial states, city-leagues,and city-statesall tried to tap into the new sources of economic wealth, particularlylong-distancetrade. Indeed, the city-based politicalorganizationsinitiallydid verywell. In the longrun,however,roughly had fallen city-states and city-leagues bythemiddleoftheseventeenthcentury, bythewayside.In thisarticle,I attemptto answerthe questionofwhythiswas rivals. statesdisplacedtheircontemporary so and charthowsovereignterritorial I argue thatthe sovereignterritorial stateprevailedbecause it provedmore at preventingdefectionbyitsmembers,reducinginternaltransaction effective to other units.It did this in three costs, and makingcredible commitments ways. First, sovereign rulers were better at centralizingjurisdictionand authority.'Consequently,theywere in a betterpositionto preventfreeriding and to graduallyrationalize their economies and standardizecoinage and I thankDeborah Avant,PeterCowhey,Dan Deudney,JoelHellman,ArvidLukauskas,Helen Milner,JohnOdell, JohnRuggie, AlexanderWendt, and the refereesof thisjournal for their commentsand critiques.The researchwas supportedby the Columbia UniversityCouncil for Research in the Social Sciences. The epigraphis fromRobert Gilpin,Warand Changein World Press,1981),p. 42. Politics(Cambridge:CambridgeUniversity state" witheitherthe term 1. In the followingpages I sometimesdenote "sovereignterritorial "territorialstate" or "sovereignstate." These termsall referto a particularformof government beyonditsborders. whereinauthority claimsinternalhierarchyand recognizesno higherauthority in TheEncyclopediaofPhilosophy(New York: For thisdefinition see StanleyBenn,"Sovereignty," Macmillan,1967),pp. 501-5. IntemationalOrganzation48,4, Autumn1994,pp. 527-57 ? 1994byThe IO Foundationand the MassachusettsInstituteof Technology 528 InternationalOrganization weightsand measures. This economic rationalizationcorrespondedwith a makeupof sovereignterritorial greatercapacityto wage war.The institutional states thus gave them competitiveadvantages over other organizational possibilities. to otheractors,was a means whenconfirmed Second,sovereignterritoriality, ofstructuring interunit behavior.2States,or ratherthepoliticaland social elites withinsovereignstates,preferredsimilartypesof unitsin theirenvironment because sovereignrulerscould more crediblycommitthe membersof their organization(throughtheircontrolof freeridingand defection)and because parameters. theirauthority was exactlyspecifiedbyterritorial Third,and as a consequence of the firsttwo conditions,actorsfromother institutionalarrangementsdefected to states or copied their institutional makeup.Displacementof alternativetypesthusoccurredfromthe bottomup as well as the top down-actors "voted withtheirfeet" or copied what they perceivedto be thesuperiororganizationaltype. fromothersystemsof authority differed The principleofsovereignterritorial rule. Althoughinherentin the early medieval attemptsto reconstructthe Roman Empire and the attemptsof the popes to build a Christiantheocracy bothorganizationalattemptslackedprecise was a notionofinternalhierarchy, types-the city-leaguesand territorialspecifications.The newer institutional and thirteenth centuriesthatemergedin thecourseofthe twelfth city-states also differedfromsovereignterritorialrule. The city-statesacknowledged had The city-leagues territorial limitsbutoftenlacked clear internalhierarchy. and fixedborders(thatis, theywere contiguity neither,lackingbothterritorial theylargelywereloose confederations notterritorially specified).Additionally, havingno clear sovereign. This article begins with the premise that the possibilitiesof continued feudalism,a centralizedempire,and theocracyhad all waned by the early The futurelaywiththreenew institutional arrangements: fourteenth century.3 and the sovereignterritorial state.The question the city-league, the city-state, is whydid the last systemof rulewin out. Thus,whilewe oftentalkabout the erergence of the state in termsof increasedtaxingpowers,the formationof and the growthof the state in termsof public ratherthan privateauthority, scale, those are not the featuresof the state thatthis essay will examine.In and sovereignterritorial stateswere all state city-states, essence,city-leagues, or territorial limits.4 Instead,thefocus forms,butnotall had internalhierarchy prejudgesthe issue,since it is an anachronismforthis 2. The term"international"semantically period. had runtheircourseby1300,see arrangements 3. For an argumentthatthesethreeinstitutional Charles Tilly,ed., The FormationofNationalStatesin WestemEurope (Princeton,N.J.:Princeton Press,1975),p. 26. University 4. For a discussionof thevariousmeaningsof the term"state," see J.P. Nettl,"The State as a ConceptualVariable," WorldPolitics20 (Summer1968),pp. 559-92. Institutional selection 529 of this essay is on a criticalfeatureof the modern state: the principleof sovereignty-theprinciplethatauthority is limitedbyprecisespatialtermsand is subjectto no otherauthority. Statedanotherway,authority is territorial and exclusive.The originsofthatprinciple,whichcame to dominateEurope,can be tracedto thelate Middle Ages. We need nowto explainitsdominance. The next part of this article suggeststhat two bodies of literature-new institutional history(NIH) and historicalsociology-can be usefulin analyzing the interactionbetween marketsand hierarchies.Both have analyzed how actors,operatingin the absence of higherauthorityto arbitratedisputesand enforce agreements,try to overcome that difficulty by favoringcertain institutionalsolutions.Historicalsociologyprovidesfor a taxonomyof how actorsin practicehave resolvedthe tensionsbetweenmarketsand hierarchies. The NIH literatureprovides a varietyof tools to explain whyinstitutional arrangements historically have takena particularshape. Moreover,while it is sometimesclaimedthatNIH is bydefinition a post hoc enterprise,I willargue thatthisapproachprovidessome a prioricriteriato suggestwhichinstitutions willbe moreviablein thelongrun. The followingpartsof thisarticlecomprisethe mainbodyof myargument, beginningwith a descriptionof how the old political order-consistingof crosscuttingand overlappingjurisdictionsof feudal lords, church,emperor, and aspiringbut weak kings-proved unsuitableforan emergingprecapitalist economicenvironment.5 The legal climatewas unfavorablefortradegiventhe underdevelopmentof writtencodes, the importance of local customary proceedings,the lack of instrumentally rationalprocedures,and the crosscutting nature of jurisdictions.Economically,commerce sufferedfromgreat variationin coinage and in weightsand measuresand a lack of clearlydefined property rights.Transactioncostswerehigh.6 Newer formsof organization-sovereignterritorialstates,city-states, and city-leagues-were in essence attemptsto solve the discrepancybetween These forms emergingtranslocalmarketsand existingpoliticalarrangements. of organizationwere all, to some degree,the resultof increasingdemandsby the towns to change the existingorder to one more conducive to their preferencesand the resultof politicalrulersseekingto expand theirrevenue and resources. 5. The literatureon emergentcapitalismranges in perspectivefroma neo-Marxistone to a liberaleconomicone, focusingon propertyrightsand individualincentives.For an exampleof the formerperspective, see PerryAnderson,LineagesoftheAbsolutist State(London: Verso, 1974); and ImmanuelWallerstein,The Modem WorldSystem, vol. 1 (New York: Academic Press, 1974). For thepublicchoice approach,see Douglass Northand RobertThomas,TheRiseoftheWestemWorld (Cambridge: Cambridge UniversityPress, 1973); Douglass North, Structureand Change in Economic History(New York: W. W. Norton,1981); and MargaretLevi, Of Rule and Revenue ofCaliforniaPress,1988). (Berkeley:University 6. I definetransactioncosts as the costs of arranginga contractex ante and monitoringand enforcingit ex post. See Thrain Eggertson,Economic Behaviorand Institutions (New York: CambridgeUniversity Press,1990),p. 14. 530 InternationalOrganization This article does not examine the origins of these organizations.The literatureon state formationis vast and diverse,and no attemptis made to engage the literatureon the emergenceof particularsystemsof rule. There is no suggestionthat the territorialstate emerged as an optimal solution to individualpreferences.Rather, I examine why sovereignterritorialstates possibilitiesin Europe. The emphasisis eventuallydisplacedotherinstitutional thusplaced on explainingselectionamongalreadyexistingalternatives. I then compare the account herein to rival explanationsand discuss the largerimplicationsof this article.The most obvious conclusion is that the thatare distinct international systemcan go throughdramatictransformations fromthe less comprehensivechangesin orderingprincipleor the distribution ofpower.7 Two perspectiveson marketsand hierarchies: newinstitutionalist theorymeetshistoricalsociology When do individualswho engage in economic transactionsseek hierarchy? Whenmightpoliticalelitesseek to capitalizeon expandingtheirruleand when not? Those questions are central to NIH and have a direct bearing on institutional relations. changein international But whetheror notNIH literaturecan explainactual politicaloutcomesis a be broughtto matterofdebate.8I arguethatthisapproachcan indeedfruitfully bear on some oftheseissues,providedit is sensitiveenoughto historicalcases; and here,historicalsociologycomesin. The deductiveperspectiveof new institutionalism as contractualagreementsbetween The NIH approachexplainsinstitutions rational individuals.This, of course, need not take the formof a formal contract,but the premiseof thisview is that individualsengage in strategic way, exchange.Individuals,whethertheybehave in an optimizingor satisficing ofinstitutional thattheybelievewillbestmeet structures pursuethe formation 7. This lies in contrastto Waltz's view of internationalsystems.His argumentis that such ofIntemational systemsvaryonlybyorderingprincipleand capabilities.See KennethWaltz,Theory Politics(New York: Random House, 1979), pp. 82ff.While bothorderingprincipleand capability of international affairs, theyalone do notdetermine remaincriticalelementsin anyunderstanding the most fundamentaltypeof change in the internastructure.In otherrealistunderstandings, tional systemis that of unit change. See Robert Gilpin, War and Change in WorldPolitics Press,1981),pp. 39-42. (Cambridge:CambridgeUniversity 8. See Kathleen Thelen and Sven Steinmo, "Historical Institutionalismin Comparative Politics(New eds., Structuring Politics,"in Sven Steinmo,KathleenThelen,and FrankLongstreth, Press, 1992), pp. 1-32; and JamesCaporaso, "Microeconomicsand York: CambridgeUniversity InternationalPolitical Economy: The Neoclassical Approach to Institutions,"in Ernst-Otto Challenges(Lexington,Mass.: Czempiel and JamesRosenau, eds., Global Changesand Theoretical D. C. Heath, 1989),pp. 135-59. Institutional selection 531 thatprotectthemphysically and Traderswillpreferinstitutions theirinterests.9 economically.That is, theywillprefersystemsof rule thathelp themto enter intostablecontractsand thatdo notchargeexorbitanttaxesor fees.Theywill mechanisms be concernedwithex post renegingand will preferinstitutional will From theirside, politicalentrepreneurs that diminishthatprobability.10 seek to capitalizeon gainsfromtradeand willseek to expandtheirrulein order to do so.11They performa roughcalculus aimed at maintainingor expanding theirownpoliticalpositions. Followingthe classic Coase theorem,marketarrangementswill sufficeto costs achieve efficient solutions.However,when transactionand information are not zero, a more hierarchicalformof organizationis called for.In short, institutions can be explainedbymicrolevelanalysisof individuals'preferences and contractualchoices. OliverWilliamsonthusexplainsfirmorganizationby costs.12That is,when individualchoicesto reduce transactionand information transactioncosts are high and propertyrights are ill-defined,then the in a hierarchitheirinteractions actorswillbenefitfromstructuring contracting willbe pursuedto thepoint thatis, hierarchy, cal fashion.Verticalintegration, thatfurtherintegrationincreasesmarginalcosts of expansionover marginal benefits.13 Individualsengagingin commercethus will have reasons to prefermore hierarchywhen this reduces informationand transactioncosts and creates more certitudein their environment.Political entrepreneurswill preferto extend such hierarchybased on a calculation of a varietyof factors.This calculationwill depend on theirresponsivenessto the demands of domestic sucha strategy. actorsand on thecostsof attempting NIH literaturealso forcesus to focuson the consequences of institutional choice. Two facets of institutionalarrangementsare critical:the abilityto preventfreeridingand the abilityto crediblycommit.The abilityto prevent free riding has an obvious internalcomponent. Collective goods will be small or unless there is a underprovidedunless the group is sufficiently 9. For excellentoverviewsof the literature,see TerryMoe, "New Economicsof Organization," AmericanJoumalofPoliticalScience28 (November1984), pp. 739-77; and Beth Yarboroughand Robert Yarborough, "InternationalInstitutionsand the New Economics of Organization," 44 (Spring1990),pp. 235-59. IntemationalOrganization 10. See, forexample,the discussionon renegingbyBeth Yarboroughand RobertYarborough, Cooperationand Govemancein IntemationalTrade (Princeton,N.J.: PrincetonUniversityPress, to limitexpostrenegingin 1992),pp. 14ff.For an exampleof how actorsseek to deviseinstitutions of CaliforniaPress, see CharlesLipson,StandingGuard (Berkeley:University foreigninvestments, 1985). 