ECO364 - International Trade Chapter 3 - Heckscher Ohlin Christian Dippel University of Toronto Summer 2009 Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 1 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Model Set-Up Difference To Ricardo I In Ricardo: I I I everyone wins from Trade. there is only one factor of production outcome is complete specialization I This is very simplistic I The Heckscher-Ohlin model aims to remedy some of these shortcomings. I It is more complex than Ricardo but gives far more subtle and nuanced predictions. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 2 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Model Set-Up Framework I 2x2x2 Model: 2 Countries, 2 Goods (Outputs), 2 Factors (Inputs). I No productivity differences. All countries share the same technology. I Identical Homothetic Preferences. I Output can be produced with different input mixes (depending on relative input prices). I Factors are mobile across sectors. Countries differ in the relative abundance of factors. This is the key of Comparative Advantage in the HO Model. I I HO is often referred to as the factor proportions theory. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 3 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Model Set-Up Preview of Insights to Come I Factor Abundance determined at Country Level I Factor Intensity determined at Industry (=Sector) Level I Specialization according to both Factor Abundance and Intensity I Countries gain from Trade but Industries may loose and Factors may loose I Trade has Subtle Effects on Industrial Restructuring I Under certain conditions, Factor Prices (e.g. wages) are equalized across countries Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 4 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Model Set-Up Recall patterns of specialization from the first class: Table: Trade by Commodities (1995) Type of Goods Canada Machinery 0.383 Food and Live Animals 0.066 Chemicals 0.059 Misc. Manufactures 0.049 Source: Robert Feenstra, “World Trade I China Thailand United States 0.230 0.045 0.041 0.455 Flows” 0.382 0.190 0.031 0.196 0.472 0.072 0.109 0.113 Canada and the United States specialize in skilled labor/capital intensive goods while China and Thailand specialize in goods that use unskilled labor relatively intensively. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 5 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Model Set-Up Set-Up Again 1. Two countries. 2. Two goods. 3. Two productive factors I Because of (1)-(3), this is referred to as the 2x2x2 model. 4. Constant returns to scale 5. Perfect competition (all agents are price takers). 6. Countries differ only in terms of their (relative) factor endowments. 7. Factors are immobile across countries but mobile across sectors. 8. Identical Homothetic Preferences Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 6 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Model Set-Up We first set up the equilibrium relations between goods prices, factor prices and factor inputs 1. Derive relationship between relative factor prices and relative factor demand. I I Based on firm profit maximization. FF curves (to be derived). 2. Derive relationship between relative goods prices and relative factor prices. I I Based on iso-value and iso-cost curves from Lerner diagram (to be derived). SS curve (to be derived). 3. Use (1) and (2), derive three-way relationship between relative factor prices, relative factor demand and relative goods prices (see slide 33/98 for an application). Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 7 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Model Set-Up This is a General Equilibrium (GE) Framework. It is important to remember what GE means (as opposed to Partial Equilibrium): 1. Firms maximize profits 2. Consumers maximize utility I I Utility/Preferences stay in the background throughout the analysis Because of homothetic preferences: Relative Demand unaffected by income 3. Labor markets clear I This is the basic set-up for any GE Framework! I The equilibrium is a set of (factor market clearing) factor prices, (goods market clearing) goods prices and sector-specific factor allocations. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 8 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Model Set-Up We consider a small open economy where prices are exogenously given and predict: 1. What happens to equilibrium relative factor prices and factor demand if goods prices change (can be interpreted as movement from autarky to free trade). I Stolper-Samuelson Theorem and Jones Magnification. 2. What happens to equilibrium relative factor prices and the production structure (sectorial composition) if the distribution of productive factors changes (can interpret as immigration). I Factor Price Insensitivity and Rybczynski Theorem. 3. Who specializes in what: I Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 9 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy To determine the optimal factor-intensity, we use the iso-value and iso-cost lines in the following Lerner Diagram. Figure: Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 10 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy The iso-value curves map combinations of capital and labor that yield $1 of output. I I Start with 1 = p x F x (K , L). For a given value of p x , what values of K and L produce $1 of output? Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 11 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy Some iso-value schedules where px,3 < px,2 < px,1 ... (at a lower price, firm needs more inputs to yield $1 of input) Figure: Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 12 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy The iso-cost curve gives combinations of capital and labor that (as a bundle) cost $1. Values of w and r are taken as given. It is derived from the following equation wL + rK = 1 K= Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) 1 r − w r L ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 13 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy Figure: Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 14 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy If w and r rise by the same proportion, the iso-cost curve shifts in parallel. Using less K and L now costs $1 Figure: Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 15 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy With zero profits, both revenue and costs are equal to 1. Therefore, K and L must lie on both curves. Figure: Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 16 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy I Equilibrium has to be at point of tangency (demonstrated on next few slides) I The straight line from the origin to the point of tangency is called the Output Expansion Path (OEP) The slope of the OEP gives us the factor intensity in a sector. I I A flatter OEP in our graph means a sector is more labor intensive Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 17 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy Value of output is $1 and costs are less than $1. Positive profits (firm entry). Not an equilibrium. