-- Midterm Elections and Divided Government: An Information-DrivenTheory of Electoral Volatility STEPHEN P NICHOLSON, SANTACLARAUNIVERSITY GARY M. SEGURA, CLAREMONT GRADUATE UNIVERSITY Divided governmentaffects individual choices over how to vote in midtermelectionsbecauseit increasesuncertaintyin the minds of voters. Particularly,divided control of government makes blame attribution more difficultby obscuringcausal connections and reducingthe overall amount of usable information.As a result, we argue that under divided government,voters are less likely to vote for the House candidatenot of the President'sparty.Using both NES and election-specificcontextual data, we examine divided government'seffect on the voters' political knowledgeand candidatepreferencesin all midtermelections from 1978 to 1994, controllingfor well identified factors that shape outcomes in House elections. We find, first, that divided government reduces the amount of politicalinformationheld by voters. Second, divided government helps the President'spartyby loweringthe probabilitythat an individual votes for the out-partycandidate. The 1994 election resulted in one of the more dramatic changes of political fortune. In two years, the Democrats went from winning their first presidential election in 16 years to their largest midterm loss and, more importantly, the loss of control of the House of Representatives for the first time in 40 years. Was 1994 NOTE: An earlierversion of this articlewas preparedfor presentationat the AnnualMeetingof the MidwestPoliticalScienceAssociation,April 10-12, 1997, Chicago,Illinois.Authors'names are presented alphabetically.The authors wish to thank Stacy Gordon, RichardFleisher, PatrickSellars,and the editors and anonymous reviewersfor their helpful comments, and NathanWoods for his effectiveresearchassistance.Remainingerrorsare,of course, our own. Vol. 52, No. 3 (September1999): pp. 609-629 PoliticalResearchQuarterly, 609 PoliticalResearch Quarterly just simply the resultof the known cyclicalpatternsin Americanelectionsor was somethingnew at work? The events of 1994 are consistent with some existing theories of midterm It is not our losses, inconsistentwith others,and open to endless interpretation.1 intentionto add to this. Rather,we wish to examinethe 1994 electionin its political context, comparingit to othermidtermelections of similarand differentcircumstances.Specifically,we want to examine the choices in 1994 as they were perceivedby the voters.What informationcould voters have about the performance of government,the positions of parties, and the effects of both on their lives? How does this level of informationand uncertaintycompare with the choices faced by voters in other midterm elections?What factorsbest explain these differences? We hypothesizethat voters in 1994 differedfrom recent previousmidterm election voters in that they made their evaluationsand arrivedat their decisions on how to vote in the context of unified government.We believe that divided governmentobscures causal connections and increasesuncertaintyso that the overallpropensityto vote againstthe candidateof the President'spartyis lower. We will show how voters'knowledge of partisangovernmentcontrols changes acrossperiodsof unified and divided governmentand, further,demonstratethat these changesaffectthe propensityof votersto punish the President'sparty In so doing, we examine the preferencesand decisions of voters in all midtermelections from 1978 to 1994, controllingfor other well-identifiedfactorsthat shape outcomesin House elections.Finally,we offersome thoughtson the implications of these findingsto issues of electoralstabilityand governance. THE IMPACTOF DIVIDED GOVERNMENTON VOTERS Studies of divided governmentfall into two broad categories:causes and consequences. Scholarsinterestedin causes ask how and why voters produce divided control of the Presidencyand Congress.Some look to how elites, both intentionallyand unintentionally,structurevote choices that produce divided government (Alvarez and Schousen 1993; Jacobson 1990a; Petrocik 1991; Seguraand Nicholson 1995; Wattenburg1991). Othersarguethat voters intentionallychoose dividedgovernment(Alesinaand Rosenthal1995; Fiorina1992). In contrast,researchon the consequencesof divided governmentexplores its impact on public policy (Cox and McCubbins1991; Fiorina 1992; Mayhew 1991; McCubbins1991) and the strategicbehaviorof politiciansin the legislative arena (Ginsbergand Shefter 1990; Kernell 1991). Curiously,this research has seldom asked how unified or divided governmentaffectspolitical attitudes among the citizenry.The only two exceptionswe know of are Bennettand Bennett (1993), who examine the factualinformationheld by voters over time, and 1 For researchaddressingthis event, see Abramowitz(1995) and Klinkner(1996). 610 Midterm ElectionsandDividedGovernment Leyden and Borrelli(1995), who examine state-level economic evaluationsas endogenous to state-leveldivided government.Examinationsof actualbehavior are harderto find. We seek to fill this lacuna by exploringthe question of whether voters are more, or less, likely to punish the President'spartyat the midtermelection based on partisancontrol of the Presidencyand Congress.For example, in periods of unified government(e.g., 1994) do voters attributegreaterresponsibilityto the President and his party?Are voters less likely to hold the President'sparty accountableunder divided government? Thesequestionshave importantimplicationsfor the responsiblepartymodel of government,which assumesthat voters can hold the partyin power responsible for its actions.Some have found supportfor this type of behaviorwith regard to economicvoting (Fiorina1981), but othershave found the electorateunableto meet the demands necessaryto engage in this behavior(e.g., Converse 1964). Here, we explore whether during unified government, voters more closely approximatethe behaviorneeded to sustaina responsiblepartymodel. MIDTERMELECTIONSAND PRESIDENTIAL POLITICS Effortsto explainthe phenomenonof midtermlosses by the President'sparty have contributedsubstantiallyto our generalunderstandingof Americanelections (Alesinaand Rosenthal1995; Campbell1966; Cover 1985; Erikson1988; Jacobson1990a;Jacobsonand Kernell1983; Kernell1977). Explanationsof this phenomenonfall into threebroadcategories. The turnout explanation,generallyreferredto as "surgeand decline" (A. Campbell1966;J. Campbell1993), presupposesno inconsistentvoting behavior on the partof citizens,nor any changeof preference.Rather,part-timevoterswho turned out for the presidentialelection, who Angus Campbellinfers disproportionatelyfavorthe ultimatevictor,fail to turn out in the less salientmidtermyear. Theirvotes, centralto the election of some of the President'sco-partisansin the presidentialelectionyear,are sorelymissed in the midtermelection. In "evaluative" explanations,the argumentis that some voters will vote in midtermelectionsin a mannerinconsistentwith theirvote for Presidentjust two yearsbefore,at the expense of the President'sparty,because of economic evaluations (Tufte1975), the personal(un)popularityof the President(Kernell1977),2 or a desire to balance the ideological composition of the elected branches 2 That Presidentshave systematicallyappeared at the nadir of their popularityas the midterm approachesis an empiricalregularityupon which the theory was built. The effects describedare asymmetric(Kerell 1977), meaning the benefits accruedto a Presidencyfrom a good economy and favorablepolicy evaluationsare substantiallysmallerthan the costs associatedwith the converse. When the Presidenttakes office his popularityand the expectationsof the electorateare invariablyhigh. Declining evaluationsrepresentan aggregatelevel regressionto the mean and should be expected under most circumstances(but see Erikson1988). 