11. For one accountthatuses such "entrepreneuriallogic" see David Friedman,"A Theoryof the Size and Shape ofNations,"JoumalofPoliticalEconomy,vol. 85, no. 1, 1977,pp. 59-77. 12. See Oliver Williamson,Marketsand Hierarchies(New York: The Free Press, 1975); and Press,1986). (New York: New York University OliverWilliamson,EconomicOrganization of states,see Beth Yarboroughand Robert 13. For an expansionof thislogicto the integration Yarborough, "InternationalContractingand TerritorialControl: The Boundary Question," Economics,forthcoming. and Institutional Joumalof Theoretical 532 InternationalOrganization dominant actor to prevent such free riding.14But it also has external implications:can a particularactorcrediblycommit?That is,to whatextentcan one expectan actorto complywiththetermsof an agreementonce it has been concluded?15I will argue that some typesof organization(particularlythe city-leagues)lacked the abilityto crediblycommit,eitherbecause it was not clear that the negotiatingpartyspoke on behalf of all the membersof the organizationor because the rulersof suchorganizationscould notpreventfree ridingbytheirconstituents. In short,NIH literaturecan be useful in explainingthe preferencesfor It furthermore contributesto explainingdomesticand particularinstitutions. outcomes. international consequencesof institutional Some problems withnew institutionalism Despite the elegant and parsimoniousexplanationsmade possible by this theoreticalapproach,anyextensionof thistheoryfromeconomicorganization to politicalinstitution buildingmustbe made withcaution.As NIH proponents themselvessuggest, economic and political organizationsdifferin some fundamentalrespects. Most notably,the absence of a clear medium of exchange-that is, the absence ofprofitmakingas an evaluativemechanismof therationaleof suchassociation-makes comparisonsproblematic.16 Second, politicalassociationsare based on a varietyof individualmotives: militaryprotection,ideological affinities,as well as economic rationale.17 Individual kings, lords, clergy,and merchantswill have variant sets of preferences.The politicalbargainstruckbetweenthemneed not a prioribe reducible to any particularset of preferences.The resultingorganization cannotbe reducedto simpleoptimalefficiency arguments. Moreover, NIH proponents,because they assume that institutionsare basically rational, run the risk of committinga similar error to that of that functionalist arguments.Namely,theydeduce fromtheexistinginstitution itsdevelopmenthad to takethisparticularcourse:theposthoc,ergopropter hoc is imputedto derivefromthefunctions fallacy.The existenceof theinstitution it performs.NIH assumes a directconnectionbetweenthe preferencesforan thatwould performcertainfunctionsand the actual existenceof a institution 14. The standardargumentis by Mancur Olson, The Logic of CollectiveAction (Cambridge, Mass.: HarvardUniversityPress, 1965). See also Russell Hardin,CollectiveAction(Washington, D.C.: ResourcesfortheFuture,1982). 15. For a brief discussion of some of the issues involved,see Williamson,Marketsand Hierarchies, pp. 20 and 48. 16. Moe, "New Economicsof Organization,"p. 761. 17. For example, Margaret Levi suggeststhat political associations are based on security motives;see Levi,OfRule and Revenue.See also RichardBean, "War and the Birthof the Nation State,"JoumalofEconomicHistory33 (March 1973), pp. 203-21; and Edward Ames and Richard Rapp, "The Birthand Death of Taxes: A Hypothesis,"Joumalof EconomicHistory37 (March 1977),pp. 161-78. Institutional selection 533 from Sometimespreferencesare thendeduced tautologically giveninstitution. performs. thefunctionsthattheexistinginstitution Finally,transactioncostsare oftenimputedpost hoc, as well. Dependingon whethera particularoutcomeoccurred,transactioncostsare suggestedto have been highor low. But as Williamsonhimselfnotes,thisleads to a tautological use oftransactioncosts.18 is warranted. For these reasons,greaterhistoricaland empiricalsensitivity can be Preferencesneed notbe imputed.The fallacyofposthoc rationalization choices thenavailable to the individuavoided by describingthe institutional one can examine als.19Ratherthandeduce preferencesfromcurrentfunctions, the individual'sactual choices amongalternatives.What transactioncostsand reallymean can be made plausible by empiricaldata. crediblecommitments Theyneed not be deduced post hoc. Stated anotherway,new institutionalism needs history.20 which In sum,a microlevelfocuson the contractualnatureof institutions, costs empiricallytakes account of the role that transactionand information choice,can be useful.It illuminatesthereasonsforpolitical playin institutional entrepreneursand merchantsto strike particularbargains. Moreover, it will be arrangements providesforhypotheseson whetheror not institutional successfulin thelongrun.Thus one mightexpectthatinstitutions competitively willbe competitively successfulif theycan preventfreeridingand defection. This abilitywill providethe means to rationalizethe domesticeconomyand costs.Additionally,ifparticularorganizareduce transactionand information tional units can reduce the level of defectionand ex post renegingbetween themselves,then theycan crediblycommitto long-termagreements.If an organizationcannotdo so, thereis good reason to excludesuch an actorfrom sovereignrulersprovidedfocalpointsto thepreferredset ofunits.Historically, Theycould do so because theycould plausiblyspeak regularizetransactions.21 on behalf of theirsubjectsand committhem.In game-theoreticterms,they were able to engagein iterativebehavior.22 of Capitalism(New York: The Free Press, 18. Oliver Williamson,The Economic Institutions 1985),p. 4. explanations,see Robert Keohane, After critiquesof functionalist 19. For briefand insightful Press,1984),pp. 80-83; BrianBarry,Sociologists, Hegemony(Princeton,N.J.:PrincetonUniversity of Chicago Press,1978), p. 169; and Yarborough Economists,and Democracy(Chicago: University and Yarborough,"InternationalInstitutionsand the New Economics of Organization,"pp. 252-55. in 20. Manyof these pointsare also raised in Thelen and Steinmo,"HistoricalInstitutionalism ComparativePolitics." 21. For a discussionoffocalpointsin enhancingcooperation,see Thomas Schelling,TheStrategy Press, 1980). In myusage, however,I do not of Conflict(Cambridge,Mass.: HarvardUniversity associateitwithtacitcommunication. 22. See the discussionof how such actorscan overtakethe elementsin an entireset in Robert Axelrod,"The Emergenceof CooperationAmongEgoists,"AmericanPoliticalScienceReview75 (June 1981), pp. 306-19. For a discussionof the prerequisitesof iteration,see Kenneth Oye, Press,1986),chap. 1. (Princeton,N.J.:PrincetonUniversity CooperationUnderAnarchy 534 InternationalOrganization Two historical solutions to marketsand hierarchy Historically,the relationbetween marketand politicalauthorityhas often taken two forms-imperialorganizationand ad hoc lord-merchantarrangements.Both formscan be understoodwithinthe explanatoryframeworkof NIH. In traditionalempires,most economic interactiontakes place withinthe boundariesof the empire.The geographicalextensionof political authority roughlycorrespondswiththe spatialextensionofthe primarymarket.Accordingto Roberto Unger,"Its mosttangiblefeatureis the overallcoincidenceof AnthonyGiddens arguesthat"imperial economicand politicalboundaries."23 expansion tends to incorporateall significanteconomic needs withinthe domainof the empireitself,relationswithgroupson the perimetertendingto be unstable."24ImmanuelWallersteinsuggeststhat economicallyintegrated into empires.25While zones, that is, world systems,oftenwere transformed such an empiremightrecognizean outsideworld,it is regardedas a periphery withwhichone would deal as a nonequal.26The overarchinghierarchycan be providedby politicalimperialcontrol,as occurredin China, or by theocratic as occurredin India.27 authority, The argumentdoes not hold just fortraditionalempires.Clearly,modern imperialpretensionsoftenhave been fosteredbycoalitionsbetweeneliteswith Economic elites transnationaleconomicinterestsand politicalentrepreneurs. mightseek resourcesor marketsfortheirproductsto whichthe empiregives thempreferentialaccess. Politicalrulersseek empireas a means of revenue, glory,or manpower.28 But, of course, not all economic transactionsfall withinunifiedpolitical control,even thoughsome tradersand rulersmightdesire such outcomes.29 Even in premodernempires,a substantialamountoftrademightbe conducted Moreover,imperialpreferenceswillbe matched beyondtheimperialfrontiers. by other actorswho seek to delimitsuch extension.Indeed, the greaterthe Press,1987),p. 113. 23. RobertoUnger,Plasticity intoPower(New York: CambridgeUniversity German and Japanese programsin Unger places such modernempiresas the twentieth-century thiscategory. of CaliforniaPress, 24. AnthonyGiddens,TheNation-Stateand Violence(Berkeley:University 1987),p. 80. p. 15. 25. Wallerstein,TheModem WorldSystem, An 26. On thispoint,see FriedrichKratochwil,"Of Systems,Boundaries,and Territoriality: InquiryintotheFormationofthe State System,"WorldPolitics39 (October 1986),pp. 27-52. 27. For an overviewofthesedynamics,see JohnHall, Powersand Liberties(Berkeley:University of CaliforniaPress,1985). Press,1986); and JackSnyder, 28. See Michael Doyle,Empires(Ithaca, N.Y.: CornellUniversity Press,1991). MythsofEmpire(Ithaca, N.Y.: CornellUniversity did notfallunderpolitical 29. As Abu-Lughodnotes,manyeconomiczones, and worldsystems, unification.She also notes, however,that unificationcan sometimesreduce uncertaintyand protectioncosts. See Janet Abu-Lughod, Before European Hegemony(New York: Oxford University Press,1989),pp. 208-9. selection 535 Institutional imperialdrive,the greaterthe possibilitythat a balancingcoalitionwill arise againsttheimperialactor.30 that Whencommerceoccursacrossboundarieswithoutpoliticalsupervision, is, when the marketgeographicallyextendsbeyondexistingpoliticalauthorities,thenmerchantsmustrelyon self-help.On the one hand,merchantsmust strikedeals withlocal lords (or kings)to obtain local protectionand trading privileges.Unger termsthis set of arrangements"overlord-peddler"agreepassage,and unobstructed ments.The overlordoffersthetraderlandingrights, protectionin exchangeforcertainfeesor taxes.In essence,tradersmuststrike deals themselves,deals that are ad hoc and subjectto defectionby the local arrangements lord.In NIH terms,merchantshad to tryto create institutional thatlimitedthe incentivesforex post reneging.It was unknownwhetherthe otherpartywould respectthe termsof the bargain.As a result,long-distance tradeoftenwas conductedbymerchantswho were relatedbykinor of similar culturalbackground.31 Clan ties,reputation,and sharedculturewerecriticalto commerce,since such traitshad particularadvantagesin preventingreneging problems.32 and in reducingtransactionand information and marketsgenerallyhas been solvedin twoways. The problemofhierarchy In the imperial logic of organization,political elites mightbenefitfrom expandingtheirauthorityover the relevantsphere of economic transaction. They mightdo so to gain more revenueor tributeor to expand theirpower base. Merchantsmightacquiesce to suchrule as itmightcreatemorecertitude The Roman Empire thus benefitedboth in their market environment.33 emperor and merchant.Similarly,the lamented "barbarian" extensionof Mongol rule over much of the Eurasian continentin factbenefitedtrade by placingEast-West trade routesunderunifiedpoliticalcontrol.Such developof ments reduced uncertaintyby providingprotectionagainst infringement propertyrights,violationof contracts,and outrightpredationby robbersand local lords. Such rule mightreduce transactioncosts by providingforcertain coinage and particularweightsand measuresand by reducingthe amountof legal customs. 