DISS. ETH NO. 19475 Voluntary Climate Change Initiatives in the U.S.: Analyzing Participation in Space and Time Dissertation submitted to ETH ZÜRICH for the degree of DOCTOR OF SCIENCES presented by Lena Maria Schaffer Dipl.-Verw.Wiss., Universität Konstanz born 04.12.1979 citizen of Germany accepted on the recommendation of Prof. Thomas Bernauer, examiner Prof. Jude Hays, co-examiner Prof. Vally Koubi, co-examiner 2011 iii Acknowledgements This dissertation is the outcome of my work at the Center for Comparative and International Studies (CIS) at ETH Zurich. Writing about a continuously evolving topic has proven to be a challenging, but also rewarding experience. My thesis would not be as it is without the help and support of advisors, colleagues and friends. First and foremost, I would like to thank my main advisor Thomas Bernauer for his encouragement and support throughout the years. He has always given me great freedom to pursue this project and has provided valuable input for the success of this dissertation. I am also thankful to Vally Koubi, who supported me throughout the years and always pushed me to think harder. Her professional and personal advice has been and continues to be invaluable and greatly appreciated. I also thank my advisors for the possibility to attend various summer schools and conferences and the inspiring academic environment they provided. Jude Hays contributed important methodological and substantive advice for this dissertation. I further want to thank Jude for his exceptional hospitality during my three month stay with the University of Illinois in Urbana-Champaign. A lot of the ideas that came out of our lunch appointments during this time have found their way into the dissertation and have improved it in various ways. Besides his academic input for this dissertation, he also helped me to finally understand American Football. I also want to thank Dana Fisher, who has hosted me as a visiting scholar at Columbia University. I profited a lot from her substantive knowledge in subnational environmental politics and the great experience she has with respect to doing qualitative research. Participants of the EITM summer institute in Michigan and various other conferences gave useful comments on previous versions of the dissertation papers, and I want to thank the discussants and participants for their comments and feedback. Gabriele Spilker and Julian Wucherpfennig gave valuable input for my work and supported me during different stages of this project. Tobias Hofmann and Thomas Malang have gone out of their way in commenting and proof-reading this dissertation and I am indebted to them for their help. iv The immense data collection effort for this dissertation would not have been possible without the knowledgable assistance of Stefan Schtz, Gwen Tiernan and Krzysztof Wojtaniec, whom I thank for their hard work. A crucial point for my research project has been the funding by the Competence Center Environment and Sustainability (CCES). The work for this dissertation was done within the funded project ClimPol, whose financial and academic support is greatly acknowledged. Many thanks go to my friends, Hanja Blendin, Christian Canstein, Benjamin Kreibich, Daniel Rittlinger, Gabriele Spilker and Susanna Steinbach, who have endured my complaints and selfdoubts and provided me with a healthy work-life balance during the dissertation years. Finally, I am more than thankful for the support and constant motivation of my husband Thomas Malang. For continuous support and so much more I am also indebted to my parents, Ute and Andreas Schaffer, and my brother Philipp. v Abstract Global climate change is one of the biggest challenges mankind is facing in the 21st century. Prominent attempts to deal with global climate change and to mitigate its consequences have focused on multilateral cooperation and international institutions. The success of these international efforts has been limited. A prime example is the Kyoto protocol. Especially large emitters of greenhouse gases such as the United States, which refused to ratify the Kyoto protocol, are generally reluctant to contribute to this global environmental effort. Given that effective cooperation between nation-states in climate politics is very difficult, the question arises whether there are other possibilities for coping with global climate change at lower political levels. In fact, such climate policy efforts already exist. The largest effort of this kind is the U.S. Mayors Climate Protection Agreement (MCPA). It was initiated by U.S. cities in 2005. Its aim is to advance the goals of the Kyoto Protocol on the local level even if the U.S. federal government lags behind. As of November 2010, 1044 cities have signed this agreement, representing 87 million people, i.e., more than one quarter of the U.S. population. Since the subnational formation of climate policy institutions is a new phenomenon, we know very little about the conditions that motivate subnational jurisdictions to join such efforts. Such knowledge is important for the evaluation of whether cooperation at this level can offer a feasible substitute or at least a useful complement for global efforts. This dissertation seeks to fill this research gap. It examines the determinants of cities’ willingness to commit to local climate change policies. I develop arguments on how various factors influence local governments’ decisions to voluntarily contribute to climate change mitigation efforts. These factors include communityspecific (e.g., income, partisanship, education) and interdependency factors. I argue that local governments’ decisions concerning climate change policies are dependent upon the choices of other local governments, and my aim is to explain these interdependencies in participation in voluntary agreements by determining the role of external influences (e.g., geography or social networks) that act as channels for the diffusion of policies. Overall, the results from this inquiry show the importance of community-specific characteristics for participation in the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. Conditions that are vi conducive to voluntary climate change mitigation efforts are a well-educated and liberal population. Factors pertaining to the natural environment play a role especially for those communities situated along coastal areas. A substantive contribution of this thesis comes from the consideration of external factors that are assumed to have an impact on the locality above and beyond its community-specific characteristics. I find some evidence for interdependent decision-making in local climate change policymaking. The importance of social networks of mayors for the diffusion of innovation is backed by evidence in both the quantitative as well as the qualitative parts of this study. A further notable contribution of this thesis lies in the collection of a unique data set on city-level MCPA adoption dates in seven Midwestern states. A particular merit of the research design is the possibility to compare results obtained from the large-N contexts with qualitative evidence from the local decision-makers. Thus, this dissertation provides the first comprehensive and systematic account of the temporal and spatial diffusion of voluntary climate change policies within a large country, using GIS and advanced statistical methods to that end. By studying in-depth the largest economy and second largest emitter in the global system, I gain insights that are also relevant to other countries, especially countries with federal political systems. vii Zusammenfassung Die Folgen des globalen Klimawandels zu bekämpfen ist eine der grössten Herausforderungen der Menschheit im 21. Jahrhundert. Zu den Versuchen mit Klimawandel umzugehen und daraus entstehende Konsequenzen abzuschwächen gehörten bislang vor allem multilaterale Verhandlungen und internationale Institutionen. Der Erfolg solcher internationaler Anstrengungen war jedoch begrenzt. Ein Paradebeispiel hierfür ist das Kyoto Protokoll. Vor allem Staaten, die einen grossen Treibhausgasausstoss haben – wie z.B. die USA, welche auch das KyotoProtokoll nicht ratifiziert haben – zeigen sich generell zurückhaltend bis unwillig zu solchen globalen Bemühungen beizutragen. Da eine effektive Zusammenarbeit zwischen Nationalstaaten im Bereich der Klimapolitik auf globaler Ebene sehr schwierig ist, stellt sich die Frage, ob es weitere Möglichkeiten gibt, Klimawandel auf anderen politischen Ebenen nachhaltig zu bekämpfen. In der Tat kann man feststellen, dass es bereits einige Anstrengungen sowohl auf verschiedenen Ebenen als auch zwischen Staaten gibt, bei denen es sich um Klimapolitik handelt. In diesem Projekt soll nun vor allem ein detaillierter Blick auf die subnationalen Ebenen geworfen werden. Die grösste nationale Initiative dieser Art ist das U.S. Mayors Climate Protection Agreement (MCPA). Diese Initiative wurde 2005 von U.S. Städten die von der Passivität der eigenen Regierung innerhalb der Klimapolitik frustiert waren ins Leben gerufen. Das erklärte Ziel dieser Initiative ist es, die für die USA im Kyoto-Protokoll anvisierten Treibhausgassenkungen in den jeweiligen Städten zu erreichen und hiermit ihren Teil zum Klimaschutz zu leisten. 2005 mit 141 Städten gestartet, umfasst das MCPA mittlerweile 1044 Städte in denen insgesamt 87 Millionen Menschen leben; das entspricht einem Viertel der US-Bevölkerung. Da die Entstehung und Entwicklung solcher klimapolitischer Institutionen auf subnationaler Ebene ein neues Phänomen darstellt, wissen wir vergleichsweise wenig über die Faktoren, die lokale Einheiten dazu veranlassen solchen freiwilligen Abkommen beizutreten. Genau dieses Wissen ist jedoch erforderlich, um bewerten zu können, ob Kooperation auf Ebenen jenseits der globalen die Möglichkeit bietet, ein Ersatz oder zumindest ein brauchbarer Zusatz zu sein. Diese Dissertation will zu dieser Forschung beitragen. Ich untersuche welche Bedingungen einen Beitritt einer Stadt zu einem freiwilligen Klimaschutzprogramm fördern bzw. hindern. Ich erörtere hierbei viii zuerst theoretisch, welche Faktoren bei der Entscheidung der lokalen Entscheidungträger relevant sind. Diese Faktoren werden in interne (d.h. stadt-spezifische Faktoren wie z.B. Einkommen, Parteizugehörigkeit, Bildung) und externe Interdependenzfaktoren aufgeteilt. Ich argumentiere dass Entscheidungen lokaler Entscheidungsträger bezüglich Klimaschutzpolitiken von den Entscheidungen anderer Entscheidungsträger abhängen. Mein Ziel ist es diese Interdependenzen in der Teilnahmen an freiwilligen Abkommen über die Rolle externer Einflüsse (z.B. Geographie oder soziale Netzwerke) zu erklären. Die Resultate meiner Untersuchung zeigen die Bedeutung von stadt-spezifischen Merkmalen für die Teilnahme an freiwilligen Abkommen. Förderliche Bedingungen für eine Teilnahme sind hier vor allem eine liberale und gut ausgebildete Bevölkerung. Ein substantiver Beitrag dieser Dissertation ist die explizite Einbeziehung externer Faktoren, von denen eine Auswirkung auf die Wahrscheinlichkeit einer Teilnahme an freiwilligen Klimaschutzabkommen erwartet wird. Die Analyse zeigt einige Hinweise dass die Entscheidungen verschiedener Entscheidungsträger voneinander abhängig sind. Zudem kann ein grosser Einfluss von sozialen Netzwerken auf die Diffusion innovativer Politiken sowohl in der quantitativen als auch in der qualitativen Studie festgestellt werden. Eine weiterer nennenswerter Beitrag dieser Studie liegt in der Erstellung eines neuen Datensatzes zu MCPA Beitrittsdaten von Städten in sieben Staaten des Mittleren Westens. Diese Dissertation liefert folglich die erste umfassende und systematische Untersuchung der zeitlichen und räumlichen Diffusion freiwilliger Klimaschutzpolitiken auf lokaler Ebene. Dadurch, dass die grösste Volkswirtschaft und der zweitgrösste CO2 Verursacher im Detail untersucht werden, können wichtige Einblicke gewonnen werden, die auch für andere Länder, insbesondere jene mit föderalen politischen Systemen, Relevanz besitzen. ix Contents 1 Introduction 1 1.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 1.2 Motivation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 1.3 Structure of Dissertation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4 1.4 Conclusion and Outlook . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 2 Climate Change Governance 9 2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 2.2 The Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 2.2.1 Geophysical Aspects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 2.2.2 Social Implications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 Evolution of the Global Governance System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16 2.3.1 Goals of the Global Governance Effort . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 2.3.2 IPCC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 2.3.3 FCCC and Kyoto Protocol . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 Why is International Cooperation Difficult? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 2.4.1 Global Public Goods and the Free-Rider Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 2.4.2 The Contested Economics of Climate Change Mitigation . . . . . . . . . . 24 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 Measuring and Explaining Variation in National Contributions to the Global Public Good . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 2.5.1 Measuring Variation in Contributions to the Public Good . . . . . . . . . 25 2.5.2 Explaining Variation in Mitigation Efforts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 Alternative Forms of Climate Change Governance: Local Dynamics in Federal Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 Normative Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31 x 3 Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? Testing Participation Patterns in Voluntary Initiatives in U.S. Counties 35 3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 3.2 Determinants of Participation in Voluntary Climate Change Initiatives . . . . . . 38 3.2.1 Natural System Factors (Nature) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 3.2.2 Socio-Economic and Political Factors (Nurture) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41 3.2.3 External Influences (Neighbors) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47 3.3.1 Dependent Variable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 3.3.2 Independent Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50 Analysis and Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 3.4.1 Exploratory Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56 3.4.2 Statistical Analysis and Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59 3.4.3 Robustness Checks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68 3.3 3.4 3.5 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79 3.6 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81 4 Voluntary Climate Change Initiatives in the U.S.: Testing Participation in Space and Time 87 4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87 4.2 Background on Voluntary Climate Change Policies in the U.S. . . . . . . . . . . 90 4.3 Theoretical Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95 4.3.1 Puzzle and Theoretical Argument . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95 4.3.2 Determinants of Adoption of Voluntary Climate Change Initiatives . . . . 99 4.4 4.5 Research Design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110 4.4.1 Case Selection . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110 4.4.2 Data Collection: Date of MCPA Adoption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114 4.4.3 Dependent Variable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117 4.4.4 Independent Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121 4.4.5 Statistical Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127 Analysis and Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128 4.5.1 Statistical Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128 4.5.2 Qualitative Evidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143 Kurztitel xi 4.6 Conclusion 4.7 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150 4.7.1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147 Questionnaire . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150 5 ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ Understanding the Mechanisms Leading to Cities’ Participation and Non-Participation in the MCPA 157 5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157 5.2 Research Design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158 5.3 5.2.1 Sampling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158 5.2.2 Conduction of the Study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 163 5.3.1 Reasons for Non-Participation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 163 5.3.2 Reasons for Participation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164 5.3.3 Further Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167 5.3.4 Success of the Agreement as a Whole 5.3.5 Impact on the Federal Government . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 169 5.4 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 172 5.5 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173 5.5.1 Email . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173 5.5.2 Study Information Sheet . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174 5.5.3 Interview Template . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 176 xiii List of Figures 2.1 Comparison of climate model predictions with empirical climate records (Source: IPCC 2007) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 2.2 GHG Emissions Scenarios (Source: IPCC 2007) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 2.3 Estimates of damage resulting from unmitigated climate change. Source: Tol and Yohe 2006 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.1 Counties in the U.S. according to their participation in the MCPA; darker shades indicate a higher percentage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.2 36 Climate zones by county for the U.S.: from 1(very hot, moist) to 7(very cold) (Source Department of Energy) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.3 15 40 Model projections of summer average temperature and precipitation changes in Illinois and Michigan for midcentury (2040-2059), and end-of-century (20802099)(Source (Hayhoe et al. 2009) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.4 Detailed map of participation and cities in the northeast; darker shades indicate a higher percentage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.5 41 50 Counties with at least one city over 10.000 inhabitants; depicted in red are leaders of innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 3.6 Interaction effect between income and % Democrats in the county . . . . . . . . 69 3.7 Interaction effect between % Democrats and unemployment in the county . . . . 71 3.8 Actual count distribution against negative binomial and poisson distribution . . 75 3.9 Comparison of the pattern of % MCPA and fatalities from natural hazards in the 1109 counties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83 3.10 Comparison of the pattern of % Democrats and unemployment rate in the 1109 counties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84 3.11 Analysis of spatial clusters with Local Moran’s I statistic (W: county contiguity) in the 1109 counties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85 xiv 3.12 (Cont’d)Analysis of spatial clusters with Local Moran’s I statistic (W: county contiguity) in the 1109 counties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86 4.1 Cities that have signed the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement . . . . . . . . 88 4.2 Sample of cities and signatories in the seven Midwestern states . . . . . . . . . . 113 4.3 Adoption of the Mayors climate protection agreement (2005-2010) . . . . . . . . 118 4.4 % of cities who signed the MCPA by state (2005-2010) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120 4.5 % of cities who signed the MCPA (2005-2010) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121 4.6 Neighbor relations within 100km . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124 4.7 Neighbor relations within 100km, reduced sample >=30k . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125 4.8 Baseline hazard . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134 4.9 Predicted Probabilities (Baseline model); other variables are kept at their mean; binary variables at their median . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140 5.1 Random sample of 60 cities from 2700 cities according to their participatory status159 5.2 Interviewed cities from sample according to their participatory status . . . . . . 161 xv List of Tables 2.1 Stratospheric Ozone and Climate Cooperation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 3.1 City-level distribution of MCPA participants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 3.2 Distribution of counties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 3.3 Regression table (Baseline) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60 3.4 Spatial ML; W based on county contiguity (0 / 1 ) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 3.5 Spatial ML; W based on Inverse Distance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65 3.6 Spatial ML; W based on Inverse Distance up to 100 km . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 3.7 Basic Models with Proximity to Leaders of Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 3.8 Regression table with Interaction terms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70 3.9 Logistic Regression whether at least one city in the county has signed MCPA . . 72 3.10 OLS (Mean) Regression vs. Quantile (Median) Regression with Koenker-Basset (kb) (1982) standard errors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74 3.11 Negative Binomial Regression on the count of MCPA signatories in the county . 77 3.12 Zero Inflated Negative Binomial Regression on the count of MCPA signatories in the county . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.13 Summary statistics 78 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81 3.14 Pattern of signature of MCPA in all states . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82 4.1 Comparison of the 7 Midwestern states and the U.S. average . . . . . . . . . . . 111 4.2 Climate change related policies on the state-level (Source: Pew Center on Global Climate Change) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111 4.3 Signatories (cities > 10k) per state by July 2010 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118 4.4 Main Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129 4.5 Robustness of main results I; exclucding t and reduced model 4.6 Robustness of main results II; external factors 4.7 Robustness of main results III: networks and impute . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137 . . . . . . . . . . 133 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136 xvi 4.8 Robustness of main results IV: reduced sample (cities >= 30.000) . . . . . . . . 138 4.9 Simulated predicted probabilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141 4.10 Simulated Probabilities, City Examples (for May 2005) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142 4.11 Qualitative evidence is based on returned questionnaires from the following cities 143 5.1 Distribution of states in the sample . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160 5.2 List of Interviewees . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162 1 1 Introduction Lena Maria Schaffer 1.1 Introduction Global climate change is one of the biggest challenges mankind is facing in the 21st century. Prominent attempts to deal with global climate change and to mitigate its consequences have focused on multilateral cooperation and international institutions. The success of these international efforts has been limited. A prime example is the Kyoto protocol. Especially large emitters of greenhouse gases such as the United States, which refused to ratify the Kyoto protocol, are generally reluctant to contribute to this global environmental effort. Given that effective cooperation between nation-states in climate politics is very difficult, the question arises whether there are other possibilities for coping with global climate change at lower political levels. In fact, such climate policy efforts already exist. The largest effort of this kind is the U.S. Mayors Climate Protection Agreement (MCPA). It was initiated by U.S. cities in 2005. Its aim is to advance the goals of the Kyoto Protocol on the local level even if the U.S. federal government lags behind. As of November 2010, 1044 cities have signed this agreement, representing 87 million people, i.e., more than one quarter of the U.S. population. Since the subnational formation of climate policy institutions is a new phenomenon, we know very little about the conditions that motivate subnational jurisdictions to join such efforts. Such knowledge is important for the evaluation of whether cooperation at this level can offer a feasible substitute or at least a useful complement for global efforts. This dissertation seeks to fill this research gap. It examines the determinants of cities’ willingness to commit to local climate change policies. I develop arguments on how various factors influence local governments’ decisions to voluntarily contribute to climate change mitigation efforts. These factors include communityspecific (e.g. income, partisanship, education) and interdependency factors. I argue that local governments’ decisions concerning climate change policies are dependent upon the choices of other local governments, and my aim is to explain these interdependencies in participation in 2 voluntary agreements by determining the role of external influences (e.g. geography or social networks) that act as channels for the diffusion of policies. In the context of the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement, the two main research question of this dissertation are: 1. What are the internal characteristics that lead communities to voluntarily commit to local climate change policies, when there are powerful incentives to do otherwise? 2. What influence do interdependence and network effects play? These two research questions are addressed in different scope throughout the four papers of this dissertation. The first paper, which is co-authored with Thomas Bernauer, gives an overview of global climate change governance and provides the framework within which the following papers on local climate change governance operate. The second paper, then, looks at participation patterns in the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement throughout the United States. I argue that to explain county-level patterns, natural characteristics (Nature), socio-economic and political features (Nurture), as well as the geographical surroundings (Neighbors) have to be taken into account. Interdependence is conceptualized through geographical proximity to neighboring counties and to leaders of innovation. In the third paper, my focus then zooms in on the individual city. I argue that three factors are crucial to the explanation of the temporal and spatial patterns in participation in voluntary climate change agreements: city-internal characteristics, external factors, and time-specific events. External factors that matter for the interdependence in cities’ decision-making concerning the MCPA are geographical neighbors, peers, and social networks. The fourth and final paper then sets out to validate the previous findings concerning internal and external factors using evidence from interviews with mayors and representatives. This paper further addresses the reasons of non-participation with the initiative. 1.2 Motivation The general motivation for looking at these questions is threefold. First, the substantive topic of voluntary political efforts to circumvent the collective action problem in the context of a global public good is inherently interesting and has not been comprehensively analyzed in the context of local climate change policies. Furthermore, arguably absent of an overarching authority that would regulate GHG emissions, implications drawn from this setting represent a unique insight also for models operating from an international politics and comparative politics perspective, where no central authority does exist and collective action problems are omnipresent. Introduction 3 Second, at the theoretical level, the fact that one observes political tensions arising from different approaches (federal and subnational) to the same problem (climate change) within one nation is in itself an interesting topic. Given that research on comparative environmental governance tends to focus on national or supranational policies, but does largely neglect the subnational level, makes it an innovative endeavour to study the subnational interdependence of policy initiatives. Recent developments in the U.S. show that researchers should pay more attention to federalism in general and in particular to the reaction of subnational units in the absence of federal regulation. Furthermore, results from research on these processes can be important for the understanding of environmental policy-making in other federal states or systems of multi-level governance (e.g. the European Union) or, alternatively, in other issue areas. Third, at the methodological level, for many phenomena of interest to social scientists, it is very difficult to argue that we are dealing with independent observations. Far more often, the policy choices of governments depend on previous decisions by other governments. This is mostly referred to as Galton’s Problem (Braun & Gilardi 2006; Jahn 2006). From a methodological perspective, incorporating interdependencies and taking Galton’s Problem seriously is recognized as a necessary step towards improving explanatory models (Simmons & Elkins 2004; Franzese & Hays 2007, 2008b). This task is especially difficult in the comparative and international politics field, where one normally has to control for strong in-sample heterogeneity on top of the difficulties of distinguishing spurious diffusion (Braun & Gilardi 2006) from truly interdependent behavior. Therefore, one of the goals of my dissertation is to contribute to existing research by studying local government behavior towards participation in voluntary initiatives, taking into account city-specific socio-economic, political, as well as environmental factors and distinguishing these factors from interdependent decision-making that emanates from external factors. Thus, this dissertation provides the first comprehensive and systematic account of the temporal and spatial diffusion of voluntary climate change policies within a large country, using GIS and advanced statistical methods to that end. By studying in-depth the largest economy and second largest emitter in the global system, I gain insights that are also relevant to other countries, especially countries with federal political systems. The findings of this dissertation contribute to a better understanding of whether and how subnational climate change mitigation efforts can complement policies at the international level. 4 1.3 Structure of Dissertation In the first paper, Thomas Bernauer and I provide an overview over global climate change governance. We first introduce the climate change problem and provide an historical account on how international institutions have thus far coped with the problem. Having elaborated that the standard governance level for mitigating GHG emissions and, thus, combating global warming, would be a concerted global effort combined with implementation of internationally agreed measures at the level of nation-states, we then turn to the reasons that make the implementation of global governance systems so hard to achieve. Even though cooperation at the global level is difficult, there is strong variation in countries’ level of effort in this respect. We examine how levels of effort can be measured and how variation in effort can be explained. After having moved from the global (systemic) to the national level of analysis, we also explore climate policy-making at the subnational level. We establish that local policy-making is, from an analytical viewpoint, particularly interesting in the case of federal political systems. The three subsequent papers concentrate on the Mayors’ Climate Protection Agreement. In the second paper, I look at the participation pattern of U.S. counties and ask which incentives and disincentives for participation exist. The paper explains participation patterns in the MCPA at the county-level throughout the U.S. by factors regarding the natural characteristics (Nature), socio-economic and political features (Nurture), and geographical surroundings (Neighbors). It is hypothesized that voluntary participation in climate change mitigation efforts are highest when the county is at risk of being adversely affected by climate change, when there are favorable socio-economic and political conditions present, and when the surrounding counties are also strong participators. As far as the natural system characteristics are concerned, being a coastal county seems to drive signature behavior. For socio-economic and political characteristics, drivers of participation are a well-educated population as well as a high percentage of Democratic voters within the county. Furthermore, the presence of universities significantly increases the relative number of signatories. Disincentives for participation include especially bad economic conditions in a county. Depending on model specification, proxies for potential abatement costs are also significantly related to participation. Findings from the spatial analysis indicate some evidence of spatial interdependence in participation, meaning that some of the variation in a county’s participation level can be attributed to participation levels in connected counties. However, of the four different specifications of geographic influence tested, only two support the conjecture of a Introduction 5 significant effect of spatial interdependence. In this cross-sectional large-N perspective, some of the issues that might play a large role for participation namely the temporal variation in signing on to the agreement cannot be studied. Furthermore, while explaining the participation rate in counties serves as a good starting point to examine which factors are important to voluntary action, it cannot provide a complete picture of the phenomenon, as it is on the city-level where the decision-makers within this agreement operate. This is where the third paper ties in. It examines the determinants of cities’ willingness to join the MCPA in cities over 10,000 inhabitants in seven Midwestern states. I develop arguments on how various factors influence local government decisions to voluntarily contribute to climate change mitigation efforts by joining the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. These factors include community-specific internal factors and external factors accounting for cities’ interdependence in decision-making. As far as internal factors are concerned, I argue that there are specific determinants leading to a higher demand for voluntary climate change policies within the city, e.g. a higher percentage of voters that support the Democratic Party, which then make governments more likely to participate in voluntary efforts. I further assume that an initiative to join the MCPA can also emanate from the supply side of local government. Here, the existence of a policy entrepreneur and a mayor-council form of government are considered to increase the propensity to participate. Interdependencies between cities are conceptualized as emanating from geographic linkages to other jurisdictions, peer group effects, as well as from participation in social networks. My theoretical framework is complemented by the consideration of certain events that are assumed to be associated with a city’s decision to sign on to the MCPA. To test my claims, I use an original data set on monthly signing behavior of 749 Midwestern cities from February 2005 to June 2010. I find that a city’s participation in social networks as well as the MCPA signing behavior of cities within the same population group increases a city’s likelihood to participate. Although internal characteristics, such as the % of Democratic votes in the city or human capital endowment, are also significantly related to a higher propensity to sign, their substantive effects are much smaller. As far as pivotal events are concerned, I find that the likelihood of participation significantly increases in the months leading up to a mayoral election in the city. Insights gained from this large-N study are further supported by qualitative evidence from an analysis of questionnaires sent to a subsample of the 749 Midwestern cities. Although this analysis provides me with a more complete picture of the temporal dynamics, the 6 mayors as the actors behind the a city’s participation decision have only partially been taken into account. The previous three papers of this dissertation on local climate change policies continuously reduce their focus. Starting from a general overview of global climate change governance, I then concentrate on subnational units within the U.S. I explain county-level participation patterns in the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement as well as city-level diffusion effects of the initiative in a temporal setting. In the two papers on the MCPA, mayors have implicitly been considered to be the ones that have to make the decision to participate in MCPA, but have not been explicitly asked about the reasons why they decided to (not) participate in the MCPA. The last paper finally opens the black box of the decision-maker in providing qualitative evidence from interviews with mayors. As regards the motivational reasons of mayors to join the MCPA, a majority of the interviewed mayors that have not signed, argue that the whole MCPA initiative is only about symbolic politics. In their opinion it serves to potentially advance a signing mayor’s political career, but produces no significant climate change policy output. Conversely, mayors who have signed the agreement claim that their reasons for participation had to do either with the federal inaction on the climate change topic or an already existing interest for environmental politics. With respect to the reasons for not signing, mayors state that there either was no demand for such policies or they have other local policy priorities, e.g. economic development policies. 