611 PoliticalResearch Quarterly (Alesina and Rosenthal 1995; Fiorina 1992).3 The midterm election, then, is driven by the voter'sevaluationof the President,economic conditions, or the desire to achievemoderatepolicy outcomes. A final explanationof midtermoutcomes is providedby Jacobsonand Kernell's(1983) "strategicpoliticians"model, which relies on the sophisticationand awarenessof potentialcandidatesand donors,who makedecisionsaboutwhether to run, or to whom to donate,based on their subjectiveestimationof the probability of winning. This estimate, in turn, is driven by national-levelpolitical forces-macro-economic performance,issues, presidentialpopularity-thereby associatingthese forceswith outcomes.The resultis thatthe President'spartydoes poorly-not because voters are sophisticatedconsumersof national trends but becausepotentialcandidatesand politicalelites behaveas though they were. underDividedGovernment MixedMessagesand theAttribution of Responsibility These three explanationsof midterm losses are not mutually incompatible and each is likely working at some level. Evaluative(and likely strategic)explanations of midtermelection losses are, to a greateror lesser extent, built upon two assumptions.First, voters must hold the Presidentaccountable,or at least politicians,potential candidates,and political elites must believe that they do. Thatis, blame must be attributed-by voters or by potentialcandidates-to the Presidentfor policies and economic circumstancesdeemed unfavorable. But, as Fiorina(1992) has observed, the attributionof blame is tricky in a system of separatedpowers. The Presidentis only a single participantin a much larger structureso the opportunity exists for the attributionof blame to be mixed, with the Presidentpointing his fingerat the Congresswhile the majority there does the reverse.Co-partisans,at the very least, distancethemselvesfrom the President. This is the second critical assumption. For these models of midterm losses to work, voters must draw connections between the President, whom they must blame, and membersof Congressfromhis party. Accountabilityacrosselectoralbrancheswould be enhancedby a responsible partymodel of government,but decliningpartisanshipamong the electorate, coupled with the advantagesof incumbencyand the personalizationof the representative-constituency relationship,make such a model unlikely.In short, partisan conflictbetween the branchesintroducesuncertaintyinto any calculations over the attributionof blame. 3 In Alesinaand Rosenthal's(1995) model of institutionalbalancing,moderatevoters achievemoderate policy outcomes through balancingpartisancontrol of the Presidencyand Congress.The ability to do so, however,is enhanced at the midtermelection when voters' decisions are made under greatercertainty-they know which partycontrolsthe PresidencyWe have expressedskepticism about this theoryelsewhere(Seguraand Nicholson 1995). Nevertheless,the argumentsuggests that moderatepolicy desiresare the drivingforcebehind midtermvoting. 612 Midterm ElectionsandDividedGovernment Dividedgovernment exacerbates theuncertainty problemsin blameattribution. wasproblematic in American [I]fresponsibility politicsevenwhengovernment wasunified,the problemis compounded whengovernment is divided.PresidentsblameCongressfor obstructing crafted whilememsolutions, carefully bersof Congressattackthe Presidentforlackof leadership. Citizensgenuinely cannottell who is to blame,and the meaningof electionoutcomesbecomes confused.(Fiorina1992:109-10) increasingly In a periodof dividedgovernment,partisanshipfailsto bridgethe inter-branch gap when assessingwhom one wishesto hold accountableforthe failingsof government. Furthermore,when governmentis divided, press coverage critical of the administrationis almost certain to be tempered with an "either/or"balance, where the Congressof the other partyis offered-usually by an administration spokesman-as an alternativesource of difficulties.With their focus and format tailoredto politicalconflict,nightlynews and Sundaymorningnetworkpolitical magazineswill, ratherthan offeringcritiquesof policies authoredwith the cooperation of both branches, weigh the merits and demerits of policy positions offeredby each institutionand the partywhich controls it. Prominentpolitical voices fromboth ends of the spectrumwill be audible,competingin the attribution of responsibilityfor all things good and bad. In short, the messages upon which the citizen must rely in formingjudgmentswill be mixed. of MixedMessages CognitiveImplications Divided governmentboth muddies the informationalwaters and, at some level, reducesthe amount of usable information.As a result,it is harderto relate the relativeapprovalor disapprovalof the Presidentand the political partiesto public perceptionsof policy outcomes or economic performance.Under divided government,plausible cases can be made for holding either institution and/or either political party responsible for outcomes. This increase in noise with a decreasein usableinformation,in turn, generatesconsiderableuncertaintyin the minds of voters and potentialcandidatesalike who are approachingdecisions. For the economic voter,blame or creditfor good or bad economic performance is hard to offer.While it is generallyassumed that the Presidentbears the greaterburden, divided governmentmust amelioratethe effects. Similarly,presidential popularityis likely to decline at a much slower rate if the public perceives (or is successfullyconvinced)thatthe apparentfailingsof the Presidentare the productof a hostile Congress.Under virtuallyany circumstances,and holding otherthingsequal, the aforementionedeffectson the Presidentand, by extension, the electoralprospectsof his co-partisansshould be smallerin a period of divided government.4 4 Similarly,for challengersand incumbentsalike, who must decide whetherto run for (re)election, this uncertaintyis equally vexing. For Jacobson and Kerell (1983), quality challengersof the 613 PoliticalResearch Quarterly We do not mean to imply thatnone of the public holds the Presidentresponsible in a divided governmentregime. The Presidentis the focal point of government for most citizens (Lowi 1985) and we would expect that to remainthe case for many people even in a divided governmentenvironment.But the portion of the electorateattributingblame to the Presidentis smallerthan it might be, as is the