30. Snyder,MythsofEmpire,p. 6. Tradein World 31. See Curtin'sdiscussionof tradediasporasin PhilipD. Curtin,Cross-Cultural Press,1984). History(Cambridge:CambridgeUniversity 32. See Janet Landa, "A Theory of the EthnicallyHomogeneous Middleman Group: An InstitutionalAlternativeto ContractLaw," Joumalof Legal Studies10 (June 1981), pp. 349-62; ofLaw: "PrivateInternationalTrade in theShadowoftheTerritoriality Hans-JorgSchmidt-Trenz, WhyDoes It Work,"SouthemEconomicJoumal58 (October 1991),pp. 329-38; and JackCarrand JanetLanda, "The Economicsof Symbols,Clan Names, and Religion,"JoumalofLegal Studies12 (January1983),pp. 135-56. 33. One mightobject thatthisexpansionshould not be perceivedas a contractbetweenruler and ruled.However,ifone assumesthatat least a minimumof quasi-complianceis necessaryfora governmentwill destroyits own basis of tradingsystemto continue,then a purelyextortionist revenueshouldittaxitsmerchantsto thepointthatthereare no incentivesto continueto engagein commercialactivity. 536 InternationalOrganization however,mighthave a negativeconsequence: it might Imperial authority, withinthe empire, exploittraderswho, giventhat the marketlies primarily forexit shortof surrendering theiroccupation would have littleopportunity altogether.Unifiedcontroloverthemarketis thusa double-edgedsword. In a decentralizedlogicof organization,merchantshave to strikedeals with predationbyone lordson an ad hoc basis. This reducesthe abilityoflong-term lord because a merchantcan shiftto another. But it increases protection problems and magnifiesthe uncertaintyand transactioncosts of crossboundarytrade withoutpoliticalprotection.(This mightbe one reason why trade across boundarieswas oftenluxurytrade.High profitmarginscompensated forhighrisksand transactioncosts.) In Europe a thirdarrangementemerged.When trade increasedin the late Middle Ages, imperialorganization,eitherin the formof the Holy Roman Empireor Roman theocracy,failed.But thisdid notmean thatmerchantsnow became had to fendforthemselves.The overlord-peddlerdeals increasingly a of Of these, supervised and routinizedby variety political authorities. in that it created to have long-term advantages proved sovereignterritoriality It reduced freeriding morecertitudein the domesticeconomicenvironment. than the alternatives.Externally,soverand transactioncosts more efficiently eign authoritybecame a focal point around which to conduct international affairs.In short,the success of the territorialstate can at least partiallybe understoodbyitssolutionto thetensionbetweenmarketsand hierarchies. The feudalera: local tradeand barterexchange privatepossesFeudalismessentiallyentaileddecentralizedpoliticalauthority, sion of the means of violence,and the lack of any distinctionbetweenpublic that and privateauthority.34 Those politicalfactorscreated an environment greatlyhinderedcommerce.While goods were produced primarilyfor local consumptionand exchangewas largelyin-kind,thisposed fewproblems.The however,necessitatedsome late medievalexpansionof tradingopportunities, institutional changes. The feudal barriersto trade were varied. First,feudal organizationlacked the absolute exclusionthatwe attachto privateproperty.Instead,continued possession over time,seisin,establishedthe legitimacyof the holder. Since productionconsistedmainlyof agriculturalcommoditiesthatwere tradedby barterand oftentook place in the contextof reciprocalfeudal relations,this was a workable solution. Holdings were embedded in a systemof mutual disputes.Strayer's featuresof feudalismare the subjectsof long-standing 34. The characteristic descriptionis widelyaccepted,and thatis the one I use here. See JosephStrayer,Feudalism(New York: Van NostrandReinhold,1965),p. 13. Institutional selection 537 obligations,and thusone could not easilyconveyanyexclusiverightto a third party.35 Second,giventhatmoneywas scarce,feudalobligationsofnecessityrevolved around in-kindtransfers.36 Indeed, the verybasis of feudal organizationwas centeredaroundthe grantingof land by a highlord or kingto a lesservassal. Lords or knightsof the manordemandedin-kindgoods and servicesfromthe peasants and serfswho workedthe lands, in exchangeforwhich theywere grantedprotection.All such relationswere highlypersonalizedand contextspecific. The legal systemfurtherhindered commercialtransactions.Feudalism evolved into a systemof preferentialbirthand operated as a closed caste systemfavoringthe warrior aristocracy.37 No amount of material wealth betweencommonerand noble. This entailedpreferendispelledthedifference tial judicial proceduressuch as trialby ordeal and combat and judgmentby noble peersratherthanbyinferiors. Clearlysucharrangements did notworkin favoroftheburgherswhosoughtmorerationalmeansofcontractenforcement. The highdegree of localized rule also yieldeda diversity of legal customs.38 Given that even lesser lords had acquired previouslyroyal rightsto pass judgment,so-called banal justice,each localityhad its own legal particularities.39This situationwas onlyexacerbatedby the general absence of written law-with theexceptionofsouthernFrance and Italy,thelandsofthedroitecrit (writtenlaw). Thus northern France,theland ofthedroitcoutumier (customary law),was governedroughlybythreehundredlocal customary codes.40 Transactioncostswere raisedfurther bythefactthatsecularand ecclesiastical lordsused theirown weightsand measures.Indeed, manipulationof such measures could yield tidyprofitsforlocal lords. They furthermore required tradersto use theirmeasuresand weightsat a givenlocation,ofcoursepayinga fee to thelordforsuchuse. By thelate Middle Ages, Englandhad hundredsof 35. Michael Saltman,"Feudal Relationshipsand the Law: A ComparativeInquiry,"ComparativeStudiesin Societyand History29 (July1987), pp. 514-32. See also Marc Bloch,Feudal Society (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,1961),pp. 115-16. 36. Thus, Polanyi definedfeudalismas an in-kindeconomy. See Karl Polanyi, "Primitive and Social Feudalismand theFeudalismofDecay," in George Dalton, ed., EconomicDevelopment Change(New York: NaturalHistoryPress,1971),pp. 141-47 and p. 142 in particular.An indicator of thislocal consumptionwas the itinerancy of kings.Kingstraveledto locationsto claimlodgings and food,to whichtheywere entitledbythegite,theclaimto hospitality fromtheirvassals. 37. Leopold Genicot, "La Noblesse au Moyen Age Dans L'Ancienne 'Francie': Continuite, Ruptureou Evolution?" (Medieval nobilityin ancientFrance: Continuity, break,or evolution?) Comparative Studiesin Societyand History, vol. 5, no. 1, 1962,pp. 52-59. 38. For a good account of the local diversityof law, see Susan Reynolds,Kingdomsand Communities in Western Europe900-1300 (Oxford:ClarendonPress,1984),chaps. 1 and 2. See also Harold Berman, Law and Revolution(Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard UniversityPress, 1983), particularly chap. 13. 39. For a discussionoftheserightsoflocal lords,see GeorgesDuby,RuralEconomyand Country Lifein theMedievalWest(Columbia: University ofSouthCarolinaPress,1968),p. 181. 40. JeanDunbabin,Francein theMaking843-1180 (Oxford:OxfordUniversity Press,1985), p. 277. 538 InternationalOrganization thousandlocal different majormeasures,withperhapsas manyas twenty-five variations.4' Finally,lords mintedtheirown coins. In France therewere perhaps three hundredminters;in Germany,perhapssixhundred.Each Italian townhad its own mint.42 Traders thus had to learn whichexchangerates were operative, what the whetheror not the local lords recentlyhad debased theircurrency, goldvalue of suchcoin mightbe, and so forth. All such mattersmade the conductof anybusinessa highlyspeculativeand transaction sometimesdangerousaffair.In the termsof new institutionalism, and informationcosts were high, and the danger of ex post renegingwas ubiquitous. As longas barterand local exchangeprevailed,none ofthiswas particularly problematic.By the late eleventh and early twelfthcenturies,however,a dramatic economic transformation began to take place.43Wastelands and forestswere cleared, and agriculturalproductionand trade began to expand. This economic revivalhad several causes-decreasing invasions,improved agricultural production,possiblyeven a changein weather.However,themost criticalfactorin this transformation was the role played by long-distance trade.44Trade made increasingdivisionof labor possible.Consequently,many newtownswerefounded,and existingtownsgrewin thewake ofthiseconomic boom. Indeed, many currentEuropean towns trace their foundingto this period.45 The growthoftownscaused a newpoliticalgroupto emerge:theburghersor towndwellers.The existinginstitutions had favoredthe interestsand perspectivesof clergyand feudal lords. The new actors,the townspeople,had little 41. Ronald Zupko, "Weights and Measures, Western European," in Joseph Strayer,ed., Dictionaryof theMiddleAges,vol. 12 (New York: Charles Scribner,1989), p. 582; Witold Kula, Measuresand Men (Princeton,N.J.: PrincetonUniversityPress, 1986), provides a fascinating accountofthevarietyofweightsand measuresand oftheirregulationas an issueofcontention.For a classic discussion of the variation in weights and measures and coinage throughoutthe World Mediterranean,see RobertLopez and IrvingRaymond,MedievalTradeintheMediterranean (New York: W. W. Norton,1967),pp. 11ff. 42. HerbertHeaton,EconomicHistory ofEurope(New York: Harper and Row, 1948),p. 175. 43. Bloch describesthisperiodas thesecondfeudalperiod.See Bloch,Feudal Society,p. 69. The in Carlo Cipolla,BeforetheIndustrial economicgrowthis well-documented Revolution(New York: W. W. Norton,1980); Georges Duby, The EarlyGrowthof theEuropeanEconomy(Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell UniversityPress, 1974); and Jacques Le Goff,Medieval Civilization(New York: Basil Blackwell,1988). 44. See Fernand Braudel, The Perspective of the World(New York: Harper and Row, 1984); Press, 1952). Henri Pirenne,MedievalCities(1925, reprint;Princeton,N.J.: PrincetonUniversity FritzRorig,TheMedievalTown of Pirenne,see Le Goff,MedievalCivilization; For a reaffirmation (Berkeley:Universityof CaliforniaPress, 1969), p. 20; GeoffreyBarraclough,Originsof Modem Germany(New York: W. W. Norton,1984), pp. 4 and 76; and Adriaan Verhulst,"The Originsof Towns in theLow Countriesand thePirenneThesis,"Past and Present122 (1989), pp. 3-35. 