1.4 Conclusion and Outlook Recent developments in the U.S., but also on a global scale, show that researchers should pay more attention to the reaction of subnational units to climate change in the absence of federal or global regulation. On November 21, 2010, Mayors from around the world met at the World Mayors Summit on Climate in Mexico City and signed a voluntary pact committing themselves to the reduction of urban greenhouse gas emissions.1 They agreed to install a ’carbon Cities Climate Registry’ (cCCR) as a first step towards harmonizing the reporting of urban GHGs. Through this mechanism, city residents will be able to track how their city is performing vis-a-vis other cities around the globe. 1 For more information, visit http://edition.cnn.com/2010/WORLD/americas/11/22/world.mayor.summit. review/index.html?hpt=Mid Introduction 7 With the increasing commitment of cities in the U.S. and worldwide to the reduction of CO2 emissions in order to mitigate the consequences of anthropogenic climate change, it becomes ever more important to understand the factors that make localities more likely to engage in local climate change policies. This dissertation has provided the first comprehensive and systematic account of the main factors that lead to participation as well as concerning the temporal and spatial diffusion of voluntary climate change policies in the U.S. Overall, the results of this inquiry highlight the importance of community-specific characteristics for the participation in the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. Conditions that are conducive to voluntary climate change mitigation efforts are a well-educated and liberal population. Factors pertaining to the natural environment play a role, especially for those communities situated along coastal areas, linking participation to the vulnerability to impacts from global climate change. A substantive contribution of this thesis arises from the consideration of external factors that are assumed to have an impact on the locality above and beyond its community-specific characteristics. I find some evidence for interdependent decision-making in local climate change policymaking. A notable finding of my thesis is that geographical proximity does not turn out to be a robust factor to explain interdependencies in local climate change policy adoption. This contradicts most of the scholarly literature on policy diffusion, where the influence of geographical neighbors on policy adoption is one of the most consistent research findings (Berry & Berry 1999). A comparatively stronger external effect on a local community’s decision to sign the agreement emanates from social networks and peer groups. The importance of social networks of mayors for the diffusion of innovation is backed by evidence in both my quantitative and qualitative studies. While the influence of other cities’ choices on local climate change policies is consistently confirmed, it becomes clear that ’space is more than geography’ (Beck et al. 2006) when it comes to MCPA participation . An additional notable contribution of this thesis lies in the collection of a unique data set on city-level MCPA adoption dates in seven Midwestern states. The particular merit of this large-scale data collection effort lies in the possibilities that it creates for the comparison of results from large-N studies and qualitative evidence from local decision-makers. Future research should build on and extend the findings of my research by looking into the patterns of actual implementation and the substantive policy output that emerges from subnational climate change efforts. Such an extension would allow us to shed light on the different 8 motivations of decision-makers to join voluntary efforts. Being able to distinguish symbolic participation from substantive participation would be a major improvement over existing research. Nevertheless, even if the actual impact from these local climate change initiatives on measurable indicators of mitigation would turn out to be negligible, my research has already found that even symbolic, voluntary agreements can act as good complements to actual policies in that they raise awareness for the issue and break common ground. The mayors’ engagement in climate change issues has definitely brought cities on the forefront of this issue. This can be seen as a fairly new development in American politics, where states are traditionally considered to be the ’laboratories of democracy’ that test novel approaches that eventually become national policy. Together with states, cities have emerged as the de facto leaders on climate change issues. Although a comprehensive national policy on climate change mitigation has still not been enacted and now, after the November 2010 election, looks even less likely to be enacted, actions in individual states and cities put pressure on the federal government by creating a patchwork of different rules in different states and cities that goes at the expense of and causes frustration among corporate actors. Furthermore, due to the 2009 decision by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) that greenhouse gases can be regulated under the Clean Air Act if they pose a danger to public health, the EPA has gained additional powers to regulate, e.g. minimum standards of energy efficiency. However, what happens within the United States on the issue of climate change mitigation policy as well as on a global scale is far from being settled and remains an important and interesting question for academic inquiry. 9 2 Climate Change Governance Thomas Bernauer and Lena Maria Schaffer 2.1 Introduction Within less than three decades, climate change has developed from a rather obscure scientific topic into a key item on the global political agenda. It has also attracted strong attention in many areas of scientific research, including the social sciences. Social scientists, and notably governance specialists focusing on climate change have addressed a wide range of important questions, including the following: • What are the key political challenges in establishing and implementing governance systems to cope with climatic changes? • Why are some countries in the international system more cooperative than others in this respect? • To what extent can local efforts in climate policy support national and global efforts? • What are the main normative issues associated with climate change policy, notably, how should the costs and benefits associated with solving the problem be distributed across countries and time? • Which policy instruments are likely to be more effective and/or efficient in dealing with climate change? In this contribution we focus mainly on the first four of these questions. The existing literature on particular climate policy instruments (e.g. carbon taxes, tradable permits, joint implementation) is very large and has been summarized elsewhere (e.g. Stavins 2003).1 1 These include regulations and standards, taxes and charges, tradable emissions permits, subsidies and tax credits, voluntary agreements between industry and government, awareness campaigns, government sponsored and/or subsidized R&D, and integration of climate policy objectives in development, trade, and investment policies. 10 We start with an overview of the climate change problem (section 2), followed by a discussion of international institutions that have thus far been established to cope with the challenge (section 3). We then look at the reasons why global cooperation for climate change mitigation is difficult to achieve (section 4). Section 5 shows that, even though cooperation at the global level is difficult, there is strong variation in countries’ level of effort in this respect. We examine how levels of effort can be measured and how variation in effort can be explained. After having moved from the global (systemic) to the national level of analysis, we also explore climate policy-making at the sub national level (section 6). Local policy-making is, from an analytical viewpoint, particularly interesting in the case of federal political systems. The chapter ends in section 7 with a brief discussion of normative issues. 2.2 The Problem 2.2.1 Geophysical Aspects In contrast to the weather, which is highly variable both spatially and temporally, the global climate is much more stable. It can be regarded as the Earth’s average weather and/or its variability over longer periods of time (typically at least decades). Whereas the weather can be experienced directly by humans, the climate is a scientific (essentially statistical) construct. For instance, while temperatures can easily vary by 20˚C in a particular location within a single day, the average global temperature does not vary by more than 1-5˚C within time-spans of thousands of years. Changes in the Earth’s climate took place also in pre-modern times (before the industrial revolution). Such changes occurred due to non-human factors, e.g. changes in heat output of the sun and volcanic activity. However, starting in 1896 with the Swedish chemist Svante Arrhenius, scientists have produced a mounting stream of evidence demonstrating that so called greenhouse gases (GHG) emitted by human activities are influencing the Earth’s climate as well. Several gases in the atmosphere, most notably water vapor and carbon dioxide (CO2 ), are instrumental in trapping some of the sun’s energy to which the Earth is exposed. This greenhouse effect is essential for life on Earth. Without this heat trapping the Earth would be more than 30˚C colder. Yet, human activity, in particular the combustion of fossil fuels (coal, oil, gas) and land-use changes, have led to a large increase in concentrations of GHGs in the atmosphere. Atmospheric concentrations of the two most important GHGs emitted by human activity, CO2 Climate Change Governance 11 (carbon dioxide) and CH4 (methane)2 , were far higher in the year 2005 than the natural range of these gases in the past 650.000 years. CO2 has increased from a pre-industrial (i.e. prior to about 1750) level of 280ppm to 379ppm in 2005, and CH4 from 715 to 1774ppm (IPCC 2007b). Climate scientists have over the past several decades invested an enormous amount of effort in trying to understand the causal pathways leading from 1. vastly increased anthropogenic GHG emissions since the industrial revolution (with a 70% growth in 1970-2004 alone) to 2. growing atmospheric concentrations of GHGs to 3. changes in radiative forcing to 4. changes in temperature (about 0.75˚C over the past 100 years, with more warming in northern latitudes, and greater warming over land than over the oceans) and precipitation to 5. various effects of changes in temperature and precipitation on plants, animals, and humans. The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (c.f. section 3.2 IPCC 2007a), a large global network including thousands of scientists and also policy-makers, has so far issued four comprehensive reports. These reports summarize and assess the available scientific evidence on the causes and implications of climate change, as well as policy options for coping with the problem. The IPCC stands out, by orders of magnitude, as the largest and most tightly organized science-policy nexus in the history of governance efforts in any policy-area we can think of. This unprecedented scientific effort has over the past two decades resulted in increasingly firm international agreement that anthropogenic GHG emissions are responsible for a large part of the observed global warming trend. Interestingly, the main conclusion from this scientific effort is rather close to what Arrhenius argued more than 100 years ago; that a doubling of CO2 concentrations in the atmosphere would increase global average temperature by around 5˚C (current estimates are around 1.5 to 4.5 degrees). More generally, the IPCC (2007b, 10) notes that: ’Most of the observed increase in globally averaged temperatures since the mid-20th century is very likely due to the observed increase in anthropogenic (human) greenhouse gas concentrations.’ 2 Other important GHGs include nitrous oxide (N2O) and halocarbons. 12 Figure 2.1: Comparison of climate model predictions with empirical climate records (Source: IPCC 2007) Note: Blue = models including only natural causes. Red = models including natural and anthropogenic causes. Black line = decadal averages of observations 1906-2005 plotted against the centre of the decade and relative to the corresponding average for 1901-1950. Dashed line = spatial coverage less than 50%.Blue shaded bands = 5 to 95% range for 19 simulations from five climate models using only the natural forcings (solar activity, volcanoes). Red shaded Bands: 5 to 95% range for 58 simulations from 14 climate models using both natural and anthropogenic forcings. Figure 2.1 illustrates that computer models trying to reconstruct the empirical climate record tend to perform better once anthropogenic emissions are included alongside non-human drivers of climatic changes. While ex post explanation of climatic changes in terms of anthropogenic GHG emissions is very complex, prediction of future temperature and precipitation is even more challenging. The main reason is that, besides incomplete understanding of geophysical mechanisms, there is great uncertainty concerning future GHG emissions. For instance, depending on assumptions about technological innovations, economic growth (which in itself is hard to predict over several decades) may be associated with very different levels of emissions. As illustrated by Figure 2.2, one IPCC scenario (A1FI) assumes rapid economic growth, rapid introduction of new and more efficient but fossil fuel intensive technologies, a mid century peak of global population, and a substantial reduction in regional differences in per capita income. In Climate Change Governance 13 ! Figure 2.2: GHG Emissions Scenarios (Source: IPCC 2007) Note: Global GHG emissions (in GtCO2 -eq per year) in the absence of additional climate policies: six illustrative SRES marker scenarios (coloured lines) and 80th percentile range of scenarios published since SRES (post-SRES) (gray shaded area). Dashed lines show the full range of post- SRES scenarios. The emissions include CO2 , CH4 , N2O and F-gases this scenario, global GHG emissions are predicted to increase from around 40 Gt CO2 -eq/yr in 2000 to about 130 Gt in 2100. Another IPCC scenario (B1) assumes a convergent world with the same population, but rapid changes in economic structures toward a service and information economy, the introduction of clean and resource efficient technologies, and an emphasis on global solutions to problems of environmental sustainability. In this scenario, emissions are predicted to increase to about 30 Gt CO2 -eq/yr by 2100 (IPCC 2007, Special Report on Emissions scenarios). Because GHGs are quite long-lived, even very optimistic emissions scenarios are likely to result in considerable global warming. The IPCC (46ff. 2007a) notes that: ’Anthropogenic warming and sea level rise would continue for centuries due to the timescales associated with climate processes and feedbacks, even if greenhouse 14 gas concentrations were to be stabilized, although the likely amount of temperature and sea level rise varies greatly depending on the fossil intensity of human activity during the next century [...]. The probability that this is caused by natural climatic processes alone is less than 5% ...World temperatures could rise by between 1.1 and 6.4˚C during the 21st century. Sea levels will probably rise by 18 to 59 cm [...]. There is a confidence level >90% that there will be more frequent warm spells, heat waves and heavy rainfall [...]. There is a confidence level >66% that there will be an increase in droughts, tropical cyclones and extreme high tides [...]. Both past and future anthropogenic carbon dioxide emissions will continue to contribute to warming and sea level rise for more than a millennium.’ 2.2.2 Social Implications The projected social implications of climatic changes depend very much on projected emissions and their radiative forcing. The IPCC (2007a)’s best estimates range from +0.6˚C by 20902099, compared to 1980-1999, in the case of continuing year 2000 concentrations (which is next to impossible in view of still growing global emissions), to +2.8˚C in a moderately optimistic scenario (A1B), to 4.0˚C and more in pessimistic scenarios. Projected sea level rise by the end of the 21st century is up to 0.59 meters in the standard scenarios. In extreme scenarios, such as those involving a complete loss of the Greenland and West Antarctica ice sheets, sea levels could rise by 7 meters or more. Besides the large natural sciences literature on the implications of climate change for weather patterns, water availability, natural disasters, plants, animals, and ecosystems, a considerable social sciences literature on climate change implications has developed as well. This literature seeks to clarify the social, economic, political and security implications of climate change. The largest part of existing social sciences research examines climate change implications in terms of economic losses and other forms of social damage (e.g. changing livelihoods, public health problems, migration), as well as adaptive capacity (e.g. Adger 2010; Fuessel 2010). By and large, this research arrives at the conclusion that poorer countries are at greatest risk, both in terms of exposure to climatic changes and sensitivity to such changes, and in terms of their capacity to adapt. Exposure, sensitivity, and capacity to adapt determine how vulnerable particular countries or social groups are to climatic changes (Fuessel 2010). Social scientists have also sought to quantify overall effects of climatic changes on economic growth in the past and project economic losses under different emissions and mitigation scenarios into the future (e.g. Stern et al. 2006; Stern 2008). Ex post statistical analysis has thus far produced some evidence that higher temperature and lower precipitation are associated with Climate Change Governance 15 Figure 2.3: Estimates of damage resulting from unmitigated climate change. Source: Tol and Yohe 2006 lower economic growth, particularly in Africa, though these findings are not very robust (e.g. Miguel et al. 2004; Dell et al. 2008; Bernauer, Koubi, Kalbhenn & Ruoff 2010). Estimates of future effects on economic growth under different climate scenarios are based on so called integrated assessment models that explore national, regional, and global cost implications. The findings from these models vary enormously. Having reviewed many such studies, the IPCC (2007b) for instance concludes: ’Global mean losses could be 1-5% of GDP for 4 degrees of warming, but regional losses could be substantially higher.’ Yet, as illustrated by Figure 2.3, cost implications reported by the influential Stern Review (Stern et al. 2006) are substantially larger than estimates provided by other scientific reports. One of the principal sources of vast differences in estimated costs of unmitigated climate change (i.e. costs in the absence of international cooperation and GHG emissions cuts) is the discount rate. The discount rate captures the extent to which future losses are less important economically than present losses. The reasons for discounting future losses are that people generally prefer the present to the future, that consumption will be higher in the future due to increased wealth (with decreasing marginal utility), that future consumption levels are uncertain, and that future technology may make it cheaper to cut emissions then. The higher the discount rate used to deflate the stream of future losses to a present value, the lower is the presently valued damage from future climate change. For instance, if we assume an annual discount rate 16 of 3%, a climate damage of $100 occurring in 25 years is worth only $50 today. While some economists (e.g. Nordhaus 2010) use standard discount rates from the investment world (around 2-3%), others (e.g. Stern 2008; Cline 1999) argue that such discount rates are too high. They use discount rates in the order of 1-2%, which are close to real interest rates for government bonds. The choice of discount rate has important implications for the assessment of governance options and involves strong normative components, to which we return in the final section of the chapter (see final section of the chapter). Repeated statements by high-ranking politicians about climate change-related wars have triggered yet another intense research effort in which social scientists are examining the validity of this claim. US President Obama, for instance, claimed in 20093 that ’The threat of climate change is serious, it is urgent and it is growing [...] The security and stability of each nation and all peoples – our prosperity, our health, our safety – are in jeopardy. And the time we have to reverse this tide is running out.’ The most likely scenario for an interstate war involves competition over scarce international water resources, food and energy, or mass migration (for extreme scenarios, see Schwartz & Randall 2003). Interestingly, existing research offers virtually no historical evidence for climate related international wars. Whether climate change could increase the probability of intrastate (i.e. civil) war is more strongly debated. A few studies (e.g. Burke et al. 2009) identify such an effect for Africa in the 1980s and 1990s and make rather worrying projections for the future. Yet, these findings remain very much contested and other authors, using similar data, do not find a significant effect of climatic changes on the probability of intrastate war (e.g. Buhaug et al. 2008; Theisen et al. 2010; Bernauer, Koubi, Kalbhenn & Ruoff 2010). 2.3 Evolution of the Global Governance System As noted above, science plays a major role in climate policy. Hence we start by discussing what are, from the viewpoint of many scientists and policy-makers, the basic goals of the global governance effort. We then describe the IPCC, the principal global institution for knowledgegeneration in this policy area. Finally we discuss the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (FCCC) and the Kyoto Protocol (KP). The latter two are, from a legal viewpoint, the backbone of the existing global governance system. 3 Delivering a speech at the climate change summit of the United Nations on 22nd of September 2009. Climate Change Governance 17 2.3.1 Goals of the Global Governance Effort A strong global consensus has emerged over the past few years that climatic changes must be addressed through mitigation of GHG emissions and, because some major climatic changes are unavoidable even with extremely ambitious mitigation efforts, adaptation. The key questions in this respect are: 1. by how much should GHG emissions be reduced, and in what time frame? 2. how much would this cost, and how should the burden be distributed among countries and over time? 3. how much should be invested in adaptation and who should pay for it? (1) The policy positions of many countries have, over the past few years, converged on the goal of limiting the global average temperature increase to 2˚C, relative to the mid-18th century level. From the perspective of most scientists, a temperature target makes more sense than an emissions or concentrations target because it is ultimately temperature that affects ecosystems and humanity. The 2˚C target emerged from discussions among scientists and policy-makers in Germany in the mid-1990s. The 2˚C temperature increase was initially used as a rather arbitrarily chosen parameter to examine climate change impacts, e.g. impacts on the Earth’s major ice sheets. When many models indicated major damages or uncertainties beyond that level (e.g. with respect to the long-term stability of the Greenland ice sheet), the two degrees developed into a political target, even though there is no clear-cut scientific reason for this particular choice. Recent calculations by Allen et al. (2009) show that it would be necessary to limit total CO2 emissions in the 2000 – 2050 period to 1000 billion tons in order to meet the 2˚C target. One third of this CO2 budget has already been used in 2000 – 2009. Consequently, emissions would have to be cut by 50% by 2050, which would implicate reductions of 25-40% by industrialized countries until 2020, and 80-95% until 2050. These targets are, by and large, in line with IPCC 2007 statements and the Stern Review. (2) Various studies have tried to estimate by how much global carbon prices (the total cost an emitter of a unit of GHG would have to pay for) would have to increase in order to reach specific reduction targets. The IPCC (2007b) for instance notes a figure of $20-80 18 per ton of CO2 equivalent by 2030 to stabilize GHG concentrations at 550ppm (roughly a doubling of pre-industrial concentrations, which were 280ppm then and 379ppm in 2005) by 2100. Optimistic studies indicate $5-$65 (IPCC 2007b). The IPCC’s best estimates of the costs of stabilizing GHG concentrations at 535-590ppm, which would probably meet the 2˚C target, are in the order of a 0.1% reduction of average annual GDP growth rates. The Stern Report arrives at a similar estimate. On the more pessimistic side, Nordhaus (2010) estimates that reaching the 2˚C target would require a carbon price of $64 in 2010 (at 2005 prices), whereas the global average price today is around $5, and rapid growth of this price over the next few years. How to share the burden of GHG reductions remains disputed. At the most general level, there is agreement that industrialized countries must shoulder most of the mitigation costs over the coming decades. The Kyoto Protocol (see below) in fact assigns that responsibility to this group of countries in the 2008 – 2012 period. But there is no consensus on how to deal with very large, and rapidly growing developing countries, notably Brazil, China, and India. We return to this point in the final section of the chapter. (3) As noted by the IPCC (2007b): ’Much less information is available about the costs and effectiveness of adaptation measures than about mitigation measures.’ In any event, the costs are likely to be high and can most probably not be met by poor countries, which tend to be most vulnerable to climatic changes. Estimates of adaptation costs range from lower two digit billion figures to $200 billion and more per year. At the Copenhagen Conference in late 2009, industrialized countries promised adaptation support in the order of $100 billion per year in the future. But it remains unclear how firm these promises really are, how much each industrialized country would contribute, and how the funding mechanism should be designed. 2.3.2 IPCC The IPCC is an intergovernmental institution. Its task is to summarize and assess existing scientific knowledge on human-induced climate change and its impacts, as well as options for mitigation and adaptation. It was set up in 1988 by the UN World Meteorological Organization (WMO) and the UN Environment Programme (UNEP). Its secretariat is located in Geneva, Switzerland. Its activities are funded by WMO, UNEP, and by direct contributions from governments. Climate Change Governance 19 The IPCC does not carry out ’in-house’ research, nor does it act as a monitoring agency in implementing global climate agreements (see below). It acts primarily as manager of a large network of scientists worldwide. Its activity centers around so called Assessment Reports. Such reports have thus far been published in 1990/92, 1995, 2001 and 2007. The next report is scheduled for 2014. The scientists involved, usually several thousand from more than one hundred countries, review the relevant scientific literature and, with the help of lead editors, summarize and assess the existing knowledge. This process is organized in three working groups: Working Group I examines geophysical aspects of the climate system and climate change; Working Group II examines vulnerability of socio-economic and natural systems to climate change, consequences, and adaptation options; and Working Group III examines options for limiting greenhouse gas emissions and mitigating climate change in other ways. The IPCC also includes a ’Task Force on National Greenhouse Gas Inventories’. In the judgment of most observers, the work on the Assessment Reports proceeds largely according to scientific criteria of due diligence. However, the synthesis work and summaries for policy-makers are also exposed to political influence because the Panel, which is composed of government delegates from all member countries, ultimately decides on their adoption. Hence the wording in the summary for policy-makers (but not the content of the detailed reports by the working groups) is subject to some political negotiation. However, governments have thus far hesitated to modify, for political purposes, the main conclusions drawn from scientific assessments. 2.3.3 FCCC and Kyoto Protocol The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (FCCC) was formally adopted at the Rio, or Earth Summit in 1992 (UN Conference on Environment and Development, UNCED). Its aim is the ’stabilization of greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere at a level that would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system. Such a level should be achieved within a time-frame sufficient to allow ecosystems to adapt naturally to climate change, to ensure that food production is not threatened and to enable economic development to proceed in a sustainable manner.’ (Art. 2, FCCC) This global treaty does not set forth mandatory emission constraints, overall or for specific countries. Yet it has established the basic legal structure for future agreements and has defined, at a very general level, the goals to be achieved in climate policy. The FCCC entered into force in March 1994 and, as of late 2009, has attracted 192 member countries. Supported by the 20 IPCC Task Force on National Greenhouse Gas Inventories and the FCCC secretariat in Bonn, Germany, the FCCC members have established national inventories of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and removals. These inventories served to identify the 1990 emission levels that are the benchmarks for emission reduction obligations under the Kyoto Protocol. The so-called Annex I countries (OECD countries and transition economies) are committed to periodically update these inventories. Since 1995 the member countries of the FCCC have met each year in Conferences of the Parties (COP). These meetings serve to review the implementation of the agreement and negotiate follow-up agreements. The most important outcome thus far is the Kyoto Protocol (KP). This Protocol was adopted in December 1997 and entered into force in February 2005 (after 55 countries representing 55% of global CO2 emissions in 1990 had ratified). The Protocol has (as of late 2009) 187 countries that have ratified it. The most important holdouts are the United States, Afghanistan, Somalia, and Taiwan. Under the KP, industrialized countries (Annex I countries) have undertaken to reduce six GHGs (carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, sulphur hexafluoride, hydrofluorocarbons, and perfluorocarbons4 ), of which carbon dioxide and methane are the most important in terms of the size of their greenhouse effect. 