share of the total blame assigned to the President.This hedging in attributionof responsibilitymay be sufficientto damp the electoralswings we would normallyexpect in midtermelections for any given set of economic and politicalcircumstances. TESTINGTHE INFORMATION EFFECTSOF DIVIDED GOVERNMENT We have arguedthat the presenceof dividedgovernmentaffectsinformation levels among voters, who, in turn, have less informationabout which partyis to blame for whateverdissatisfactionsthey have with government.The effect, we believe, benefits the President'sparty during midterm elections. Beforewe test this hypothesis,we want to demonstratethe occurrenceof the informationeffects that drive our argument.Specifically,we turn now to whether voters really do possess less electorallyuseful informationin periods of divided government. A simple way to test this question is to ask exactlyhow many respondents actuallyknow whethergovernmentis divided (a useful piece of informationthat we shall employ in anothercontext momentarily).Bennettand Bennett(1993) asked a similarquestion.Theirdependentvariablewas a three-pointscale which was the sum of two dichotomies:the correctidentificationof the pre-electionand post-electionHouse majorities.Using 17 regressors,all but one significant,they wereableto explain28 percentof the variance.Withrespectto the effectof divided government,they found that"peoplefind dividedgovernmentconfusing,but unifiedpartycontrolof nationalelectiveinstitutionsboostspoliticalinformation" (76). Our hypothesis is simpler and our measure focused on the pre-election period of interest in this effort.We expect that during periods of divided government,a smallerpercentageof the electoratecan identifywhich politicalparty controlsthe House beforethe election. This is a good questionby which to judge the level of informationsince the answeris both simple and, for the time period of this study,alwaysthe same-the Democrats.5In short, this is a very low highbar over which we have asked the respondentsto jump. President'spartyusuallypreferto sit out midtermelectionswhile good challengersfromthe opposition smell blood and qualify Incumbentsdeciding whether to retire face similar choices and incentives.Butif these potentialcandidatesare less certainabout the tilt of nationalforcesand the prospectsof success, both effectsare almost certainto be damped. 5 We assumethat no one who correctlyidentifiedthe partycontrollingCongresswould be unaware of the President'spartisanidentification.Unfortunately,the NES, to our knowledge, has never asked this question during the yearsof our study. 614 Midterm Elections and Divided Goverment Using data from the National Election Studies for midterm elections from 1978 to 1994, pooled, we comparedthe responses on this question, grouping 1978 and 1994 as unified governmentperiodsand 1982, '86, and '90 as divided is coded one (1) if the pargovernmentperiods.The variableDividedGovernment tisan control of the two elective branchesis divided prior to the midtermelection, and zero (0) if the governmenthad been under unified partycontrol. As is clearlyapparentin Table 1, divided governmentdramaticallyreduces the level of usableinformation.When governmentwas unified, 72.02 percentof all respondentscould correctlyidentifythe Democratsas the partycontrollingthe House. When governmentwas divided,only 38.33 percentof respondentscould performthe same task. That is, over 60 percentof respondentsgot this question wrongin 1982, '86, and '90 despitethe factthat the answerhad been unchanged for 30-40 years prior to the respondent'sinterview.The differenceis statistically significant,with Chi-square=1009.44 and an associatedp-valueof .000. TABLE1 THEHOUSEBYPARTISAN CROSSTAB OF PARTYCONTROLLING CONTROL OF KNOWLEDGE IN MIDTERMELECTIONS: OF GOVERNMENT 1978-1994 Knowledgeof Controlof the House PartisanControl of Government Unified Divided Total No Total Yes N % N % N % 1037 3416 4453 27.98 61.67 48.17 2669 2123 4792 72.02 38.33 51.83 3706 5539 9245 100.0 100.0 100.0 PearsonChi2(1) = 1009.4378 Pr = .000 To see how importantdivided governmentis to producing this difference, we ran a Probitmodel where the abilityto identifycorrectlythe partycontrolling we the House was the dependent variable.In addition to DividedGovernment, control for two predictorsof voter knowledge. First, Levelof Informationis the NES interviewer'sassessmentof the respondent'spoliticalknowledge, a variable found elsewhereto be both reliableand valid (Bartels1996). Second, Partisanis coded one (1) for both weak and strong partisanidentifiersand coded zero (0) for Independentsand independentLeaners(towardone of the majorparties).We estimatedmodels for all NES respondents,as well as for only those respondents who voted. In Table2, the model examiningall respondentspredicts72.7 percentof the cases correctly,and has a ProportionalReductionof Error(Lambda-p)of .433. Not surprisingly,those respondentsthe interviewerassessedas politicallyknowledgeableand strongpartisanswere likely to get it right,and the effectsarehighly 615 PoliticalResearch Quarterly TABLE 2 PROBITCOEFFICIENTS ESTIMATING OF RESPONDENTS EFFECTSON THELIKELIHOOD KNOWINGPARTISAN CONTROLOF THEHOUSEOF REPRESENTATIVES BEFORE MIDTERM ELECTIONS: 1978-1994 Variable All Respondents Partisan MidtermVotersOnly .193*** (.033) -.984* * Divided Government (.030) .131** (.045) -1.104*** (.046) Levelof Information .555*** (.015) .508*** (.024) Constant -.485*** (.036) -.148* (.063) N 9164 Chi Square 2729.81 .000 Significance PercentPredictedCorrectly 4334 72.7 PRE(Lambda-p) .433 1085.91 .000 73.4 .246 *Significantat p < = .05 **Significantat p < = .01 ***Significantat p < = .001 significant.But more to our point, even when we control for these obvious and powerful predictors,DividedGovernmentstill suppresses the level of information-more respondentsget it wrong. When we look at the changes in the predicted probabilitiesassociatedwith changes in the values of the independent variables,DividedGovernment actuallyoutperformsPartisan.The model predicting the knowledgelevel of midtermvoterspredicts73.4 percentof the cases correctlyand has a PREof .246. The resultswere consistentwith the earliermodel, the only differencebeing a slight reductionin significancefor Partisan,almost certainlya product of the self-selectioneffect of those who turned out. Divided is once againan extremelypowerfulpredictor. Government Sinceprobitcoefficientsarenot directlyinterpretable,it is helpfulto examine the changein the predictedprobabilitiesresultingfromthe model acrossthe range of values of each independentvariablewhile holding all othersconstant. For all decreasedby 37.4 percent the likelihood that respondents,DividedGovernment the respondentwould correctlyidentify the party controllingthe House, ceteris paribus.Among actual midtermvoters, the decreasewas 40.1 percent. In both was clearlystrongerthan strengthof partisanship.Parcases, DividedGovernment more tisanswere 7.6 percent likely to know who controlledthe House among all 6 We thankJ. Scott Long for his innovativeprogramto generatepredictedprobabilitychanges. 