45. See Paul Hohenberg and Lynn Lees, The Making of Urban Europe (Boston: Harvard UniversityPress, 1985); and Edith Ennen, The Medieval Town (Amsterdam:North Holland Publishing,1979). Institutional selection 539 influencein thatpoliticalset of arrangements. Thus, coupled withthe rise of the towns,a new set of interestsand ideologicalperspectivesemergedwitha newset of demands.The feudalorder-based on crosscutting jurisdictionsand on ill-defined property rightsand judicialprocedures-did notfittheburghers' mercantilepursuits.Marketexchangeand traderequiredabstractcontractual obligationswithmoneyas a medium.46 The emergenceoftownsthuscreateda dynamicelementin the European politicalsystem.As Georges Duby wrote, "Centralto therevitalizedprincipalities, townsnowheld thekeypositionin the politicalorderthatslowlyemergedfromthetangleoffeudalrelations."47 Despite the oppositionof the feudal aristocracy, the Germanemperor,and the church,the economic transformation made new political arrangements possible. Most accountsargue thatthe possibilitiesof continuedfeudalism,a centralizedempire,and theocracyhad waned bytheearlyfourteenth century.48 The futurelay withthree new institutionalinnovations:the city-league,the city-state,and the sovereignterritorialstate. All three responded in some degree to the demands of commercialactors,that is, of the townspeople. statesemergedparticularly in England and France,while Sovereignterritorial city-states graduallyarose out of the roughlytwo hundredto threehundred independentcommunesof Italy. Germanybecame the primarylocation of whichunitedto curtailpredationbythelords. city-leagues, All three were able to respond to the precapitalistopportunitiesof the period.It is thusa mistaketo arguethatsovereignterritorial statessupplanted feudal organizationin a linear and sequential way. All three institutional arrangements-city-league, city-state,and sovereignterritorialstate-could mobilize more resources than could traditionalfeudal organization.The questionis notwhyterritorial statesreplacedfeudalismbutwhytheyultimately managedto displacetheircontemporary competitors. In short, until the late Middle Ages, European political development differedlittlefromthat elsewhere.Decentralized politicalauthoritynecessitated ad hoc bargainsand relianceon self-helpby social actors.Alternatively, both emperorand pope attemptedto reestablishimperialorganization.In Europe none of these possibilities-feudallordships,empire,or theocracyeventuallycarried the day. Instead, the dramaticeconomic change led to institutional innovationunique to theEuropean historicalexperience. We mightconjecturethat the new institutionthatwould ultimatelyprove most successfulwould be the one that could lessen the problemsof feudal particularismthe most. A successfulinstitutionwould have to reduce the 46. For a discussion of the significantimplicationsof that transition,see Marvin Becker, MedievalItaly(Bloomington:Indiana University Press,1981). 47. Duby, The Early Growthof theEuropean Economy,p. 252. For a similarview, see John Morrall,PoliticalThought in MedievalTimes(Toronto:University ofTorontoPress,1980),p. 42. 48. For an assessmentthatthesethreeinstitutional arrangements indeedhad cometo theend of theirprimacyby 1300, see Tilly,The Formationof National Statesin Western Europe,p. 26; and Morrall,PoliticalThought in MedievalTimes. 540 InternationalOrganization number of crosscuttingand rival jurisdictions.By centralizingjustice and authority,it could also reduce defectionby its constituents.Furthermore, wouldreducethenumberoflegal codes, standardizejudicial internalhierarchy procedure,and providefor an appeals process. In the economic sphere,an organization'ssuccessmightbe measuredbythe centralizationof coinage and ofweightsand measures.Consequently,ifone acceptsthat thestandardization of laws,weightsand measures,and coinage are at least some standardizations of theprerequisitesfora moderneconomy,thenwe have a prioriindicatorsof success. Furthermore,given that European trade would be transboundary that could a prioribe specifiedas an institution trade,a successfulinstitution could crediblycommitto internationalagreements.Of the new institutional typesthatemergedin the late Middle Ages,whichperformedthese functions in thecourseofthenextcenturies? mostsuccessfully Rivalryand selectionamongthenew possibilities institutional Sovereign territorialrule The possibility ofunifiedpoliticalcontrolovertheprimaryarea ofeconomic century. interactions(the imperialsolution)had failedbythe earlyfourteenth The expandinglevel of trade,therefore,occurredacross politicalboundaries. of theirown,such as the Consequently,tradershad to workout arrangements a varietyofpolitical with negotiate developmentofmerchantlaw,49and had to authoritiesoverwhoseborderstheycrossed. theeconomiesoftheirkingdoms Rulers,however,realizedthatrationalizing in own interests. Consequently,theybecame were their trade and facilitating tasks. Internally, politicalauthoriin and international both domestic involved domesticeconomyby ties graduallybecame involvedin creatingan efficient combatingfeudal particularism.Externally,theybegan to create conditions that made long-termiterativebehaviorpredictableand relativelystable. In claimedbyEnglishkings fact,as P. H. Sawyerwrote,"One of theprerogatives centurieswas the rightto regulatemerchants in the thirteenth and fourteenth and commerce."50 One aspect of such regulationwas the attemptto centralizeand regulate coinage. The disseminationof mints(for example,the small duchyof Berry 49. Merchant law is discussed by Berman, Law and Revolution,chap. 11. For a new view of merchantlaw, see Paul Milgrom,Douglass North,and BarryWeingast, institutionalist "The Role of Institutionsin the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant,PrivateJudges,and the ChampagneFairs," Economicsand Politics2 (March 1990), pp. 1-23; AvnerGreif,"Institutions and InternationalTrade: Lessons fromthe CommercialRevolution,"AmericanEconomicReview 82 (May 1992),pp. 128-33; and Bruce Benson,"The SpontaneousEvolutionofCommercialLaw," EconomicJournal55 (January1989),pp. 644-61. Southern 50. The quotationis drawnfromp. 139 ofP. H. Sawyer,"Kingsand Merchants,"in P. H. Sawyer ofLeeds, 1977),pp. 139-58. and I. Wood, eds.,EarlyMedievalKingship(Leeds: University Institutional selection 541 alone had twelvedifferent mints) correlatedwith frequentdepreciationby manyofthemintinglords.51 To combatsuchfragmentation, theearlyCapetian kingsdeclared royalcurrencyto be the onlycurrencyof the French realm.52 Althoughfeudallordscontinuedto mintcoins,theirarea of usage increasingly was limitedto that area immediatelyunder each's control.The numberof mintsdeclined fromroughlythreehundredto thirtyby the beginningof the fourteenth century, the end oftheCapetian reign.53 AlthoughEnglishmintingalreadywas muchmore centralized,the English kingtriedto decreasefurther thenumberofbaronialmints.Moreover,English tradersbenefitedfroma regularcurrencythatwas debased onlyrarely.54 Monarchsalso triedto standardizeweightsand measures.Here the French kinginitiallywas less successful.It was clear to the bourgeois,however,that could ultimately onlya hierarchicalformof government make inroadsin that direction.PhilipV (1316-22) was one of thefirstFrenchmonarchsto regulate weightsand measures, but others continued the policy. Louis XI in the fifteenth Louis XII in thereformof 1508,and FrancisI and HenryII in century, a varietyof edicts in 1540, 1557, 1575, and 1579 all tried to reduce the mind-boggling varietyof measures then used throughoutthe kingdom.55 In England, centralauthoritymade greaterinroads into standardizingweights and measures.Some progressalreadyhad been made beginningin the twelfth century.In 1317,thecrownhad orderedthatthestandardsofLondon be used. Otherorders,such as the statuteof 1389 and the parliamentary legislationof 1413,further declared standardsand specifiedpenaltiesforoffenders. But the movementtoward standardizationreceived particularimpetus during the Tudor government.In the words of Ronald Zupko, "Before the imperial weightsand measuresera began in the thirddecade of thenineteenthcentury, no period in Englishhistorywas as importantfromthe standpointof physical standardsas theTudor."56 and customaryproceduresin the legal fieldalso were tackled. Particularism By themiddleof the thirteenth century, kingshad forbadetrialbycombatand 51. Duby,TheEarlyGrowthoftheEuropeanEconomy,p. 249. 52. For French royaleffortsin thisregard,see Robert Fawtier,The CapetianKingsof France (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1960), pp. 188-91. In general, all royal authoritiestried to standardizeand rationalizethe legal process and bringmore certitudeto economictransactions. See Berman,Law and Revolution,pp. 466-77; Peter Spufford,"Coinage and Currency,"The CambridgeEconomicHistoryofEurope,vol. 2 (Cambridge:CambridgeUniversity Press, 1987), p. 812; and HenryMyers,MedievalKingship(Chicago: Nelson-Hall,1982),p. 319. 53. See Heaton, EconomicHistoryofEurope,pp. 174-75; and WilliamJordan,Louis IX and the ChallengeoftheCrusade(Princeton,N.J.:PrincetonUniversity Press,1979), p. 209. 54. Carlo Cipolla, "CurrencyDepreciationin Medieval Europe," EconomicHistory Review,vol. 15,no. 3, 1963,pp. 413-22. For the stabilityof Englishcoinage,see Duby, TheEarlyGrowthofthe EuropeanEconomy,p. 251. 55. See particularlyKula, Measuresand Men, chap. 22. Also see Elizabeth Hallam, Capetian France987-1328 (New York: Longman,1980),p. 284; and Myers,MedievalKingship, p. 319. 56. Ronald Zupko,BritishWeights and Measures(Madison: University ofWisconsinPress,1977), p. 74. For anotherdiscussionof Englishsuccess at centralization, see Rorig,MedievalTown,pp. 65ff. 542 InternationalOrganization byinsistingon hierarchiordeal.57Rulers triedto decrease local particularism cal appeal procedures and by turningto Roman (that is, written)law for greatercertitude.Roman law not onlyjustifiedsovereignrule,and hence was desirablefromthe king'spositionforthatreason alone, but it also contained WhileEnglishlaw did nottake thesame route, developedtheoriesofproperty. theretoo kingsbegan to rationalizejudicial procedure.As earlyas the twelfth century,HenryII had startedto revolutionize"the systemof law in England primarily byimposingroyaljurisdiction,and royallaw,upon criminaland civil mattersthathad previouslybeen under local and feudaljurisdiction,"in the was wordsofHarold Berman.58One ofthedimensionsofthisroyaljurisdiction dispossessed. This ocgreaterprotectionfor those who were illegitimately curredeven priorto the developmentof such principlesin Roman law on the Continent.59 of theirdomesticconstituExternally, kingsstartedto act as representatives encies.60For example,theFrenchkingclaimedduringtheHundredYears War that only he was allowed to negotiatewiththe English.6'Governmentalso became involvedin regulatingtrade. Accordingto Jacques Bernard,"They controlledall 'lettersof mark'and reprisalsagainstforeignmerchants, strictly and in their place substituteddue process of law.... they also tried to validityand executionof tradingagreements."62 guarantee the authenticity, Gradually,merchantlaw, the systemof law thatthe merchantshad adminiswas replacedbyroyal teredthemselvesin an ingeniousself-helpconstruction, law.63To use Nettl'sterm,sovereignrulersbecame thegatekeepersseparating arena.64 theirdomesticrealmsfromtheinternational thejudicialsystem The processofrationalizing theeconomyand centralizing was a lengthyone. England was initiallymuch more successfulthan France. Still,the latterhad also made considerableinroads into centralizationeven policies of the earlyseventeenth beforeJean-BaptisteColbert's mercantilist rule,which century.In short,fromthe verybeginningof sovereignterritorial the was formally claimedbykingsin thelate thirteenth centuryand throughout p. 467. 57. See Fawtier,The CapetianKingsofFrance,p. 188; and Berman,Law and Revolution, p. 445. 58. Berman,Law and Revolution, 59. R. C. Van Caenegem, The Birthof the English Common Law (New York: Cambridge University Press,1988),2d ed., pp. 44 and 91. by 60. For an argumentthatthe Capetian kingshad formedthe basis forsovereignauthority 1300, see Hallam, CapetianFrance 987-1328, pp. 262, 266, and 308; and Fawtier,The Capetian KingsofFrance,pp. 47 and 189. 61. Aline Vallee, "Etat et Securite Publique au XIVe Siecle: Une Nouvelle Lecture des century:A new reading ArchivesRoyales Francaises" (State and publicsecurityin the fourteenth ofFrenchroyalarchives),Histoire, EconomieetSociete1 (Spring1987),pp. 3-15. Similarlytheking claimedjurisdictionin translocalaffairssuch as piracy.See FredericCheyette,"The Sovereignand thePirates,"Speculum,vol. 45, no. 1, 1970,pp. 40-68. 