39 of 40 potential Annex I countries (except the USA) have ratified, and 34 countries have committed to emission reductions – 5 of the KP Annex I members are allowed to maintain or increase their 1990 emission levels (e.g. Russia, Australia, Iceland). The European Union is treated as a ’bubble’: it received a single target and then allocated emission rights to its member countries. Total reductions are supposed to be in the order of 5.2% by 2012, from the 1990 level (each GHG is weighed by its global warming potential). The KP also provides for ’flexible mechanisms’, such as emissions trading, the clean development mechanism, and joint implementation. The purpose of these economic instruments is to make GHG emissions cuts more cost-efficient, with the assumption that countries are willing to curb their emissions more if doing so is cheaper. Monitoring of compliance relies primarily on annual reports of GHG emissions by Annex I countries and (on a voluntary basis) by other countries. Most observers of the KP agree that many Annex I countries are currently experiencing difficulties in meeting their emissions targets domestically and are likely to make use of flexible mechanisms in order to be able to meet their legal obligations. Also, the USA, which has not ratified the KP but could still implement its Kyoto targets voluntarily, has increased its emissions 4 CO2 , CH4 , N2O, HFC, PFC, SF6. Climate Change Governance 21 quite dramatically (its Kyoto target was -7% relative to the 1990 level). Moreover, negotiations on a follow-up agreement to the KP, which ends in 2012, have thus far failed, most recently in Copenhagen. A recent study (Rogelj et al. 2010) suggest that, even if all unilateral reduction pledges made at Copenhagen were implemented, the probability of limiting global warming to 3˚C by 2100 would only be 50%, while global emissions would increase by 20% over 2010 levels. If emissions were cut by 50% by 2050 the probability of exceeding 2˚C would still be 50%. 2.4 Why is International Cooperation Difficult? GHG reduction targets set forth in existing governance arrangements are still far from what would be required to limit temperature increases to 2˚C. It remains unclear whether those rather non-ambitious targets will be reached by 2012, and even greater uncertainty exists with respect to unilateral pledges for the post-2012 period and the prospects for formal, follow-up international agreements. At the most general level, namely the global political and economic system, climate change mitigation is difficult because it has the character of a global public good. Moreover, there is considerable disagreement over the costs and benefits of GHG mitigation. We discuss these two problems in this section. The following section (section 5) sheds light on additional challenges to effective governance that emanate from country characteristics, such as differences in economic conditions and political institutions, which make some countries more reluctant to cooperate than others. 2.4.1 Global Public Goods and the Free-Rider Problem Climate change mitigation is one of the most typical public goods problems imaginable. Efforts to reduce GHGs correspond by and large to an N-actor prisoner’s dilemma, which is similar to the tragedy of the commons (Hardin 1968). The Earth has one indivisible atmosphere that can be used as a sink for GHG emissions worldwide; i.e. it is a common pool resource characterized by open access and rivalry in consumption (Ostrom et al. 1994). By implication, GHG reductions by any country generate costs and benefits (in terms of avoided damages) for that country, but also benefits for other countries (positive externalities). Because in the climate case positive externalities from emission cuts are quite large in relation to national benefits, international cooperation is necessary, but countries are reluctant to do so. 22 For example, if Italy or Ireland were to cut its GHG emissions by 20%, but no other country did the same, this reduction would probably create some local benefits of a non-climatic nature (e.g. less local air pollution, more technological innovation) and some, albeit minuscule climatic benefits. But the overall net benefit for the respective country would probably be very small and could even be negative. Assuming that countries follow a rationalist, interest-based logic when deciding on their climate policy, they will not implement any major unilateral GHG emission cuts unless other countries credibly commit to a similar policy (e.g. Sandler 1997; Barrett 2003; Mitchell 2006). The Kyoto Protocol reflects this problem very clearly: it requires ratification by 55 countries representing 55% of global emissions before entry into force. This clause protects countries from getting ’caught up’ in legal obligations to reduce emissions if they ratify early but other countries (and major emitters in particular) end up not joining. In essence, global governance in climate change policy uses mechanisms of reciprocity to prevent free riding on positive externalities. Reciprocity implies that each country exchanges its commitment to reduce emissions against similar commitments by other countries. The international climate change regime described above is quite typical in this regard. It offers an arena for step-by-step cooperation and exchanges of information (monitoring). As is the case with most global governance systems, the climate regime has no centralized enforcement mechanisms but relies on monitoring instruments inside and outside the regime to identify non-complying countries, and on decentralized enforcement in the form of political and economic pressure imposed by governments and other actors on non-complying countries. Several cases of successful international cooperation for the provision of global public goods, such as cooperation to protect the stratospheric ozone layer, demonstrate that problems of this type can be solved. Hence the public goods character of climate change mitigation alone cannot explain why climate policy is progressing much slower than say cooperation in the ozone case (Barrett 2003; Oye & Maxwell 1995). The similarities and differences between the two cases, some of which are summarized in Table 2.1, suggest that we need to account for costs and benefits as well. Table 2.1 suggests that the costs of climate change mitigation are much higher than the costs of dealing with the stratospheric ozone problem. However, as discussed in the next subsection, mitigation costs and benefits remain contested. This circumstance, together with the global public goods character of the climate change issue, makes global cooperation difficult. Climate Change Governance 23 Table 2.1: Stratospheric Ozone and Climate Cooperation Stratospheric ozone regime Climate change regime Type of problem Framework convention, followed by protocols Framework convention, followed by protocols Costs (damage) if mitigation effort fails Short to long term, clearly identifiable damages (e.g. higher skin cancer rates, crop damage); developing and developed countries are approx. equally vulnerable to damages Medium to long term damage that is difficult to quantify; developing countries are more vulnerable to damage Mitigation costs Less than $10 billion globally; substitutes for ozone depleting chemicals (ODS) are available; phase-out costs are spread over around 2-3 decades; costs are spread across a vast number of consumers, but per capita costs of more expensive substitutes for ODS are very small Several hundred billion $; substitutes are partly available; phaseout costs are spread over many decades; costs are spread across a vast number of consumers, with rather high per capita costs 24 2.4.2 The Contested Economics of Climate Change Mitigation As noted above, uncertainty concerning the costs of failing to reduce GHG emissions (and, conversely, the benefits of GHG reductions) remains rather high. The same holds for the costs of reducing GHG emissions. Uncertainty with respect to benefits and costs combines to create serious difficulties in estimating the net benefits (benefits minus costs) of reducing emissions. The IPCC and the Stern Review arrive at a favorable net benefit assessment because they use rather pessimistic assumptions about climate change related damages, rather optimistic assumptions about mitigation costs, and a low discount rate. For instance, Watson (2009) argues that • ’do nothing’ would result in an average annual loss of 5-20% of global GDP now and forever due to a 50% chance of exceeding a 5˚C temperature increase by 2100 (relative to pre-industrial levels); • moving to a 550ppm trajectory would result in costs of 1% of global GDP in 2050, with a 50% change of exceeding a 3˚C temperature rise; • moving to a 450ppm trajectory would cost about 3% of GDP in 2050 and would offer a 50% change of remaining below a 2˚C temperature increase. Net benefit estimates by other social scientists, e.g. Nordhaus (2010) and Tol & Yohe (2006) are more pessimistic. The main reason is that they use higher discount rates, which leads to lower estimates of the present value of (discounted) future climate change-related damages and lower costs of mitigation the more mitigation is postponed. Based on their respective assessment, the IPCC and the Stern Review arrive at very different conclusions compared to Nordhaus, Tol, and some other economists. While the former point to large net benefits of starting early with major GHGs reductions, the latter advocate starting slowly and implementing deep cuts only in the long run. Note, however, that none of these studies denies that human-induced climate change exists and poses very serious problems, and that major emission cuts are necessary. But they disagree on when emissions should be cut by how much in order to generate net benefits to present-day decision-makers. It is easy to see why many policy-makers are more attracted to the Nordhaus-type estimates than the Stern-type estimates. Policies that incur rather high costs in the short-term and uncertain, even though potentially high benefits in the medium to long run are inherently less attractive than policies that generate a ’return on investment’ within the near future. Climate Change Governance 25 2.5 Measuring and Explaining Variation in National Contributions to the Global Public Good Most research on climate change governance concentrates on describing and explaining the climate change policies of individual countries or regions. Rather few studies focus explicitly on explaining observed variation across a large number of countries in national contributions to climate change mitigation. The following section discusses how national contributions to global climate change mitigation have been measured. The subsequent section deals with the main explanations in the existing literature. 2.5.1 Measuring Variation in Contributions to the Public Good To explain differences in climate change mitigation efforts across countries, we need, first of all, indicators that provide accurate und useful information on various dimensions of national mitigation efforts. These indicators must cover two principal dimensions: policy outputs and policy outcomes. Policy outputs include laws, regulations and various other types of policy measures that can tell us how serious or ambitious a government is about climate change mitigation. Policy outcomes are phenomena located either at the interface of human behavior and the environment, such as emissions, or environmental conditions mitigation policies are aiming at, such as GHG concentrations in the atmosphere. Existing research focuses mainly either on policy output or policy outcome, though some composite indicators have recently been developed to bundle information on different facets of climate change mitigation efforts. Economists have concentrated mainly on environmental outcomes, such as emissions, and usually explain those with economic factors (Holtz-Eakin & Selden 1995). The political science and international relations literature, in contrast, pays more attention to environmental policy-making and thus also policy output, for instance international political commitments (e.g. Von Stein 2008; Bernauer, Kalbhenn, Koubi & Spilker 2010; Sprinz & Vaahtoranta 1994). Very few studies offer a direct comparison of differences in climate change policy output and outcomes (see Congleton 1992; Baettig & Bernauer 2009; Ward 2008). Environmental performance indicators have become quite popular in research on sustainable development in recent years (e.g. Singh et al. 2009). Yet, the construction of such composite indicators is methodologically challenging and their validity is usually contested (e.g. Boehringer & Jochem 2007; Singh et al. 2009). Freudenberg (2003, 29), for instance, advises researchers to 26 bear the conceptual limits of composite indicators they use in mind and accompany them ’by an account of their methodological limits and include detailed explanations of the underlying data set, choice of standardization technique and selection of weighting method ’. To draw robust inferences about the determinants of cross-national and longitudinal variation in national climate change mitigation efforts we need data on many countries over longer periods of time. Such data is readily available for GHG emissions, and existing scientific debates focus primarily on whether explanatory models should focus on emission levels or on trends, and which GHGs and sources should be included in policy outcome variables. The largest data gap exists with respect to policy outputs. Existing large-N data sets for climate change policy outputs are thus far rather simple in terms of the types of policy output they capture, and they are mostly cross-sectional (e.g. Baettig & Bernauer 2009; Germanwatch 2010). Finally, large-N data on climate adaptation efforts does, unfortunately, not yet exist. 2.5.2 Explaining Variation in Mitigation Efforts The most prominent explanations of variation in mitigation efforts focus on economic factors, political factors, and risk-related factors. The Environmental Kuznets Curve and related determinants Among economists the most popular explanation for differences in environmental behavior across countries and over time is the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC).5 The latter holds that an inverted u-shaped relationship exists between income and pollution. Grossman & Krueger (1995) are usually credited for the first empirical test of the EKC (c.f. Dasgupta et al. 2002; Dinda 2004) in their study of the relationship between pollutants (SO2 and smoke) and income per capita, where they identify such a relationship. Recent research argues, however, that economic growth has somewhat more complex effects on pollution, including GHG emissions. Three types of effects are usually considered: a scale effect, a composition effect, and a technological effect. Since more economic output due to economic growth tends to increase pollution and waste, economic growth is assumed to have a negative scale effect on the environment. The composition effect is argued to have a positive impact on environmental performance because economies usually develop from (dirtier) manufacturing towards (cleaner) services industries. As long as the composition effect does not simply lead to 5 See also de Bruyn & Heintz (1998); Dinda (2004). Climate Change Governance 27 a re-location of dirty production to poorer and less regulated countries, the composition effect can also reduce global (rather than only local) pollution levels. Economic growth is usually associated with technological innovations that help replace old technologies with newer and cleaner ones (technology effect). In addition, growing income is presumably associated with increasing public demand for environmental protection once a country’s population has satisfied its basic needs and becomes willing to invest in ’postmaterial’ goods. While the basic tenets of the EKC may well be plausible, critics argue that it conveys the message to developing countries that they should ’grow first, then clean up’ (Dasgupta et al. 2002; Hill & Magnani 2002; Huang et al. 2008). This has obvious implications for the discount rate (see section 2). There is a lively academic (and also policy) debate on the empirical relevance of the EKC in general and CO2 and other GHG emissions in partiuclar (e.g. Millimet 2003; Galeotti et al. 2006). While many studies identify a statistically significant relationship between income and different local pollutants (notably, SO2, NOx, CO; e.g. Lempert et al. (2009), global pollutants such as CO2 tend to either increase monotonically with income or have high turning points (e.g. Holtz-Eakin & Selden 1995; Dinda 2004; Neumayer 2002a). Some studies also point to a less favourable N-shaped curve to describe the relationship between income and CO2 (e.g. Galeotti et al. 2006; Dinda 2004). Moreover, Galeotti et al. (2006) find that the inverted ushaped relation for some pollutants exists for OECD countries, but not for other countries.6 One conclusion from this research (c.f. Holtz-Eakin & Selden 1995; Huang et al. 2008) is that gambling on an automatic reduction of GHG emissions as income grows would be risky and probably be a mistake.7 Yet another problem with empirical results for the EKC is that they do not take into account regulatory policies. This implies that it remains hard to tell whether observed decreases in GHG emissions are due to income, technology, or composition effects, or whether they are caused also by effects of regulatory policies or other factors (Hill & Magnani 2002, see below). Moreover, it remains contested to what extent GHG reductions observed in some country are due to ’bad’ composition effects, meaning relocation of GHG-intensive production to pollution havens. The main long-term problem with ’bad’ composition effects is that they may allow richer countries to reap the ’low-hanging’ fruits and could eventually leave poor countries at the bottom of the risk-shifting cascade where beneficial composition effects must be achieved within the respective country. 6 7 One explanation is that poorer countries are still on the upward slope of the EKC (Lempert et al. 2009). Huang et al. (2008, 246) argue that an expansion of the Annex I group under the KP is necessary. 28 Effects of the political system The political system of a country is likely to have implications for climate change mitigation policy (Fredriksson & Millimet 2004a). Many studies show that democracies tend to be better providers of environmental quality (e.g. Bernauer & Koubi 2009). Even though democracy offers greater political access also for non-green interests and the median voter may not always prefer more environmental protection, existing theories expect, on balance, a positive net effect of democracy on environmental protection. The gist of the argument is that, in democracies, freedom of information and political rights enable citizens to acquire more information on environmental risks and express their demands more easily vis-a-vis policy-makers. The latter, in turn, have greater incentives than autocrats to meet citizen demands because they are more dependent on broad public support, for instance in elections (Baettig & Bernauer 2009; Gleditsch 2002; Li & Reuveny 2006). Note that this argument is relative, not absolute. While the environmental performance of democracies may well be bad, the performance of non-democracies is likely to be even worse. Whether democracies outperform non-democracies with respect to climate change policies is largely an empirical question. Existing studies on policy outcomes (usually defined as GHG emissions) arrive at mixed results. For instance, Gleditsch (2002) find that democracy is associated with lower CO2 emissions. Congleton (1992) finds that democracies emit less methane. Midlarsky (1998) observes that democarcies emit more CO2 . Li & Reuveny (2006) find that democracy is associated with less per capita CO2 emissions. The relationship between democracy and climate policy output appears to be more robust than the relationship between democracy and climate policy outcomes (e.g. Neumayer 2002b). Von Stein (2008) observes a positive effect of democracy on climate change treaty participation. Baettig & Bernauer (2009) compare climate policy output and outcomes side-by-side. They find that democracies contribute more to the global public good in terms of policy output, i.e. political commitments, but that the effect on policy outcomes is ambiguous. They describe this result in terms of a ’word-deeds’ gap, which appears to be larger in democracies than in autocracies. Reasons include the fact that mitigation efforts have started only a few years ago, and that, relative to local public goods, such as air pollution, there is a stronger free-rider problem. One major research gap in this research area is whether the positive democracy effect is driven more by the demand or the supply side (e.g. Ward 2008; Baettig & Bernauer 2009). Climate Change Governance 29 Researchers have recently started to disaggregate democracy and examine the implications of different types of democracy, such as presidential vs. parliamentary systems, consensus democracies vs. other types, etc.. Ward (2008), for instance, finds that presidential democracies perform worse than parliamentary democracies in environmental terms. Fredriksson & Millimet (2004b) observe that governments set stricter environmental policies under proportional than under majoritarian systems. Effects of the natural system The natural (i.e. geophysical climate) system may, on the one hand, influence the emissions behavior of countries. On the other hand, it may also affect their vulnerability to climatic changes and thus their willingness to contribute to the global public good. Neumayer (2002a), for instance, examines natural factors such as climatic conditions, the availability of renewable and fossil fuel resources, and transportation requirements. He finds that these factors have significant effects on cross-country differences in CO2 emissions, though the income level remains the most important determinant. Aldy (2005) examines U.S. states and observes that climatic conditions and coal endowments are positively related to per capita CO2 emissions. Natural system characteristics may also contribute to variation in climate risk exposure, which in turn could affect countries’ willingness to commit to climate change mitigation. Sprinz & Vaahtoranta (1994), for example, argue that countries facing greater vulnerability and lower costs of cooperation are more likely to commit to stronger international environmental policies. However, empirical research on climate policy has thus far not been able to identify such a vulnerability effect. For instance, Baettig & Bernauer (2009) do not find any evidence that climate risk exposure has a positive effect on policy output or policy outcomes. Their analysis uses a climate change risk exposure index (Baettig et al. 2007) and several other indicators for risk exposure. One potential explanation for the absence of a positive vulnerability-cooperation effect is that the available scientific information has not yet spurred sufficient public demand for risk mitigation. Another explanation is that the most vulnerable countries may have greater incentives to invest in climate adaptation, which is a national, ’private’ good, rather than mitigation, which is a global public good associated with positive externalities; or, they may be poor countries that are unable to invest in either adaptation or mitigation. 30 2.6 Alternative Forms of Climate Change Governance: Local Dynamics in Federal Systems Mitigation of climate change through effective global treaties to which all countries adhere has proven very difficult. In this section we look at other forms of governance that have emerged out of this conundrum. The focus is on sub-national climate change governance.8 Local climate policy-making is particularly interesting in the case of federal political systems. One noteworthy example is the United States, a typical federal state that is also important because it accounts for around 25% of global GHG emissions, but has thus far refused to ratify the Kyoto Protocol. The absence of federal laws and regulations on GHG emissions has led to a plethora of state- and city-level initiatives over the past few years. As of June 2010, 32 U.S. states have adopted a climate action plan, 21 states have adopted GHG emission targets, and 12 states have adaptation plans (Pew Center 2010). Furthermore, the first mandatory cap-and-trade program for CO2 in the U.S. started in 2009 for the ten member states of the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI). Similar regional initiatives have been initiated in the Western U.S. states as well as in the Midwest (Pew Center 2010). At the level of cities, the U.S. Conference of Mayors Climate Protection Agreement (MCPA) is the largest agreement. It involves more than one thousand U.S. cities. It was initiated in February 2005 by the then Seattle mayor Greg Nickels. Yet another local initiative is the International Council for Local Environmental Initiatives (ICLEI)’s Cities for Climate Protection (CCP) program. The ICLEI is an international initiative that involves around 600 cities worldwide. It started in 1991 and has also helped generate political support for reducing local GHG emission in U.S. cities (Betsill 2001). Such local and regional activities are interesting from an academic viewpoint. But they also beg the question of whether bottom-up activity can substitute for absent national level climate policy. Lutsey & Sperling (2008) examine the effects of decentralized climate change policies in U.S. states and cities on GHG emissions, exploring the development of emissions based on current inventories and chosen sub-national policies. They argue that ’efforts of states and cities are so pervasive at this point that future federal policy will benefit by adopting the most popular and best functioning GHG mitigation programs [...]’ (Lutsey & Sperling 2008, 683). Selin & VanDeveer (2007) are less optimistic about the emission-reducing effects of local climate initiatives. But 8 For reasons of space, we cannot discuss yet other forms of governance in climate policy, such as public-private partnerships and civil society involvement. Climate Change Governance 31 they also stress the importance of such programs because they allow policy-makers to ’[...] see which of the many available policy options are gaining support in the public and private spheres’ (Selin & VanDeveer 2007, 22) and thereby are most likely to influence future federal policy development. Tang et al. (2010) study 40 local climate change action plans in U.S. cities. They find that, although these plans reflect a high level of environmental awareness, they have only limited effects on emissions. While existing research has not yet been able to demonstrate the effectiveness of local and regional initiatives in terms of reducing GHG emissions, recent research offers interesting insights into the factors that affect the dynamics of such initiatives. Employing event history analysis, Vasi (2006) finds that adoption of the Cities for Climate Protection (CCP) program is driven by spatial or cultural proximity to earlier adopters, and that organizational embeddedness in transnational frameworks also fosters participation. With respect to CCP county-level participation patterns, Brody et al. (2008) observe that counties with landscape characteristics of high risk, low stress, and high opportunity are more likely to join the CCP campaign. Schaffer (2010) examines county-level participation patterns for the Mayor’s Climate Protection Agreement. She highlights the importance of natural system characteristics, such as whether the county is a coastal county, as well as political preferences of the inhabitants to determine where participation rates in this initiative are highest. Lee (2009b) uses a multilevel setting to analyze what cities participate internationally in the CCP and other networks, such as C40. Controlling for city and country-level variables, he finds that cities’ position in the global economy and transportation hub characteristics significantly influence participation in these networks. By and large, existing studies suggest that local and regional climate policy initiatives have gained ground in recent years, particularly in federal political systems. There is little evidence that such initiatives can substitute for slow progress in adopting and implementing ambitious mitigation policy at national and international levels. Nonetheless, evidence from the U.S. and other countries indicates that such activities can serve as policy-experiments in trying to find efficient mitigation options and changing the ’mind-set’ of business actors and citizens in a climate-friendly direction. 2.7 Normative Issues We end this chapter with a discussion of two normative issues that have received particular attention in research on climate change governance (e.g. Paterson 2001; Allen 2003; Klinsky & 32 Dowlatabadi 2009; Vanderheiden 2008; Posner & Sunstein 2007; Johnson 2009). One concerns intergenerational fairness, the other concerns the fair division of responsibilities for mitigation and adaptation. As discussed above, there is strong disagreement in the scientific literature on whether and by how much future costs and benefits of climate change and its mitigation should be discounted when deciding today how much to invest in solving the problem. Some scientists (e.g. Nordhaus 2010; Lempert et al. 2009) view the climate problem as one of many problems policy-makers need to deal with in parallel; so they need to weigh the costs and benefits and decide in which policy to invest more when and where. In their view, there is, from an economic perspective, nothing that makes e.g. investment in combating infectious diseases or maintaining law and order inherently different from investment in solving an environmental problem like climate change. They also assume that future generations will be wealthier and have more technological means to mitigate climatic changes at lower cost. Hence they apply a higher discount rate to mitigation costs and also assume that damage from unmitigated climate change is less costly as it occurs in the future. Other scientists regard this position as unethical because it burdens future generations with an environmental problem. Many of them consider that only a small or even no discount rate is the appropriate choice, and the issue should be viewed from a ’rights’ perspective (e.g. Collier 2010). The policy implications of these two contrasting views are quite obvious: the former position is associated with proposals to start mitigation very slowly and invest more over the mediumto long-term; the latter position generates proposals to ’front-load’ mitigation efforts, i.e., start early and invest a lot in the short- to medium-term. However, most analysts agree that there is no scientific solution that could identify the ’correct’ discount rate. Yet another issue that has attracted considerable attention in social sciences research is the question of fair burden sharing in mitigation and adaptation. Since past and current emissions have a greenhouse effect over many years to come and predictions of future emissions vary greatly, researchers have used complex models to calculate how much particular countries and regions contribute to global warming. A paper by Den Elzen et al. (2005), for instance, shows that responsibilities of specific regions can be calculated, though these responsibilities differ somewhat depending on the time period of emissions, the mix of GHG, climate impact indicators, and climate models. Such calculations indicate what share in temperature increases can be attributed Climate Change Governance 33 to specific countries or regions. Den Elzen et al. (2005) find that the average contributions to the global mean surface temperature increase in the year 2000 amount to around 40% for OECD countries, 14% for Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union, 24% for Asia, and 22% for Africa and Latin America. The OECD share decreases when later attribution periods are selected and increases for industrial latecomers, such as Asia. Including land-use related GHG emissions tends to reduce the OECD share at the expense of other regions. Other authors, e.g. Boehringer & Helm (2008) have sought to come up with specific modes of fair division based on compensation schemes. Again, such calculations show that normative assumptions (e.g. how industrial latecomers should be treated, which GHG should be considered) play an important role in establishing responsibilities for and, consequently, also burden-sharing formulas for climate change mitigation. Finally, another line of research assumes that climate-related damage is unavoidable even with the most ambitious mitigation efforts. Accordingly, it asks who should pay for adaptation measures. Dellink et al. (2009) use two principles, historical responsibility for radiative forcing and capacity to pay, to estimate the shares of individual countries in the financial burden. The results turn out to be more sensitive with respect to variation in capacity to pay assumptions than model input concerning historical responsibility. The authors assume adaptation costs of USD 100 billion per year and conclude that Annex I countries should contribute around USD 65-70 billion, which amounts to around USD 43-82 per capita and year in Annex I countries and USD 1-21 in non-Annex I countries. 