616 Midterm ElectionsandDividedGovernment respondents,and only 5.1 percent among actual voters. Not surprisingly,the largesteffect was from the interviewer'sassessmentof the respondent'sinformation level, with an increaseacrossthe rangeof valuesof 73 percentfor all respondents and 67.3 percentfor midtermelectionvoters.Nevertheless,the importance of DividedGovernment to the knowledgeof the respondentis demonstrable. We wanted to check if this informationdeficit appearedin other contexts, perhapsmoredirectlyrelatedto the congressionalelectionsin which we areinterested.We look, therefore,at questionsaboutwhetherrespondentscould recallthe name and partyof both candidatesrunningin their House district.Even in unified periods,only 8.67 percentof all respondentscould recallthe name and party of both candidates.Butwhen governmentwas divided,the numberrecallingboth names decreasedto 5.65 percent.The Chi-square(38.17) was againsignificantat p = .000. The conclusionhere is simple. Duringperiodsof divided government, votersclearlyhave less politicallyand electorallyuseful information. IN CONTEXT ELECTIONS THE 1994 CONGRESSIONAL Having demonstrated,we think, that the amount of useful informationand specificallyinformationrelevantto blame attribution-varies significantly from divided to unified electoralenvironments,we arrive,again, at the starting point of this effort.The 1994 congressionalelections took place in a period of unified government.Under such circumstances,it is our expectation that the attributionof blame for unsatisfactorypolicy or economic performanceis a simpler task for most citizens and reinforcedby relativelyconsistentmessagesto be found in both the media and the public discourse.7The results in 1994, while they might have been worse than we might otherwise have expected for the Democraticincumbents given the contemporaryperformanceof the economy, were driven in part by the unified nature of nationalpolitics. All policymaking brancheswere in the hands of the same politicalparty.8 In order,then, to get a handle on the information-drivenprocessesat work, we hypothesize that at the individual level, ceterisparibus,the likelihood of a respondentpreferringa congressionalcandidatenot of the President'sparty in midtermelections is smallerwhen the nationalgovernmentis divided. Specifically, using the National Election Studies for midterm congressionalelections Our explanationis also consistentwith Jacobson and Kemell'sstrategicmodel, since politicians and donors may also have difficultyperceivingthe prevailingdirectionof nationaltrendsin a poor informationenvironment. 8 Takento its naturalconclusion, we would hypothesizethat, at the aggregatelevel, the size of the midtermloss by the President'spartywill be smallerthan it otherwisewould have been (controlling for economic and politicalconditions)should an election take place in an era of divided government.Such a hypothesisis difficultto test given the relativelysmall N and the inabilityto control for importantfactorssuch as campaignspending prior to 1972. 7 617 PoliticalResearchQuarterly from 1978-94, we will examine the vote choice of respondentsin their district's race for the House of Representatives.9 Controllingfor incumbency,spending, respondent'sparty,presidentialapproval,economic evaluations,and other factors usually associatedwith midtermvoting, we will estimatethe probabilityof voting for the out-party-the party not currently in control of the White House'0-between periods of unified and divided government.In so doing, we take a close look at the 1994 election to assess if it is an "outlier"or consistent with the rhythmsand dynamicsof congressionalelections. The effectsof unified or divided governmentmay not be the same acrossall voters,especiallywith regardto politicalknowledgeand degreeof partisanidentification. First, as for political knowledge, we are curious as to whether this effectvariesacrossrespondentswho know,or do not know,whethergovernment is unified or divided. Those knowledgeableabout the partisancontrol of governmentshould be more susceptibleto the hypothesizedeffectsthan those without this knowledge. However,those with high informationlevels might also be sufficientlypartisanor awareof the issues at hand thatblame attributionremains a straightforward task,even in an era of dividedgovernment.' Therefore,the relativestrengthof the relationshipswe hypothesizewill varyacrossstrengthof partisanship.Those stronglyidentifiedwith a partyareless likely to cross partylines to vote, regardlessof presidentialpopularity,economic evaluations,or the quality of their party'scandidate,thus reducingthe availablevariancefor which the informationenvironmentand the divided controlof governmentmight account. Independentsand partisanleaners should be more subject to the forces traditionallyperceivedto be at work in midtermelections, and specificallythe factors identifiedhere, though their lower level of informationand sophisticationmay confound these effects. 9 Theinclusionof campaign seemedessentialbutlimitsouranalysisto financeas a controlvariable Act.Theelectionof 1974wasexcluded electionsthatpost-datetheFederalElectionsCommission effectof Watergate. documented becauseof thepreviously overwhelming 10Bycustomin thestudyof American refersto the politicalpartynot occupypolitics,"out-party" Thatis, in periodsof dividedgovof theirstatusin the Congress. regardless ing the Presidency, is themajority ernment,theout-party partyin theCongress. 11Anotherconfounding factoris thatthehypothesisdoesnot,strictlyspeaking,requiretheresponof thepolitunaware is dividedorunified.Evenrespondents dentsto knowwhethergovernment icalcontrolof the electoralbranchesmightmanifestdifferences if, as we haveargued,theinforA circumstances. andthenatureof politicalmessagesvariesacrossdifferent mationenvironment in 1982or 1990,forexample,maynot knowthatpoliticalcontrolis divided,butis respondent whilerespondents to conflicting stillsubjected messagesof creditclaimingandblameattribution, environin 1978and 1994couldbe sensitiveto an information unawareof unifiedgovernment We willtest, is the the Democratic that a consistent mentcharacterized problem. party message by is relatedto the size and then,to see if factualknowledgeof unifiedor dividedgovernment strengthof theeffectwe hypothesize. 