62. JacquesBernard,"Trade and Finance in the Middle Ages 900-1500,"in Carlo Cipolla, ed., ofEurope,vol. 1 (Glasgow: Collins,1972),p. 314. TheFontanaEconomicHistory 63. Benson,"The SpontaneousEvolutionofCommercialLaw," p. 651. 64. Nettl,"The State as a ConceptualVariable," p. 564. selection 543 Institutional the remnantsoffeudal era, monarchsworkedtowardeliminating preindustrial particularism. Of course,kingsand queens had reasonsof theirown to do so. By providing such goods, they obtained the support of the towns and therebycapital. Moreover,byenhancingthe economicwell-beingof the realm,theyincreased theirownabilityto raise morerevenue.65 The city-league:fragmented sovereigntyand nonterritoriality The city-leaguelies in starkestcontrastto the state.The mostpowerfulof suchleagues was the Hanseatic League, or Hansa, whichconsistedof 160-200 This league did notadopt townsand monopolizedmostofthenortherntrade.66 It had no clear internalhierarchyand the principleof sovereignterritoriality. bordersto markitsjurisdiction.Because of its importance,and no territorial because its organizationwas typicalof manyothercity-leagues(such as the RhenishLeague, the Saxon League, the Swabian League, and others),I will in general. ofcity-leagues takethecase oftheHansa as representative Unlike the situationin England and France, where the interestsof the economycorrespondedwiththoseof theburghers,no monarchin an efficient claimto be a providerofinternalcollective could legitimately centralauthority the objectivesof the others.In such goods in the Hansa. Each townmistrusted transactions remainedunstable.Efforts economic an arena of mutualdistrust, weightsand measuresmet to standardize say, or Bremen, Hamburg, byLubeck, withnoncooperation.Consequently,city-leaguememberscontinuedto use a varietyof weights and measures to their own advantage.67Moreover, to measuresmightvarywiththe distancefrom complicatematterseven further, the pointof origin.That is to say,tradersmanipulatedmeasuresto hide illicit profitmarginsfromecclesiasticalscrutiny. to overcomethislack of collectiveactionand create One wayof attempting greater standardizationwas the demand of the Hansetag (the Hanseatic betweenkingand burghers,see GianfrancoPoggi, The Developmentof the 65. On the affinity Press, 1978), p. 63; Edward Miller,"GovernModem State(Stanford,Calif.: StanfordUniversity mentEconomicPoliciesand PublicFinance 1000-1500,"in Cipolla, TheFontanaEconomicHistory ofEurope,vol. 1,pp. 356 and 369; and Rorig,TheMedievalTown,pp. 58-64. 66. The seminalworkon the Hansa is by Philippe Dollinger,The GermanHansa (Stanford, Calif.: StanfordUniversityPress, 1970). Wernicke gives a good descriptionof the Hansa's formativeperiod and its regionaland local subassemblies.See Horst Wernicke,Die Stddtehanse 1280-1418 (The Hanseatic cities 1280-1418) (Weimar: HermannBohlaus Nachfolger,1983). A good introductionto the historyof the Hansa can be found in G. V. Scammel, The World Encompassed: The FirstEuropean MaritimeEmpires Circa 800-1650 (Berkeley: Universityof CaliforniaPress,1981),chap. 2. 67. On the lack of success in standardizingmeasuresand weights,see Otto Held, "Hansische im Mass und Gewichtswesenbis zum Jahre1500" (Hanseatic attemptsat Einheitsbestrebungen 45 (1918), pp. unityin measures and weightsuntil the year 1500), Hansische Geschichtsbldtter 127-67. 544 InternationalOrganization Parliament)that its regionalassociationsadopt the standardsof one of the dominanttownsof thatregion.The Dutch towns,forexample,were expected to followthe lead of Cologne. But the Dutch, of course,benefitedfromusing and manipulatingtheirown measuresand hence had littlereason to comply.68 to use and who Nor could themanyHanseatictownsagreeon whichcurrency should mintit. The Hansa saw the use of Brandenburgtalers,Lubeck and Prussianmarks,Rhenishguilders,Flemishpounds,and othercurrencies.The various attemptsto standardizecoinage, for example throughthe Wendish unionon coinage,failedmiserably.Relativeto Englandand France,Hanseatic currenciesremainedin disarray.69 Legal codes also remaineddiversethroughoutthe Hansa. Daughter cities adopted the codes of mothercitiesin an ad hoc manner.Some citiesadopted thelegal code ofLubeck,othersacceptedcodes fromMagdeburg,Hamburg,or ofthe decisions and implementation enforcement Furthermore, othertowns.70 of the Hanseatic parliamentwere leftto the individualtowns.Althoughthe such as exclusion,fortownsthatdefected,in Hansa providedforpunishment, general the sanctioningprocess left a great deal of leeway for individual shirking. Given the lack of effectivecontrolof each townover the others,even the major townstended to pursue theirown objectivesratherthan providefor collectivegoods as a hegemonicpower might.Thus, despite the political organizationof the Hansa, memberscontinuedto relyon mechanismsusually associatedwithself-helpsystemsto organizetrade.One such mechanismwas of ordinancesto ensurethe maintenanceof strongfamily the implementation ties. Marryingnon-Hanseaticswas forbiddenand businesspartnershipswith themcould be penalizedbytheloss oftwofingers.7' The distrustamong Hanseatic membersnot only obstructedeffortsfor butat thesame led to freeridingwhenexternalcollective greatercentralization activitywas called for. While the Hansa was sometimesquite successfulin wagingwar,therewas alwaysthe dangerof individualcitiesrefusingto fulfill theirobligations.Thus, the Saxon memberswere slowto supporttheWendish townsin the war withDenmark.72Some of the Dutch membertownswere reluctantto supportthe league againstnonmemberDutch townsin Holland 68. Leo Lensen and WillyHeitling,De Geschiedenisvan de Hanze (The historyof the Hansa), (Deventer,Holland: Arko,1990),pp. 24 and 36. 69. Dollinger,The GermanHansa, p. 207. WilhelmJesse,"Die Munzpolitikder Hansestadte" 53 (1928), pp. 78-96, (The coinage policyof the Hanseatic cities),Hansische Geschichtsblftter contraststhe lack of success in standardizingcoinage and mintingin the Hansa withthe relative success of France. See also Rorig,The MedievalTown,p. 65. Holborn commentson the lack of centralizationand the chaotic currencyconditionsin Germanyas comparedwithEngland. See Hajo Holborn, A Historyof Modem Germany:The Reformation(Princeton,N.J.: Princeton Press,1959),p. 68. University p. 376. 70. Berman,Law and Revolution, vande Hanze, p. 41. 71. Lensen and Heitling,De Geschiedenis 72. MatthiasPuhle, "Der SachsischeStadtebundund die Hanse im Spaten Mittelalter"(The Institutional selection 545 and Zeeland.73Even Lubeck and Hamburg,whichas the Hansa's dominant townswere mostlikelyto preventfreeriding,were at one timebriefly expelled fromtheleague fordefectingfromtheleague themselves. Sovereignactorsdeliberatelyprofitedfromthislack of unity.For example, the Danish kingclaimed thatcertainprivilegeswere due to the Wendishbut not the Prussiantowns,althoughprivilegeshad in factbeen agreed upon for the Hansa as a whole. The Prussiansdrew the incorrectconclusionthat the Wendish towns had defected and had negotiatedprivatebenefitsof their own.74 also made it difficult forthe league to The lack of clear sovereignauthority agreements.Treatieswere negotiatedby crediblycommititselfto international the league as a whole, but individualtownswere able to choose whetherto ratify thetreatyor not.Thus,althoughPrussiantownsrefusedto signthepeace treatywith England in 1437, the Hansa neverthelessinsistedthat English concessionswere due to the Prussians.75When English negotiatorsin the sixteenthcenturydemanded a list of all Hanseatic townsso that theycould claimthespecificprivilegesthattheHansa knowwhichshipscould legitimately had negotiated,the league refused.76 It fearedthatthe crownwould seek to negotiatewithindividualtownsat the expenseof the league as a whole,a not illusorydanger,sinceEnglandstoodto gainbyenticingtownsto defect.77 From its side, the league would occasionally welcome free riding to forinfractions of internationalagreeexonerateitselffromany responsibility ments. For example, when England claimed that membersof the Hansa engaged in piracyand violated agreementsthereon,the Hanseatic League arguedthatit had no controloverindividualtowns.In otherwords,it had no clearmeansto deal withfreeriding.78 The Hansa thus could not crediblycommititselfto long-termiterative relationshipswith other governmentssince it could not controlindividual towns' incentivesto free ride. Benefitsof defectionwould accrue to the individualtown,whereasthecostswouldbe bornebyall. Moreover,theHansa whichmemberswere partof the league, and itselfbenefitedfromobfuscating partners. hence non-Hanseaticsoftendistrustedtheirnegotiating 104 (1986), Saxon city-leagueand theHansa in the late Middle Ages), HansischeGeschichtsbldtter pp. 21-34. vande Hanze, p. 155. 73. Lensen and Heitling,Geschiedenis des Sundzolls" (On the questionof the 74. DietrichSchafer,"Zur Frage nach der Einfuhrung 5 (1875), pp. 33-43. introduction ofcustomsdutiesin thesound),HansischeGeschichtsblitter 75. T. H. Lloyd,Englandand theGermanHanse 1157-1611 (New York: CambridgeUniversity Press,1991),p. 370. 76. Georg Fink,"Die RechtlicheStellungder DeutschenHanse in der Zeit ihresNiedergangs" (The juridicalpositionofthe GermanHansa in thetimeofitsdecline),HansischeGeschichtsblftter (1936), pp. 122-37.See also Lloyd,Englandand theGermanHanse, pp. 294-304,319, and 378. 77. On Englishexpansioninto the Baltic,see Ralph Davis, EnglishOverseasTrade 1500-1700 (London: Macmillan,1973),pp. 16-19. Press,1987). 78. JohnConybeare,TradeWars(New York: ColumbiaUniversity 546 InternationalOrganization Finally,the Hansa did not followthe principleof territorial delimitationof its authority.79 It had no recognizedborders.Consequently,its attemptsto bringnew membersinto the league ran directlycounterto the interestsof sovereignstate actors,posing to themthe same danger as imperiallogics of organization.Indeed, the Hansa acquiredprivilegesin Englandthatexempted itfromparliamentary statutes.80 In short,the city-leaguehad problemswithestablishinginternalhierarchy, and consequentlyitwas less successfulthanstatesin standardizing coinageand centralizingjurisdiction.Externally,it was not able to crediblycommitto internationaltreaties.Moreover,given its lack of clearlydefinedterritorial itwas less compatiblewiththeterritorial unitsin theinternational jurisdiction, system.In the Peace of Westphalia, for example, the princes refused to recognizethe league.81However,individualcitiessuch as Bremen,Hamburg, and Lubeckwereconsideredimperialcities(hence,de factoindependent)and as city-states were allowed to participate.82 The league thereforewas refused noton thebasis ofthetotalmaterialresourcesat itsdisposalbuton thebasis of itsparticularorganizationallogic.The structureof the league was such thatit did notfitthatof an international statesystem:itwas nota liketype. I do notsuggestthatthematerialresourcesoftheorganizationare irrelevant to excludethe Hansa in itsprime.However,a altogether.It would be difficult materialexplanationalone cannotclarifywhyso manysmall actorscontinued as legitimateactors in internationalrelations.Bremen,Hamburg,and many otherswere consideredindependentactorsformanycenturiesafterWestphalia. Whiletheirlimitedresourcesmighthave made themsecond-or third-order playersin international politics,theywereconsideredas legitimate players.83 The demiseof the Hansa, therefore, had severalcauses. First,itwas due to the competitivenatureof the internationalsystemin whichit was confronted by rivalformsof organization.Sovereignstates proved betterat mobilizing their societies and enhancingtheir domestic economies. Territorialunits graduallyencroachedon the independenceof the citiesthatwere membersof theleague. Parallelwiththis"Darwinian"selectiveprocesswerethechoicesof 79. See WernerLink,"Reflectionson ParadigmaticComplementarity in the Studyof International Relations," in ErnstCzempiel and James Rosenau, eds., Global Changesand Theoretical Challenges(Lexington,Mass.: D. C. Heath, 1989),p. 101. 80. Lloyd,Englandand theGermanHanse, p. 375. 