35 3 Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? Testing Participation Patterns in Voluntary Initiatives in U.S. Counties Lena Maria Schaffer 3.1 Introduction The global scientific community, as organized through the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), is largely in agreement that anthropogenic causes, emissions from the combustion of fossil fuels in particular, are to blame for increasing temperatures in many areas of the world and on global average. It also agrees that the economic and social effects of human-induced climate change are grave and potentially disastrous, notably for societies with insufficient means to adapt (Stern et al. 2006; Stern 2008; IPCC 2007a). While international treaties to reduce CO2 and other greenhouse gases (GHG) – such as the Framework Convention on Climate Change (FCCC) and the Kyoto Protocol – have been agreed on by a majority of countries around the world (IPCC 2007), several large emitters of GHGs such as the U.S. are still reluctant to support global efforts in climate change policy. Regardless of its reasons why, the 2005 decision of the U.S. federal government not to participate in the effort to cut GHG emissions can be regarded as a landmark decision. It impacted on the international community, but more importantly triggered action within U.S. subnational units that wanted to proceed along with global efforts to curb GHG emissions. Now five years on, and with a different administration, while there continues to be no comprehensive national climate change legislation1 , state and local governments have created many different initiatives and laws that explicitly aim at installing climate change policies in their jurisdictions. One such initiative, that started in February 2005 and has been promoted in many cities all over the U.S., 1 The topic has been given considerably more attention within the Obama Administration and gradual steps have been made in the climate change policy area. An example of this is the Supreme Court ruling that the Clean Air Act could be applied to GHGs, giving the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) more leeway to set minimum standards on energy efficiency. Despite the fact that the energy bill that came out of the Senate in July 2010 failed to include the expected cap-and-trade scheme, and now proposes little more than subsidies for home insulation and trucks that run on natural gas (Economist 2010) 36 is the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement (MCPA). Seattle Mayor Greg Nickels launched the initiative to advance the goals of the Kyoto Protocol through leadership and action by American cities. Joining the initiative constitutes a voluntary act by the local governments that sign the agreement, and thereby commit their cities to reduce emissions to seven percent below 1990 levels by 2012 (Mayors Climate Protection Center 2010). Over 1040 cities joined this initiative by Fall 2010. It is a prime example for subnational environmental policy formation. However, as can be seen in figure 3.1, participation in this initiative is not distributed equally throughout the United States. The map shows the MCPA participation rate of cities within all counties of the 48 contiguous U.S. states. Counties where no city has signed the agreement are shown in red tones in figure 3.1, whereas different shades of yellow to green reflect participation rates from 1 % up to 100%. Counties where participation reaches nearly 100% of the cities that could sign the agreement are depicted in dark green on the map. Figure 3.1: Counties in the U.S. according to their participation in the MCPA; darker shades indicate a higher percentage The idea that subnational units engage themselves in new policy areas is neither new to American policy making nor limited to the field of environmental politics. Quite to the contrary, the notion that states 2 try out innovative policies that they deem necessary within their jurisdiction became famous through Judge Brandeis’ dissent in the New State Ice Co. vs. Liebmann Case (1932, 310). He stated that ’There must be power in the States and the Nation to remould, through experimentation, our economic practices and institutions to meet changing social and economic needs’ and went on to claim that ’[i]t is one of the happy incidents of the federal system 2 This can also be extended to other subnational units such as county or city governments Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 37 that a single courageous State may, if its citizens choose, serve as a laboratory; and try novel social and economic experiments without risk to the rest of the country’. This potential of states to act as laboratories of democracy can be seen as a desired outcome of federalism (Shipan & Volden 2006), or an ’all-purpose defense of the legitimacy of states pursuing divergent policies’ (Levy 2007). However, the general desirability of states experimenting with climate change policy is not the focus of this paper. In fact, this paper relates more to Brandeis’ comments on the changing social and economic needs that lead to different economic practices or institutions in different states or parts of the federation. Proceeding from the observed outcome of voluntary subnational climate change policies and their uneven distribution over the United States, I seek to find out which social, economic, or other needs lead to the creation of this pattern. Therefore, this paper proposes to explain participation patterns in the MCPA at the countylevel throughout the U.S. by factors regarding the natural (Nature), socio-economic and political (Nurture) characteristics, and their geographical surroundings (Neighbors). It is hypothesized that voluntary participation in climate change mitigation efforts are highest when the county is at risk of being adversely affected by climate change, when there are favorable socio-economic and political conditions present, and when the surrounding counties are also strong participators. I test these claims for the MCPA participatory behavior of cities in counties within the 48 contiguous states and thus contribute to the literature on local voluntary climate change initiatives in two respects. First, there exists a gap in the literature on local voluntary climate change initiatives with respect to comprehensive hypothesis testing within a large-N framework. Studies dealing with local climate change initiatives overwhelmingly rely on descriptive or case study evidence (Betsill 2001; Betsill & Bulkeley 2006; Engel & Orbach 2008; Engel 2009; Kousky & Schneider 2003; Schreurs 2008; Schreurs & Epstein 2007; Urpelainen 2009). Evidence from the large-N analysis conducted in this paper represents an important step forward in understanding the motivations behind voluntary climate change actions. Moreover, the few studies that explore participation within a quantitative framework (Brody et al. 2008; Lee 2009a; Vasi 2006; Zahran, Grover, Brody & Vedlitz 2008) have thus far focused on explaining participation in the Cities for Climate Protection (CCP) program initiated by the ICLEI - the International Council for Local Environmental Initiatives. This program started in 1991 and was the first of its kind to introduce the topic of climate change at the city level (Betsill 2001; Betsill & Bulkeley 2006). While participation within the CCP is still at around 160 cities throughout the U.S., 1040 cities 38 have signed the MCPA during the past five years. Due to this difference in scope as well as the greater saliency of the climate change issue in the past few years, participation in the MCPA fundamentally differs from the CCP and calls for a more detailed study. So far only few authors have focused on this initiative (Engel & Orbach 2008; Engel 2009; Schreurs & Epstein 2007; Warden 2007; Tang et al. 2010) and the second contribution therefore concerns the topic under study, the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. By analyzing the determinants of participation in the Mayors’ Climate Protection Agreement throughout all 48 states, I aim at closing important gaps in the literature. From my OLS and spatial analyses, I find that as far as natural system characteristics are concerned, being a coastal county seems to drive signatory behavior. For socio-economic characteristics, bad economic conditions in a county significantly decrease the relative number of signatories, whereas higher democratic vote shares and a well-educated population significantly increase the relative number of signatories. By controlling for risks related to climate change and socio-economic incentives and disincentives of counties to sign voluntary agreements, most of the spatial pattern is explained. Alternative model specifications and robustness checks confirm these results and show other potential ways to model the research question at hand. The paper is structured as follows. First, a theoretical overview of the determinants for participation in such a voluntary climate change initiative is given. Then each of the three groups of factors (nature, nurture, and neighbors) and deduced testable hypotheses are introduced. In the second part, the data and operationalizations of the main concepts are provided. The results from the analysis and robustness checks are shown in the third part. The paper concludes with a discussion of the results and suggests further extensions. 3.2 Determinants of Participation in Voluntary Climate Change Initiatives Policies get formulated and implemented to solve given societal problems as long as their (political) costs do not outweigh their benefits to office- and/or policy-seeking politicians. Thus, participation in voluntary initiatives by any given jurisdiction results from specific incentives and disincentives to join (Meyer & Konisky 2007). Incentives are favorable conditions present within the jurisdiction that will minimize the cost or maximize the benefit from adopting such voluntary measures. Factors are disincentives or stressors if they increase costs for the locality due to adopting voluntary measures. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 39 I argue that there are three dimensions that need to be taken into account when talking about the voluntary adoption of climate change policies. First and foremost, climate change is an environmental problem that might cause serious damage for those that are likely to be affected by it. Thus, the first factor for explaining participation in voluntary climate change initiatives that should be considered is natural risks (Nature) from climate change associated with a locality. Secondly, combating climate change and its implications might incur costs for a locality (e.g., from curbing CO2 emissions), but might also have beneficial health effects (Jacobson 2010). Depending on such socio-economic and political conditions (Nurture), elected representatives will deliberate about whether to engage in voluntary climate change initiatives or not. Thirdly, since climate change policies are not yet common practice in the localities’ toolbox, learning from or emulating other localities - as suggested by Brandeis’ dissent earlier - might take place. I therefore argue that one also has to pay attention to what neighboring localities (Neighbors) are doing on the issue to explain participation patterns. 3.2.1 Natural System Factors (Nature) Recent observations of global climate have shown that climate change is unequivocal (IPCC 2007a). However, the consequences of global warming, such as rising sea levels, do not impact in a similar way across the globe. Whereas nations such as the Maldives might cease to exist due to further rises of the Indian Ocean, in other regions warmer climates could lead to increased crop yields and agricultural productivity, as would be the case in many northern European and North American countries. This considerable disparity in global climate change effects can also be observed within such a large country as the United States, where climatic conditions are very different throughout, with cold and dry conditions in the Northeast compared to very hot and dry conditions in the Southwest. The map in figure 3.2 shows the IECC climate zones within the United States, ranging from 1-7, with 1 as very hot and moist, and 7 as very cold. Possible scenarios of the impact of climate change for the United States include more intense hurricanes with corresponding increases in wind, rain, and storm surges, as well as drier conditions in the Southwest (Karl et al. 2009). Reduced precipitation and increased evaporation might lead to an increase in droughts in these regions. Moreover, sea level rises due to global warming are an especially urgent topic at the Gulf and East Coast of the U.S.. Karl et al. (2009) estimate that a global increase in sea levels of 2 feet would result in a relative rise of 2.3 feet in New York and about 3.5 feet in Galveston, TX, but only about 1 foot in Neah Bay in 40 Map of DOE’s Proposed Climate Zones Dry (B) Moist (A) Marine (C) 7 6 4 6 5 5 4 3 All of Alaska in Zone 7 except for the following Boroughs in Zone 8: Bethel Dellingham Fairbanks N. Star Nome North Slope Northwest Arctic Southeast Fairbanks Wade Hampton Yukon-Koyukuk Warm-Humid Below White Line 3 2 2 2 Zone 1 includes Hawaii, Guam, Puerto Rico, and the Virgin Islands 1 March 24, 2003 Figure 3.2: Climate zones by county for the U.S.: from 1(very hot, moist) to 7(very cold) (Source Department of Energy) Washington state. Estimates of damages from rising sea levels come to the conclusion that in the Gulf coast area alone, about 2700 miles of major roadway, and 246 miles of freight rail lines could be permanently flooded within the next 50-100 years(Kafalenos et al. 2008). Moreover, 10 major ports are located in the area. However, as stated above, different regions are affected differently by climate change. For example, figure 3.3 indicates that summers in the two Midwestern states of Illinois and Michigan are expected to feel progressively more like summers that are currently experienced in states south and west of those states (Hayhoe et al. 2009). For agriculture and crop yields, changes might not be as severe and harvest might even benefit from warmer temperatures. Risks and opportunities from global warming are spread unevenly throughout the U.S. (Mendelsohn 2001), and I thus expect participation in voluntary climate change initiatives to also vary. When it comes to environmental policies generally, it is assumed that policy-makers draft policies or propose actions in accordance with existing problems within their jurisdiction (Daley & Garand 2005; Ringquist 1994; Potoski & Woods 2002), or in expectation of future adverse effects if such a policy is not enacted. Studying local wetlands bylaws under the Massachusetts Wetlands Protection Act Meyer & Konisky (2007) find strong evidence that environmental need plays an important role. Brody et al. (2008)’s study on the determinants of CCP also shows that counties with a higher risk of climate change impacts are more likely to join the CCP network. Accordingly, I assume that in counties that are more likely to be seriously affected by Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 41 Figure 3.3: Model projections of summer average temperature and precipitation changes in Illinois and Michigan for midcentury (2040-2059), and end-of-century (20802099)(Source (Hayhoe et al. 2009) rising sea levels, severe droughts, floods or hurricanes, participation rates in voluntary climate change agreements will be higher compared to counties that are not affected or those that might even benefit from a changed climate. Thus, the severity of the problem in the locality at risk is supposed to influence participation in voluntary initiatives. Hypothesis 1: Participation in voluntary climate change agreements is higher the more the county is exposed to the effects of climate change. 3.2.2 Socio-Economic and Political Factors (Nurture) In deciding whether to engage themselves voluntarily in climate change policies, politicians are assumed to not only take the environmental need or appropriateness of a solution into account. 42 Rather, as office-seeking politicians (Mueller 2003), I expect policy-makers to evaluate whether there is support for such a solution to be gained or obstacles to be faced within their constituencies (Oates & Schwab 1988)3 . Structural conditions within the constituencies determine whether demand exists for such policies. Hence, if structural conditions are favorable (incentives) within the jurisdiction, more local governments are expected to participate in the MCPA. Which composition of a constituency is more likely to support climate change policies, and what structural conditions lead to a lower probability of voluntary climate change policy adoption? The following two paragraphs will deal with these questions and deduce testable hypotheses from them. Incentives for participation in MCPA In the literature on people’s environmental attitudes, socio-economic factors play a central role (Dunlap & Mertig 1992). In their 2002 study, Theodori & Luloff (2002, 471) put it quite comprehensively: ’young individuals, the more highly educated, people with higher incomes, and those with liberal political ideologies were more likely than their opposites to maintain proactive positions on environmental issues’.4 O’Connor et al. (2002) specifically look at the climate change issue in their 2002 study on 623 individuals in central Pennsylvania. They find a particular strong effect for education, whereas income and age do not turn out to be significantly related to policy support for climate change issues. Moreover, Democrats were more likely than Republicans to support government efforts to reduce emissions, however, as far as voluntary measures were concerned, the difference between Democrats and Republicans was not significant (O’Connor et al. 2002). In their study on local commitment within the Cities for Climate Protection (CCP) Program, Zahran, Brody, Vedlitz & Grover (2008) find that in localities characterized by high percentages of environmentally concerned and ideologically center-left inhabitants, politicians selectively benefited from participation in the CCP campaign. Based on these findings in the literature, effects of income, education, partisanship, and age are expected to matter in different ways for participation. 3 In a similar way to Oates & Schwab (1988)’s model where regulators set environmental standards at the level which maximizes the utility of the median voter in the constituency. 4 Although Dunlap & Mertig (1992) concentrates more on air and water pollution issues and Theodori & Luloff (2002) focus on positions on general environmental issues, I assume that similar socio-demographic factors matter for the climate change issue. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? Wealth 43 Endowment with resources, or wealth, is a factor that matters in policy-making (Gray 1973). One line of argumentation points to a greater capacity to compensate losers from potential regulation. As far as environmental policies are concerned, research has shown that with more wealth there comes additional demand for environmental quality (Beron et al. 2003; Cornes & Sandler 1996). Due to its high income elasticity, economists have conceptualized environmental quality as a luxury good (Baumol & Oates 1988). Demand for climate change policies should therefore be higher in localities with a higher income. More public demand for such policies translates into less costs and potentially even benefits for policy makers associated with policy adoption, which in turn should make adoption more likely. Hypothesis 2: Counties that are better endowed with monetary resources are more likely to engage in voluntary climate change initiatives. Education Education is a major factor explaining individual level environmental attitudes. Theodori & Luloff (2002) find that better educated individuals were more likely to contribute money or time to an environmental group, to read environmental magazines, or to vote for or against a political candidate because of his or her position on the environment. O’Connor et al. (2002) speak of the ’awareness of consequence’ that comes with education and which will then translate into the correct interpretation of implications and solutions associated with climate change. Analogously, I therefore expect a higher number of educated people per locality to translate into more demand, and also more policy initiative on climate change issues. Hypothesis 3: Counties with a higher human capital endowment are more likely to engage in voluntary climate change initiatives. Partisan orientation Turning to the political component, the ideological dispositions of the population should generally be taken into account for any policy decision. In the U.S., the Democrats and their political leaders have been more supportive of efforts to curb greenhouse gases than the Republicans (O’Connor et al. 2002). In general, I expect the vote patterns in general elections within the locality to matter for participation, with a higher proportion of votes for the Democrats leading to a higher demand for voluntary climate change policies. Hypothesis 4: The higher the proportion of voters for the party representing environmental issues is, the higher the participation in voluntary climate change initiatives within the county. 44 Age Literature on the connection between age and environmentalism (e.g. Buttel 1979) claims that environmentalism can be seen as an age- or generation-based phenomenon rather than as an education- or class-based movement. Hornback (1974) finds that age is inversely associated with ’pro-environmental bias’ and positively associated with ’anti-environmental bias’. At the time of writing of both studies, this connection between age and environmental attitudes was quite strong within the United States even when controlling for education. However, this clear-cut intergenerational gap might have vanished over the years. As Buttel (1979, 251f.) wonders: ’As the cohort of youth that took part in the mushrooming of environmentalism on college campuses and other youthful milieus during the late 1960’s progresses through careers and builds up attachments to society, community, and family, will their levels of pro-environmentalism wane? Or as they replace their generally anti-environmental elders in positions of power and authority, can we thereby expect greater institutional expressions of environmental awareness and concern?’ Overall, it is far from obvious why a generation that actively fought long and hard for more environmental protection should lose its environmental attitudes as it grows older. That said, the long-term nature of climate change as an environmental problem could explain a difference in attitudes. In their lifetimes, older people are less likely to be adversely affected by climate change than young people, and should therefore not be as concerned.5 Hypothesis 5: The younger the people living within a locality are, the higher is participation in voluntary climate change initiatives. Disincentives for participation in MCPA The factors mentioned above lead to more favorable conditions, with policy-makers accruing less costs and potentially even reaping benefits for the initiation of voluntary climate change policies. However, there are also disincentives that make voluntary policies more costly for policy-makers and potentially suppress action toward more climate friendly policies. Economic development Regulations on environmental protection inflict costs on companies within the locality that have to comply with those regulations, and worsen their competitive position vis-a-vis enterprises in other jurisdictions. Several studies (e.g. Meyer (1995); List et al. (2003)) have found regulations to have a negative impact on economic growth and development. 5 Related to this, but on a global scale is Sandler (1997)’s work concerning intergenerational public goods provision in the context of climate change. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 45 Pagoulatos et al. (2004)’s results indicate however, that although more stringent environmental regulations have a short-run cost, they can be beneficial over time. The rationale behind this effect is that if strict regulations are already in place, then the risk to businesses facing additional regulations may be lower. Since there is still great uncertainty about policy instrument choice in the realm of climate change policies, I assume that in localities experiencing economic distress, participation in voluntary climate change policies is less likely. Hypothesis 6: Participation in subnational climate change regulation decreases with higher economic distress in the county. Pollution intensity Of all the greenhouse gases (GHGs), Carbon Dioxide (CO2 ) as emitted by human activity is usually given most attention. Therefore, global mitigation policies as well as local voluntary efforts, focus on reducing or stabilizing the concentration of CO2 in the atmosphere (Bernauer & Schaffer 2010). CO2 -intensive industrial production might be faced with high abatement costs from voluntary action that could make them less competitive. Betsill (2000) in her four city case studies as well as Zahran, Brody, Vedlitz & Grover (2008) in their county-level analysis on CCP membership, find that dependence on carbon intensive activities and industries is a restraint on the development of local climate change policies. I therefore expect less voluntary action in localities where there are a lot of CO2 -intensive industries. Hypothesis 7: Participation in subnational climate change regulation decreases with the importance of CO2 intensive industries in the county. 3.2.3 External Influences (Neighbors) The last two sections considered factors related to the natural environment and to socio-economic and political characteristics of localities and linked them to expected participation patterns. Both explanations assume that the decision to participate in voluntary climate change efforts and the resulting patterns are solely based on locality-specific attributes. Above, I cited Brandeis’ argument about ’states as policy laboratories’. This argument implies that policy experimentation by a state can lead the way to a solution that other states might want to emulate. Studies of this kind of diffusion of policy innovations among U.S. states has a long tradition and has more recently received renewed scholarly interest (Walker 1969; Gray 1973; Berry & Berry 1990; Berry & Baybeck 2005; Baybeck & Huckfeldt 2002; Boehmke & Witmer 2004; Daley & 46 Garand 2005; Shipan & Volden 2006, 2008; Volden 2006). Concerning participation in voluntary climate change agreements, the laboratories argument would suggest that unit-external influences might also determine participation. As climate change as an issue for subnational units is a relatively new phenomenon, it is conceivable that localities take into consideration what other localities are doing on the issue before deciding on whether to participate or not. Since I am not able to look at individual decision-making processes, but deal with aggregated participation patterns in this paper, I am interested in whether there is explanatory power to be gained by accounting for spatial associations of localities. Hence, the question posed here is whether interdependence between units’ participation patterns exists above and beyond their locational and socio-economic characteristics. To this end, two possible conceptions of interdependence are introduced. The first, geographical proximity, taps on the notion of closeness, whereas the second, leaders of innovation, refines the geographical proximity argument to account for the special role of leaders of policy innovation. Geographical proximity Localities are more likely to emulate or to learn policies from their geographic neighbors (Shipan & Volden 2006, 2008; Millimet et al. 2002). This is what we expect from Tobler (1970)’s first law of geography, which states that: ’Everything is related to everything else, but near things are more related than distant things’. Spatial dependence should conform to this basic theorem, and observations that are close to each other should reflect a higher degree of dependence. Such interdependencies between counties would manifest themselves in reactions of cities’ participation decisions in one county in view of their peers’ actions in neighboring counties. As far as strategic interactions between states in the field of environmental policies are concerned, studies have found evidence for such strategic considerations of other states’ policies in policy-making (Levinson 2003; Fredriksson & Millimet 2002; Konisky 2007). These strategic considerations of cities would result in more similar MCPA participation outcomes in neighboring counties compared to those farther away. However, cities within a county could either be more likely to emulate the policies of their peers (positive spatial dependence) or specifically avoid adoption of such voluntary policies (negative spatial dependence). In most of the literature on environmental regulations or treaties (Beron et al. 2003; Perrin & Bernauer 2010), free-riding behavior (negative spatial dependence) is expected. However, since the participation and scope of the agreement is voluntary and can be determined by the respective locality, I rather assume a positive effect of spatial interdependence. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 47 Hypothesis 8: The higher MCPA participation is in neigboring counties, the higher is a county’s own MCPA participation Leaders in innovation High MCPA participation rates may not only arise from participation rates in neighboring jurisdictions, but may emanate from geographical closeness to one of the leaders of policy innovation. Such leaders are cities that were among the first movers within the climate change policy field, and therefore serve as a likely example to be imitated by nearby localities. The role of leaders or pioneers for the process of policy diffusion was already a central question in Walker (1969)’s classic study. Jaenicke (2005, 145) claims that leaders legitimize subsequent adoptions by other jurisdictions by demonstrating the political feasibility of the innovation. Leaders of innovation in this study are cities that were among the first movers within the climate change policy field in the U.S. and therefore serve as a likely example to be imitated by nearby localities. The then Seattle Mayor Greg Nickels had initiated the Mayor’s Climate Protection agreement in early 2005 by sending around emails and advertising the initiative on Seattle’s webpage. The original goal was to mirror the Kyoto Protocol, which became binding for 141 nations on the 16th February 2005, and have at least 141 Mayors to sign his initiative to locally commit to reducing CO2 emission. By the June 2005 annual conference of USCOM in Chicago, this goal was reached and 141 Mayors had signed the MCPA. On this meeting, the MCPA was formally endorsed as a policy by the United States Conference of Mayors. These first 141 cities have committed themselves very early in the process and can therefore be seen as leaders of innovation. Without their swift reaction on Mayor Nickels agreement, momentum might not have gained during this crucial first months. I therefore expect that cities that are located near one of those original 141 have learned about the MCPA very early on in the process and could potentially imitate and learn from those leaders. Hypothesis 9: The closer a county is to one of the leaders of innovation, the higher is its participation rate. 3.3 Data The previous section identified three competing factors of influence and derived hypotheses. To test the hypotheses derived in the previous section, I use U.S. counties as the unit of analysis. Although the decision whether or not to participate in the MCPA is made by the city (i.e. the 48 mayor), the county level was chosen because of feasibility reasons. Collecting city-level data for the 48 contiguous states and all 2700 cities within them was beyond the scope of this project because in contrast to counties, data is not readily available in spreadsheet form. By aggregating the cities within each county, I am not able to analyze individual policy-makers’ decisions, but can comprehensively compare structural factors in all counties throughout the U.S to obtain first estimates of which factors make participation more likely. In the United States, the U.S. Census Bureau lists 3140 counties or county-equivalent administrative units in total. I excluded Hawaii and Alaska and used only counties in the 48 contiguous states for the analysis.6 3.3.1 Dependent Variable The dependent variable of interest gives information on the proportion of cities in each county that have signed the U.S. Conference of Mayors Climate Protection Agreement out of those that could have potentially signed it. To determine which cities were selected, I have used a GIS shapefile from the U.S. Bureau of the Census of all cities and townships in the U.S. As far as the size of cities in the sample is concerned, 2700 cities with 10,000 inhabitants or above were included in the analysis. Most city-level research uses a considerably higher threshold of 30,000 or 50,000 inhabitants and consequently include less cities (Brody et al. 2008; Shipan & Volden 2006, 2008). In order to allow for a comprehensive analysis of cities’ participation at the county level, I chose the lowest possible threshold which still guarantees sufficient political and administrative capacities to engage in local climate change policies. The collection of the signature data of the MCPA for the dependent variable was done through the website of the Mayors Climate Protection Center (www.usmayors.org/ climateprotection/). I have collected the participation records as of November 2008. This specific date was chosen because it coincides with the election of Barack Obama as President of the United States. I presume that the logic of signing a voluntary climate change agreement has changed after the election simply due to the situation of uncertainty about national climate policy. In other words, the certainty of no national climate change policy was not present anymore, since Obama and the Democratic Party were expected to enact climate change policies at the national level. Since the cross-sectional nature of the data does not allow a test of different participation logics of policy-makers over time, I only include MCPA participation until November 2008. Table 3.1 shows the city-level distribution of participation in the MCPA. Of 6 Most of the research on the county-level uses the 48 contiguous states Pagoulatos et al. (2004); Brody et al. (2008) and excludes Hawaii and Alaska Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 49 the 2700 cities with over 10,000 inhabitants, 631 or 23.4 % had signed the MCPA by November 2008.7 Table 3.1: City-level distribution of MCPA participants MCPA signed not signed Total No. 631 2,069 2,700 % 23.4% 76.6% 100.0% In a next step, the 2700 cities were then allocated to their specific county using the FIPS identifier and were merged with different county-level data sets. Due to the merge, the 631 cities that had signed are now located in 318 counties (or 10.2 %)8 of all 3109 counties. Taking a closer look at the 2791 other remaining counties, it has to be noted that in a large proportion there are no cities over 10.000 inhabitants. These counties would therefore have a value of zero on the dependent variable. However, it would not be possible to distinguish a case where no city in a specific county is in the sample from a case where there are cities over 10 000 inhabitants in the county, but no city has signed. Since these describe two very different outcomes, the analysis would potentially be biased by using all 3109 counties. Table 3.2: Distribution of counties MCPA status cities have not signed cities have signed Total City over 10.000 inhabitants in county 0 1 Total No. % No. % No. % 2,000 100 791 71.3 2,791 89.8 0 0 318 28.7 318 10.2 2,000 100 1,109 100 3,109 100 Table 3.2 identifies counties that include at least one city that is over the cut-off of 10,000 inhabitants, and shows those where at least one city signed the MCPA. To avoid this bias, I therefore only include the 1109 counties (c.f. table 3.2) where at least one city is present and has a chance of signing the MCPA. Figure 3.4 illustrates this for the northeastern part of the U.S. Note that the counties where there is no city in the sample are light red. Accordingly, the black 7 8 Appendix table 3.14 further shows how participation is spread across the 48 states. Dealing with counties, it has to be noted that they - sometimes dramatically - differ in size. For example, the range goes from Loving county in Texas that has 46 inhabitants to Los Angeles County in California that has around 9 million inhabitants 50 dots are the cities in the sample; counties where no city has signed the MCPA are dark red; the different shades of yellow and green indicate counties where differing proportions of their cities have signed. In figure 3.4 there are some clusters of ’green’ counties up in Massachussetts and New Hampshire, whereas there are some ’red’ clusters in Pennsylvania. Figure 3.4: Detailed map of participation and cities in the northeast; darker shades indicate a higher percentage For this reduced data set, the dependent variable on the county level was then calculated as the proportion of cities that signed the MCPA of the possible cities over 10,000 citizens within that county (%MCPA).9 3.3.2 Independent Variables Nature In section 3.2, I assumed that cities or states that are more likely to be affected by climate change (by droughts, hurricanes, or an increase in sea levels) will be more prone to act than cities or states, whose potential damage from climate change is perceived to be relatively lower. In order to operationalize the concept of ’risk from climate change’, I use four different proxies. The first proxy indicates whether a county is located at a coastline (coastal county) and is taken from the National Association of Counties (NaCo). As Karl et al. (2009) conclude, the largest 9 Results from other possible operationalizations of the dependent variable, such as the count of cities, or a binary measure indicating a 1 when at least one city in the county has signed and 0 otherwise are presented in the robustness section. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 51 probable climate change impact in the U.S. might arise from rising sea levels. Thus, coastal counties should be directly affected. This becomes even more important with Rappaport & Sachs (2003)’s observation of the U.S. as a coastal nation, where 50% of the population live somewhere near a coast and a disproportionately large share of income and enterprises can be found there. Other natural risks emanating from climate change come from the intensifying of already observable natural disasters. Hurricanes, as well as droughts and floods are predicted to become more intense and frequent as the climate warms. I proxy the risk from future adverse effects by using data on climate-related natural disasters such as hurricanes, tornadoes, floods, droughts or storms10 in each of the counties from the Spatial Hazard Events and Losses Database for the United States (SHELDUS) (Institute, Hazards & Vulnerability Research 2009). I use ’property damage’ and ’fatalities from natural disasters’ within counties during the years 2000-2007 as the second and third measure. I thus expect that a recent history of extreme weather-related events leads to more voluntary participation. The fourth measurement taps into the concept of regions’ benefitting from warmer climate. I use IECC (2007) Code Climate Zones ranging from 0(very cold) – 14(hot-humid). Among other indicators, these data include information on Heating Degree Days (HDD) and Cooling Degree Days (CDD). Data are scaled so that a higher value means a less negative and potentially beneficial impact from climate change. I would expect that participation in counties that are less affected is lower and thus a negative impact on voluntary participation. Nurture Incentives Each county population has their own preferences and attitudes toward environ- mental regulation and these socio-economic and political factors were linked to the MCPA participation rate in section 3.2. Socio-economic and political characteristics expected to positively influence participation in voluntary GHG mitigation initiatives are wealth, education, partisan orientation, and age. I proxy the wealth of the community by the per capita income (ICPSR 2008). For reasons outlined earlier, I suppose that the higher the per capita income is in a county, the higher the participation rate. 10 For example, earthquakes were not included in the data since there is no direct relation with climate change. 52 Education, or the human capital within a county, is measured using several indicators. For the empirical test of hypothesis 3, I firstly use the percentage of persons with college education (% of people that have had 4 years of college education) from the ’COUNTY CHARACTERISTICS, 2000-2007’ data set by ICPSR (2008). Here I also assume that the more educated the population of a county is, the higher the participation rate is. To tap at a slightly different concept, I further include a measure on how many universities or colleges are in the county. Universities might help to address climate change in their broader communities (Betsill 2001). Knuth et al. (2007, 487) argue that universities can ’provide expert knowledge, research experience, and faculty and student time to communities lacking the necessary skills and resources to reduce their GHG emissions’. I use the count of universities and colleges in counties from the Higher Education General Information Survey (HEGIS) XVIII: Institutional Characteristics of Colleges and Universities (ICPSR 1984) scaled by the number of cities in the county. I generally include only 4-year universities or colleges that had a liberal arts program due to the fact that 2-year colleges or those without liberal arts program often concentrate on vocational or professional education. However, in this context, my theoretical rationale has to do with the humanistic background of such universities to be more involved in the development of the community. Unfortunately, I was not able to obtain more recent data on the institutional characteristics of colleges and universities. However, I do not expect a great deal of variation in 4-year universities and colleges, since their reputations are established over long time periods. In order to test my hypothesis 4, I proxied how liberal counties are by the share of votes for the Democrats (% Dem vote) in election data on the 2004 presidential election. These data were taken from the US Election Atlas (http://uselectionatlas.org/RESULTS/). The assumption is that Democrats are more environmentally friendly (Volden 2006; O’Connor et al. 2002). The median age of the county population was also taken from ICPSR (2008). I expect that a younger population renders a county more liberal in general and should also make the city more likely to support voluntary initiatives against climate change. Disincentives To proxy economic conditions in a community, I use the unemployment rate in the county (Unemployment). I use the county level average from the County Characteristics Dataset (ICPSR 2008). I expect that bad economic conditions would lead to less participation. The U.S. produces more coal than it consumes (Fisher 2006) and since emissions from coal are more CO2 -intensive than other energy sources, voluntary climate change regulations would Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 53 hit producers of coal and coal-powered energy hard. I would therefore expect less involvement in the MCPA in counties with high coal production. I obtained data on coal production and employment per county from the U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA 2007). CO2 intensity in a county proxies potential abatement costs from voluntary climate change policy. The higher CO2 emissions are, the less participation in voluntary agreements is expected. In October 2010, county-level CO2 data from the Vulcan Project (Gurney et al. 2009) was made available. It is based on a number of data sources and relies to a great extent on data collected by the EPA (and therefore relies on the integrity of the EPA data and models) through the Clean Air Act (Gurney et al. 2009). I use per capita tonnes of carbon in the county to approximate abatement costs in the locality. Neighbors In the spatial context employed here, the specification of the channels of interdependence on the theoretical level implies the use of a certain specification of the empirical weights matrix to account for spatial interdependence in the empirical model. The weights matrix and, thus, the structure between the units of interest must be specified prior to an analysis of dependence between observations and is, therefore, a crucial step in estimating a spatial model (Anselin 1988, 2004). Due to the inherent subjectivity in determining the spatial connectivities, Pluemper & Neumayer (2010) advise scholars to show that their results hold for different weighting matrices. I follow this suggestion in the sense that I use three connectivity matrices with slightly different conceptions of geographical nearness.11 Gleditsch & Ward (2001) differentiate between strict contiguity, which is what I measure with my first weights matrix, and proximity, which relates to a more loose definition of contiguity that also incorporates units that do not necessarily physically share a border. The second and third matrices belong in this category and measure the geographic distance between counties. These two types of locational information – contiguity and distance – are the ones most commonly used to quantify relative positions of units of observation in space (Beck et al. 2006). The fourth measure then measures the concept of leaders of policy innovation. Geographical proximity In the empirical literature on diffusion, geographical proximity has always played a major role in explaining policy diffusion since it is widely acknowledged to 11 To avoid problems pertaining to identification, the weights should be truly exogenous to the model (Manski 1993). The exogeneity of geography is unambiguous. 54 be a primary force shaping the opportunity for interaction (Walker 1969; Gray 1973; Tobler 1970; Gleditsch & Ward 2001; Berry & Berry 1990; Franzese & Hays 2006). Using ArcGIS, geographical proximity is measured in three different ways here. The first weights matrix measures strict contiguity. It is an N x N (1012 x 1012)12 county contiguity matrix with non-zero entries for spatially contiguous counties. The second one then measures the distances dij from the centroid of each county i to all the other counties in radians.13 Since I want to explore whether nearer counties are more similar, the inverse distance ( d1 ) was calculated, so that counties that are closer to one another receive larger weights. Therefore in each of the cells wij there is a measure of proximity between the counties. The third matrix uses the similar set up as the second but employs a cut-off at 100km. This means that if counties were more than 100km apart, a zero entry would result, while for each distance below the threshold, the original distance was entered in the matrix. Each weighting matrix was row - standardized (each row entry was divided by the row sum, to add up to 1) for all further analyses as is standard in the spatial econometrics literature (Franzese & Hays 2006; Gleditsch & Ward 2001; Ward & Gleditsch 2008).14 While the county contiguity matrix is limiting in the sense that it gives equal weight to all bordering neighbors, the inverse distance matrix without a threshold assumes that each unit in the system has some, albeit small impact on each other. Due to these deficiencies in the conceptualization of proximity, specifying connectivities in an inverse distance matrix with a cut-off appears to be the most viable option from a theoretical point of view. Nevertheless, all three conceptualization of geographic distance will be tested in the spatial analysis section. Leaders of Innovation To proxy for the concept of leaders of innovation stated in hypothesis 9, I have gathered data on the first 141 cities that signed the agreement in early 2005. Figure 3.5 shows the map of all counties in the sample with all cities within them. Note that the red cities are the first 141 that signed before the initiative was officially endorsed by the U.S. Conference of Mayors (USCOM). Using ArcGIS, I have calculated the nearest distance of each county’s centroid to one of the 141 cities. Since these cities then serve as external leaders that explain 12 The reduction from the original 1109 counties comes from the fact that there are isolated counties (i.e. counties that have no contiguous neighbors) that were excluded from the analysis. 13 To calculate these point distances, GIS employs a formula using polar coordinates (φ, λ) to represent latitude and longitude expressed in radians. These then can be converted to other units such as miles or km (c.f. www.spatialanalysisonline.com/output/html/DistanceOperations.html). 14 For a more comprehensive and critical discussion concerning the topic of row standardization, see Pluemper & Neumayer (2010) Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 55 the variation in participation, I had to exclude them from the analysis to avoid bias. I then recalculated a new dependent variable for the signatories minus the first 141. This leads to a reduced data set of 1085 counties, since in 24 counties, a city among the first 141 was the only city that had signed. As stated in the theoretical part, for this concept of proximity, I expect that cities that are located near one of the original 141 learned about the MCPA very early on in the process, and had the potential to imitate and learn from those leaders. Accordingly, the sign of the inverse distance variable is expected to be positive. Figure 3.5: Counties with at least one city over 10.000 inhabitants; depicted in red are leaders of innovation 3.4 Analysis and Results To analyze the data at hand, I rely on a mixed strategy. Firstly, I take an exploratory look at the data and visualize distributions of key variables across the U.S. This provides a first hint regarding the possible clustering of values in specific regions. I then use more formalized measures of spatial cluster analysis to determine whether a spatial analysis strategy is warranted. Confirming the need to account for spatial interdependence in the analysis, I present in turn the results for all three theoretically derived explanations (Nature, Nurture and Neighbors) for the participation pattern in voluntary climate change initiatives. These results are then affirmed using several robustness checks on different specifications of the dependent variable and different estimation strategies. The section ends with a discussion on possible extensions. 56 3.4.1 Exploratory Analysis Conveying data to the reader in numerical format using tables is one way, however, for a more indepth exploratory analysis, I follow the suggestion given by Ward & Gleditsch (2008) and start my analysis by taking a look at maps. How does the participation pattern in the MCPA relate to selected independent variables specified in the theoretical part? Can clusters of certain values on different variables be detected, and do they significantly differ from what we would expect from randomness? The two figures 3.9 and 3.10 in the appendix show the distribution of values throughout the sample for four different variables. The dependent variable % MCPA is illustrated in subfigure 3.9(a), one explanatory variable on fatalities from natural hazards (Nature) in subfigure 3.9(b), one explanatory variable depicts the distribution of votes for the Democrats (Nurture: Incentives) in subfigure 3.10(a) and finally the distribution of unemployment rates (Nurture: Disincentive) throughout the U.S. is given in 3.10(b). Figure 3.9(a) shows that spatial clustering is clearly observable on the dependent variable. Clusters of high values are recognizable in large parts of Washington State, New Jersey, New York, and the New England states on the East Coast, in Florida as well as California on the West Coast and in Illinois and Minnesota in the Midwest. A clustering of low values can be spotted in parts of Colorado, Wyoming, and Nebraska as well as in the southern states of Louisiana and Mississippi. A very first glance at the data shown in the map therefore seems to support the conjecture made in section 3.2, that participation patterns of neighbors are more similar than those of others farther away. Proceeding now to look at the two other explanations of MCPA participation patterns, Nature and Nurture, I seek to determine whether a first exploratory analysis can indicate sources for the spatial clustering in the dependent variable. Figure 3.9(a) serves as the baseline. In the case of the natural explanatory factors, we can see that indeed, in the southwestern part of the U.S., especially in southern California and southern Arizona, higher participation patterns and a high vulnerability to natural hazards seem to coincide. The high concentration of fatalities in these areas mostly comes from severe heat waves and droughts in the years 2005 (for Arizona) and 2006 (for California). A similar observation can be made for southern Florida, where most of the fatalities are due to hurricanes and tornadoes. Here also, participation in the voluntary climate change initiative is quite high. However, northern Florida and Alabama along the Gulf Coast, who are also affected by these natural hazards, do not seem to participate as enthusiastically as their southern counterparts. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 57 In subfigure 3.10(a), which shows clustering of the % of votes for the Democrats as a proxy for a liberal and environmentally conscious electorate, we can see that clusters at the east coast in the New England states as well as in California and Washington state on the west coast seem to mirror high relative MCPA participation (subfigure 3.9(a)). However, a high concentration of democratic votes along the Mississippi in states such as Mississippi, Arkansas, and Tennessee do not seem to correlate with a high proportion of participation in the MCPA in these areas. One explanation for the non-participation in the MCPA could be that there are more disincentives than there are incentives to participate. Subfigure 3.10(b) shows that exactly this region around the Mississippi is plagued by high unemployment rates, which were related to less participation in section 3.2. In contrast, in other regions where unemployment rates are also quite high, such as Michigan, California, and Washington, MCPA participation rates are nevertheless high. Whether these regions have other incentives to participate cannot be deduced from this visual evidence, but will be taken into account in the statistical analyses below. One can see that a lot of the spatial clustering of the dependent variable might be attributed to clustering in the explanatory variables. However, from such a cursory look, we cannot conclude much, and as Ward & Gleditsch (2008, 11) correctly point out, ’humans are adroit at recognizing patterns, even where no patterns exist’. To see whether spatial clustering is present, we have to rely on more formal measures of spatial association, such as Global and Local Moran’s I (Anselin 1988). Local Moran’s I is a measure to detect clusters with values similar in magnitude on the one hand and clusters of counties with very heterogenous values on the other. The statistic is calculated as follows n(yi − y) � Ii = �n wij (yj − y) 2 i=1 (yi − y) (3.1) j∈Ji Figures 3.11 and 3.12 in the appendix show the associated z-standardized values of the local Moran’s I statistic for the dependent variable and the three explanatory variables; fatalities, % Democrats, and unemployment rate. The values are based on a county contiguity weights matrix. Significant results are either depicted in red or in blue shades, and indicate whether similarity or dissimilarity in values between the county and its neighbors is greater than what we would expect by chance (Anselin 1988). A highly positive and significant Z score for a county is illustrated in red and means that surrounding counties have similar values, either high (HH) or low (LL). If there are several high Z scores next to each other, we speak of a cluster of high or 58 low values. A highly negative and significant Z score is shown in blue and means that a county has dissimilar counties bordering it. So it either has a high value while the neighborhood is full of low values (HL) or it has a low values relative to a high value neighborhood (LH). As far as the spatial clustering in the dependent variable in subfigure 3.11(a) is concerned, two or three of such high value clusters can indeed be spotted in California, Minnesota, Florida, and New England. In these regions there exist more similar high values than we would predict by chance. Apart from those larger clusters, there are several counties that have exceptionally high MCPA participation values, but are surrounded by counties that have very low participation. So it can be said that some spatial clusters of high MCPA participation exist. However, there are less than would have been expected from our first cursory look at the distribution. I turn now to the explanatory variables to see whether we can relate some of the clustering in the dependent variables to exceptional clusters present in one of the explanatory variables. Subfigure 3.11(b) indeed shows that the high values in Arizona and southern California in subfigure 3.9(b) were exceptional and form one large cluster of counties with high numbers of fatalities surrounded by counties with similarly high values. The same holds true for southern Florida. Here, a cluster of high vulnerability to natural hazards corresponds to a cluster of high MCPA participation in the region. Similarly, the significant cluster of high vote shares for the Democrats in New England as well as in the Bay Area of California that can be seen in subfigure 3.12(a), corresponds to a cluster of high MCPA participation counties in figure 3.11(a). As far as the Moran’s I Z scores from the unemployment rate in subfigure 3.12(b) are concerned, no apparent similar clustering compared to the MCPA participation can be observed from this visual inspection except again for southern Florida, where a cluster of counties with comparatively low unemployment rates can be detected in an area where MCPA participation is exceptionally high. This exploratory analysis has provided an overview of the data at hand and served as a first step in determining whether interdependence – as suggested by hypotheses 8 and 9 – truly could be an important driver of participatory patterns in voluntary climate change initiatives. To conclude the exploratory analysis, there is some evidence that there might be spatial dependence in participation. However, the patterns we observe might not be caused by contagion. As we have seen, another potential cause for the spatial pattern in the dependent variable are similarities in values in observable explanatory variables (correlated X’s) as well as unobservable phenomena, like common culture, preferences, or perceptions (Franzese & Hays 2008b). Spatial analysis can Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 59 help answering whether the spatial pattern of the dependent variable is due to spatial dependence in the data or spatial clustering in the explanatory variables. The following section first presents the results concerning the relation of Nature and Nurture to participation in the MCPA and then focuses on adequately testing for the Neighbors component. 3.4.2 Statistical Analysis and Results Nature and nurture: regression analysis In the following, I first test the arguments brought forward in the theoretical section concerning the Nature and Nurture components. To this end, I have estimated several ordinary least squares (OLS) regression models on participation in the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement, which are depicted in table 3.3. The dependent variable in my analysis ranges from 0 to 100 and gives the percentage of cities within the county that have signed over those that could potentially have signed.15 For the estimation of these models, robust standard errors were used (White 1980; Wooldridge 2009).16 The first column of table 3.3 shows a test of hypothesis 1 concerning the impacts of natural risk factors on participation in voluntary agreements. We can see that the coefficient on the climate region variable is negative and strongly significant. This result is in accordance with the theoretically specified conjecture that one would expect counties in regions which might benefit from climate change (a higher value on the climate region variable) to have lower participation rates compared to counties in those regions that are more likely to be negatively affected. Similarly, being a coastal county and, therefore, more exposed to climate change risk shows to have a huge impact on MCPA participation. As regards to the two measures to proxy the vulnerability towards natural hazards, the coefficient on the property damage variable does not turn out to be significantly different from zero, while a higher number of fatalities through natural hazards is positively related to more participation. The difference in relative impact of the two natural hazards measures might be due to the fact that property damage is not seen as threatening as reports about fatalities, and property damage alone might not raise awareness for consequences from climate change. 15 16 Summary statistics for all variables used in the regressions can be found in appendix table 3.13. Diagnostic tests on the OLS residuals have detected heteroscedasticity of the residuals meaning the assumption V ar(�i ) �= σ 2 is not fulfilled. The non-constant variance of the residuals does not bias the coefficients, but renders them inefficient (Maddala 2001). A remedy for this problem is the use of robust standard errors (White 1980). 60 Table 3.3: Regression table (Baseline) (1) Nature -1.70∗∗∗ (0.32) 0.00 (0.00) 19.00∗∗∗ (2.76) 1.40∗∗∗ (0.48) Climate Region Property Damage Coastal County Fatalities % 4yrs College % Dem Vote Lib arts scaled by cities p.c. income Median Age Unemployment Rate p.c. tonnes carbon Population Pop Growth (00-05) % Manufacturing Empl Coal Production Industry dependent % Loc/State Gov Empl EPA non-attainment 25.72∗∗∗ (2.66) 1109 0.07 32.54 Constant Observations Adjusted R2 s.e. of estimate Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 (2) Nurture 0.90∗∗∗ (0.22) 0.88∗∗∗ (0.10) 4.20∗∗∗ (1.17) -0.07 (0.28) -0.17 (0.30) -2.62∗∗∗ (0.64) -0.05 (0.03) -0.00 (0.01) 0.12 (0.15) -0.01 (0.16) 0.00 (0.00) -0.68 (2.14) -0.10 (0.24) 0.01 (2.26) -16.26 (14.13) 1080 0.27 28.63 (3) Full -0.18 (0.31) 0.00 (0.00) 7.80∗∗∗ (2.76) 0.74∗ (0.44) 1.03∗∗∗ (0.23) 0.81∗∗∗ (0.10) 4.09∗∗∗ (1.13) -0.23 (0.27) -0.22 (0.30) -2.63∗∗∗ (0.65) -0.05 (0.03) -0.03∗ (0.02) 0.05 (0.15) 0.09 (0.16) 0.00 (0.00) -0.26 (2.11) -0.10 (0.24) 0.58 (2.24) -10.68 (14.58) 1080 0.28 28.49 (4) comb’I (5) comb’II 5.75∗∗ (2.41) 0.54 (0.42) 0.81∗∗∗ (0.23) 0.79∗∗∗ (0.09) 4.12∗∗∗ (1.17) -0.03 (0.25) -0.31 (0.29) -2.58∗∗∗ (0.62) -0.05 (0.03) 5.72∗∗ (2.40) -9.88 (11.19) 1109 0.27 28.75 0.85∗∗∗ (0.14) 0.78∗∗∗ (0.08) 4.35∗∗∗ (1.23) -2.35∗∗∗ (0.58) -23.90∗∗∗ (4.20) 1109 0.27 28.76 Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 61 The second column in table 3.3 then provides a first test of hypotheses 2-7, taping at the socio-economic and political conditions in the county that are assumed to either provide incentives or disincentives for participation. Starting with hypothesis 2, we can see that counter to expectation, wealth (as measured by per capita income) does not have the expected positive influence on participation. Instead, the coefficient is negative and not statistically significant.17 An ad-hoc explanation for this non-finding might be that most of the pro-environmental effect of income is picked up by other variables, such as education or age. I will return to this nonfinding in more detail below. For hypothesis 3, the suggested strong and positive influence of education on MCPA participation is confirmed by both indicators. First, a higher % of the population in a county that has a college education leads to higher participation rates. Second, a higher concentration of universities or colleges with liberal arts programs within the county 18 also has a sizable impact on participation. Another characteristic of the communities in the county that is assumed to increase MCPA participation is the % of Democrats supporters within the county. The coefficient on the variable % Dem Vote is positive and highly significant, confirming hypothesis 4. Democratic constituencies seem to be successful in demanding more voluntary participation in those counties. I now turn to hypothesis 5 stipulating that the higher the median age in the county is, the less likely is participation. Although the coefficient on median age bears the theoretically expected sign, it is not statistically significant. This seems to indicate that younger constituencies are not more concerned about climate change than their older counterparts. Further potential incentives leading to high participation were tested by the % of employment in state or local government. This variable is supposed to proxy a higher capacity and professionalism of governmental agencies within the county that might lead to more participation in voluntary agreements due to more information about voluntary climate change initiatives. However, no such effect could be found. With respect to the hypotheses about disincentives to participation, hypothesis 6 is confirmed by evidence from table 3.3. The coefficient on unemployment shows a huge negative and significant effect of bad economic conditions on participation. A high unemployment rate in a region might, therefore, indicate that politicians are interested in policies to ameliorate the economic situation rather than subscribing to voluntary climate change commitments. A further disincentive might arise from high abatement costs from voluntary climate change agreements that the 17 18 Using other indicators, such as total personal income, does not change the substantive result. Using also universities without a liberal arts program (only 390 of 1863 did not offer a liberal arts program) does not change the substantive result, however, as expected, the effect size is slightly smaller. 62 county would have to suffer in case of participation. The results from table 3.3, however, only weakly confirm hypothesis 7. Although the coefficient on CO2 emissions (p.c. tonnes carbon) in the county does not reach standard levels of significance, it shows the theoretically expected negative sign. Other control variables proxying abatement costs such as the % of manufacturing employment, industry dependence of the county, coal production in the county, or the EPA nonattainment status19 are also not found to be significantly related to participation. This finding is quite counter to what I expected, and it is not affected by different model specifications (not shown here). I will return to the relatively better performance of the indicators proxying incentives compared to those looking at disincentives more extensively in the section on robustness checks and alternative specifications. Column three of table 3.3 then displays a full model of Nature and Nurture characteristics. The substantive results from columns 1 and 2 remain unchanged. However, in this model, the climate region variable is no longer significant as it seems that socio-economic and political characteristics perform better in explaining the variation in the dependent variable. Furthermore, the coefficient on the variable population size just reaches significance and indicates that a larger population in a county is less likely to widely participate in the MCPA. Adding natural risk characteristics, however, does not add a lot to the model fit as we can see from the only slight increase in the Adjusted-R2 and the decrease in the standard error of the estimate. The last two columns in table 3.3 then combine Nature and Nurture characteristics in a more parsimonious way. The model in column 4 includes the variables that were deemed by theory to be most important for participation in voluntary climate change agreements, namely vulnerability to climate change, income, education, age, political identification, economic distress, and abatement costs. Dropping all other variables from the model does not change the model fit drastically. In column 5, the theoretical baseline model is further reduced to include only those variables that were significantly related to MCPA participation in the models in columns 1-4. Again, neither model fit nor the substantive results change as a consequence of further reducing the number of explanatory factors to only five. This gives a first indication on the robustness of the reported effects. One issue that regularly raises concern, e.g. when confronted with non-findings from theoretically relevant variables, is multicollinearity. In the presence of multicollinearity, coefficients 19 This control variable measures whether the county has been a non-attainment county for Criteria Air Pollutants under the Clean Air Act in 2004, 2005, or 2006. Non-attainment counties that already have difficulty complying with given EPA legislation are expected not to participate in voluntary GHG efforts. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 63 may have the wrong sign or lower / higher than predicted magnitudes. When is multicollinearity a problem? Greene (2003) suggests calculating the variance inflation factor (VIF) for each coefficient as a diagnostic statistic to gauge whether the variances of the estimates are adversely affected by the intercorrelation between them. This VIF then shows how much of the estimate’s variance is inflated by multicollinearity. Observing the VIF factors of all the models calculated in table 3.3 shows that they are well below the commonly accepted rule of thumb of 10 (O’Brien 2007). The estimate of % 4yrs college and the one of per capita (p.c.) income had the highest VIF factors with just over 3. In addition, a simple pairwise correlation of all the variables shows that those two variables were correlated with .68. While this could explain the insignificance of the coefficient on income, additional tests show that it does not. As multicollinearity does not affect the overall results and as education and income are assumed to be theoretically relevant for the explanation of MCPA participation, both variables are included in subsequent models. Neighbors: Spatial analysis To empirically test the hypothesis 9 concerning the interdependence in participation between geographically proximate counties, I use spatial analysis. Spatial analysis can help to take dependence into account and deal with spatially clustered phenomena. Furthermore, spatial models allow to examine the impact that one observation has on other, proximate observations (Ward & Gleditsch 2008). To this end, the following spatial model (Franzese & Hays 2008b) is estimated y = ρWy + Xβ + � (3.2) where y is an N x 1 vector of observations on the % of MCPA signatories, X is an N x k matrix of observations the independent variables concerning the Nature and Nurture characteristics, β is an k x 1 vector of coefficients on the X� s and � is an N x 1 vector of disturbances. W is the spatial weighting matrix that reflects the connectivity between neighboring observations and ρ is a scalar that measures the impact of MCPA participation in the neighboring (as defined by wij ) counties on the participation in county i. Wy – the spatial lag– is the weighted average of MCPA participation in county i’s neighbors. However, because of the endogenous spatial lag on the right-hand side, estimating the model in equation 2 with standard OLS will induce bias (Anselin 1988). More precisely, estimating the model using standard OLS regression would in the case of expected positive spatial dependence lead to an overestimation of spatial interdependence and 64 underestimate the strength of unit-level factors (Hays 2009; Franzese & Hays 2007). Franzese & Hays (2008a) recommend using spatial maximum likelihood (S-ML) in this case. To test whether it is warranted to use spatial econometrics, I have checked the residuals from the OLS regression for spatial dependence. The residuals are usually inspected to see whether the OLS results, which assume independent observations, are affected by spatial clustering in the dependent and independent variables. Both the global Moran’s I test statistic as well as the Lagrange Multiplier test (Ward & Gleditsch 2008) indicated the presence of such dependencies in the data and therefore empirically confirmed theoretical considerations about the importance of interdependence in studying MCPA participation. Table 3.4: Spatial ML; W based on county contiguity (0 / 1 ) (1) Neighbors mu % 4yrs College % Dem Vote Unemployment Rate Median Age p.c. income p.c. tonnes carbon Lib arts scaled by cities Coastal County Fatalities Constant rho Constant Log lik. χ2 Prob> χ2 Observations 14.49∗∗∗ (1.22) 0.21∗∗∗ -4978.37 (0.04) 1012 (2) Combined I 0.66∗∗∗ 0.76∗∗∗ -2.96∗∗∗ -0.48∗ 0.01 -0.06 4.31∗∗∗ 6.02∗∗∗ 0.41 0.00 (0.18) (0.09) (0.70) (0.29) (0.20) (0.07) (0.83) (2.27) (0.34) (11.35) 0.08∗ -4814.38 323.58 0.00 1012 (0.05) (3) Combined II 0.75∗∗∗ 0.74∗∗∗ -2.65∗∗∗ (0.13) (0.09) (0.69) 4.55∗∗∗ 5.80∗∗∗ (0.83) (2.21) -19.97∗∗∗ (5.04) 0.08∗ -4817.38 320.69 0.00 1012 (0.04) Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 As mentioned in section 3.3.2, I use three different conceptions of geographic proximity. Each of the three weighting matrices is tested in turns. I conduct the empirical testing of hypothesis 9 with the first conception of proximity, strict contiguity (Gleditsch & Ward 2001). The results from the spatial-ML based on the county contiguity W are shown in table 3.4. Model 1 tests the Neighbors hypothesis with an empty model, only including the spatial lag. We can see that the estimate for the spatially lagged y is positive and highly significant, indicating that a county’s MCPA participation positively covaries with the level of MCPA participation of its neighbors. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 65 A one unit positive shock to the MCPA participation level in the neighbors would lead to an immediate 0.21 increase in the county’s own participation (Franzese & Hays 2006). However, so far I do not account for other covariates explaining MCPA participation. In models 2 and 3, I add the two baseline models from the Nature and Nurture context (models 4 and 5 from table 3.3). The coefficients in this spatial model differ from those obtained in the non-spatial model in that models 2 and 3 control for spatial dependence in y. For example, in model 2, the coefficient on % Dem Vote now represents the effect of democratic votes for MCPA participation while not only controlling for other Nurture and Nature characteristics, but also for the extent that county i’s participation level can be described by the value of y in connected counties j (Ward & Gleditsch 2008; Franzese & Hays 2006). As expected, all coefficients remain robust in their direction and significance. The only change that can be observed is that, in model 2, the coefficient on median age has a negative impact on participation and reaches conventional levels of significance. Table 3.5: Spatial ML; W based on Inverse Distance (1) Neighbors mu % 4yrs College % Dem Vote Unemployment Rate Median Age p.c. income p.c. tonnes carbon Lib arts scaled by cities Coastal County Fatalities Constant rho Constant Log lik. χ2 Prob> χ2 Observations 12.82∗∗∗ (1.34) 0.30∗∗∗ -5457.89 (0.05) 1109 (2) Combined I 0.82∗∗∗ 0.75∗∗∗ -2.45∗∗∗ -0.35 -0.06 -0.04 4.24∗∗∗ 5.25∗∗ 0.55 -8.83 (0.18) (0.09) (0.69) (0.27) (0.20) (0.06) (0.85) (2.25) (0.35) (10.92) 0.10∗ -5291.47 383.08 0.00 1109 (0.05) (3) Combined II 0.86∗∗∗ 0.74∗∗∗ -2.19∗∗∗ (0.13) (0.09) (0.67) 4.46∗∗∗ 5.17∗∗ (0.84) (2.19) -24.70∗∗∗ (4.94) 0.09∗ -5294.32 375.49 0.00 1109 (0.05) Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 As a second test, I now use the N x N (1109 x 1109) spatial weights matrix connecting the inverse distance between counties to estimate the spatial ML (see table 3.5). Again, an empty model including only the spatial lag is estimated first. As in table 3.4, ρ, the coefficient on the 66 spatial lag, is highly significant in the first model and is only marginally significant at the 10% level as soon as the other theoretically relevant explanatory variables are included. Once more, the substantive results from the two baseline models stay exactly the same. In table 3.6, the spatial ML is now calculated using the second distance weights matrix with the imposed threshold of 100km.20 In section 3.2.3, it was argued that compared to the county contiguity matrix, which gives equal weight across all bordering neighbors, and the regular inverse distance matrix, where all units are expected to influence one another, the inverse distance matrix with a threshold allows us to better capture spatial distances. Once again, nothing changes with respect to the county-internal Nature and Nurture characteristics. However, interestingly, ρ is only significantly related to more MCPA participation in the empty model. In model 2 and 3, it does not reach conventional levels of significance, while all other coefficients remain unchanged. This fact is not too surprising given that both other spatial weights, although generally indicating the presence of spatial dependence, were only marginally significant at the 10% level.21 Lastly and as a fourth test of the effects of spatial interdependence, I look at the influence of leaders of innovation. In section 3.2.3, I have assumed that the closer a county is to one of the 141 leaders of innovation that first signed the Mayors’ Climate Protection Agreement in 2005, the higher is its participation level. Analogously to the tables before, in table 3.7 the measure of proximity (inverse distance) to the closest of the 141 cities is highly significant in an empty model (model 1). The positive effect from the proximity to the leader cities on MCPA participation in the county is huge. However, as I add theoretically important covariates to the model, the effect again vanishes and even gets negative. This would imply that, controlling for all other covariates, nearness to one of the leader cities is even detrimental for MCPA participation. However, this effect is not significant in models 2 and 3. Other than that, no coefficients substantively change direction in the models including the proximity to a leader city. How can we interpret the findings regarding the Neighbors component in MCPA participation patterns? Although evidence that MCPA participation patterns are positively influenced by MCPA participation in neighboring counties was found, the spatial analysis did not find a robust spatial effect for the different conceptions of nearness. Furthermore, Hypothesis 9 on the 20 Results from an inverse distance matrix with a threshold of 200 km can be provided, however, they do not change results 21 Although Franzese & Hays (2008a) find from Monte Carlo Simulations that spatial ML tends to underestimate the strength of interdependence, they also find that this is a more serious problem in small-N samples, thus, the analysis of 1109 counties should not seriously be affected by this bias. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 67 Table 3.6: Spatial ML; W based on Inverse Distance up to 100 km (1) Neighbors mu % 4yrs College % Dem Vote Unemployment Rate Median Age p.c. income p.c. tonnes carbon Lib arts scaled by cities Coastal County Fatalities Constant rho Constant Log lik. χ2 Prob> χ2 Observations 15.32∗∗∗ (1.19) 0.16∗∗∗ -5459.57 (0.04) 1108 (2) Combined I 0.81∗∗∗ 0.77∗∗∗ -2.53∗∗∗ -0.33 -0.05 -0.04 4.19∗∗∗ 5.53∗∗ 0.54 -9.01 (0.18) (0.09) (0.69) (0.28) (0.20) (0.06) (0.85) (2.25) (0.35) (10.95) 0.04 -5288.21 397.84 0.00 1108 (0.03) (3) Combined II 0.86∗∗∗ 0.76∗∗∗ -2.28∗∗∗ (0.13) (0.09) (0.67) 4.41∗∗∗ 5.48∗∗ (0.84) (2.19) -24.00∗∗∗ (4.94) 0.03 -5290.89 391.28 0.00 1108 (0.03) Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 Table 3.7: Basic Models with Proximity to Leaders of Innovation (1) Neighbors Proximity to leader city % 4yrs College % Dem Vote Unemployment Rate Median Age p.c. income p.c. tonnes carbon Lib arts scaled by cities Coastal County Fatalities Constant Observations Adjusted R2 s.e. of estimate 17.21∗∗∗ 14.30∗∗∗ 1085 0.02 31.30 Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 (4.17) (0.99) (2) Combined I -4.65 0.54∗∗ 0.66∗∗∗ -2.11∗∗∗ -0.43 0.27 -0.04 4.84∗∗∗ 4.17∗ 0.66 -8.02 1085 0.21 28.11 (4.64) (0.22) (0.09) (0.60) (0.28) (0.26) (0.03) (1.29) (2.41) (0.43) (10.54) (3) Combined II red -3.65 0.74∗∗∗ 0.66∗∗∗ -2.04∗∗∗ (4.47) (0.15) (0.09) (0.57) 5.17∗∗∗ 4.93∗∗ (1.17) (2.42) -19.99∗∗∗ 1085 0.20 28.15 (4.45) 68 distance to leaders of innovation was refuted. The fact that a weakly significant spatial effect is present in two of three weights matrices is of concern only due to the fact that the two distance weights matrices, Inverse Distance and Inverse Distance (100km) do not appear to make a huge difference at first glance. However, the choice of using one over the other would substantively change the result from the spatial analysis. This result corroborates Pluemper & Neumayer (2010)’s concern about justification and validity of one chosen set of connectivities as compared to another. As Beck et al. (2006, 28) remark: ’The assumption that these connectivities are known a priori is both a strong assumption and critical for the methods of spatial econometrics to work ’. Unfortunately, precise theoretical considerations about which spatial connectivity is the right one for a given substantive problem do virtually not exist (Anselin 2004), and even with better theories, some arbitrariness will remain (Pluemper & Neumayer 2010). Although hypothesis 8 on the influence of participation in neighboring counties on a county’s participation could not be unambiguously confirmed, results pertaining to the two other explanations of MCPA participation, Nature and Nurture, were supported by the OLS as well the spatial ML analysis. Robust results are that favorable conditions for a high participation in the MCPA are highly educated and liberal constituencies. Coastal counties that are vulnerable to the effects of global warming are also consistently found to increase participation in voluntary climate change agreements. A high proportion of unemployed persons means that policies concerning climate change are not the first priority within the county and lead to less participation. However, income did not have a statistically significant positive effect on participation, although in theory it was seen as an important determinant for environmental consciousness. Also, abatement costs, as proxied by CO2 emissions, which substantively should have a deterrent effect, do not seem to play a role in predicting participation. The following robustness section rigorously checks whether these main results hold for different model specifications and estimation methods. 3.4.3 Robustness Checks The first part of the robustness section looks at different model specifications with respect to the inclusion of interactive terms to the regression and their implication for the substantive results discussed in the previous section. In the second and more extensive part, I then use three alternative estimation methods to explain participation in local climate change agreements and compare the results with the ones obtained in the main analysis above. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 69 Model specification In this subsection, I directly follow up on the puzzling result obtained from the main analysis that income did not have a statistically significant effect on MCPA participation, although in theory it was seen as an important determinant for environmental consciousness. To that end, I test whether income might not have a direct effect on participation, but if the effect of income could be conditional on the % of voters for the Democratic Party. Models 1 and 2 in table 3.8 show the results from adding an interactive term to the baseline regression models. It can be seen that while the coefficient on % Democrats stays significant and similar in magnitude compared to the baseline, the coefficient on the interactive term does not reach statistical significance and shows no effect. To better grasp the result, figure 3.6 visualizes the marginal effect of p.c. income on MCPA participation at varying percentages of democratic vote. As suspected, we can see a slightly negative marginal effect of income on MCPA in areas where the constituency is leaning more to the Republicans and approaching zero for higher values of % Democrats. However, the effect never reaches statistical significance. This result confirms the results obtained in the -1 Marginal Effect of p.c. income on \% MCPA -.5 0 .5 1 previous section regarding the null effect of income on MCPA participation. 0 20 40 60 80 100 \% Dem Vote Dashed lines give 95% confidence interval. Figure 3.6: Interaction effect between income and % Democrats in the county The second interactive term also has to do with the % of democratic votes in counties. In hypothesis 4, the pro-environmental effect of democratic votes was related to the positioning of the democratic leaders on the issue. However, I would not have expected this effect of the % of Democrats on MCPA participation to be so persistently high. The reason for this is that the electorate of the Democratic Party is quite heterogeneous. Due to their stance on social security, many low income or unemployed individuals belong to their vote base (CNN exit polls 70 Table 3.8: Regression table with Interaction terms % 4yrs College % Dem Vote Unemployment Rate Median Age p.c. income p.c. tonnes carbon Lib arts scaled by cities Coastal County Fatalities %Dem x Income (1) %Dem*Income 0.81∗∗∗ (0.23) 0.79∗∗∗ (0.09) -2.58∗∗∗ (0.61) -0.30 (0.30) -0.05 (0.26) -0.05 (0.03) 4.08∗∗∗ (1.16) 5.72∗∗ (2.43) 0.55 (0.42) 0.00 (0.01) (2) %Dem*Income 0.93∗∗∗ (0.19) 0.78∗∗∗ (0.09) -2.46∗∗∗ (0.60) -0.18 (0.23) 4.15∗∗∗ (1.16) 5.79∗∗ (2.43) 0.58 (0.42) 0.00 (0.01) %Unemp x %Dem Constant -9.72 (11.13) 1109 0.27 28.76 Observations Adjusted R2 s.e. of estimate Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 -20.01∗∗∗ (5.60) 1109 0.27 28.76 (3) Unemp*%Dem 0.73∗∗∗ (0.23) 1.59∗∗∗ (0.21) 4.05∗∗∗ (1.48) -0.44 (0.30) -0.02 (0.26) -0.04 (0.03) 4.26∗∗∗ (1.21) 5.34∗∗ (2.43) 0.59 (0.41) (4) Unemp*%Dem 0.81∗∗∗ (0.14) 1.50∗∗∗ (0.20) 3.84∗∗ (1.51) -0.15∗∗∗ (0.03) -38.36∗∗∗ (12.47) 1109 0.28 28.61 -0.14∗∗∗ (0.03) -54.73∗∗∗ (8.47) 1109 0.28 28.62 4.36∗∗∗ (1.29) 4.93∗∗ (2.44) 0.61 (0.41) 71 -2 Marginal Effect of \% Dem Vote on \% MCPA -1 0 1 2 Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 0 5 10 Unemployment Rate 15 Dashed lines give 95% confidence interval. Figure 3.7: Interaction effect between % Democrats and unemployment in the county 2008). Among these voters, environmental concerns may not rank highly, and I therefore expect that in areas where there is high unemployment, but also a high proportion of votes for the Democrats, the pro-environmental effect of the Democratic Party is less pronounced. Models 3 and 4 in table 3.8 show the baseline models with the inclusion of an interactive term between the % of democratic votes and % unemployment. As expected, the interactive term is negative and also significant. Figure 3.7 nicely illustrate how the effect of % democratic vote is positive and very strong for low levels of unemployment. However, as unemployment increases, the positive effect becomes less strong and eventually even turns into a negative one for very high levels of unemployment. As far as all other covariates in the models are concerned, they remain unchanged. In addition, the model fit has slightly increased compared to the baseline models. Estimation Logistic Regression In a similar study, Brody et al. (2008) look at county-level CCP participation patterns and operationalize their dependent variable to take the value one if there is a city within the county that has committed to the CCP agreement and zero otherwise. Although this reduces information or variance on the dependent variable, I use a different operationalization of my dependent variable as a robustness check on the results obtained from the OLS regression above. Table 3.9 presents the results of a logistic regression on the existence of at least one city in the county that is a participant in the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. The estimated models are the same as for the regression analysis with two slight changes. First, the university / colleges variable is now also binary, indicating whether a county has a university with a 4-year 72 Table 3.9: Logistic Regression whether at least one city in the county has signed MCPA (1) Nature 0.53∗∗∗ (0.06) -0.12∗∗∗ (0.03) -0.00 (0.00) 1.13∗∗∗ (0.19) 0.10∗∗ (0.04) MCPA No.of cities Climate Region Property Damage Coastal County Fatalities % 4yrs College % Dem Vote Uni/Coll p.c. income Median Age Unemployment Rate p.c. tonnes carbon Population Pop Growth (00-05) % Manufacturing Empl Coal Production Industry dependent % Loc/State Gov Empl EPA non-attainment -1.49∗∗∗ (0.22) 0.23 -513.25 1109 Constant Pseudo R2 Log lik. Observations Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 (2) Nurture 0.28∗∗∗ (0.09) 0.05∗∗ (0.02) 0.09∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.74∗∗∗ (0.24) 0.00 (0.03) -0.00 (0.03) -0.26∗∗∗ (0.09) -0.02∗ (0.01) 0.01 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) 0.01 (0.02) -0.00 (0.00) -0.12 (0.25) -0.01 (0.02) 0.03 (0.23) -5.82∗∗∗ (1.54) 0.41 -384.59 1080 (3) Full 0.28∗∗∗ (0.09) -0.01 (0.04) 0.00 (0.00) 0.44∗ (0.26) 0.08 (0.05) 0.06∗∗∗ (0.02) 0.08∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.76∗∗∗ (0.24) -0.01 (0.03) -0.01 (0.03) -0.25∗∗∗ (0.09) -0.02∗ (0.01) 0.01 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) -0.00 (0.00) -0.10 (0.25) -0.01 (0.02) 0.04 (0.23) -5.54∗∗∗ (1.57) 0.41 -381.76 1080 (4) comb’I 0.38∗∗∗ (0.07) (5) comb’II 0.42∗∗∗ (0.07) 0.30 (0.22) 0.10∗∗ (0.04) 0.04∗ (0.02) 0.08∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.81∗∗∗ (0.22) 0.03 (0.03) -0.03 (0.03) -0.24∗∗∗ (0.08) -0.02∗ (0.01) 0.39∗ (0.22) -5.21∗∗∗ (1.23) 0.39 -402.33 1109 0.05∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.08∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.82∗∗∗ (0.22) -0.25∗∗∗ (0.08) -5.83∗∗∗ (0.55) 0.39 -406.75 1109 Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 73 program or not. Second, a variable was added on how many cities there are in the county. The rationale behind the inclusion is, of course, that the likelihood that at least one city signs the MCPA increases with more cities in a county. As expected, the coefficient on the number of cities is positive and highly statistically significant. As far as the natural characteristics are concerned, the effect of being a coastal county does not reach statistical significance in all models, whereas fatalities become a significant predictor of whether there is at least one city in the county that has signed the MCPA. The only significantly changed variable is the per capita carbon emission. A higher emission value per capita now significantly decreases the likelihood of having a city in the county that has signed the agreement. The difference in results from the logistic regression compared to OLS obviously lies in the interpretation of the dependent variable. Whereas p.c. emissions might not serve as a good predictor of the percentage of MCPA signatories, it turns out to be a significant predictor whether there is at least one city that signs in a county or not. I will address this slight difference in interpretation in more detail in the following alternative conceptualizations of the dependent variable. Quantile (Median) Regression In the statistical analyses above, it was mentioned that the dependent variable is rightly skewed. Therefore, the homoscedasticity assumption is not met and robust standard errors were used to circumvent the problem. However, while this remedy renders perfectly valid standard errors, it can be regarded as fixing the nuisance associated with the distribution of the dependent variable rather than explicitly modeling the substance of it. Traditional regression analysis focuses on the relationship between a response variable and its predictor variables by modeling the conditional mean of the response (Hao & Naiman 2007). However, in instances of high skewness, only relying on the mean as a measure of central tendency might fail to capture other informative trends in the response function (Hao & Naiman 2007). The right skewness of the distribution of MCPA participation makes the mean (18.2) considerably larger than the median (0). In such cases, median regression might be an alternative approach. Median regression estimates the median instead of the mean of the dependent variable, conditional on the values of the independent variables (For a more complete and formal introduction in quantile regression models c.f. Koenker & Bassett 1982; Hao & Naiman 2007; Wooldridge 2009). Table 3.10 compares the result for the two baseline models estimated using standard OLS regression in models 1 and 3 with the models from the median regression using Koenker-Bassett standard errors (Koenker & Bassett 1982). For the first 74 model with all the theoretically relevant covariates, we observe some differences between OLS and median regression, whereas in the second baseline model, no huge changes are noticeable. Similar to the linear framework, coefficients can be interpreted as the change in the median of Table 3.10: OLS (Mean) Regression vs. Quantile (Median) Regression with Koenker-Basset (kb) (1982) standard errors % 4yrs College % Dem Vote Unemployment Rate Median Age p.c. income p.c. tonnes carbon Lib arts scaled by cities Coastal County Fatalities Constant Adjusted R2 Observations (1) Mean (Comb’I) 0.81∗∗∗ (0.23) 0.79∗∗∗ (0.09) -2.58∗∗∗ (0.62) -0.31 (0.29) -0.03 (0.25) -0.05 (0.03) 4.12∗∗∗ (1.17) 5.75∗∗ (2.41) 0.54 (0.42) -9.88 (11.19) 0.27 1109 (2) q50 kb 0.12∗∗ (0.05) 0.25∗∗∗ (0.02) -0.33∗ (0.19) -0.34∗∗∗ (0.08) 0.62∗∗∗ (0.06) 0.00 (0.01) 1.68∗∗∗ (0.24) 4.54∗∗∗ (0.64) 0.67∗∗∗ (0.10) -13.91∗∗∗ (3.10) 1109 (3) Mean (Comb’II) 0.85∗∗∗ (0.14) 0.78∗∗∗ (0.08) -2.35∗∗∗ (0.58) (4) q50 kb 0.56∗∗∗ (0.03) 0.27∗∗∗ (0.02) -0.36∗∗ (0.17) 4.35∗∗∗ (1.23) 5.72∗∗ (2.40) 1.01∗∗∗ (0.22) 3.56∗∗∗ (0.56) -23.90∗∗∗ (4.20) 0.27 1109 -16.79∗∗∗ (1.28) 1109 Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 the dependent variable for a one unit change in the independent variable (Buchinsky 1998). A remarkable change can be seen for the coefficient on unemployment, which increases from -2.58 to -0.33. For the substantive interpretation, this means that for an unemployment rate increase of 1 %, average MCPA participation would decrease by 2.58. However, predicting the median, the decrease in participation from more unemployment would not be as substantial (0.32). Note also how the coefficient on income changes to the theoretically expected positive and significant relation, when predicting the median instead of the mean. Due to the right-skewed distribution, OLS or the conditional-means function reflect to a greater extend what is going on in the upper tail of the distributions (biased to predicting participation) rather than what is going on in the Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 75 middle of the distribution. This has lead to the differences we observe comparing the baseline regression models with the ones obtained from median regression in table 3.10 Although there are some changes in statistical significance and effect sizes of the coefficients, it nevertheless can be seen that – in spite of the fact that 50% did not receive the treatment and had zero values – the main results concerning the influence of Nature and Nurture still hold. Count models Finally, the substantive interest lies in the explanation of MCPA participation and, therefore, using the count of MCPA signatories in a county as the dependent variable is another possibility. For data on counts, the Poisson distribution usually serves as a baseline to represent the variability in the count data. However, the Poisson model mostly does not fit in practice since in many applications the restriction that the conditional mean equals the conditional variance does not hold (Long 1997). In such cases, the negative binomial regression model is the right choice. Tests to account whether the Poisson model or the Negative Binomial fit the MCPA count data at hand found significant overdispersion and suggested a better fit of the Negative Binomial model as can be seen in figure 3.8. The observed proportion (count of cities that have signed the MCPA) is well described by one that we would expect from a negative binomial. Table 3.11 accordingly shows the results of a negative binomial regression on the count of cities that have signed the MCPA in the county. The two combined models from the baseline regression were estimated to allow for comparisons. To account for the different compositions of counties, the number of cities in the county is also added as an explanatory variable. Both models show significant overdispersion (i.e. σ 2 > 1) and justify the modeling 0 .2 Proportion .4 .6 .8 choice. 0 2 4 6 8 10 Count MCPA mean = .5744; overdispersion = 3.238 observed proportion neg binom prob poisson prob Figure 3.8: Actual count distribution against negative binomial and poisson distribution 76 The results from table 3.11 generally reflect the results obtained from the simple OLS regression, with the one exception that the number of universities or colleges with liberal arts programs is not statistically significant any more. All other explanatory variables bear the theoretically expected signs and statistical significance levels. Of course, the substantive interpretation of the coefficients changes in comparison to the OLS regression. For a unit change in the respective explanatory variable xk , the expected count changes by a factor of exp(βk ), keeping the other variables constant (Long 1997). As an example, going from the minimum value of % Democratic vote to the maximum value while keeping the other variables at their median results in a total effect for % Democratic vote of 1.54 on the expected MCPA count. These results again strengthen my confidence in the obtained substantive results from the OLS and spatial regressions. One additional test, which could deal with the high number of counties with no MCPA signatories, is to estimate a zero-inflated negative binomial regression model (Sattler & Bernauer 2011). These models explicitly model the occurrence of ’excess’ zero. The process generating the zeros might, however, depend on other factors than the process for strictly positive outcomes (Winkelmann 2008). Zero-inflated negative binomial models estimate two equations, one for the count model and the other for predicting the excess zeros. This modeling of the count outcome allows the researcher to specify a separate model to account for the zeros. In the case of the MCPA participation, I would suspect that those variables that are seen as disincentives for participation are the ones to predict excess zeros best. In table 3.12, I therefore included CO2 emissions, the unemployment rate, whether the county is dependent on industrial production, and whether there is coal production in the county as predictors in the logit (inflation) part. The count models have not changed from the ones in table 3.11. Again, the substantive direction and significance of the coefficients remains robust with the exception of the coefficient on the unemployment rate, which becomes insignificant in the count equation. Turning to the inflation equation predicting excess zeros, the theoretically derived disincentives all perform well in predicting whether a county would be beyond the zeros. A high unemployment rate as well as CO2 emissions increase the probability of observing a zero. All measures bear the expected sign and are statistically significant. Also, the Vuong test to see if the zero-inflated negative binomial is a significant improvement over the standard negative binomial model (Long 1997) takes on a large positive value and a large z value, favoring the zero-inflated negative binomial model over the standard negative binomial (Greene 2003). Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 77 Table 3.11: Negative Binomial Regression on the count of MCPA signatories in the county (1) Nature 0.16∗∗∗ (0.02) -0.07∗∗∗ (0.02) 0.99∗∗∗ (0.11) -0.00 (0.00) 0.02 (0.02) Count MCPA No.of cities Climate Region Coastal County Property Damage Fatalities % 4yrs College % Dem Vote No. Lib Arts Uni/Coll p.c. income Median Age Unemployment Rate p.c. tonnes carbon Population Pop Growth (00-05) % Manufacturing Empl Coal Production Industry dependent % Loc/State Gov Empl EPA non-attainment -1.15∗∗∗ (0.13) -0.28 (0.22) 0.18 -885.91 1109 Constant lnalpha Pseudo R2 Log lik. Observations Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 (2) Nurture 0.08∗∗∗ (0.02) 0.03∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.05∗∗∗ (0.01) -0.07 (0.04) 0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.02) -0.18∗∗∗ (0.05) -0.03∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.00 (0.00) 0.02∗∗ (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.00 (0.00) -0.08 (0.16) -0.02∗ (0.01) 0.22∗∗ (0.11) -2.83∗∗∗ (0.78) -1.00∗∗∗ (0.16) 0.28 -766.20 1080 (3) Full 0.08∗∗∗ (0.02) -0.00 (0.02) 0.36∗∗∗ (0.11) 0.00 (0.00) -0.00 (0.04) 0.04∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.05∗∗∗ (0.01) -0.06 (0.04) 0.00 (0.01) -0.02 (0.02) -0.16∗∗∗ (0.05) -0.02∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.00 (0.00) 0.01∗ (0.01) -0.00 (0.01) -0.00 (0.00) -0.08 (0.16) -0.02∗ (0.01) 0.26∗∗ (0.12) -2.47∗∗∗ (0.75) -1.14∗∗∗ (0.16) 0.29 -761.00 1080 (4) comb’I 0.10∗∗∗ (0.02) (5) comb’II 0.11∗∗∗ (0.02) 0.37∗∗∗ (0.11) 0.44∗∗∗ (0.11) 0.02 (0.02) 0.03∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.04∗∗∗ (0.00) -0.03 (0.04) 0.01 (0.01) -0.02 (0.02) -0.14∗∗∗ (0.05) -0.03∗∗∗ (0.01) -2.77∗∗∗ (0.65) -0.89∗∗∗ (0.19) 0.27 -793.18 1109 0.04∗∗∗ (0.01) 0.04∗∗∗ (0.00) -0.02 (0.03) -0.15∗∗∗ (0.04) -3.49∗∗∗ (0.33) -0.82∗∗∗ (0.20) 0.26 -799.07 1109 78 Table 3.12: Zero Inflated Negative Binomial Regression on the count of MCPA signatories in the county (1) Combined I Count MCPA No.of cities % 4yrs College % Dem Vote Unemployment Rate No. Lib Arts Uni/Coll Coastal County Median Age p.c. income Fatalities Constant inflate p.c. tonnes carbon Unemployment Rate Coal Production Industry dependent Constant lnalpha Constant Log lik. Voung test Prob> z Observations 0.11∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ -0.08 -0.02 0.44∗∗∗ (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.06) (0.03) (0.12) -3.71∗∗∗ (0.39) 0.10∗∗∗ 0.03∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ -0.07 -0.04 0.39∗∗∗ -0.02 0.01 0.03 -3.37∗∗∗ (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.06) (0.03) (0.12) (0.02) (0.01) (0.02) (0.75) 0.26∗ 2.51∗∗ 0.00∗ 5.58∗ -26.23∗∗ (0.14) (1.18) (0.00) (3.30) (12.54) 0.26∗ 2.51∗∗ 0.00∗ 5.47∗ -26.05∗∗ (0.14) (1.17) (0.00) (3.26) (12.44) -0.88∗∗∗ -789.89 3.13 0.00 1109 (0.17) -0.92∗∗∗ -787.83 3.12 0.00 1109 (0.17) Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ (2) Combined II p < 0.01 Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 79 The zero-inflated negative binomial model translates the theoretical split between incentives and disincentive for participation nicely into an empirical model. It further can account for the difference in interpretation that came out of the logistic regression in the sense that the variables measuring theoretically derived disincentives can explain the excess zeros and, therefore, the high number of counties where no city has signed the agreement. Simultaneously, the negative binomial count model predicts the number of MCPA signatories by focusing on the incentives for participation plus the natural risk variables. In conclusion, it can be said that the robustness section does not only provide clear evidence in support of the general robustness of the initial findings concerning hypotheses 1-7, but also shows that and how alternative specifications can fit the theoretical set up. 3.5 Conclusion This paper set out to explain county-level participation rates in voluntary climate change initiatives throughout the U.S. by factors regarding a county’s natural (Nature) and socio-economic and political (Nurture) characteristics, as well as their geographical surroundings (Neighbors). It was hypothesized that voluntary participation in climate change mitigation efforts are highest when the county is at risk of being adversely affected by climate change, when there are favorable socio-economic and political conditions present, and when the surrounding counties are also strong participators. I have tested these claims for the MCPA participatory behavior of cities in counties within the 48 contiguous states in the period 2005-2008. As far as the natural system characteristics are concerned, being a coastal county seems to drive signatory behavior. For socio-economic and political characteristics, drivers of participation are a well-educated and liberal population as well as a high percentage of democratic voters within the county. Furthermore, the presence of universities significantly increases the relative number of signatories. Disincentives for participation include especially bad economic conditions in a county. Depending on model specification, proxies for potential abatement costs are also significantly related to participation. Findings from spatial analysis indicate some evidence of spatial interdependence in participation, meaning that some of the variation in a country’s participation level can be attributed to participation levels in connected countries. However, of the four different specifications of geographic influence tested, only two support the conjecture of a significant effect of spatial interdependence. 80 How can we interpret these ambiguous results on the spatial interdependence in participation? First, it generally seems that most of the spatial clustering in the dependent variable is explained by the independent variables other than the spatial lag. This is positive news for the Nature and Nurture components. Their influence on MCPA participation has also been shown to be very robust to model specification and choice of estimation method. With respect to the spatial dependence that prevailed in two of the spatial models, this effect is either due to true interdependence between the units or caused by unobserved heterogeneity (Franzese & Hays 2007). This distinction amounts to the essence of Galton’s Problem (Franzese & Hays 2007; Jahn 2006; Braun & Gilardi 2006; Pluemper & Neumayer 2010), namely to the difference between true interdependence in decision-making as opposed to spatial clustering or unobserved heterogeneity. From this analysis, a first indication was attained that interdependence has to be taken further into account in future research on MCPA participation. To adequately model interdependence in climate change decision-making, research at the city level as well as research including the temporal dimension is warranted. This paper is the first contribution looking at the determinants of participation in the Mayors’ Climate Protection Agreement throughout the 48 states. Evidence from the large-N analysis conducted in this paper represents an important step forward in understanding the motivations behind voluntary climate change actions. Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 81 3.6 Appendix Table 3.13: Summary statistics Variable MCPA % MCPA Count MCPA % Dem Vote p.c. income % 4yrs College Uni/Coll Unis scaled by cities Lib arts scaled by cities No. Lib Arts Uni/Coll Population Pop Growth (00-05) Loc/State Gov Empl Unemployment Rate Industry dependent Median Age p.c. tonnes carbon Pop Loss 1980-2000 % Mining Manufacturing Empl EPA non-attainment Property Damage Climate Region Fatalities Coastal County %Dem x Income %Unemp x %Dem Mean 0.3 18.2 0.6 42 30.4 20.9 0.6 0.7 0.6 1.1 22.3 4.6 14.7 5.2 0.3 36.4 7.3 0.1 0.7 11.5 0.4 69.4 7.5 0.7 0.2 1301.8 223.6 Std. Dev. 0.5 33.7 1.6 12.2 7.2 8.7 0.5 1.8 1.1 2 48.1 7.2 30.6 1.6 0.5 3.9 14.6 0.3 2.1 24.4 0.5 464.6 3.3 2.5 0.4 613 104.3 Min. 0 0 0 7.1 12.2 6.9 0 0 0 0 1.1 -11.3 0.9 2.3 0 22.2 1 0 0 0.1 0 0 1 0 0 117.1 19.2 Max. 1 100 22 89.2 93.4 63.7 1 39 20 29 994.8 46.9 540.5 16 1 52.9 258.1 1 26.5 504.5 1 6136.7 14 39 1 7664.4 956.8 N 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1086 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1080 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 1109 82 Table 3.14: Pattern of signature of MCPA in all states MCPA 1 0 Total State name No. % No. % No. % Alabama 6 1.0 46 2.2 52 1.9 7 1.1 26 1.3 33 1.2 Arizona 3 0.5 29 1.4 32 1.2 Arkansas 112 17.7 239 11.6 351 13.0 California 4 0.6 30 1.4 34 1.3 Colorado 11 1.7 14 0.7 25 0.9 Connecticut 1 0.2 2 0.1 3 0.1 Delaware 1 0.2 0 0.0 1 0.0 District of Columbia 70 11.1 78 3.8 148 5.5 Florida 8 1.3 53 2.6 61 2.3 Georgia 2 0.3 14 0.7 16 0.6 Idaho 34 5.4 168 8.1 202 7.5 Illinois 11 1.7 59 2.9 70 2.6 Indiana 12 1.9 22 1.1 34 1.3 Iowa 5 0.8 28 1.4 33 1.2 Kansas 5 0.8 28 1.4 33 1.2 Kentucky 3 0.5 31 1.5 34 1.3 Louisiana 6 1.0 4 0.2 10 0.4 Maine 8 1.3 14 0.7 22 0.8 Maryland 25 4.0 24 1.2 49 1.8 Massachusetts 20 3.2 72 3.5 92 3.4 Michigan 25 4.0 58 2.8 83 3.1 Minnesota 2 0.3 35 1.7 37 1.4 Mississippi 14 2.2 50 2.4 64 2.4 Missouri 4 0.6 3 0.1 7 0.3 Montana 3 0.5 13 0.6 16 0.6 Nebraska 4 0.6 4 0.2 8 0.3 Nevada 7 1.1 6 0.3 13 0.5 New Hampshire 41 6.5 84 4.1 125 4.6 New Jersey 4 0.6 14 0.7 18 0.7 New Mexico 25 4.0 65 3.1 90 3.3 New York 19 3.0 44 2.1 63 2.3 North Carolina 2 0.3 7 0.3 9 0.3 North Dakota 20 3.2 146 7.1 166 6.1 Ohio 5 0.8 35 1.7 40 1.5 Oklahoma 10 1.6 31 1.5 41 1.5 Oregon 8 1.3 63 3.0 71 2.6 Pennsylvania 3 0.5 5 0.2 8 0.3 Rhode Island 5 0.8 28 1.4 33 1.2 South Carolina 1 0.2 8 0.4 9 0.3 South Dakota 4 0.6 44 2.1 48 1.8 Tennessee 21 3.3 167 8.1 188 7.0 Texas 1 0.2 34 1.6 35 1.3 Utah 1 0.2 2 0.1 3 0.1 Vermont 9 1.4 28 1.4 37 1.4 Virginia 24 3.8 34 1.6 58 2.1 Washington 1 0.2 13 0.6 14 0.5 West Virginia 14 2.2 59 2.9 73 2.7 Wisconsin 0 0.0 8 0.4 8 0.3 Wyoming Total 631 100.0 2,069 100.0 2,700 100.0 Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 83 Text (a) MCPA participation rates in counties, calculation based on quartiles, darker shade indicates more participation Text (b) fatalities of natural hazards; calculation based on quartiles; darker shade indicates higher number of fatalities Figure 3.9: Comparison of the pattern of % MCPA and fatalities from natural hazards in the 1109 counties 84 Text (a) %Democratic vote in counties; brown 3 50%; darker brown 3 70% Text (b) unemployment rate in counties; calculation based on quartiles; darker shade indicates higher unemployment Figure 3.10: Comparison of the pattern of % Democrats and unemployment rate in the 1109 counties Nature, Nurture or Neighbors? 85 HH HH HH HH HH HL HHHHHH HH HH HL HL HL HHHH HLHL HL HH HH HHHH HL HH HHHH HH HH HHHH HH HHHHHH HH LH HH HHHH HL HL Text HH HL HL HL HH HHHH HHHH HH (a) Local Moran’s I for participation rates in MCPA LH LH HL LH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HHHH HH HHHH HL HL Text HH HH HH LH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH HH (b) Local Moran’s I for fatalities of natural hazards Figure 3.11: Analysis of spatial clusters with Local Moran’s I statistic (W: county contiguity) in the 1109 counties 86 LH HL LH HH LH LH LL LL LH LL LL HH HH LL LH LL LH LH HH HH HHHH HHHL HH HL LL HH HH HH HH LH LH LH LL LL LLLL LLLL LLLL HL LL LLLL HHHH LH HHHH LL LH LH HH HH HH HH LH LH LH HH HH HHHH LLLL LHLH LH HH LLLL HL LL Text LH LL LL LL LL LL LL LL LL LL LL HH HH LH HH LL HL LL LL LLHH LL LH HH LH LL LH HL LL LH HHHH (a) Local Moran’s I for %Democratic vote in counties HH HH HH HH HH HH LL LH HHHH HH LH LH LH HH HH HHHH HH LL LL LL HH HHHH HH LH LH LL LH LL LHLH LLLL LH LH HL LL HH LL HH HH LL LL HL LH LL LH LL LL LL LH HLLL LL LLLL HH HH LH LL LL LH HH LH LH HHHH LH HL LL LLLL HL LLLL HH HHHH Text LL HL LL LH LL HH HH HH HH LHHL HH HL HL LL HL HHHH LL HH HH LH LH HH LL LL (b) Local Moran’s I for unemployment rate in counties Figure 3.12: (Cont’d)Analysis of spatial clusters with Local Moran’s I statistic (W: county contiguity) in the 1109 counties 87 4 Voluntary Climate Change Initiatives in the U.S.: Testing Participation in Space and Time Lena Maria Schaffer 4.1 Introduction Global climate change is one of the biggest challenges facing mankind in the 21st century. Prominent attempts to deal with global climate change and to mitigate its consequences have focused on multilateral cooperation and international institutions. The success of these international efforts has been limited. A prime example is the Kyoto protocol. Particularly large emitters of greenhouse gases, such as the United States, which refused to ratify the Kyoto protocol, are generally reluctant to contribute to this global environmental effort. Given that effective cooperation between nation-states in climate politics is very difficult, the question arises whether there are other possibilities for coping with global climate change at lower political levels. In fact, such climate policy efforts already exist. The largest scale effort of this kind is the U.S. Mayors Climate Protection Agreement (MCPA). Its aim is to advance the goals of the Kyoto Protocol on the city level even if the U.S. federal government lags behind. As of November 2010, 1044 cities have signed the agreement, representing a population of 80 million, effectively more than one quarter of the U.S. population.On February 16, 2005, the Kyoto Protocol came into force for the 141 countries that had ratified it. On the same day, the then Seattle Mayor Greg Nickels launched the initiative called the ’U.S. Mayors’ Climate Protection Agreement’ to advance the goals of the Kyoto Protocol through leadership and action by American cities. Joining the initiative constitutes a voluntary act by the local government that signs the agreement. The MCPA stipulates that mayors should ’strive to meet and beat the Kyoto Protocol targets in their own communities’, as well as expects local governments to ’[u]rge their state governments, and the federal government, to enact policies and programs to meet or beat the greenhouse gas emission reduction target’ (Mayors Climate Protection Center 2010). Originally Mayor Nickels planned to mirror the Kyoto Protocol and 88 have at least 141 Mayors throughout the U.S. sign the initiative. By the June 2005 annual conference of the United States Conference of Mayors (USCOM) in Chicago, this goal was already reached. At this meeting, the MCPA was formally endorsed by USCOM. The map in figure 4.1(a) shows the first 141 signatories. Over the past 5 years, this initiative has grown immensely to now incorporate the 1044 participating cities in figure 4.1(b). ! 5 ! 5! ! 5 5! ! 5 5 ! 5 55! ! !! 5 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 5 !! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! . ! 5! 5 ! 5 ! . 5 ! 5 ! ! 5 ! . 5 ! 5! ! 5 ! 5 ! . ! . ! 5 ! 5! 5 . 5! !! 55 ! 5! ! 5! 5! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! . ! . ! . ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! . ! 5 ! 5 ! . ! .! . ! . ! . ! .. ! . ! . ! .! !! . .! . ! . ! . ! . ! . ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 5 ! 5 ! ! 5 Text ! 5 ! 5 ! . .! ! .! .! !! . . . . ! . ! ! . ! . ! 5 ! 5 ! . ! 5 ! 5 ! 5 ! . ! 5 ! 5 ! . ! . ! . ! . ! . ! . .! ! . (a) June 2005 (b) June 2010 (Source: USCOM) Figure 4.1: Cities that have signed the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement Since the subnational formation of climate policy institutions is a new phenomenon, we know very little about the conditions that motivate local governments to join such efforts. Such knowledge is important for the evaluation of whether cooperation at this level can offer a fea- Testing Participation in Space and Time 89 sible substitute or, at least, a useful complement to global efforts. This paper examines the determinants of cities’ willingness to join the MCPA in cities over 10,000 inhabitants in seven Midwestern states. I develop arguments on how various factors influence local government decisions to voluntarily contribute to climate change mitigation efforts by joining the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. These factors include community-specific internal factors and external factors accounting for cities’ interdependence in decision-making. As far as internal factors are concerned, I argue that there are specific determinants leading to a higher demand for voluntary climate change policies within the city, e.g., a higher percentage of voters that support the Democratic Party, which then make governments more likely to participate in voluntary efforts. I further assume that the initiative to join the MCPA can also emanate from the supply side of local government. Here, the existence of a policy entrepreneur and a mayor-council form of government are considered to increase the propensity to participate. Interdependencies between cities are conceptualized as emanating from geographic linkages to other jurisdictions, peer group effects, as well as from participation in social networks. My theoretical framework is complemented by the consideration of certain events that are assumed to be associated with a city’s decision to sign on to the MCPA. To test my claims, I use a unique new data set on monthly signing behavior of 749 Midwestern cities from February 2005 to June 2010. I find that a city’s participation in social networks as well as the MCPA signing behavior of cities within the same population group increases a city’s likelihood of participating. Although city-internal characteristics, such as the % of Democratic votes in the city or human capital endowment, are also significantly related to a higher propensity to sign, their substantive effects are much smaller. As far as pivotal events are concerned, I find that the likelihood of participation significantly increases in the months leading up to a mayoral election in the city. Insights gained from this large-N study are further supported by qualitative evidence from an analysis of questionnaires sent to a subsample of the 749 Midwestern cities. This paper seeks to contribute to the scholarly literature in at least three ways. First, existing research on voluntary climate change initiatives emphasizes city-internal characteristics. This paper considers the behavior of other cities and their effects on the dynamics of MCPA adoption. To this end, I present a coherent framework of municipal voluntary climate change adoption that is based on both internal and external characteristics and that considers the different channels through which cities may be influenced by the choices of others. Hence, the main focus of this paper is on the interdependence in the decision-making between different jurisdictional 90 units vis-a-vis internal factors. For many phenomena within social sciences, it is very difficult to argue that we are dealing with independent observations. Far more often, policy choices by governments depend on previous decisions of other governments. This is mostly referred to as Galton’s Problem 1 (see Jahn 2006; Braun & Gilardi 2006). Second, this study is the first comprehensive large-N inquiry into the determinants of MCPA adoption over time. By including a temporal dimension, I am not only able to test different internal and external influences that are supposed to matter for the participation in voluntary climate change policies, but to also account for the importance of specific events that influence the likelihood of MCPA adoption. Third, this paper complements large-N statistical evidence with qualitative evidence on cities’ motives for joining the MCPA. The paper is structured as follows. I first provide an overview of the existing literature on voluntary climate change initiatives and define my own contribution to this literature in section two. In the theoretical section that follows, I discuss theoretical problems and elaborate on my arguments before introducing the determinants of voluntary climate change initiative adoption and presenting testable hypotheses. In section four, I then introduce my research design and the operationalization of the main variables before presenting the results from my statistical and qualitative analyses, and robustness checks. The paper concludes with a discussion of the main empirical findings and suggests further extensions. 4.2 Background on Voluntary Climate Change Policies in the U.S. This section gives a background on the ever-increasing literature on voluntary climate change policies in the U.S. and carves out the contribution of this paper. Research on subnational climate change policies in the U.S. has so far focused primarily on state level activity. Scholars have examined the determinants, as well as the implications of state policies in a multilevel governance setting (Rabe 2004, 2008; Schreurs & Epstein 2007). Rabe (2008) examines states’ strategic choices in climate change mitigation policies with reference to their mix of emission trends and policy adoption rates. Recognizing the importance of states’ policies as a political feasibility test for subsequent national policies, he concludes with a set of scenarios on how to integrate subnational efforts into a functioning multilevel governance 1 Galton’s Problem arises when the independence of the units of analysis cannot be regarded as given and potential outcomes could be linked to interdependent behavior between these units. Any conclusions drawn from such a setting risks bias. For a historical account of the implications of this problem, see Franzese & Hays (2007) Testing Participation in Space and Time 91 framework. Schreurs & Epstein (2007) further raise questions concerning federalist practices with respect to the future leadership role in climate change policies. More recent publications look at whether and how state and local government initiatives will continue in the wake of potential national action (Engel 2009). She concludes that although it remains to be seen what happens to existing cap and trade regimes, state and local government leadership in climate change policies will likely continue and intensify. While Rabe (2004) has provided a careful categorization of the different approaches of state climate change policy with reference to national policy, Lutsey & Sperling (2008) go one step further and try to quantify the potential impacts of lower level government commitments in the U.S.. They focus on the consequences of decentralized climate change policies on actual GHG emissions, exploring the development of these emissions based on current inventories and chosen policies. They find that if the 17 states that have set an GHG emission-reduction target were to achieve these targets, U.S. GHG emissions would be stabilized at 2010 levels by the year 2020 (Lutsey & Sperling 2008, 683). The question of whether bottom-up activity can substitute for absent national level climate policy is at the core of many studies. Selin & VanDeveer (2007, 22) arrive at differing conclusions concerning the significance of emission reductions emanating from these subnational policies. They stress the importance of such programs as they allow policy-makers to ’[. . . ] see which of the many available policy options are gaining support in the public and private spheres’ and thereby are most likely to influence future federal policy development. Turning now to the impact of cities, Kousky & Schneider (2003) compare the policies of twelve Cities for Climate Protection (CCP) members and the CO2 reduction achieved from their implemented policies. Their results indicate that most reduction targets are fairly modest, and they express concern that after picking the proverbial ’low hanging fruit’, free-riding problems might re-emerge and bring mitigation efforts to a halt. Also looking into the feasibility of climate action at the city level, Tang et al. (2010) analyze 40 local climate action plans to explore how well they grasp the concepts of climate change and prepare for climate change mitigation and adaptation. In their view, climate action plans indicate a serious consideration and commitment for climate change mitigation. They find that although these plans reflect a high level of environmental awareness, they have only limited effects on emissions. More recently, Krause (2011b) collected information on the GHG reduction activities in 53 cities in Indiana to gauge whether implementation of such policies is higher in communities that had committed 92 themselves to an agreement like the MCPA. One of the results from her study is that while policies that have important co-benefits (e.g., curbside recycling) are very commonplace, more formal and explicit climate policies are lacking. Furthermore, when considering a specific climate protection focus (N=17), she does not find a significant difference between MCPA members and non-members, which leads her to the conclusion that participation is only symbolic. Although presenting evidence from one U.S. state to view MCPA participation as symbolic is a huge improvement for research on implementation, we still do not know why some communities chose to proclaim their efforts by joining a national framework of mayors, while others obviously chose not to. This paper seeks to take a step forward in explicitly considering what determines communities’ adoption of national efforts such as the MCPA. Among the pioneering research concentrating on cities as units of analysis and their adoption of voluntary climate change efforts, is the contribution by Betsill (2001). She studies the opportunities and obstacles with respect to the Cities for Climate Protection (CCP) program in the United States. This program began in 1991 and was the first of its kind to introduce the topic of climate change at the city level (Betsill & Bulkeley 2006; Betsill 2001). Most of the scholarly work on local climate change action has thus far centered on the CCP initiative (Betsill 2001; Betsill & Bulkeley 2004; Brody et al. 2008; Kousky & Schneider 2003; Lee 2009a; Lindseth 2004; Vasi 2006; Zahran, Grover, Brody & Vedlitz 2008).2 Based on interviews with policy-makers and qualitative case study evidence, Betsill (2001) argues that in order for cities to successfully participate in this program, the issue of global climate change is best framed as a local issue. Along the same lines, Bulkeley and Betsill (2002: 184-85) emphasize the value of networks and local capacity for action in addressing climate change, and highlight the importance of ’the way climate protection is framed, particularly in relation to economic incentives’. Lindseth (2004) takes a more critical view of this result and objects to the pragmatic CCP policy of framing climate change policies as being about solving problems locally and enjoying local benefits. In his view, local actors should be more aware of the various dimensions of climate change. Another important part of the literature seeks to understand the motivations for the public’s as well as of decision-makers’ preferences for local climate change initiatives. Kousky & Schneider (2003) use interview evidence from officials in 23 CCP municipalities across the U.S. to see what makes communities voluntarily implement these efforts. They find that implementation is generally not driven by demand from the population, but is rather a top-down issue initiated by 2 An interesting study that does not deal with a specific climate change initiative, but also with local environmental institutions, is the one by Meyer & Konisky (2007) on Massachussetts Wetlands Protection Testing Participation in Space and Time 93 policy-makers. Also, the cost savings and local co-benefits from climate change policy matter for participation in the CCP. By modeling the public good provision in the realm of climate change policies across two levels – national and local – Urpelainen (2009) finds that local policymakers have an informational advantage concerning local political benefits. These unobservable benefits lead politicians to overcome the collective action problem and pursue local climate policy. As an example of potential political benefits for the decision-maker, Urpelainen (2009, 87) refers to energy efficiency requirements that would favor producers using advanced technologies. In a similar vein, Engel & Orbach (2008) do not specifically concentrate on one initiative, but give a comprehensive overview of U.S. state and local level initiatives. To explain participation in the initiatives, they point to and discuss potential supply and demand side explanations. On the demand side, they see the potential for participation as a symbolic statement against the inactivity of the U.S. government as one motivation, but other sources for participation may be altruism (’warm glow’), as well as the localization of global problems. On the supply side, they (similar to Rabe (2004); Krause (2011b)) stress the role of political, as well as administrative entrepreneurship in promoting such initiatives. Furthermore, they also discuss the possibility that communities might present certain municipal policies as having a climate change component due to the popularity of actions on climate change. This is contrary to what earlier studies (Betsill 2001; Lindseth 2004) have found in the CCP context, and I will further elaborate on this issue below. Despite the plethora of different possible reasons for climate policy action, Engel & Orbach (2008) do not empirically test their claims. While the research mentioned so far relies primarily on case study evidence or interviews with officials, systematic quantitative large-N analyses of the subject are still rare and predominantly focus on the CCP program (Vasi 2006; Brody et al. 2008; Zahran, Grover, Brody & Vedlitz 2008; Lee 2009a). Drawing on research on organizational innovations, Vasi (2006) combines qualitative and quantitative methods to examine how organizational environments and framing processes jointly influence the diffusion of organizational innovations in the context of local climate change policies within the CCP program. Employing event history analysis, his two key findings are that adoption of the CCP program is determined by spatial or cultural proximity to earlier adopters, and that organizational embeddedness in transnational frameworks also fosters participation. Lee (2009a) uses a multilevel setting to analyze which cities participate internationally in the CCP and other networks such as C40. Controlling for city and country-level variables, he finds that cities’ positions in the global economy, and transportation hub characteristics significantly 94 influence participation in these networks. In a similar paper, Zahran, Grover, Brody & Vedlitz (2008) study metropolitan areas in the U.S. and explain their participation with respect to physical location, natural capital, production and transportation modalities, and socioeconomic characteristics. They find that those metropolitan areas that contribute most to the problem in terms of CO2 emissions are least likely to engage in the CCP, while those with high levels of civic capacity are more likely to engage. An interesting finding from their study is that natural climate change risk does not seem to matter for metropolitan engagement in the CCP. However, in a similar study, Brody et al. (2008) use county-level participation in the CCP and find that natural risk plays a large role in explaining participation in the CCP. While Brody et al. (2008)’s study is one of the first large-N studies examining participation in the CCP, they approach the issue from an urban planning background and pay only very scant attention to political and economic determinants of climate policy adoption. As regards more recent climate change initiatives, such as the mayors climate protection agreement, few authors have conducted in-depth examinations. Clearly one of the first scholarly writings on this newer phenomenon is Warden (2007)’s dissertation on the initial years of the MCPA and the importance of networks for the proliferation of local climate policies. Through document analysis and interviews with 17 officials (mayors, city officials, representatives from relevant organizations), she was able to find ten themes of municipal motivation. While some officials claimed that there was a moral urgency to act on the issue due to national inaction, others also hinted to economic incentives due to energy efficiency policies. Interestingly, she also finds evidence for competition between neighboring cities to be ’green’, and also stresses the importance of the mayor’s characteristics and his leadership role on the issue. Concerning the MCPA movement as a whole, there is another recent article by Krause (2011a), where she looks at the adoption of the MCPA in a multilevel setting, taking states’ climate policies into account. She looks at 1026 cities over 25.000 inhabitants and finds that state-level characteristics cannot explain the signing of the MCPA by a city. Instead, internal characteristics, such as income, education, votes for the democrats, and if there are participating neighbors are important determinants for a city to sign. This is the first study to hint at the existence of possible interdependence or diffusion effects in MCPA participation. Furthermore, the substantive result that most of the variation in cities’ participatory behavior can be attributed to city- or countyinternal variables is a great step towards a better understanding of cities’ participation patterns. However, there are some shortcomings. First, one shortcoming that Krause (2011a, 13) also Testing Participation in Space and Time 95 addresses is that the model tested in this study is entirely cross-sectional, while the process being studied is dynamic. Berry & Berry (1999) recommend the use of panel data or event history analysis as the most appropriate methodology when trying to model policy adoption. A second and related point, concerns the time period under study, which is the three years up to May 2008. The choice of May 2008 seems to be due to practical reasons, however the initiative grew substantially afterwards. A less arbitrary time point to use for such a cross-section might have been the election of President Barack Obama in November 2008, since it ended the time of certainty of no national climate change action (Schaffer 2010). In conclusion, despite notable systematic studies on the subject (Brody et al. 2008; Vasi 2006; Krause 2011a; Zahran, Grover, Brody & Vedlitz 2008), there are still large gaps in the literature. This paper seeks to contribute to the scholarly literature in at least three ways. First, existing research on voluntary climate change initiative emphasizes city-internal characteristics. This paper considers the behavior of other cities and their effects on the dynamics of MCPA adoption. To this end, I present a coherent framework of municipal voluntary climate change adoption based on city internal and external characteristics, considering the different channels through which cities may be influenced by the choices of others. Second, using the first multi-state panel design, this paper can also control for temporal variation in adoption and the importance of specific events on the likelihood of adoption. Third, this paper complements large-N statistical evidence with qualitative evidence on cities’ motives for joining the MCPA gained from questionnaires. In the following section, I will first develop my theoretical argument, starting with a discussion of the theoretical problem. In a second part, the main hypotheses will be introduced. 4.3 Theoretical Framework 4.3.1 Puzzle and Theoretical Argument Why should policymakers in local communities tackle problems related to climate change and what is the substantive puzzle underlying this paper? First and foremost, environmental quality, with respect to climate change, is a global public good (Hardin 1968). The production of GHG emissions, irrespective of the location, increases the risk of adverse climatic changes, whereas a reduction of GHG emissions contributes to the mitigation of such risks (Baettig & Bernauer 2009). The standard prescription for mitigating GHG emissions, and thus combating global warming, is a concerted global effort combined with implementation of internationally agreed 96 measures at the level of the nation-state. In a more general way, the scholarly literature on environmental regulation stipulates that when environmental effects are felt in the vicinity of the source, local governments should be best positioned to control the problem. However, ’when effects are not localized, as with carbon dioxide and other precursors of climate change, centralized control may be more appropriate’ (Kolstad 1996, 349). According to this argument, GHG emissions should be tackled at the federal level. Therefore within the non-binding national framework present within the United States up until November 2010, cities should have faced a strong incentive to free-ride on the mitigation efforts of others. This describes a standard collective action problem (Olson 1965). Second, concerning the interjurisdictional competition within the United States, cities act as ’growth machines’ (Molotch 1976) in order to sustain themselves. Local governments are in competition with each other for resources and should, therefore, not voluntary burden themselves with potentially costly tasks. In line with this notion and according to Oates (2002, 7), local government cannot be ’entrusted with the responsibility for setting environmental standards, because it will sacrifice the environment on the altar of economic development’. We can therefore conclude that neither is local government the ideal level of government for tackling climate change mitigation policies, nor do local governments have strong incentives to withstand free-riding on the efforts of others to provide the public good. This is what conventional theory of public good provision would predict when climate change is viewed as a global public good. However, empirical observations show that actually, a lot of local governments are taking part in voluntary initiatives and embrace local climate change policies. So, to what extend can climate change policies be an issue at the local level? What are the reasons why cities engage in climate change initiatives such as the MCPA? Finally, why is participation in the MCPA commonplace despite the convincing theoretical arguments that predict the absence of local action on climate change issues? First, regarding the nexus between climate change and cities, cities are responsible for the bulk of worldwide GHG emissions. According to Kamal-Chaoui & Robert (2009), cities consume about 60-80% of energy production worldwide and contribute a similarly large share to global CO2 emissions. Second, not only do cities contribute to the problem, they also have key competencies to act on climate change. Some of the core competencies of local government include issues of land-use planning, energy supply, transportation, and waste management. All of these are essential domains of environmentally sustainable policies and central to any climate change Testing Participation in Space and Time 97 mitigation strategy. In this context, Glaeser & Kahn (2010) stress the impact of cities’ land-use regulations on CO2 emissions. Traffic management can also be important as arrangements with less congestion (e.g., introducing congestion charges) or reduced start and stop times at intersections (e.g., with roundabouts (Rouphail et al. 2006)) lead to lower CO2 emissions. Therefore, it can be established that cities do have the possibility to actually enact relevant mitigation policies at the local level. Furthermore, recent research on the local effects of CO2 in cities, Jacobson (2010) looks at so called domes of high CO2 levels that build over U.S. cities. He finds that although CO2 is usually said to have the same effect on global temperatures no matter where it was emitted, high levels might worsen the effects of localized air pollutants like ozone and particulates (Jacobson 2010). This would indicate that strategies to curb GHGs might also lead to better air quality with respect to localized pollutants. There are many additional links between climate change policy and sustainable development that might drive the development of innovative policies at the local level. Communities may well conceptualize climate change as having a public health dimension. The possibilities for cities to implement climate policies and enjoy co-benefits with regards to energy efficiency, improved public health, and general quality of life are manifold. In fact, that is what Betsill (2001)’s research on the Cities for Climate Protection (CCP) campaign suggests, namely that cities should frame climate change as a local issue, utilizing links between climate change policy and issues already on the local agenda. From the above, it can be established that on the one hand, cities potentially incur costs from enacting climate change policies due to their competitive position vis-a-vis other communities that free-ride on their efforts. On the other hand, it can be shown that climate change policies are complementary to many efforts on the agenda of local governments, and that possible cobenefits from engaging in those policies exist. Notwithstanding all the possibilities presented so far, and given that it can make sense for local governments to pursue climate change policies, especially when framing them as a local issue of concern (Betsill 2001), the question remains as to why local government would want to frame policies as being climate change policies in the first place? As mentioned in section 4.2 above, there is no consensus in the scholarly literature on one allencompassing reason for why local communities act on climate change. A plethora of different factors are assumed to be at play, and many of them have more to do with the specific situation in the U.S. during the time the MCPA began to evolve than providing a universal explanation of communities’ climate change mitigating behavior. Generally, I assume that two different 98 sources of motivation stand out, substantive environmental concerns, and symbolic participation. Whereas some cities and mayors are genuinely concerned about the environment, symbolic participants only join because of the political statement their participation makes, and the political benefit it brings. Due to the agreement’s flexibility in timing and scope with respect to the implementation of local climate change policies, one of the reasons for joining could be a symbolic statement (Engel & Orbach 2008) against the current national policies, be it in the realm of climate change policies or elsewhere. Environmental concern and symbolic participation might of course also overlap. Furthermore, environmental concern could be motivating the community to pressure their local government to sign, while the government’s reason could be symbolic participation alone. Separating these different motivations is difficult, and it has to be assumed that, more often than not, both motivations are present simultaneously. Therefore and unless otherwise specified, I consider them both to be at work throughout the following theoretical discussion. Of course, empirically separating one from the other is just as daunting a task. Disentangling these different motivations necessitates two things: first, qualitative evidence from decision-makers as well as communities, and second, further research into the extent of actual implementation of climate change policies at the community level (Krause 2011b; Tang et al. 2010). In section 4.5.2, I will address the first of these two points, presenting qualitative evidence from questionnaires that were sent to mayors throughout the U.S. My theoretical argument derives from the above observations and concentrates on the local government as the decision-making body that either choses to join an initiative or not. I assume that the existence of political benefits from joining voluntary climate change initiatives is the driving factor. Whether the political benefits are gained by sincerely acting on the climate change cause or merely by making a symbolic statement through participation in climate change initiatives is considered to be largely unobservable (not only in the context of a large-N analysis). However and independent of the ’channel of motivation’, the extent to which political benefits can be reaped by the local decision-maker is theorized to depend on conditions within the city, external factors, as well as on initiative- and time-specific factors. The local and city-specific factors that matter for the signing the MCPA are assumed to emanate either from the demand side (the community) or the supply side (the city government). For both of them I discuss factors that make participation more likely, as well as factors that are supposed to make signing the MCPA less likely. Testing Participation in Space and Time 99 Given my overarching research framework that deals with the importance of interdependent choice in joining voluntary climate change initiatives, I then introduce external factors that are assumed to facilitate the diffusion of voluntary climate change policies. I argue that there are three main channels that matter for the interdependence of cities: neighbors, peers, and social networks. As already noted above, a unique feature of this paper is that it provides the first examination of MCPA participation in a large-N context and over time. Hence, a more careful investigation into the time period and the events occurring in it is possible. I argue that alongside – and conditional upon – internal and external factors, there are pivotal events, such as the presidential election of Barack Obama, that had an impact on cities’ signatory behavior. In the subsequent section, I introduce the three groups of determinants for the adoption of voluntary climate change initiatives and develop hypotheses about their effect on the main outcome of interest – participation of cities in voluntary climate change initiatives. 