618 MidtermElectionsandDividedGovernment DATA AND VARIABLES The dataused for our analysisare a mergedset of two distinctcollectionsof information.First, as we have indicated, we pooled responses to the 1978-94 midterm National Election Studies. We then merged this individual-leveldata with contextualvariablesappropriateto the congressionalrace in that respondent'shome district:the presenceor absenceof an incumbent,the qualityof the challenger,the relativespending of the two candidatesinvolved (as reportedto the FEC), and the partisanidentificationof the incumbent and challenger.In addition, we included several dummy variablesto account for the presence or absenceof dividedgovernment,by yearand in total. The resultingdataset, then, containsboth individualand contextuallevel variablesthat collectivelytake into considerationmultiple explanationsof voting at the midterm. DependentVariable The dependent variableis a simple dichotomy of whether the respondent candidatein the district'sHouse election. This variable voted for the "out-party" was obtainedby recoding each respondent'sself-reportedvote, where Outparty equals one (1) if the respondentclaimed to have voted for the candidatenot of the President'spartyand zero (0) if the vote was cast for the President'sco-partisan. Those who report having not voted are-for obvious reasons-excluded fromthe analysis.The resultingN from these five midtermelections is 3636. Variables Independent We control for three individual-levelvariablesof importance:PartyID, IdeApproval.PartyID is a seven-pointscale that incorporates ology,and Presidential both partisanpreferenceand strengthof preference.It is recodedfor each yearin a mannersuch that the highest value (6) correspondswith that of the out-party candidatewhile the lowest value (0) implies strongidentificationwith the President'sparty.Naturally,we expect that strong identificationwith the out-partyis a positive predictorof castinga vote for that out-partycandidate. Ideologyis the respondent'sself-reportedideology,againrecodedin a manner such that the highest value indicates an ideologicalbias for the out-partyand againstthe President.Our reason for including this variablealongside partisanship is that committednon-partisanswho have an ideologicalself-identification and a traditionallypartisanvoting preferencewould be missed by the previous variable.These two variablesarenot collinear,correlatingat only .31, well below the usual thresholdfor concern.We againexpect a positive relationship. Presidential Approvalis the respondent'sassessmentof the President,coded as a simple dichotomywhere one (1) indicatesthe approvalof the Presidentand zero (0) the disapproval.This variableis included to accountdirectlyfor the negative voting thesis previously discussed. Ceterisparibus,we expect Presidential 619 PoliticalResearch Quarterly Approvalto be negativelyrelatedto the probabilitythat a respondentvotes for an out-partycongressionalcandidate.'2 We include two variablesto account for the specific context in which the voting decision was taking place-that is, district-specificvariables:Spending, and Quality.Spendingis the ratioof dollarsspent by the two candidates.To reach this figurefor each race,we divide the spendingof the out-partycandidateby the spendingof the candidateof the President'sparty.In-partycandidateswho spent nothing have been recodedto one dollarto avoid undefinedterms.The measure that resultsshould be positively associatedwith the likelihood that the respondent votes for the out-partycongressionalcandidate.The impact of money on congressional elections has been documented on numerous occasions (e.g., Fenno 1982; Jacobson 1980, 1990b; Sorauf1988 among many others) and our expectationsdo not vary.Significantspending is the only way challengerscan accumulatethe necessaryname recognitionand is a well-recognizedpart of the incumbent'sadvantage,given his/her generallyhigher access to contributions fromboth individualsand groups.A substantialspending differentialin favorof the President'sco-partisancould preventa loss of a seat, even in the presenceof other factorstending in the opposing direction.We control for Spending,therefore, in order to prevent its effect from potentiallyoverwhelmingthe information-drivenbehaviorwe want to identify. Quality,like Spending,is a relationalmeasure of the two candidates.The quality of each candidateis coded as two (2) if the candidateis an incumbent, one (1) if holding (or havingheld) other politicaloffice, and zero (0) if the candidateis a politicalneophyte.'3The resultingqualityscore of the candidatefrom the President'spartyis then subtractedfromthat of the out-partycandidate.The resultingvariable,Quality,ranges from 2 to -2 and should be positively correlated with the likelihood of a voter casting a ballot for the out-partycandidate. Without doubt, incumbency,and the advantagesit accrues to a candidate,is a huge advantagein an election (Alfordand Hibbing 1981; Cain, Ferejohn,and Fiorina 1987; King 1991). Similarly,the literatureon the importanceof challenger quality is large (Abramowitz1988; Jacobson 1990a; Squire 1992) and with few exceptions (e.g., Seguraand Nicholson 1995) seems to suggest that the relativepolitical experienceof candidatesis stronglyassociatedwith predicting congressionalelection votes and outcomes. Qualitychallengersrunning against incumbentsof the President'spartyare farmore likely to producea midtermseat loss than those with no politicalexperience. Somerespondentsdid, in fact,refuseto eitherapproveor disapproveof the President,but they representedonly 1.15 percentof all respondentsand less than 1 percent(.82 percent)of thosewho voted. For the purposeof simplicity,they were droppedfromthe analysis,but theirinclusiondoes not, in any way,alterthe size or significanceof the otherestimatesnor the predictivepowerof the model. 13 We thank GaryC. Jacobsonfor providingus with these data. 12 620 Midterm ElectionsandDividedGovernment In additionto these district-specificcontextualvariables,we account for the differentpolitical circumstancethrough the inclusion of two variables:Divided Government,and EconomicEvaluation.Again, DividedGovernmentis coded one (1) if the pre-electionpartisancontrol of the elective branchesis divided, and zero (0) if it is unified. Ceterisparibus,DividedGovernment should damp the attribution of blame to the President'spartyand thereforebe negativelyrelatedto the probabilitythat a respondentvotes for the out-partyHouse candidate. Economic Evaluationis used here as a controlvariablesince it has been widely suggested(acobson 1990b; Kramer1971; Tufte1975) that the voter'sperception of the macro-economy'sperformanceleading up to the midterm election has much to do with the evaluation of the President as well as the vote in the midtermHouse elections.We measureEconomicEvaluationusing a retrospective evaluationquestion from the NES. Specifically,respondentsindicated whether they thoughtthe economyhad improved,worsenedor stayedthe same in the last year.14 The variableis recoded so that poor economic assessmentsare coded as one (1), a perception of an improvingeconomy as negative one (-1), and no changecoded zero (0). The resultingmeasureshould be positivelyrelatedto the likelihood of voting for the out-party TESTINGAND RESULTS Table3, column 1 presentsestimatesfroma multivariateprobitanalysis.The chi-squaredstatisticis highlysignificantwhich meansthatwe can rejectthatnullhypothesisthat all the independentvariablesin our model areunrelatedto voting for the out-partyin these midtermelections. Furthermore,the model correctly predicts81.8 percentof the caseswith a ProportionalReductionof Error(Lambdap) of .609 over the null model. Takentogether,these tests indicatethat our model is well-suitedto explainingvoting for out-partycandidatesat the midterm. Turningto individualpredictors,we see that our hunch was correct:voters are less likely to vote for the out-partyduring periods of divided government. Controllingfor other factors, divided governmenthas a statisticallysignificant negative effect (p = .001) on voting for the out-partyHouse candidate at the midterm. To make any judgments about this effect in the 1994 congressional elections, in column two we reestimatedthe model by disaggregatingthe two periods of unified governmentin our sample by election. Both the 1978 and 1994 dummyvariablesare statisticallysignificant(p < .05 for 1978, p < .001 for 1994) and the signs of the coefficientsare positive, meaning that unified gov14 For 1978, the specific questionwordingreferredto the "businessconditions."The exact question wordingused in the other four surveyswas not employedin the 1978 survey,so the discrepancy was unavoidable.Resultson this variable,then, should be read with caution but, we think, are suggestive.Nevertheless,we think this approachis superiorto an aggregatelevel measureof inflation and unemploymentwhich can only vary acrossthe five elections. 