81. Krasneris rightin pointingout thatWestphaliais nota dramaticbreakwiththepast. I see it as a codification of practicesalreadyunderwaycenturiesbeforethat.Nevertheless,it does servea useful purpose as a benchmarksignifying that the formationof a state systemwas comingto fruition.See Stephen Krasner, "Westphalia and All That," in JudithGoldstein and Robert Keohane, eds.,Ideas and ForeignPolicy(Ithaca, N.Y.: CornellUniversity Press,1993),pp. 235-64. 82. Hans-BerndSpies, "Lulbeck,die Hanse und der WestfalischeFrieden" (Luibeck,theHansa, and thePeace ofWesphalia),HansischeGeschichtsblatter 100 (1932), pp. 110-24. 83. Structuration theoristsmightframethisin termsofthe systemempoweringonlylike actors. See, forexample,Giddens,TheNationStateand Violence,p. 282. Rephrasedthisimpliesthatactors recognizeotherunits onlyon theirterms-they admitonlyother states as legitimateactors in international relations. Institutional selection 547 individuals to form or join units they perceived as superior modes of organization.84 The Germanprincesthusstartedto mimicthe administrative processes and legal frameworkof territorialstates.85Towns, no longer convinced of the benefitsof membershipin the league, defected to the protectionof territorialrulersor styledthemselvesas independentstates in theirown right-howeversmall theymightbe. But the demise of the Hansa also proceeded along anotherdimensionof mutualempowerment and mutual recognition.The Hansa-nonterritorialin nature,withonly a weaklyestablished hierarchy,and fraughtwith free riding-did not fit a systemof demarcatedstates where sovereignscould crediblynegotiateon territorially behalfofthemembersof theirsocieties. City-statesand fragmentedsovereignty City-statesshared characteristicsof both sovereignterritorialstates and looked somewhatlike leagues in thatthey city-leagues.Internally,city-states lacked the clear internalhierarchyof sovereignterritorialstates. Indeed, CharlesTillydescribesbothsuchurbanorganizationsas fragmented sovereignties.86When the two hundredto three hundredindependentcommunesof northernItaly graduallywere incorporatedinto about a dozen largercitystates,theyweregiveninferiorstatus,roughlysimilarto thatofcolonies.87Such subjugatedtowns,however,retainedmuch autonomy.Accordingto Giorgio were leftto cities-a distribution of power Chittolini,"Large responsibilities thatsome historianshave called a diarchy."88 theinhabitantsofthesubjugatedcitiesdid notenjoythebenefits Conversely, that derived frombeing a citizen of such dominantcities as Venice and Florence.89When threatenedby foreignpowers,the subjugatedtownsoften 84. In otherwords,theyexercisedexitratherthan loyalty.See AlbertHirschman,Exit,Voice, and Loyalty(Cambridge,Mass.: HarvardUniversity Press,1970). 85. For this institutionalmimicry, see Barraclough,Originsof Modem Germany,pp. 279 and 342-52; and Holborn,A History ofModemGermany, pp. 34-36 and 57. 86. Charles Tilly, Coercion,Capital, and European States,AD 990-1990 (Cambridge: Basil Blackwell,1990),p. 21. 87. For the earlyhistotyof thesecommunes,see Daniel Waley,TheItalian City-Republics (New York: McGraw-Hill,1969). 88. The quotationis drawnfromp. 699 of GiorgioChittolini,"Cities,City-States, and Regional States in North-CentralItaly," Theoryand Society18 (September 1989), pp. 689-706. Also see Anderson,Lineages of theAbsolutistState, p. 152; Brian Pullan, ed., Crisisand Change in the VenetianEconomyin theSixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries(London: Methuen,1968), p. 15; and Jean-ClaudeHocquet, "Venise, Les Villes et les Campagnesde la TerrefermeXVe-XVIe siecles" ofthemainlandin thefifteenth and sixteenthcenturies"in (Venice, and thetownsand countryside NeithardBulst and Jean-PhilippeGenet, eds., La Ville,La Bourgeoisieet la Genese de L'Etat Modeme(The city,thebourgeoisie,and thecreationof themodernstate) (Paris: CNRS, 1988),pp. 211-28. 89. For an expositionofthisinternalfragmentation, see Eric Cochrane,FlorenceintheForgotten Centuries1527-1800 (Chicago: Universityof Chicago Press, 1973), p. 65; Eric Cochrane,Italy 1530-1630 (London: Longman, 1988), pp. 46-47; Stuart Woolf,A Historyof Italy 1700-1860 (London: Methuen, 1979), pp. 57 and 63; and Frederic Lane, Venice:A MaritimeRepublic (Baltimore,Md.: JohnsHopkinsUniversity Press,1973), p. 424. 548 InternationalOrganization would favorforeignpowersover theirown dominantcity.The subjectcities Consequentlythey perceivedVenice as "the cityof threethousandtyrants."90 wereusuallygarrisonedbytroopsofthedominanttown. This lack of internalunitycan be seen in the lack of rationalizationof internaleconomies.Althoughmuch researchneeds stillto be done, particularlyon city-statesafterthe Renaissance, the evidence suggeststhat-not unexpectedly,given these divisionsand lack of centralization-weightsand did notoccur late. Most standardization measureswerestandardizedrelatively The lack ofunityalso was visiblein thetensions untilthe eighteenthcentury.91 betweencapitaland subjectcitieson economicmatters.For example,evidence suggeststhatVenice deliberatelykept some industrieson its mainlandfrom developingso as to preventcompetitionwithVenice itself.92 ofthedominant was seen,withthecurrency issues,less diversity On currency citybeing the one usually accepted throughoutthe city-state.Particularly, stablecurrencysystem.93 Venice seemsto have establisheda relatively however,remaineddiverse.Guilds, aristocLegal codes in the city-states, racy, clergy,and the subject towns retained their own legal authority. Jean-Claude Hocquet wrote that Venice "did not dream of issuing an ordinancethatmighthave applied to theentirestate."94 In general,while in the course of the sixteenthand seventeenthcenturies stateswere on theirwayto rationalizingtheireconomies, sovereignterritorial the opposite tendencyseemed at workin Italy.Althoughthe various ruling themselvesintoterritorial had attemptedto transform elitesof the city-states states,theywere largelyunsuccessful.As Michael Knaptondescribes,Venice took "no planned actionto create a moreeconomicallyintegratedregionwith deliberatepolicies to favourfreerpatternsof internalflowof goods."95Italy thus remainedplagued by "the survivalof innumerabletransitduties" and dutiesand internalin sufferedfromthe continuedexistenceof "protectionist barriersto trade,"in StuartWoolfs words.96 Indeed, accordingto manyhistorians,the Italian city-statesrefeudalized. into more inteblocked their transformation Their internalfragmentation grated and rationalizedeconomies. To again quote Woolf,feudal formsof 90. Denys Hay and JohnLaw, Italyin theAge of theRenaissance(London: Longman,1989), p. 261. of the World,p. 289; Cochrane,Italy1530-1630,p. 183; and 91. See Braudel, The Perspective ofItaly1700-1860,p. 208. Woolf,A History Venice(Cambridge, and EconomicDecline in Seventeenth-Century 92. Richard Rapp, Industry Press,1976),p. 160. Mass.: HarvardUniversity Republic,p. 427. 93. Lane, Venice:A Maritime p. 210; and Woolf,A 94. See Hocquet, "Venise, Les Villes et les Campagnesde la Terreferme," ofItaly1700-1860,p. 64. History 95. Michael Knapton,"CityWealth and State Wealth in NortheastItaly,Fourteenththrough SeventeenthCenturies,"in Bulst and Genet, La Ville,La Bourgeoisieet la Genese de L'Etat see Cochrane,Italy1530-1630,p. 9. Modeme,p. 189. For a similarevaluationofFlorentineefforts, 96. Woolf,A HistoryofItaly1700-1860,pp. 52 and 59. See also Cochrane,Italy1530-1630,p. 183. Institutional selection 549 Indeed, tenurebecame "obstacles to the possessionof fullpropertyrights."97 territorialdemarcationbetween such city-statesonce again became amorphous,sincefeudatoriesheld contiguousdomainsacrossborders.98 Externally,however,city-statesbehaved much like sovereignterritorial states.They recognizedformalterritoriallimitsto theirjurisdiction-thatis, they accepted borders-and routinized their diplomatic representation.99 While the subjugatedtownsretainedmuchlocal autonomy,as faras external affairswere concernedthe dominantcitiesrepresentedthe entirecity-state.100 In other words,city-stateshad the means of establishingcredible commitments.101 thecity-states died a slowdeath.While city-leagues Unlike the city-leagues, wereconsidered city-states wereunacceptableto theotheractorsin thesystem, given that theywere legitimatemembersof the internationalcommunity, definedand providedclear focalpointsfornegotiation.Unlikethe territorially at odds with was not inherently the systemof rule of the city-state city-league, circumscribed authority. theprincipleofterritorially however,the city-statessufferedfromsome of the same Competitively, problemsas the leagues, in thattheylacked internalunityand consequently did notcome to wereslowin rationalizing theireconomies.Whiletheyformally an end untiltheirincorporationby Napoleon, theirdecline had begun much earlier. Because sovereignterritorialstates were competitivelymore successful, modelsforinspiration.When political individualsturnedto thoseinstitutional elites recognized the consequences of localism and the lack of economic in theircity-states, rulesof Frederick theyturnedto the territorial integration and CatherinetheGreat as modelsworthyofemulation.102 In sum, some political and social actors will preferinstitutionsthat can in theirinternaland externalenvironments. Specificallyin reduce uncertainty commerce, actors will prefer organizationsthat reduce transactionand didjust information costsand can preventexpostreneging.Sovereignauthority that. Sovereign rulers centralized fragmentedpolitical systemsand thus and domestictransactioncosts.As a consequence,by reducedlegal uncertainty 97. Woolf,A History ofItaly1700-1860,p. 51. 98. Cochrane,Italy1530-1630, p. 14. For similarassessmentsof the returnof feudalism,see Woolf,AHistoryofItaly1700-1860,pp. 17-18; Knapton,"CityWealth and State Wealth,"p. 195; and RuggieroRomano,"Italyin theCrisisoftheSeventeenthCentury,"in PeterEarle, ed.,Essays in EuropeanEconomicHistory1500-1800(Oxford:ClarendonPress,1984),p. 193. RenaissanceDiplomacy(New York: Dover, 1988), 99. See the discussionin GarrettMattingly, firstpublishedin 1955. 100. Eugene Rice, The Foundationof Early Modem Europe 1460-1559 (New York: W. W. Norton,1970),p. 115. see F. H. Hinsley, 101. For the long-rundiplomaticsuccessesof some of the Italian city-states, 2d ed. (New York: CambridgeUniversity Press, 1986); and WilliamMcNeill, Venice: Sovereignty, ofChicago Press,1974). TheHingeofEurope1081-1797(Chicago: University 102. Woolf,AHistory ofItaly1700-1860,p. 85. 