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 18 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy Could use a different mix of K and L to attain positive profits. Not an equilibrium. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 19 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy Could use a different mix of K and L to attain positive profits. Not an equilibrium. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 20 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy Value of output is $1 and costs are more than $1. Negative profits and firm exit. Not an equilibrium. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 21 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy With a second good of another factor intensity, we can add a second iso-value curve. Figure: Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 22 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy The preceding slide determines equilibrium factor intensities ( KLTT , KLCC ) in both sectors I I for a given set of goods prices pC , pT and a given set of input prices w , r I These goods prices and input prices are an equilibrium because both iso-value lines are tangent to the iso-cost curve I Suppose that pT increases. In order to produce $1 worth of textiles, fewer inputs are needed. I Consequently, the iso-value curve T shifts in while the iso-value curve C does not move Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 23 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy Figure: Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 24 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy I Now, there are profit opportunities in the textile sector because costs are unchanged but revenue has increased. I Capital and labor flow into the textile sector. I Because textiles are relatively labor intensive (flatter OEP), labor’s wage is bid up more than capital’s rental rate. (w /r ) rises in response to pT /pc increasing. I I I Importantly, r actually falls in this case to allow for non-negative profits in the Computer-sector Intuition: for every unit of labor that shifts from the Computer to Textile-sector, Computer-firms want to free up more capital than textile-firms are demanding. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 25 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy note that r has to fall if pC is fixed. Figure: Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 26 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy This relationship between goods and factor prices is represented in the SS curve: Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 27 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy I This SS curve gives us the relationship between goods prices and factor prices I What about the relationship between factor prices and factor intensities? I We saw that a rise in PT /PC raises w /r This makes labor more expensive and naturally leads to substitution effects where each firm demands a higher K /L ratio I I I Note that for markets to clear this has to imply that the labor-intensive sector expands (intuition: PT rises) There is therefore a positive relationship between w /r and K /L in both sectors Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 28 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy restructuring if w /r increases Figure: Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 29 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy There is therefore a positive relationship between w /r and K /L in both sectors Supposing computers are relatively capital intensive (F C F C is below and to the right of F T F T ): Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 30 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy I We can soon combine the graphs on slides 27 and 30 to have a graphical representation of the General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy (with prices exogenous) I But first, let’s make this more formal through the firm’s profit maximization problem. I In competition, the nominal wage paid to a factor in production of good X equals its marginal revenue product such that where w is the wage and r is the rental rate of capital w = px mpl(K , L) Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) r = px mpk(K , L) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 31 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy We can divide these two expressions such that px mpl(K /L) mpl(K /L) w = = r px mpk(K /L) mpk(K /L) Because the marginal product of labor is increasing in and the marginal product of capital is decreasing in K /L, we can rewrite the right hand side into a single expression that is increasing in K /L. w = f (K /L) r Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) , ∂ wr = f 0 (K /L) > 0 ∂(K /L) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 32 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy Example: Suppose that computers are capital intensive and textiles are labor intensive with Cobb-Douglas production functions. QT = K 1/3 L2/3 QC = K 2/3 L1/3 Firms producing X maximize PX QX − wLX − rKX First Order Conditions (FOC) give {KC , KT , LC , LT } as functions of {w , r , pC , pT } : (1) (2) 1/3 −1/3 w = pT 23 KT LT −2/3 2/3 LT r = pT 13 KT 2/3 −2/3 (3) w = pC 13 KC LC (4) r = pC 23 KC −1/3 1/3 LC But {w , r } are also unknown so we need 2 more equations given by the endowments. (5) KT + KC = K (6) LT + LC = L Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 33 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Dividing (1)/(2) and (3)/(4) gives us: General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy KT w w 1 KC r = 2 LT r = 2 LC pT KT −1/3 KC 2/3 ( LC ) pC 2 = ( LT ) Setting (1)=(3) (or (2)=(4)) gives us: Combining these expressions gives us a solution for w/r (as a function of pT 1/3 which we can plug back in to solve for prices): pC = (w /r ) {KC , KT , LC , LT } Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 34 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy We can now combine these two graphs into one picture. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 35 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I For a given set of relative goods prices, we can now predict: I I I General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy Relative factor prices Factor intensities For a given set of relative factor prices, we can now predict I I Relative goods prices. Factor intensities I In a small open economy (where prices are exogenous) we predict relative factor prices and factor intensities given output prices. I This can be represented in the following picture: Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 36 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 37 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I The SS curve is the graphical representation of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem: I I Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems As the relative price of a good increases, the nominal wages of the factor used relatively intensively in that good increase relative to the nominal wages of the other factor. Jones Magnification is an important corrollary that the real wages of the factor used relatively intensively in that good increase and the real wage to the other factor decreases. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 38 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems I Example 1: If pT rises relative to pC , then the relative return to labor over capital rises, the real wages of workers increase and the real return to capital falls. I Example 2: If pT falls relative to pC , then the relative return to labor over capital falls, the real wages of workers falls and the real return to capital rises. I Using “Jones’ Hat-Notation”, denote a change in x by x̂ I Then it can be shown for Example 1, that: ŵ > p̂T > p̂C > r̂ Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 39 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Figure: The Price of Textiles Rises Relative to the Price of Computers Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 pT pC ↑ 40 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Figure: The Price of Textiles Falls Relative to the Price of Computers Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 pT pC ↓ 41 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems If the price of textiles rises and the price of computers stays unchanged, how do we know... 1. that the nominal wage of labor rises and falls for capital? 2. that the real wage of labor rises and falls for capital? Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 42 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Figure: nominal wage changes follow from the Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 43 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems I We now know that r falls and w rises. I But how do we know that the real wage of labor rises and falls for capital? I w pC I If consumers consume both goods, the price level that consumers face will be a combination of the price of textiles and computers. and I w pT are not real wages! e.g p = 21 (pC + pT ) I If pT rises and pC stays unchanged, the aggregate price level (p) that consumers face must go up! I Because r falls, r p Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) must fall! ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 44 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems I How do we know that the real wage of labor rises? I Label the cost share of labor in textile production as α and the cost share of capital in textile production as (1 − α) (see Question 2c on 2nd HO Problem Set) Recalling “Jones’ Hat-Notation” from previous slide and with zero profits, we have: I I p̂T = αŵ + (1 − α)r̂ I Because r falls, w has to rise by more than pT I Therefore w pC and Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) w pT must both rise and ECO364 - International Trade w p must rise! Summer 2009 45 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems The results on real wages and return to capital are an extension to the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem called Jones Magnification. I Jones Magnification holds very generally (i.e. without holding PC constant) but that is harder to show. I Jones Magnification matters because it is real wages (i.e. purchasing power) that determine welfare! I It can be shown more generally than here but the algebra gets a bit involved. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 46 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems I We will now derive a very important result called the Rybczynski Theorem. I To do this, we will use an Edgeworth Box... I First, note that LT + LC = L and KT + KC = K . Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 47 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 48 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Figure: The Textile Sector is Relatively Large Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 49 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Figure: The Computer Sector is Relatively Large Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 50 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Remember from the “relative prices graph” that we know the ratio of K to L in each sector. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 51 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems I For given factor and goods prices, the Lerner Diagram gives us the ratio of K to L (slope of OEP) in each sector. I We can use this information in the Edgeworth Box. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 52 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Combinations of capital and labor in each sector must lie on the rays below: Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 53 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems I These curves only intersect at one location. I Therefore we know what inputs will be in each sector (and, therefore, what output will be). Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 54 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I I Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems How do production patterns change if we increase one of the endowments? To do this, we simply expand the Edgeworth Box along the dimension whose factor has increased in quantity I Suppose we increase the amount of labor in the economy. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 55 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 56 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems I Labor and capital employed in computers both fall. I Labor and capital employed in textiles both increase. I Production of computers falls and production of textiles increases. I Rybczynski Theorem: As endowments of one factor change, a country will produce more of the goods that use that factor intensively and less of those that don’t I A corollary is that Migration leads to industrial restructuring because it changes relative factor abundance Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 57 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Factor Price Insensitivity I Notice that the OEP’s did not change slope as we expanded the Edgeworth Box. This means that w/r did not change and this irresponsiveness of w/r with respect to changes in factor endowments is referred to as Factor Price Insensitivity (FPI) . I When does it hold? Intuitively, w/r cannot change in the Lerner diagram because goods prices are exogenously given to a SOE. I The only way w/r can change is if the country specializes in only one good. I This implies that the condition for FPI is that both countries are diversified (produce both goods). Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 58 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Diversification vs. Specialization I The discussion of FPI is a good point to check your understanding of production functions in the Ricardian and HO Model. I Why is there a tendency to fully specialize in the Ricardian Model but not in the HO Model although both models have CRS production function? I The reason is that the HO Model is a two-factor model and the production function has declining marginal products in each factor (despite being CRS - make sure you get the difference). I This implies that as one sector expands at the expense of the other, the marginal product of the scarce factor will eventually tend to infinity in the shrinking sector. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 59 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Stolper Samuelson and Rybczynski Theorems Recap I We have learnt how wages and factor intensities respond to price changes I I ... and how factor intensities and industry structure (how much labor employed in each sector) respond to factor endowments I I This is Stolper Samuelson This is Rybczynski Now we learn about the patterns of specialization. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 60 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin Unlike the Ricardian model, the PPF in the HO model is bowed out to reflect imperfect substitutability across sectors... Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 61 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin Optimal output will be attained when the value of output is maximized. V = pC QC + pT QT We can rewrite this as QT = V pT − pc pT QT We can also think of this as an isovalue line that keeps the value of production constant while varying the composition of production. Utility will be maximized when the value of production is maximized and this curve is as far up and to the right as possible. Do not confuse this isovalue line with the isovalue curve in the Lerner diagram. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 62 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin Value, and consequently utility, is higher as these curves shift up and to the right Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 63 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Heckscher Ohlin I A key insight is that, when there is no trade (autarky), the consumption bundle must lie on both the iso-value line and the PPF. I This is similar to the Ricardian model in which a consumption bundle must lie on both the PPF and the budget constraint. I Of course, in autarky, the production point is actually determined by tangency of PPF and indifference curve and the price ratio adjusts to be equal to the slope of both. I In autarky, an economy can only consume what it produces. I But under trade, the iso-value line can be thought of as a budget constraint in that it gives all the consumption bundle that a country can afford. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 64 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin As ppTC increases, the economy produces more computers relative to textiles. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 65 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin This also gives us a relative supply curve for the two goods Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 66 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin Combine with Relative Demand Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 67 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Heckscher Ohlin I The relative supply (RS) curve comes from the PPF and the iso-value lines. I The relative demand (RD) curve comes from utility maximization as in the Ricardian model. I Two countries in autarky: I Because preferences are identical and homothetic, the relative demand curve is the same in both countries in autarky. I Using the Rybczynski theorem, we know that the relative supply curve for the North is to the left of the relative supply curve for the South in autarky. To see this:.. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 68 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin With free trade in goods, both pT and pC must equate across countries. Therefore ppTC must equate across countries. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 69 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) Heckscher Ohlin ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 70 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin With free trade and perfect competition, relative prices equate across countries. The relative price of a given good will rise in one country and fall in the other. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 71 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin For a given good, there will be excess relative supply in one country and excess relative demand in the other country. This good will be exported by the first country and imported by the other. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 72 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Heckscher Ohlin I We can use the PPF graph to present the same information and to illustrate the gains from trade. I The following equation presents a country’s balanced trade condition: PC CC + PT CT = PC QC + PT QT This can be rewritten as CT − QT = pc pT (QC − CC ) This is a budget constraint in that the value of goods consumed must be no greater than the value of goods produced. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 73 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Heckscher Ohlin I Looking at the South, recall that in Autarky, consumption equals production. I In equilibrium in autarky, we see production and consumption occur at the point where the indifference curve is tangent to the PPF. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 74 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) Heckscher Ohlin ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 75 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin However, with trade, countries are no longer constrained to QC = CC and QT = CT . Now, they can trade at any point along their budget constraint. I pT pC rises ( ppTC falls) in the South. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) pT pC falls ( ppTC rises) in the North. ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 76 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin For the South: Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 77 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin For the North: Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 78 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Heckscher Ohlin I In the above example, the price of computers relative to textiles rises in the North and falls in the South. I More generally, the relative price of the good that intensively uses the relatively abundant factor rises. The relative price of the good that intensively uses the relatively scarce factor falls. I By the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem, the abundant factor wins and the scarce factor loses. “Society” gains in each country because consumers can attain higher indifference curves I I This can be easily seen on the last two slides Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 79 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Heckscher Ohlin The Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem: Under all of the previously stated assumptions, a country will export the good that relatively intensively uses its relatively abundant good. The same country will import the good that relatively intensively uses its relatively scarce factor. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 80 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Factor Price Equalization I Stolper-Samuelson tells us what happens to relative factor prices in each country. I Owners of each country’s relatively abundant factor win as its factor wage rises. I Owners of each country’s relatively scarce factor lose as its relative factor wage falls. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 81 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) Factor Price Equalization ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 82 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) Factor Price Equalization ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 83 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Factor Price Equalization I How far does this factor price convergence go? I With Factor Price Equalization (FPE), goods price equalizing across countries leads to factor prices equalizing across countries. I Relative factor prices converge across countries even though factors are immobile across countries! I This is a striking result but when is it true? I The next slides show that FPE will happen as long as endowments are not “too” different. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 84 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Factor Price Equalization Recall the Lerner Diagram Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 85 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Factor Price Equalization ... and the Edgeworth Box. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 86 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Factor Price Equalization Equilibrium Allocations can be found in two equivalent ways. Points A and B are equivalent. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 87 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Factor Price Equalization The “Integrated Equilibrium Approach” I I So far, we have considered how factors are divided across sectors in one country. Now, let’s engage in a thought experiment: I I I I Suppose we combine 2 countries and drop all barriers between them (we have already assumed free trade and ignore financial flows so the only addition is free migration) The two countries are now “like one” and there will be a unique General Equilibrium set of goods and factor prices. This can again be represented in an Edgeworth Box that looks exactly like before. The boundaries given by the OEP’s mark the “Cone of Diversification”. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 88 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Factor Price Equalization Figure: the Cone of Diversification Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 89 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Factor Price Equalization I We can pick a factor allocation anywhere in the Edgeworth box to slice the country into two (drawing national boundaries). I Claim: Any factor allocation inside the Cone of Diversification will lead to FPE. FPE is equivalent to saying the OEP’s in the two countries are the same. I I I I I The goods prices have to be the same under free trade Also, countries have the same technology. Together, this implies the iso-value curves in each country’s Lerner Diagram are the same. The OEP’s can then only be the same under FPE (only then are the iso-cost curves the same) Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 90 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Factor Price Equalization Allocation α lies inside the Cone of Diversification and FPE is attained Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 91 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Factor Price Equalization I More intuitively, factor prices will be equalized if endowments are not too different. I Endowments that are similar lie inside the Cone of Diversification because it is “centered around the diagonal” in the Edgeworth Box. I Free Trade between Canada and the USA is likely to erase wage-differences. But Free Trade between Canada and China? The endowments are likely too different. I I I Let’s say the last point α sliced the world into Canada and the US. Instead, let’s slice the world into Switzerland and Bangladesh: Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 92 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Factor Price Equalization The North runs out of labor and the South runs out of capital Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 93 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Volume of Trade Volume of Trade I I With identical preferences, all countries consume on the diagonal of the global Edgeworth-Box (understand this!) The factor content of trade is determined by the endowment point and the factor prices. I I I I To see this, note that Home is capital-abundant if its endowment lies above the diagonal. It exports capital-intensive goods and imports labor-intensive goods. factor content of trade is the labor and capital embedded in these good-flows. Home exports good B and imports good A. Can read the imported and exported labor and capital of the Edgeworth-Box. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 94 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) Volume of Trade ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 95 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Volume of Trade The aggregate volume of trade is larger, the more different endowments are. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 96 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Size and Gains from Trade Size and Gains from Trade I the integrated equilibrium graph suggests that the volume of trade is larger if countries are more similar in size (as you get to the corners of the box, the boundaries of the cone get closer to the diagonal) I Hoe does country-size relate to gains from trade? I Assertion: small countries gain more from the movement from autarky to free trade than do large countries. I Recall that the gains from trade come from free trade prices being different than autarky prices. I The more different free trade relative prices, the larger the gains from trade. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 97 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Size and Gains from Trade I In autarky, relative factor prices are determined by aggregate relative factor endowments in each country. I In a free trade equilibrium, relative factor prices are determined by world relative factor endowments. I The larger a country, the closer its relative endowments are to world relative endowments. I Suppose we look at the two countries as Canada and China... Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 98 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model I Size and Gains from Trade Let’s look at a couple of examples... Table: Size and Equilibrium Factor Prices Canada China World I Large Canada K L K /L 200 100 2 5 20 0.25 205 120 1.71 Large China K L K /L 20 10 2 50 200 0.25 70 210 0.33 (integrated) World equilibrium factor prices will more closely resemble autarky factor prices in the large country than in the small country. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 99 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Size and Gains from Trade Figure: Size and Factor Prices: Large Canada Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 100 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Size and Gains from Trade Figure: Size and Factor Prices: Large China Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 101 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Wrapping Up Wrapping Up I Unlike the Ricardian model, there are winners and losers from trade liberalization. I Owners of the scare factor lose because they become relatively less scarce. I Owners of the abundant factor win because they become relatively more scarce. Winners win by more than the losers lose due to the gains from specialization. I I I In order for “everyone” to gain from trade, we must see transfer payments from the owners of the relatively abundant factor to the owners of the relatively scarce factor. Aggregate gains from trade come from the fact that consumers can attain a higher indifference curve. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 102 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Wrapping Up I Combining the Rybczynski and Heckscher-Ohlin theorems, a country will export the good that relatively intensively uses its relatively abundant factor and will import the other. I As a country moves from autarky to free trade, the relative price of the good that relatively intensively uses its relatively abundant factor increases. I As a country moves from autarky to free trade, the relative price of the good that relatively intensively uses its relatively scarce factor falls. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 103 / 103 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Wrapping Up I As a country moves from autarky to free trade, we can use the Stolper-Samuelson theorem to show that the nominal wages of a country’s relatively abundant factor rise and the nominal wages of the country’s relatively scarce factor falls. I Jones Magnification shows that the same is true for real wages. I This will lead to owners of the relatively scarce factor ”losing” and owners of the relatively abundant factor ”winning.” I However, winners win by more than losers lose so trade can lead to gains for everyone. I For everyone to gain from trade, there must therefore be transfer payments from the winners to the losers. I Factors of production are immobile across countries but goods are mobile. Trade in goods is enough to lead to factor price convergence. Christian Dippel (University of Toronto) ECO364 - International Trade Summer 2009 104 / 103