621 Political Research Quarterly TABLE 3 PROBIT COEFFICIENTS ESTIMATING INFLUENCE OFPARTISAN CONTROL OF GOVERNMENT ONVOTING FORTHEOUT-PARTY IN MIDTERM ELECTIONS: 1978-1994 Variable Model 1 Model 2 PartyIdentification .366 ** (.015) .366 ** (.016) Ideology .195*** (.042) .195*** (.042) EconomicEvaluation .048 (.035) .055 (.035) 9.16e-07* (4.68e-07) 8.84e-07* (4.68e-07) Quality .371*** (.017) .373*** (.017) PresidentialApproval -.274* ** (.063) -.264 ** (.064) Divided Government -.199*** (.063) Spending 1978 .128* (.074) 1994 .278*** (.077) -.996* ** (.087) Constant 3417 N 3417 Chi Square 1998.67 Significance PercentPredictedCorrectly .000 81.8 PRE(Lambda-p) -1.203*** (.090) .609 2001.97 .000 82.0 .614 *Significantat p < = .05 **Significantat p < = .01 ***Significantat p < = .001 ernments in these two elections increased the probability that a voter chose the out-party candidate. To be sure, the effect in 1994 is larger, but it does not alone drive our findings on the importance of divided or unified government. To estimate the approximate effect of the independent variables, we again turn to the changes in the predicted probabilities associated with each. In column 1, Divided Government decreases the likelihood of a voter choosing an out-party congressional candidate by 7.8 percent, a substantial change given the presence of important controls like partisanship, incumbency (as part of Quality), and Spending. In the second column, the year dummies also have a substantial effect. Since each of the years represent elections under unified government, we 622 MidtermElectionsandDividedGovernment would expect the change to be positive. The 1978 dummy increasesthe likelihood of voting for the out-partyby 5.1 percent,while the 1994 dummyincreases the probabilityby 10.8 percent.As we shall see momentarily,when we subdivide the electorateby their strengthof partisanshipand level of informationso that we can look at potentialswing voters, these effectsare even stronger. Most of the control variablesworked as we had expected. The impact of party identification,ideology, spending, and the quality of candidates (taking into account both challengersand incumbents) all had statisticallysignificant coefficientswith signs in the predicted directions.Like most researchon congressionalelections, partisanidentificationand candidateattributesappearto be the most importantdeterminantsof voting.5 An unexpectedresultis the marginalinsignificanceof the respondent'sevaluation of the economy. Recallwe expected that voters offeringa more critical assessmentof recenteconomic performancewould be more likely to choose candidatesfromthe out-partyThe coefficientsarein the predicteddirectionbut they fail to reachsignificance,with a p-value of .083 for the model with DividedGovernmentand .061 for the model with the two year dummies. WhoDecideson theBasisof DividedGovernment? Whose choices are affectedby the presence or absence of divided government?Earlier,we hypothesizedthat not all voters should behave in this manner. Indeed,we expect that many voters do not care, or even know, if governmentis divided. For those voters who do not care, we expect them to have partisan attachments.In this group, we would expect them to resist informationthat is inconsistentwith their partisandispositions.Democratsblame Republicansand vice versa.Basedon these considerations,we breakthe sampleinto two groups: (1) partisans,which includes both strong and weak party identifiers;and (2) Independents,which includes both Independentswho lean toward either the Democraticor Republicanparties and "pure"Independents. Given that both groups include respondentswith varyinglevels of commitmentto either party, we still must include the partisanidentificationvariableto take into account the very differentcandidatepreferencesof these groups. We furthersubdividedthe sampleby whetheror not the respondentwas able to identifycorrectlywhich party controlledthe House of Representatives (again assumingthey know the partyof the President).Thoseunableto performthis task since theylackthe specific correctlyarefarmoreproneto blameattribution"errors" 15 The most significantdangerin our generalapproachis the possibilityof serialautocorrelation.We tested for such a possibilityby including the full arrayof time dummies. Since divided government only variesacrosstime, it by necessity falls out of the equation.The resultingmodel, however, does not appreciablyaffectthe remainingcoefficientsnor improvethe predictivecapacityof any of the models we present,suggestingthat autocorrelationis unlikely. 623 PoliticalResearch Quarterly knowledgethatthe policymakingbrancheswerecontrolledby the sameor different parties.We expectthatthe effectof dividedor unifiedgovernmenton the probability that a respondentvotes for an out-partyHouse candidatewould be weakeror missingamongrespondentswho do not know whethergovernmentis divided.'6 We tested our model in each of these four groups,expectingthat only pure Independentsand independentLeanerswho correctlyidentifiedthe partyin controlof the Housewould be influencedby dividedor unifiedgovernments.Able to make the necessarycausalattributionsof responsibilityand unhinderedby partisan disposition,these votersshould be influencedby clearor unclearattributions of responsibilitythat are based on control of the two branchesof government. Independentsuninformedaboutcontrolof Congress,for obviousreasons,cannot bring this informationto bear on theirvote choice. One could arguethat even if these voters "gotit wrong,"they may neverthelessvote like the group that "gotit right."We think this scenariounlikely given that these respondentsare not generallywell informedaboutpolitics.'7Finally,since causalattributionsof responsibility areless importantto these partisans,we also expect that this groupwill not show much effectfromdivided or unified governmenton theirvote choice. The analysis largely supports our hypotheses. Looking at the first two columns of Table4, partisanswere less affectedby the unified governmentsin 1978 or 1994. There was no support for a unified governmenteffect among strong partisansin 1978, whether or not they had correctinformationon congressionalcontrol.For 1994, thereappearsto be a significanteffectamong those who could correctlyidentifythe partycontrollingthe House, but no effectamong those less informed. Instead, it appears that the vote choice for partisansis affected primarilyby the strength of their partisanidentification,presidential approval,and candidatequality Columns 3 and 4 depict the results for Independentsand Leaners.Those knowledgeableabout the partisancontrol of Congress(column 3) voted on the basis of unified governmentin the 1978 and 1994 midtermelections. What is most striking about this finding is its strong effect. When compared to other groups of voters, Independentsand Leanerswho correctlyidentified the party controllingCongressappearto be highly influencedby unified government. 