550 InternationalOrganization preventingfree ridingand by rationalizingtheireconomies,such systemsof rule were able graduallyto expand the level of resourcestheycould bringto bear againstopponents.Unityand integratedeconomieswereprerequisitesfor successinwar. But sovereignauthoritiesalso reduced the problemsfacingtransboundary trade by providingfor clear focal points throughwhich to negotiate.Such rulers,moreover,could more crediblycommittheir subjects to long-term agreements.Hence stateshad good reasons to preferlike units,thatis, other sovereignterritorial states,in theirenvironment. Consequently,individualshad reasonsto mimicthosesuccessfulinstitutions and to shiftloyalties.Individualsemulatedwhattheyperceivedto be successful in orderto reduceuncertainty and gain legitimacy.103 arrangements A briefcomparisonwithalternativeaccounts and the Hansa lay many No doubtbehindthe declineof the Italian city-states in oceanic shipcauses. Changingtrade routes,technologicalbreakthroughs ping,evenmigrating herring(in thecase of theHansa) have been suggestedas causal variables.This essaydoes notdisavowtheimportanceofthosevariables. Instead, it draws attentionto the internal and external consequences of examinesthe Hansa and the particulartypesof rule.Thus,whileit specifically it means to suggestwhytheyas institutional Italian city-states, typeswere less made themless successful-than soversuccessful-whytheircharacteristics states. eignterritorial Are there alternativeindependentvariables that explain equally well the generalnatureof unitchange in the European systembetweenroughly1300 and 1650? Given the anarchical nature of the internationalsystemand consideringthefrequentoccurrenceof conflictin preindustrial Europe, we do well to ask howtheabove accountsquareswiththeprevalentviewthatchanges inwarfarelayat theheartof stateformation. Much of the discussionof thecauses of thefeudal-statetransformation is at cross-purposes.The questionof whetherwar made statescentersaround the growthin extractivecapacities of government.Changes in warfarefavored larger and more expensive armies, which necessitatedmore taxation and That issue largelyhas been settled.Warfareindeed has rationalgovernment. had a profoundeffecton the growthof governmentand the influenceof That is to say, when "state" denotes "formal governmenton society.104 see Paul DiMaggio and WalterPowell,"The Iron mimicry, 103. On the notionof institutional Cage Revisited:InstitutionalIsomorphismand CollectiveRationalityin OrganizationalFields," AmericanSociologicalReview48 (April 1983), pp. 147-60. My thanksto Guy Peters and Stephen thisargumentto myattention. Krasnerforbringing 104. See, forexample,Karen Rasler and WilliamThomson,"War Makingand State Making: GovernmentalExpenditures,Tax Revenue,and Global War,"AmericanPoliticalScienceReview79 Institutional selection 551 government"there is littledoubt that protractedconflicthas influencedthe size and functionsofpublicauthority. The questionexaminedbythisessay,though,is whydid thisparticularform of state prevail.What preciselyabout a public authority thatwas hierarchical and spatiallydefinedcaused itto survivewhentheothertwotypesof authority, seemed also quite viable? One mightargue that city-leaguesand city-states, because states were superior in waging war, defeated city-leaguesand were absorbed into them.But such an account needs elaboration city-states and specification.For instance,the abilityto wage war itselfmust firstbe explained.To argue thata particularinstitutional form,thatis, the sovereign territorial form,was superiorat war begs the question.Whywas it superior? Most accountsimplythatmilitary superiority was largelya functionofsize, and in so doing,theyneglecttheconsequencesofinstitutional characteristics.105 Some researchershave compared the institutionalefficiency of different territorialstates,by analyzingthe relativeefficiency of similartypesof units. BarryWeingastand Douglass North,forexample,have takena publicchoice approachto investigate whyEnglandwas able to raise capital at low rates,and hencewage war at considerablyless costthanFrance.106 But thepresentarticle is one of the firststudiesof the institutional efficacy of different typesof units, comparingterritorial statesto theircontemporary alternatives. Second, since city-states were at one time as powerfuland resourcefulas sovereignstatesor even moreso, one mightask whystatessurvivedthatinitial period.Indeed, in manycases therevenueof theItalian city-states outstripped thatof the emergingsovereignterritorial states.And ifmoneyis the sinewof power,thenduringthisperiodofmercenaryarmiestheanswerto thatquestion is not straightforward.107 it is said thatmanyItalian townswere Furthermore, able to bringlarge armies to bear, even compared with France: by some (June 1985), pp. 491-507; JohnBrewer,The Sinewsof Power (New York: AlfredKnopf,1989); Michael Mann, States,War,and Capitalism(Cambridge:Blackwell,1988); WilliamMcNeill, The Pursuitof Power (Chicago: Universityof Chicago Press, 1982); Tilly, Coercion,Capital, and EuropeanStates;and BrianDowning,TheMilitary Revolution and PoliticalChange(Princeton,N.J.: PrincetonUniversity Press,1992). 105. Oftenthese argumentsallude to military and economicefficiencies of scale. See Leonard Dudley,"StructuralChange in InterdependentBureaucracies:Was Rome's Failure Economicor Military?"Explorations in EconomicHistory27 (April 1990),pp. 232-48; Bean, "War and theBirth oftheNationState"; and Ames and Rapp, "The Birthand Death ofTaxes." 106. See Douglass Northand BarryWeingast,"Constitutionsand Commitment: The Evolution of InstitutionsGoverningPublic Choice in Seventeenth-Century England,"Journalof Economic 49 (December 1989),pp. 803-32; Northand Thomas,RiseoftheWestemWorld;and North, History and ChangeinEconomicHistory. Structure 107. For example,theDella Scala signoria,comprising Parma,Lucca, and Modena, had a yearly revenueofabout 700,000florinsin thebeginningofthefourteenth Thiswas double thatof century. England at the time.See Reinhold Schumann,Italyin theLast FifteenHundredYears (Lanham, Md.: UniversityPress of America, 1986), p. 116. The revenueof Venice and its Terra Ferma aroundthe middleof the fifteenth centurywas 60 percenthigherthanthatof France-more than double thatof England or Spain. See Braudel, The Perspective of the World,p. 120. See also the estimatesin Knapton,"CityWealthand State Wealth." 552 InternationalOrganization estimates Genoa could raise an army of fortythousand in 1295.108 The Rhenish-Swabian League united about eighty-ninetowns to oppose their feudaloverlordsin 1385. In 1377 a league of southernGermancitiesdefeated againstwhomtheyhad allied,but also the notonlythe CountofWurttemberg, forcesof EmperorCharles IV when he chose to back the count. The Hansa frequentlywaged war with Denmark, England, Holland, and Sweden. In Fernand Braudel's estimate,initiallythe balance swung against territorial Size was an imperfect states.109 predictorof how the Darwinianprocesswould thatinstitutional mightmatterconsidefficiency workand suggests,therefore, erably. Moreover, the abilityto wage war cannot explain why so many small forceis the territorial statessurvived.If thepossessionofconsiderablemilitary only explanation of which units survive,why did Germany-as well as Italy-see the survivalof independentcitiesand miniatureprincipalitiesuntil well into the nineteenthcentury?While city-leaguesand city-stateswere such setbacksdid not lead to theirends as occasionallydefeated militarily, institutionaltypes.The Hansa's decline was slow and not premisedon any withterritorialstatesdid particularmilitarydefeat.Likewise,confrontations not end thephenomenonof thecity-state. the aggregatesize of politicalorganizationis not irrelevantAdmittedly, small townscan hardlywield as muchforceas greatempiresno mattertheir predictorof success.For example, efficacy-butit is an imperfect institutional is sometimesexplainedbyreferenceto the the declineof the Italian city-state size of France and Spain,whichinvadedthe Italian peninsulain the sixteenth century.Sovereignstateswere largerand hence could mobilizelargerarmies and raise more revenue.However,those wishingto pursue that explanation shouldrecall thatthe Republic of the Netherlands,a leadingpowerifnot the hegemon of the seventeenthcentury,had as many citizens as Venice (1.5 million).Similarly,England,withonly40 percentof France's populationand area underitscontrol,was able to matchFrance and Spain muchless territorial quite well. The Republic of the Netherlandsand England were able to fight beforeacquiringempiresthemselves.In empiresand largerstatessuccessfully thatsuccesshas multipleexplanations,myparticushort,whileacknowledging lar emphasis is the effectivenessand efficiencyof particularinstitutional in mobilizingand rationalizingtheirdomesticeconomies.That arrangements in turnis an important factorin determining success. military Consequently,the approach here suggestsanswersto some of the puzzles mentioned above. First, continued internal particularismmight partially 108. On the number of Genovese troops, see Scammel, The WorldEncompassed,p. 161. thousandmen in 1550; see Cochrane,Florencein theForgotten Florencefieldedabout twenty-four Centuries, p. 91. On the Rhenish-Swabianleague, see RhimanRotz, "GermanTowns,"in Joseph Strayer,ed., Dictionaryof theMiddleAges,vol. 5 (New York: Charles Scribner,1985), p. 464. By contrast,the Frenchstandingarmyafterthe end of the HundredYears War in the middleof the fifteenth centurynumberedabout fourteenthousand. oftheWorld,p. 91. 109. Braudel,ThePerspective Institutional selection 553 explain the decline of Florence, Genoa, and other city-states.Second, in thatselectionalso dependson whetheror nota unitis recognizedas suggesting legitimatebyotheractors,we have an explanationofwhysmallstatessurvived. to sovereignterritorial UnliketheHansa, theywerenot logicallycontradictory rule."11 The approach taken here has, therefore,much in commonwiththe work pioneered by North and Robert Thomas, by MargaretLevi, and by others. Nevertheless,there are significantdifferences.First,NIH is susceptibleto particularmethodologicalflaws.This articlehas triedto avoid some of those existingalternative pitfallsby lookingat competitionbetweensimultaneously was an institutions, withoutsuggesting thatanyof thosecompetinginstitutions optimaloutcome.1"'A varietyof factorsintervenesbetweenpreferencesand the creation of institutions.For example, second-ordercollective action Moreover,dominant problemsmaypreventthecreationof such an institution. as theirprimary social and politicalelitesalso need not have overallefficiency emergencerequiresretracing preference.A completeaccountof institutional and the changesin relativepoweramongsocial actorsthat theold institutions enable themto pursue new institutional choices, and analysisof the overall change.That cannot bargainstruckto createcoalitionsin favorof institutional be done withinthe scope of this essay. I have looked only at the relative of simultaneously duringa specificperiod. efficiency competinginstitutions selectionother Second,thisarticledrawsattentionto aspectsof institutional than Darwinian struggles.Competitivesuccess also depends on what actors themselvesfindto be acceptable as a unit.Theyenforcetheirchoices through recognitionof whichtypesof unitscan morecrediblycommitand hence form deals. preferablepartnersin international to avoida tautologicaluse oftransactioncosts,thisarticlehas Third,in trying in a plausibleway. triedto operationalizesuchcostsand crediblecommitments I have definedtransactioncosts as the generalcostsof concludinganytypeof contractin a given economy,ratherthan as the costs between ruler and ruled.112 Fourth,I have extendedtransactioncostsand propertyrightsanalysisbythe suggestionthatthese are heavilyinfluencedbywhetheror not a politicalunit has a clear sovereignauthority who has an incentiveto reduce such costs and provide for protectionof such rights.That is, I have suggesteda specific units. independentvariableto accountforthevariationbetweendifferent 110. This notionof international empowerment also explainswhyAfricanstateshave persisted despitetribaland irredentist movements.For thatargument,see RobertJackson,"Quasi-States, Dual Regimes, and Neo-classical Theory: InternationalJurisprudenceand the Third World," 41 (Autumn1987),pp. 519-49. IntemationalOrganization 111. Northarguesthatthe flawof suggestingoptimality in outcomesexistedparticularly in his earlierwork.See Douglass North,Institutions, Institutional Change,and EconomicPerformance (New York: CambridgeUniversityPress, 1990), p. 7. For a discussionof thisproblem,also see Moe, "New Economicsof Organization." 112. For the latteruse of transactioncosts,see Dudley,"StructuralChange in Interdependent Bureaucracies";and Levi,OfRule and Revenue. 