Lecture 2: Key Concepts in Environmental Economics • Demand (benefits) and supply (costs) • Economic efficiency and markets • Economics and environmental quality • Assignment #1 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Overview Economically efficient management of ecosystems (maximization of social welfare – not minimal energy use or environmental impact – as the basis for making resource allocation choices) Difficulties include valuing complex, adaptive natural systems; pervasive externalities (negative and positive); and uncertainty. Intergenerational and intragenerational equity issues must also be considered. For example, how are alternative uses of land used to produce olives valued? Tropical forest ecosystems? Mangrove swamp ecosystems? 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Demand and benefits Demand, benefits, and willingness to pay Total WTP and marginal WTP Consumer surplus: a measure of net economic welfare for consumers Individual and aggregate (market) demand Measuring economic benefits 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Benefits of an economic activity Consumer surplus equals total benefits (the area under the demand curve from the origin to the last unit purchased) less the total amount paid (the area of the rectangle) at each price. CS is a measure of net economic welfare for consumers, derived from individual or aggregate demand curves for a commodity. If price is $5, consumer surplus is maximized at a quantity of 20, and is ($130 – 100) = $30. Price Consumer surplus at p = $5 $8 $5 $2.50 MB = Demand 0 10/3/01 20 35 50 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Quantity/time period Costs and supply Supply and willingness to incur costs Total vs. marginal costs Producer surplus, a measure of net economic welfare for producers Individual and aggregate (market) supply Measuring economic costs 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Net benefits of an economic activity Net economic benefit (welfare) is the excess of benefits over costs at a given level of output, equal to the portion of the area under the demand curve that lies above the supply curve. At a price of $5, total net benefits to consumers and producers are maximized at q = 20. Note that total net benefits are maximized where marginal benefits and marginal costs are equal. MC = S Price $8 $5 Net Benefit MB = D $1 20 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Quantity/time period Static and dynamic efficiency static efficiency – a resource allocation is efficient if the net benefit from the use of resources is maximized by that allocation. dynamic efficiency – a resource allocation across n periods is efficient if it maximizes the present value of net benefits resulting from the use of resources of the n periods. 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Equimarginal principle Total costs will be minimized when total output is allocated among producing units in amounts such that marginal costs are equalized among the production sources. This principle applies for producing any type of good or service, including pollution abatement. 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Economic efficiency and markets Social efficiency vs. private effficiency Markets and social efficiency External costs External benefits and public goods External costs and benefits as the basis for corrective public policies 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Social vs. private efficiency Economic efficiency: total net benefits are maximized (MB=MC). Private markets may not automatically yield socially efficient outcomes. With external costs, private output will exceed socially efficient output. With external benefits, private output will be less than socially efficient output. 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Points worth noting Open-access resources (common property) as a source of external costs Air, water, and other environmental resources as open-access resources External benefits result from private pollution control activities. Public goods as examples of large-scale external benefits (EQ improvements?) 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Economics of pollution control (or environmental quality) The efficient level of an activity that generates external costs is where MSC=MSB. The efficient level of pollution abatement is where marginal benefits of abatement equal marginal costs of abatement. The economically efficient level of pollution is where marginal damages of pollution equal the marginal abatement costs. Reducing pollution damages, achieving higher environmental quality levels, and reducing output of polluting activities are equivalent ways of analyzing the problem of pollution. 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Economic efficiency in pollution control Net economic benefits (welfare) from pollution control are maximized when marginal benefits of more abatement are equal to the marginal costs of more abatement. Note that the optimal level of abatement depends on the positions of the MB and MC curves, which depend on the type of pollutant, control options, etc. MB, MC ($) a MC of abatement b Net Benefits of Abatement d 0 10/3/01 MB of abatement (reduced damages) q IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Quantity of pollution abatement The efficient level of emissions The efficient level of emissions is the amount where the sum of damages plus abatement costs (total pollution costs) is minimized. This is the amount where MD = MC. The efficient level of emissions depends on the positions of the marginal damage (MD) and marginal abatement cost (MC) curves, which depend on the type of pollutant, control options, etc. MD, MC ($) Marginal damages (MD) d a b c Total pollution costs Marginal abatement costs (MC) 0 v x q z w Total emissions/time period 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz Efficient emissions (continued) The efficient level will change with changes in marginal damages and abatement costs. Enforcement costs will increase abatement costs and the efficient level of emissions. The MC curve reflects minimum abatement costs, which requires marginal abatement costs among sources to be equalized. Static efficiency, dynamic effficiency, and sustainable development 10/3/01 IST Lecture 2 : F. Menz