16 17 We suggestedearlierthat this assumptionmight not be correctif the informationaspects of this dynamic,i.e., the media'spresentationof either/orexplanationsfor policy failureor economic distress, might have a sufficienteffecton even uninformedvoters to maintainthe differencebetween voting behaviorsunder unified and divided governments.If this is correct,we would expect that the DividedGovernment coefficientwould remainsignificantacrossthe two groups(albeit,perhaps, of a smallermagnitudeamong those unawareof partisancontrol). The correlationbetweenthe interviewers'assessmentsof the respondents'politicalknowledgeand Knowledgeof Congressis (rs = .32). While this correlationis moderate,it likely severelyunderestimatesthe associationbetween generalsophisticationand the dichotomousmeasuregiven that some respondentsprobablyguessed correctlywhich partycontrolledthe House. 624 MidtermElectionsand Divided Government TABLE 4 THEINFLUENCE PROBITCOEFFICIENTS ESTIMATING ON OF UNIFIEDGOVERNMENTS IN MIDTERMELECTIONS, AND VOTINGFORTHEOUT-PARTY BYPARTISANSHIP OF HOUSE CONTROL:1978-1994 KNOWLEDGE VotersKnowledge of House Control Strongor Weak PartyIdentifiers Correct Incorrect and Partisan"Leaners" Pure Independents Correct Incorrect PartyIdentification .357*** (.022) .339*** (.027) .450*** (.079) .622*** (.107) Ideology .270*** (.066) .031 (.091) .189* (.086) .185 (.132) EconomicEvaluation .070 (.055) .041 (.076) .030 (.074) .088 (.108) 9.25e-07 (8.22e-07) 8.56e-07 (7.22e-07) 5.10e-07 (1.06e-06) 2.60e-06 (2.21e-06) Quality .359*** (.027) .347*** (.033) .405*** (.037) .471*** (.052) PresidentialApproval -.266** (.105) -.285* (.128) -.260* (.139) -.076 (.186) 1978 .030 (.119) .106 (.172) .383** (.158) .236 (.210) 1994 .264* (.116) .233 (.422) .414** (.163) .323 (.505) -1.624*** (.292) -2.049*** (.396) Spending Constant -1.238*** (.142) -.908*** (.169) 330 N 1568 851 601 Chi Square 1087.98 516.07 229.78 Significance % PredictedCorrectly PRE(Lambda-p) .000 84.6 .000 82.6 .676 .583 .000 76.7 .524 149.41 .000 77.6 .507 *Significantat p < = .05 **Significantat p < = .01 ***Significantat p < = .001 When we look at changes in the predictedprobabilities,this impressionis supported.Among Independentswho knew which partycontrolledthe House, our potentialswing voters, unified governmentsignificantlyincreasedthe likelihood that they would vote for the out-partyby 15 percentand 16.2 percentfor 1978 and 1994, respectively.Moreremarkableis how potent this effect is given the presenceof the controlvariableslike spending and ideology.In sum, unified and divided governmentsare criticalfactorsfor these so-called "swingvoters"in midtermelections. 625 PoliticalResearch Quarterly Although partisansin 1994 were influenced by unified government, the effectis little more than half the size of the effect on Independentsand Leaners. Thus, despite the generaleffectof unified governmentidentifiedhere, it appears that the elections of 1994 did have a greatereffecton partisansthan in the elections of 1978. This insight regardingpartisaninfluencescertainlymerits further investigationin studies of the 1994 elections. CONCLUSION We began by hypothesizing that divided governmentshaped the choices made in elections. Specifically,the muddied informationalenvironmentwould enhance the prospects of candidatesof the President'sparty,who normallyare held accountablefor all that ails the society but, when governmentis divided, can blame the other side. Our findings are supportive of our claims. In the first analyses, we show that respondents and voters alike are less likely to be able to identify which party controls the House of Representativesunder divided government, even controlling for other important predictors including overall assessments of political informationlevels and strong partisanship.In the second set of analyses we examinedvote choice for all respondentswho voted in the midtermelections from 1978 to 1994, and saw thatunified governmentwas a significantpredictorof voting for out-partycandidateswhile divided governmentdampedthis effect, holding constant other importantfactors.Unpacking differentsegments of the electorate,we saw that divided government'simpact was greatestamong pure Independentsand independentLeanerswho knew about the partisancontrol of Congress.Among these voters, causalattributionsof responsibility,blaming who is firmly in charge, can be achieved when institutionalcircumstances permit. It could be suggestedthat our information-driventheoryis similarto extant evaluativeexplanations,particularlythe policy-balancingmodel (Fiorina 1992; Alesinaand Rosenthal1995), insofaras voting for House membersis linked to the President.But our argumentis distinct in that the causal mechanismis the institutionalcontext of the evaluation,i.e., unified or divided government.More importantly,our findings would not support policy-balancingas an alternative explanation.The causal mechanism in the balancing model is the ideological proximityof House candidatesto the President.Votersemploying this decision rule would vote alwaysfor the out-partyHouse candidatewho is more ideologically distant from the President.The presence of divided government, then, should make no differenceat the individuallevel of analysis.Since the balancing voter "wants"divided government after the election, the institutionalcontext before the election is irrelevantto their preferences.Of course, the number of in the electoratecould, itself, be endogenous to divided and "policy-balancers" unified government.But even in this event, the inclusion of divided government 626 Midterm ElectionsandDividedGovernment as a predictorof midtermvoting behaviorrepresentsan explanatorycontribution distinct fromwhat the policy-balancingargumentoffers. It is worth noting that we have not attemptedan examinationof aggregate outcomes. The effect of divided government estimated here is on individual behavior.How this behavioraggregatesinto the partisandivision of the House of Representativesis a complicatedquestion.A full model of seat loss would need to account for individualpreferences,which we examine here, as well as individual decisions over whether to vote, the recruitmentand funding of quality candidates, retirements,and the distributionof partisansacross