554 InternationalOrganization Beforeconcluding,I mustnote thatI have notexaminedthequestionofwhy states ultimatelyextended across the globe.113The focus has been narrow, I do notclaim lookingonlyat whystatesdisplacedotherEuropean institutions. to have accountedfortheultimatedeclineof MingChina,TokugawaJapan,or other imperialorganizations.However, the logic herein mightbe used to that extendthe argumentin thatdirection.For example,one could arguefirst, exploit no actor could political of discrete jurisdictions, because oftheplurality his or her subjectsto the same extentas imperialrulerscould. That is to say, withina state system,predationis limitedbecause social actors have more opportunityto exit that political systemand to seek refuge and better ofJews oftheHuguenotsand themigration elsewhere.The flight environments fromAntwerpto Amsterdamare but two such examples;while the reasons behindeach reason are complex,clearlybothmovementshad large economic repercussions.Even Frenchabsolutismwas limitedin scope.114 Second, the developmentof the individualstateswas drivenbytheveryfact An isolationistpolicysuch and competitively. thatstatesinteractedfrequently as thatpursuedbyTokugawaJapansimplywas impossible.Competitiondrove innovation.115 internaldevelopmentand institutional Third,one mightexamineto whatextentsuchempireswerecompatiblewith a systemof de jure equivalent actors. Since empires deny others such equivalence,stateactorswouldhave an incentiveto prefersimilarinstitutional elsewhere. arrangements Conclusionand implications Why then did sovereignterritorialstates "win out" over rival institutional forms?The answer advanced here lies along three dimensions.One causal authority Sovereignterritorial efficiency. variablewas competitiveinstitutional rivalsdue to its internalstructure.While provedsuperiorto itscontemporary rivalformsof organizationinitiallymighthave controlledmore resources,in the long run sovereign authorityproved to be better at combatingthe Such rule could take the formof absolutist of feudal authority. fragmentation as in England,but in all governmentas in France or of a king-in-parliament cases authority was centralized.Polities such as the Republic of the Netherlands,whichlacked a formalsovereign,made up forthatlack by the de facto 113. For a comparisonbetween the competitivestate systemand non-European autarkic empires,see Hall, Powersand Liberties;and John Hall, ed., States in History(Oxford: Basil Blackwell,1986). 114. See David Parker,TheMakingofFrenchAbsolutism(New York: St. Martin'sPress,1983), forthe argumentthatFrenchabsolutismwas paradoxicallyquite weak vis-a-visthe multitudeof social actors.Robin Briggsnotes how monarchswere constrainedin the level of debasement,as this would weaken their "internationalposition." See Robin Briggs,Early Modern France Press,1977),p. 44. 1560-1715(New York: OxfordUniversity 115. As JohnHall pointsout,thatargumentalreadyhad been made byGibbon.Hall, Powersand p. 14. Liberties, selection 555 Institutional hegemonyof one city,Amsterdam,whichproduced much of Dutch revenue ran the country.In the long run,however,the lack of formal and effectively centralgovernment hurteven theDutch.1"6 institutionalized In addition,territorialdemarcationof jurisdictionwithinternalhierarchy proved to be an effectiveway of structuringinternationalrelations. By withotherunits,sovereignrulersprovided monopolizingexternalinteractions focal pointsthroughwhichto regularizeinternationalrelations.This second efficiency goes hand in hand withthe first.The less the aspect of institutional the greaterthe abilityto mobilizesocietyand prevent politicalfragmentation, defectionand free riding.This in turnyielded a greaterabilityto commit gains. statescould achievelong-term credibly.Hence sovereignterritorial Third, sovereignterritorialstates proved mutuallycompatible. Indeed, bordersare explicitagreementson respectivespheresofjurisdiction.Statesare Bytheirspatial de jure equivalent,althoughde facto,of course,theyare not.117 delimitation,they recognize that there is no logical necessitywhy such formsof organiauthoritiesshouldencroachupon one another.Nonterritorial zation such as the city-leaguethenor pan-Arabismtodayare logicallyat odds withsovereignstatehood.118 Fourth, once the benefitsof internal centralizationand the abilityof sovereignterritorialstates to engage in longer-termcommitmentsto one or defectto anotherbecame clear, actorsbegan to imitatesuch institutions them. This account of how and whysovereignterritorialstates displaced other institutional typesmightshed some lighton the questionofwhythe sovereign territorial statecontinuesto existgiventhe apparenttensionbetweenspatially definedauthorityand the increasingly nonspatialnatureof the international Put another way, why have states become, and why do they economy.119 unitsof the internationalsystemdespite the continueto be, the constitutive factthatthelevelof economicinteractionhas increasedso much?120 116. For a discussionoftheDutch case, see C. R. Boxer,TheDutchSeabomeEmpire1600-1800 (London: Penguin,1965), pp. 119 and 328; and R. J. Holton, Cities,Capitalism,and Civilization (London: Allen and Unwin,1986),p. 108. see David Held, PoliticalTheoryand theModem State(Stanford,Calif.: 117. For the difference, Press,1989),chap. 8. StanfordUniversity of Islam and statehood,see JamesPiscatori, views about the compatibility 118. For different Press,1986). (New York: CambridgeUniversity Islam in a WorldofNation-States 119. The earlyindependenceliteraturein emphasizingtransnationalrelationsbelow the state rule and the nonspatial level can be read as describingthe tensionbetweensovereignterritorial characteroftheglobal economy.See RobertKeohane and JosephNye,Powerand Interdependence (Boston: LittleBrown and Company,1977). See also Robert Reich, The Workof Nations(New York: AlfredKnopf,1991). Porterargues thatthe state is stillrelevant,but onlyin termsof an ofNations(New York: Free aggregationof sectors.See Michael Porter,TheCompetitiveAdvantage Press, 1990). For the developmenttoward trulytransnationalorganization,see Christopher Bartlettand Sumantra Ghoshal, ManagingAcross Borders(Boston: Harvard UniversityPress, 1989). and Beyond:Problematizing 120. This issue is raised explicitlyin JohnRuggie,"Territoriality 47 (Winter1993),pp. 139-74. Modernityin InternationalRelations,"IntemationalOrganization 556 International Organization This articlesuggestsa partialanswerto thatquestion.Politicalentrepreneursandsocialgroupshadgoodreasonstoprefer a system ofsovereign states: andpredictability inboththeir suchunitscreatedsomemeasureofregularity The principle ofterritoridomestic economiesand in international relations. within whichwassovereign thoseborders, delineated authority, allydelimited whatwas to be "domestic"and what"international.121 Onlythoseformsof thatwerebasedon suchdistinctions by wererecognized politicalorganization otheractors.Despitethe much-lamented existenceof sovereign territorialthatmakes international relations ity,'22it is in facta methodof structuring interactions more predictableand regularized.In game theoreticterms, statescouldplayiterative sovereign territorial games,atwhichotherunitswere less adept,precisely becauseothers'governments couldnotcredibly commit theconfederated natureof city-leagues made themparticularly themselves; suspect. The previousargument fromtheGrotianpositionadvancedby thusdiffers HedleyBullandothers.123 Thatistosay,I do notcontendthatterritorial states butthattheparticular international createa particular internal society makeup of the sovereign of a unit,specifically territorial state,had externalconsethe particular of theunit quences.In the Grotianargument characteristics The Grotianargument largelyare irrelevant. is a sociological one in thatit rules. explainshowunitsactwithin a givensetofintersubjective of the Although lack government clearlyis a fundamental problemof international realistpositionthat relations,I disagreewiththe structural andthedistribution certainpatterns oforderareimposedonlybyhierarchy of of powerin the systemimposescertain Justas the distribution power.'24 behaviorson actors,so the dominanttypesof unithave consequencesfor ina given andconflict. cooperation Indeed,whichtypeofunitgainsdominance who is to countas an international era itselfdetermines actorin the first place. Thus,whichever unitof the typeof unitbecomesthe constitutive at a giventimedetermines tobe an international whomwe understand system andwhomweconsider a domestic international actoroperating underanarchy 121. This issue has been well-describedbyKratochwil,"Of Systems,Boundaries,and Territoriality"; J. L. Holzgrefe,"The Origins of Modern InternationalRelations Theory," ReviewOf International Studies15 (January1989),pp. 11-26; and JohnRuggie,"Continuit and Transformationin theWorldPolity,"in RobertKeohane, ed., Neorealismand Its Critics(New York: Columbia University Press,1986),pp. 131-157. 122. For example,WrightcitesArnoldBrecht'sviewthatthe anarchyof the statesystemis the primarycause of armed conflict:"There is a cause of wars betweensovereignstatesthatstands above all others-the factthatthere are sovereignstates,and a verygreatmanyof them." See of ChicagoPress,1942) p. 896. QuincyWright,AStudyof War,vol. 2 (Chicago: University 123. HedleyBull, TheAnarchicalSociet (New York: ColumbiaUniversity Press,1977). 124. Realists such as Robert Gilpin have suggestedthatthe mostfundamentaltypeof system changeis changein the typeof units, but therehas been littleresearchon whatthe effectsofsuch change are. See Gilpin, War and Change in WorldPolitics,pp. 41-42; and Peter Katzenstein, "InternationalRelationsTheoryand the Analysisof Change," in Czempiel and Rosenau, Global Changesand Theoretical Challenges,pp. 291-304. Institutional selection 557 Sovereigngovernmentworks as a gateactor operatingunder hierarchy.125 keeper. This essay,therefore,providesan empiricaland materialexplanationof a but not explained.Given that facetthatstructuration theoryhas highlighted the natureof a systemneeds to be accountedforby the actionsof its agents (i.e., states),we need to explainwhystatesempoweredonlylike units-other states.AlexanderWendtarguesthatsinceindividualdiscreteunitsare takenas approach... given,"themostimportant weaknessofneorealism'sindividualist is thatitfailsto providea basis fordevelopingan explicittheoryofthestate."126 This essay contendsthattherewere materialreasons foragentsto empower only similartypes of units,thus creatinga structurethat severelylimited subsequentpossibilitiesforothertypesofunits. The notionthateveryinternationalactorhad to have some formof internal of what was hierarchyand externaldemarcationalso led to a determination "private"and what"public."As JaniceThomsonhas shown,actorsclassifiedas system.For example,piracywas privatewere disallowedintothe international fora longtimea perfectly legitimatepolicyforsovereignstates,butitgradually was disallowedbecause itdid notfitthemoldofinternalhierarchy and external demarcation.Were pirates subjects of territorialstates and hence private of theirsovereign?Or were theyactors actorssubjectto the public authority in the state systemand hence had to be weeded who worked interstitially out?127The same held true for mercenaries.Sovereign territorialstates graduallyphased out theiruse.128The use offorcebynonstateactorsdid notfit the territorialmode of authoritywherebyinternationalrelationswere conductedbysovereigngovernments. of internaland externalrealmscontinuesas a constitutive The specification rule of internationalaffairs.It is exactlybecause a state systemis an ordering in anotherstate'saffairs.That is, devicethatone stateis reluctantto interfere withautonomy.Since stateshave been one wayof we have equated sovereignty orderinginternationalrelations,ethnic and irredentistmovementsdefine themselvesas statistin theirintent.With the possible exceptionof Islamic movementsdefinethemselvesin the termsof the internafundamentalism, tionalstatesystemin orderto be recognizedbytheothermembers.Theyclaim ruleofthe international legitimacy based on theiradherenceto theconstitutive system-sovereignterritoriality. betweenunits. 125. This correspondswithwhat Ruggiedescribesas the mode of individuation and Beyond." See Ruggie,"Territoriality Problemin InternationalRelationsTheory," 126. AlexanderE. Wendt,"The Agent-Structure 41 (Summer1987), pp. 335-70 and p. 342 in particular.Ashleymakesa IntemationalOrganization perspective.See RichardAshley,"The PovertyofNeorealism," similarpointfroma poststructural pp. 255-300. in Keohane,Neorealismand Its Critics, 127. See Janice Thomson, "Sovereigntyin Historical Perspective:The Evolution of State ControloverExtraterritorial Violence," in JamesCaporaso, ed., TheElusiveState(NewburyPark, Calif.: Sage, 1989), pp. 227-54. See also Ritchie's account of Captain Kidd in Robert Ritchie, Press,1986). thePirates(Cambridge,Mass.: HarvardUniversity CaptainKiddand theWarAgainst 128. JaniceThomson,"State Practices,InternationalNorms,and theDecline ofMercenarism," 34 (March 1990),pp. 23-48. IntemationalStudiesQuarterly