electoral districts,none of which we areable to addressfullywith these data.For this reason, we cannot definitivelyanswerwhy 1994 was such a debacle for the Democrats. Unified government,however, certainlymade the Democraticparty an easier target-blame attributionwas simpler. What are the broaderimplicationsof our study?First, the responsibleparties model of governmenthas long held sway among political scientists. This model depends on the abilityof citizens to link policies and performanceto particular political actors. Divided partisancontrol of governmenthas significant implicationsfor the workabilityof such an ideal type since it deprivesvoters the opportunity to judge only one party for policy outputs-the sine qua non of responsible party government-and it appears to have a significanteffect on voters'decisions. Second,our findingsseem to suggestsomethingthat politicalobservershave speculatedaboutfor some time-Presidents mightbenefitpoliticallyfromdivided government.Thoughpartisandivisionof the electedbranchesdoes seem to shape the electoratein a mannercontraryto the President'sinterests,it seems also to reduce the likelihood that any given voter holds the Presidentat fault and punishes his partisancolleagues.This logic could conceivablybe extended to presidentialapprovaland disapproval,a subjectbeyond the specificscope of this article but certainlyworthyof study.In addition,dividedgovernment'seffectson the composition of the electorate,a subjectjust beginning to be examined at the aggregatelevel (Franklinand Hirczy de Mifo 1998), should be more closely examinedat the individuallevel. Findingthatthe President'spoliticalfortunesare not only divorcedfromthose of his partisancolleaguesin the legislaturebut, perhaps, inverselyrelatedto them would suggestthatprospectsfor responsibleparty governmentwill remainpoor, and the futureof divided governmentlengthy. REFERENCES Abramowitz,Alan. 1988. "ExplainingSenateElectionOutcomes."AmericanPolitical ScienceReview82 (2): 385-403. . 1995. "TheEnd of the DemocraticEra?1994 and the Future of ConPoliticalResearch 48 (4): 873-89. Quarterly gressionalElectionResearch." 627 PoliticalResearch Quarterlv Alesina,Alberto,and HowardRosenthal.1995. PartisanPolitics,DividedGovernment,and theEconomy.New York:CambridgeUniversityPress. Alford,John R., and John R. Hibbing. 1981. "IncreasedIncumbencyAdvantage in the House."Journalof Politics43 (4): 1042-61. Alvarez,R. Michael, and MatthewM. Schousen. 1993. "PolicyModerationor AmericanPoliticsQuarterly21 (4): 410-38. ConflictingExpectations?" Bartels,LarryM. 1996. "UninformedVotes:InformationEffectsin Presidential Elections."American Journalof PoliticalScience40 (1): 194-230. Bennett,StephenE., and LindaL. M. Bennett.1993. "Outof Sight, Out of Mind: Americans'Knowledge of Party Control of the House of Representatives, 1960-1984." PoliticalResearchQuarterly46 (1): 67-80. Cain, Bruce,John Ferejohn,and MorrisFiorina. 1987. ThePersonalVote:ConCambridge,MA: HarvardUnistituencyServiceand ElectoralIndependence. versityPress. Campbell,Angus. 1966. "Surgeand Decline:A Study of ElectoralChange."In Campbell,Converse,Millerand Stokes,eds., Electionsand thePoliticalOrder. New York:Wiley Elections.LexingPulseof Congressional Campbell,JamesE. 1993. ThePresidential ton: Universityof KentuckyPress. Cover,Albert.D. 1985. "Surgeand Decline in CongressionalElections."Western PoliticalQuarterly38 (4): 606-19. Converse,Phillip E. 1964. "TheNature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics."In David E. Apter,ed., Ideologyand Discontent.New York:Free Press. Cox, GaryW, and MatthewD. McCubbins.1991. "DividedControl of Fiscal Policy"In GaryW Cox and SamuelKernell,eds., ThePoliticsof DividedGovernment.Boulder,CO: Westview. Erikson,RobertS. 1988. "ThePuzzle of MidtermLoss."Journalof Politics50 (4): 1011-29. Fenno, RichardE 1982. TheUnitedStatesSenate:A BicameralPerspective.Washington, DC: AmericanEnterpriseInstitute. Fiorina,MorrisP. 1981. Retrospective Votingin AmericanNationalElections.New Haven:YaleUniversityPress. New York:Macmillan. . 1992. DividedGovernment. Franklin,MarkN., and WolfgangP Hirczyde Mino. 1998. "SeparatedPowers, Divided Government,and Turnoutin U.S. PresidentialElections."American Journalof PoliticalScience42 (1): 316-36. Ginsberg, Benjamin, and Martin Shefter. 1990. Politicsby OtherMeans:The of Electionsin America.New York:BasicBooks. DecliningImportance Elections.New Haven:YaleUni1980. Jacobson,GaryC. Moneyin Congressional Press. versity 1990a.TheElectoral Boulder,CO:Westview. OriginsofDividedGovernment. in of "The Effects 990b. 1 CampaignSpending House Elections:New Science34 (2): 334-62. EvidenceforOldArguments." AmericanJournal ofPolitical 628 Midterm ElectionsandDividedGovernment Jacobson,GaryC., and SamuelKernell.1983. StrategyandChoicein Congressional Elections,2nd.ed. New Haven:YaleUniversityPress. Kernell,Samuel. 1977. "PresidentialPopularityand NegativeVoting:An Alternative Explanationof the MidtermCongressionalDecline of the President's Party."AmericanPoliticalScienceReview71 (1): 44-66. . 1991. "Facingan Opposition Congress:The President'sStrategicCircumstance."In GaryW Cox and SamuelKernell,eds., ThePoliticsof Divided Government. Boulder,CO:Westview. King,Gary.1991. "ConstituencyServiceand IncumbencyAdvantage."British Journalof PoliticalScience21 (1): 119-28. Klinkner,PhilipA., ed. 1996. Midterm:TheElectionsof 1994 in Context.Boulder, CO:Westview. Kramer,Gerald H. 1971. "Short-termFluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896-1964."AmericanPoliticalScienceReview65 (1): 131-43. Leyden,KevinM., and StephenA. Borrelli.1995. "TheEffectof StateEconomic Conditions on GubernatorialElections:Does Unified GovernmentMake a Difference."PoliticalResearchQuarterly48 (2): 275-90. Lowi, TheodoreJ. 1985. The PersonalPresident:PowerInvested,PromiseUnfulfilled. Ithaca,NY:CornellUniversityPress. andInvesMayhew,DavidR. 1991. DividedWeGovern:PartyControl,Lawmaking, tigations,1946-1990.New Haven:YaleUniversityPress. McCubbins,MatthewD. 1991. "Governmenton Lay-Away:Federal Spending and DeficitsUnderDividedPartyControl."In GaryW Cox and SamuelKerBoulder,CO:Westview. nell, eds., ThePoliticsof DividedGovernment. Petrocik,John R. 1991. "DividedGovernment:Is It All in the Campaigns?"In GaryW Cox and Samuel Kernell,eds., ThePoliticsof DividedGovernment. Boulder,CO:Westview. Segura,GaryM., and StephenP Nicholson. 1995. "SequentialChoices and Partisan Transitionsin U.S. Senate Delegations:1972-1988."Journalof Politics 57 (1): 86-100. Sorauf,FrankJ.1988. Moneyin AmericanElections.Glenview,IL:Scott,Foresman. Squire,Peverill. 1992. "ChallengerQuality and VotingBehaviorin U.S. Senate Elections."Legislative StudiesQuarterly17 (2): 247-61. R. 1975. of the Outcomes of MidtermCongresEdward "Determinents Tufte, sional Elections."AmericanPoliticalScienceReview69 (3): 812-26. Wattenburg,MartinP 1991. "TheRepublicanPresidentialAdvantagein the Age of PartyDisunity."In GaryW Cox and SamuelKernell,eds., ThePoliticsof DividedGovernment. Boulder,CO:Westview. Received:March5, 1998 Accepted:February,1999 snicholson@scu.edu gary.segura@cgu.edu 629