4.3.2 Determinants of Adoption of Voluntary Climate Change Initiatives The previous section introduced the theoretical puzzle that follows from the nature of the climate change issue and the level of government in a federal system. I have then considered alternative explanations as to why cities or local governments might be interested in pursuing climate change policies. This section presents the conditions that are supposed to have lead to the patterns of local climate change policy adoption that we currently observe. It also asks what the factors leading to participation in climate change initiatives are.3 I argue that to explain the temporal and spatial patterns in participation in voluntary climate change agreements three factors are decisive: city-internal characteristics, external factors, and time and initiative-specific events. As this is the first comprehensive study of cities’ participation in the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement over time, I introduce each of these determinants in more detail below and provide testable hypotheses for all of these decisive factors. However, I am especially interested in how well external factors can explain participation in voluntary climate change initiatives and whether there is evidence for interdependent decision-making. 3 Elsewhere I have looked at the influence of vulnerability and natural risk on the participation in voluntary initiatives (Schaffer 2010) and have found that especially coastal counties and to a lesser extend also fatalities from natural hazards related to extreme weather conditions tend to increase participation. However, socioeconomic and political factors were found to be better predictors of MCPA participation levels. Therefore, I concentrate on these influences to explain the adoption and timing of cities’ climate change policies. 100 Internal determinants of policy adoption Turning to the internal determinants of policy adoption, I start with a discusion of the demand for local climate change policies. I expect that policy-makers can evaluate whether there is support for climate change policies or whether their constituencies oppose such policies (Oates & Schwab 1988).4 I then consider factors concerning the supply side, i.e. characteristics of the local government that are assumed to either facilitate or hinder MCPA participation. As in any market-related model, these two are, of course, interrelated. Demand side explanations Endowment with resources or wealth is a factor that matters in policy-making (Gray 1973). One line of argument points to a greater capacity to compensate losers from potential regulation. A second line of argument however, stresses the relationship between levels of income and the demand for environmental quality. Due to its high income elasticity, economists have conceptualized environmental quality as a luxury good (Baumol & Oates 1988). As far as environmental policies are concerned, research has shown that people with higher incomes increasingly care about quality of life issues (Kahn 2006). As mentioned above, climate change policies complement other local policies, such as public health or transportation (e.g., the lowering of congestion or the provision of more public transport), thus enhancing the quality of life (Betsill 2001). With increasing wealth, I therefore expect additional demand for environmental quality in general (Beron et al. 2003; Cornes & Sandler 1996) and climate change policies in particular. Consequently, demand for climate change policies should be higher in localities with a higher median income. Correspondingly, bad economic conditions in a city are expected to lower demand for more climate friendly policies. Although Engel & Orbach (2008, 132) argue that ’labour unions often support renewable energy projects because, in contrast to imported oil, they generate jobs’, cities with high economic distress are assumed to prioritize economic development over becoming active on climate change. As argued already in chapter 3, education is a major factor explaining individual level environmental attitudes. Theodori & Luloff (2002) find that better educated individuals are more likely to contribute money or time to an environmental group, to read environmental magazines, or to vote for or against a political candidate because of his or her position on the environment. Generally, better educated people tend to be more informed about the consequences of human 4 This is similar to Oates & Schwab (1988)’s model where regulators set environmental standards at the level which maximizes the utility of the median voter in the constituency. Testing Participation in Space and Time 101 activity on the earth’s climate (Betsill 2001). This effect may be due to correlates, such as a higher income or a more liberal ideology. However, I posit that the effect of education is separate from income and can be conceptualized as a sort of ’learning to embrace climate change’ effect, which is similar to the one identified by Hainmueller & Hiscox (2006). Following this logic, higher levels of education bring about exposure to information about climate change and lead to an ’awareness of consequence’ (O’Connor et al. 2002). Therefore, I expect that demand for local climate change policies, and therefore the likelihood of MCPA adoption increases with the percentage of college-educated people in a city. Furthermore, the ideological dispositions of the population are typically taken into account for any policy decision. Generally, the environmental movement has often been associated with policy liberalism and therefore, ’liberals are often seen as more likely to support government solutions to environmental problems than conservatives, who are more likely to rely on private sector or market-based solutions’ according to Daley & Garand (2005, 619). During the past decade, the Democrats and their political leaders in the U.S. have been more supportive of efforts to curb greenhouse gases than the Republicans (O’Connor et al. 2002). I thus expect a higher demand for climate change policies in cities with a higher proportion of Democratic voters. In sum, I assume that mayors who want to be re-elected behave like any other office-seeking politician. Hence, if voters within the local jurisdiction demand action on climate change, local governments will be more likely to adopt more stringent environmental politics (Oates & Schwab 1988). I further expect that local decision-makers know the preference of their constituents (Oates 1998; Urpelainen 2009). More public demand for climate change policies should therefore translate into potential political benefits for the policy makers that are associated with policy adoption, which in turn should make adoption more likely. Hypothesis 1a: The propensity of a city to adopt voluntary climate change policies increases with higher demand for climate change policies Supply side explanations Supply side explanations that matter for the adoption of local climate change policies concern the local government and more specifically, the mayor or the city council as policy-makers. As mentioned in the section on demand side explanations, local policy-makers are assumed to react to the demand for climate change policies in their constituencies and draft policies accordingly. To be able to respond to the demands of the population, administrative 102 capacity is an important factor. There is also the possibility that the local government acts according to its own agenda i.e., getting involved in local climate change policies as a policy entrepreneur even in the absence of a manifest demand by the population (Engel & Orbach 2008; Engel 2009). Furthermore, political benefits from voluntary climate change policy adoption are not uniformly distributed. Depending on the form of government, political benefits from participation may vary. In the following paragraphs, I discuss how the supply of local climate change policies is influenced by the form of government, administrative capacity, and the local government’s own environmental agenda. Each of these factors either acts as a facilitator to voluntary action or as an institutional barrier that make MCPA adoption less likely. Form of local government: One feature of the executive branch of city governments that is frequently analyzed and debated is the difference between a ’reform’ council-manager or a mayor-council system (Davis & Hayes 1993; Feiock et al. 2003; Lubell et al. 2009). The introduction of the council-manager abolished the position of the mayor as the chief executive. Instead, the elected council hires a professional city manager for daily administrative decisions in the council-manager system (Lubell et al. 2009). Mayors, in this arrangement, have largely representative functions and less political and administrative power. Therefore, mayors in towns with the council-manager arrangements are referred to as ’weak mayors’. In contrast, ’strong mayors’, who are directly elected, have more political and administrative power, but face elections. Therefore, they also have to be more responsive to their electorate. Generally, Kwon et al. (2009) argue that the mayor-council form creates a political incentive for officials to adopt visible policies, which they can claim credit for. In the case of voluntary climate change policies, and especially in the context of the Mayors Climate Protection agreement, I assume that due to gains in visibility and popularity, strong mayors are more likely to participate in the agreement. Hypothesis 1b: The propensity to sign the MCPA is higher for a city with a mayorcouncil as compared to one with a council-manager form of government. Administrative capacity: City-level research has shown that larger cities with great administrative capacity are among the first to develop an interest in climate change solutions (Kern & Gotelind 2009). With respect to the MCPA, the original proposal that initiated the agreement was drafted by Seattle’s Office of Sustainability and Environment (Warden 2007). While larger cities have specific personnel that are dedicated to traditional environmental protection issues, Testing Participation in Space and Time 103 such as sustainability and air pollution, smaller cities may not have such specialized administrative capacity. I expect that cities with higher administrative capacity are more likely to be informed about climate change and its possible city-specific impacts. Therefore, the likelihood of joining the MCPA should increase with the level of administrative capacity in the city. Hypothesis 1c: The propensity of cities with high administrative capacity increases the likelihood of voluntary climate change adoption. Policy entrepreneur : According to Mintrom (1997, 739), policy entrepreneurs are political actors that promote specific policy ideas, identify problems, network in policy circles, and build coalitions to implement such policies. The importance of policy entrepreneurs for the promotion and implementation of voluntary climate change initiatives is one of the most consistent findings in the relatively new literature on these initiatives (Betsill 2001; Krause 2011a; Rabe 2004, 2008; Vasi 2006). As the word ’policy’ entrepreneur already suggests, it is assumed that the mayor as the decision-maker receives political benefits from the pursuit of his own agenda. For example, if the mayor has previously been involved in the promotion of environmental policies at the city level, I expect him to also act as a policy entrepreneur in the realm of voluntary climate change policies. Cities that have been active promoters of local environmental policies are considered to have a higher propensity to engage in voluntary climate change policies. Hypothesis 1d: The existence of a policy entrepreneur in the city increases the likelihood of signing the MCPA. External determinants of voluntary action The theoretical argument above posits that city-specific factors alone do not suffice to explain adoption decisions in voluntary climate change policies. Research on voluntary climate change initiatives has so far either neglected the influence of external factors altogether or has tested them only as controls (Krause 2011a).5 In this paper, I therefore want to explicitly account for unit-external factors that may lead to interdependent policy choices. In essence, I argue that cities, when deciding whether to sign up to the MCPA, consider what other cities have done on the issue. Such interdependencies between cities would therefore manifest themselves in reactions of local governments in view of their peers’ actions (Brueckner 2003). 5 A notable exception is Vasi (2006). In his event history analysis on the adoption of the CCP program, he controls for the effects of geographical neighbors’ adoption of the CCP. 104 Interdependent choice is the basis of the field of policy diffusion studies, where diffusion can be dened as ’a process where choices are interdependent, that is, where the choice of a government inßuences the choices made by others and, conversely, the choice of a government is inßuenced by the choices made by others’ (Braun & Gilardi 2006, 299). The question of how policies diffuse between American states has a long tradition (Walker 1969; Gray 1973; Berry & Berry 1990; Mooney & Lee 1995) and has more recently received renewed scholarly interest (Berry & Baybeck 2005; Baybeck & Huckfeldt 2002; Boehmke & Witmer 2004; Daley & Garand 2005; Shipan & Volden 2006, 2008; Volden 2006; Nicholson-Crotty 2009). In a large variety of issue areas, most studies have found that diffusion is more likely to happen between neighboring rather than distant states. The positive effect of a neighbor’s adoption on one’s own policy has been found, e.g., for anti-smoking legislation (Shipan & Volden 2006, 2008), Indian gaming (Boehmke & Witmer 2004), lottery adoption (Berry & Berry 1990; Berry & Baybeck 2005), and welfare programs (Volden 2007). The discussion on how policies diffuse has evolved over the years, starting with the assumption of a simple imitation process at work. For example, Gray (1973) states that the ’gain in adoptions is due to nonadopters’ emulation of adopters’ (Gray 1973, 1176). Berry & Baybeck (2005, 505) finds that decision-makers learn from others to the extent that ’when confronted with a problem, decision makers simplify the task of finding a solution by choosing an alternative that has proven successful elsewhere’. Although different conceptualizations of diffusion mechanisms have been proposed by different fields, i.e. sociology (Rogers 1995), economics (Young 2009), and political science (Braun & Gilardi 2006; Simmons et al. 2008), these conceptualizations are very closely related. Furthermore, while Shipan & Volden (2008) as well as Simmons et al. (2008) establish four main mechanisms of diffusion; learning, economic competition, imitation, and coercion, Gilardi (2010, 651) recently stated that ’there is agreement that competition, learning and social emulation are the main drivers of diffusion [. . . ].’ In general, the specific kind of mechanism that applies may differ according to which units (e.g., cities, countries, or people) are examined and what kind of policy diffuses. To give an example, although Shipan & Volden (2008) also use cities as their unit of analysis, I do not necessarily share their argument concerning the theoretical distinction between what is emulation and what is learning. In their conception of learning, the opportunity to learn is the decisive factor, and therefore, a city’s likelihood to adopt increases when the policy in question is adopted broadly throughout the state. In contrast, emulation only happens if comparatively smaller cities Testing Participation in Space and Time 105 imitate their larger (in population size) neighbors. Besides the small conceptual difference in the definition, I would posit that in the case of signing a voluntary climate change agreement, small cities instead look at other small cities for information on signatory behavior. This makes sense in the area of climate change policies because contrary to anti-smoking bans, the problems and solutions differ for different city sizes. This would even hold if one would regard voluntary climate policies as purely symbolic. It is intuitive to assume that policy-makers in smaller cities experience different political benefits than those in larger ones. Whether voluntary climate change policy adoption is caused by learning or emulation is very difficult to identify, since both processes are a consequence of new information on how other cities position themselves on the issue. Furthermore, given that the object that is supposed to be diffused from city to city is in its substantive content a voluntary policy, coercion does not seem to apply. Economic competition in the direct sense is also not entirely plausible given that cities have discretion over the scope of the climate policies they implement. However, following up on Warden (2007)’s work, there may be competition between cities to be the green champion within a region. Concluding the discussion on the differing mechanisms of diffusion, I assume that learning, emulation and – to a certain extent – competition are at work. However, since I am mainly interested in the comparison of unit-internal and unit-external factors for MCPA adoption on the one hand, and testing different conceptions of contingency on the other, disentangling these mechanisms is not the goal of this paper. In the following part of this theoretical section, I claim that there are three main channels through which interdependence in the adoption of voluntary climate change policies operates; closeness to neighbors, similarity of peers, and participation in national networks. Neighbors The positive influence of geographical neighbors on policy adoption is one of the most consistent elements in state-level (e.g. Walker 1969; Berry & Berry 1990) and city-level diffusion studies (Krause 2011a; Vasi 2006; Shipan & Volden 2008). In a similar vein, I argue that local governments are more likely to adopt policies if neighboring cities already have them in place. Serving as their geographic peer group as well as general competitors for resources, cities compare themselves to cities that are geographically close. Neighbors can influence local policy adoption through internal demand, i.e. if the constituency observes climate change policy adoption in surrounding communities, they could also try to lobby for similar action within their 106 community. The rationale lies in the fact that more social interactions happen in geographically close settings. Hypothesis 2a: Participation in nearby cities increases the likelihood that a city will participate. Peers Although it is probably easier for decision-makers to observe whether the cities that are located geographically closer to their own locality adopt climate change policies, these surrounding cities might not be the relevant peer group to refer to. Interdependence is theorized to occur due to perceived similarities between subnational units. I assume that cities know who their peers are as they interact in multiple policy dimensions. In general, cities either learn from the experiences of their peers or compete with them for resources, e.g., federal grant money. Therefore, when considering whether or not to sign up to a voluntary climate change initiative, they refer to their peers’ previous actions on the issue. Rincke (2005) argues that it may be rational for office-seeking governments to choose policies that are similar to those implemented in benchmark jurisdictions. In the context of voluntary climate change initiatives, I argue that such benchmark jurisdictions or relevant peer groups consist of cities with a similar population size and those in the same income bracket. This assumption is fairly straightforward and has something to do with the problems that a city government faces as well as its capacities to solve these problems. In the realm of climate change policies, larger cities might be more concerned about urban sprawl, while smaller communities might concentrate on renewable energy solutions. A richer community might decide to invest more in alternative energy production, whereas less well-endowed communities might want to save energy cost. When it comes to the adoption of voluntary climate change initiatives, I therefore expect that cities take into account what similar cities have already done. Hypothesis 2b: The likelihood that a city signs the MCPA increases with the share of cities of the same population group that have joined the MCPA. Hypothesis 2c: The likelihood that a city signs the MCPA increases with the share of cities of the same income group that have joined the MCPA. Social networks Besides these similarities that are assumed to help diffuse voluntary climate change policy adoption, participation in networks is also thought to increase the likelihood of Testing Participation in Space and Time 107 joining climate change agreements. In theory, social networks connect participants that otherwise may not interact. Therefore, networks emphasize the relationship between participants rather than the participant’s own inherent characteristics (Leitner & Sheppard 2002). However, as Gore (2010, 35) points out, ’the loose, flexible character of some networks makes it difficult to understand how networks and network participants operate and how they influence the actions of other network members’. An essential means for conceptualizing social networks is the presence of an opportunity or platform to exchange knowledge, e.g. about solutions to local problems, and to encourage learning from other participants. Meetings of the U.S. Conference of Mayors (USCOM) provide such opportunities for the cities that attend.6 I expect that local governments that are part of such national networks are generally interested in new ideas and the exchange of information about environmental policies with representatives of similarly interested communities. As actors in environmental policy networks, local governments learn about best practices and communicate successes or failures of climate change policies. Also, several studies have found that advocacy organizations, as integral component of these networks, facilitate policy adoption (Mintrom 1997; Shipan & Volden 2006). Therefore, participation in national networks can be expected to spread knowledge about a new policy to a city, and participation in networks increases the likelihood of the adoption of innovative voluntary climate change initiatives. Hypothesis 2d: A cities’ participation in networks of cities increases the likelihood of MCPA adoption. Events In a temporal setting, there are also time-specific events to be considered that have an impact on the whole system or parts of it. These events are assumed to influence decision-making concerning voluntary climate change initiatives. Generally, one can differentiate between unitinternal events and external shocks. Unit-internal events, such as a mayoral election, only concern the city in which the election is being held, whereas external shocks apply to all units. Mayoral elections In section 4.3.2 mayors were considered to be office-seeking politicians that care about re-election. In order to get re-elected, it was further assumed that mayors implement policies in accordance with the city-specific demand for these policies, supply-side considerations, 6 In social network theory, the whole concept of an affiliation network is based on the idea that actors are linked through event participation (Wasserman & Faust 1994). 108 and external factors influencing the decision to implement. A mayoral election or more precisely the campaign before such an event represents the time when the mayor is especially in need of accumulating political capital by reacting to the needs of the citizens and making public gestures. Therefore, I expect that in cities where mayors have not yet signed the MCPA, the closer a mayoral election is, the more likely it is that a city will join the MCPA. Hypothesis 3a: The propensity of cities to participate in the MCPA is higher in the time period before a mayoral election. Energy efficiency and conservation block grants Section 4.3.1 dealt with the fundamental puzzle underlying the observed high participation in voluntary climate change initiatives, and the theoretically expected collective action problems underlying the provision of a global public good. Large voluntary groups, such as the MCPA, should theoretically only be able to overcome free-riding behavior if they can offer certain excludable benefits through participation (Mueller 2003). Olsen (1971, 51) stipulated that: ’only a separate and selective incentive will stimulate a rational individual in a latent group to act in group-oriented ways’. In the case of the CCP, Brody et al. (2008, 34) establish such separate and selective incentives as software and analytic services, as well as strategic plans that enable cities to inventory and track their GHG emissions. It has been hard to argue that such selective benefits emanate from MCPA participation however, as this agreement is even less exclusive than the CCP, which at least charges membership fees. However, I argue that two related events slightly altered the incentive structure of MCPA participation and thereby changed the existing ’rules of the game’. The two events relate to legislation concerning the so-called energy efficiency and conservation block grants (EECBG). This legislation entered Congress for debate in July 2007 and was signed into law on 19th of December 2007 as part of the Energy Independence and Security Act (EISA). However, it was funded for the first time by the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (Recovery Act) of 2009, where the EECBG Program was appropriated $3.2 billion.7 This program is intended to assist U.S. cities and counties ’to develop, promote, implement, and manage energy efficiency and conservation projects and programs designed to a) reduce fossil fuel emissions; b) Reduce the total energy use of the eligible entities; c) Improve energy efficiency in the transportation, building, and other appropriate sectors; and d) Create and retain jobs’ (U.S. Department of Energy 2010). As the national mayors advocacy group, USCOM had long been lobbying for this 7 Further information can be obtained at http://www1.eere.energy.gov/wip/eecbg.html Testing Participation in Space and Time 109 funding and proclaimed the legislation in 2007 to be huge success (Mayors Climate Protection Center 2007). To obtain funding from the competitive grants within the EECBG, cities have to apply with an energy efficiency-related project proposal.8 Due to the success of the MCPA within the U.S. Conference of Mayors and nationwide, I assume that participation in the MCPA could act as a signal to the government that a city has expertise in the realm of climate change policies in general, and energy efficiency policies in particular. I therefore expect participation to increase with the advent of legislation on the EECBG program. Hypothesis 3b: The likelihood of cities to participate in the MCPA increases with the initiation of the EECBG program. Obama administration As elaborated above in section 4.3.1, I assume that one of the motivations for local politicians to join the MCPA was to deliver a statement against the inaction on the climate change issue by the federal government of President George W. Bush. Before the general election of 2008, such a motion is supposed to have created political benefits in constituencies that lean towards the Democratic Party or such that are discontent with the federal government. With the election of Barack Obama, the candidate of the Democratic Party, I hypothesize that this motivational logic came to a halt, in the sense that the new administration was first granted a period of adjustment to tackle the issue of national climate change policies. This period, however, would have ended by the summer of 2010 with Barack Obama and the Democrats failing to bring meaningful climate change legislation through Congress. However, since this coincides with the time period I am looking at, I expect therefore that the election of Barack Obama lead to a decrease MCPA signature due to the expected national approach on the topic. Hypothesis 3c: The likelihood of cities to participate in the MCPA decreases with the election of Barack Obama as the President of the U.S.. This concludes the theoretical part of this paper. I have argued that voluntary policies on the local level are not only influenced by local factors such as the resource endowments of a community, but are also determined by a city’s interdependence with others. The following paragraphs gives an introduction into the research design used to empirically test the hypotheses. 8 For example, a project involving the ’developing, implementing, and installing on or in any government building of onsite renewable energy technology that generates electricity from renewable resources (solar and wind energy, fuel cells, and biomass)’ (U.S. Department of Energy 2010) 110 4.4 Research Design 4.4.1 Case Selection Selection of States While I would have liked to conduct a study on the temporal and spatial variation in voluntary climate change policy adoption for all cities within the U.S., severe data limitations on city data availability (c.f. section 4.4.4) as well as concerning cities’ MCPA adoption dates (c.f. section 4.4.2) prompt me to test the temporal and spatial dynamics within a significantly smaller subset of states. The states that I chose for this analysis of MCPA adoptions are the seven Midwestern states of Illinois, Indiana, Michigan, Minnesota, Missouri, Ohio, and Wisconsin.9 In order to be able to generalize findings from this study, I wanted to make sure not to exclusively analyze states that are either leaders (e.g., California, Florida, or the Northeastern states of the U.S.) or laggards (e.g., Texas) on the climate change issue. Since the focus of this study is on socio-economic and interdependence factors, climate change vulnerability needs to be kept constant. For instance, this is why I do not include coastal as well as non-coastal states in this study. Compared to other parts of the U.S., the risk from climate change is comparatively low in the Midwest (Karl et al. 2009), except from a potential worsening of already existent extreme weather-related natural hazards. Therefore, I can assume that participation in voluntary climate change agreements are determined by socio-economic and political characteristics of cities or the result of interdependence between neighbors or peers. I now introduce the states in my sample.10 Table 4.1 provides a comparison of the Midwestern states on several relevant indicators. In subtable (a), the average per capita GDP is listed for all seven states and the U.S. alongside the ranking of the state across all 50 states. Whereas Illinois and Minnesota are above average, the remaining five states are below. Considering the ranking of all 50 states, the range exhibited by my seven states – from 10 (MN) to 40 (MO) – seems to be quite large. A similar picture presents itself in subtable (b), which lists the states according to their energy consumption in 2007. Total Energy Consumption is calculated as the sum of all energy sources (fossil and non-fossil) in each state. Here we can see that Indiana as well as Minnesota are among the consumption leaders, whereas Michigan and Illinois consume comparatively less energy. Heavy industry, especially the steel industry, accounts for 9 The only directly contiguous Midwestern state missing is Iowa, which was excluded due to its mainly agricultural economy. 10 Data are from Climate Analysis Indicators Tool (CAIT US) version 4.0. (2010) Testing Participation in Space and Time 111 Indiana’s lead on this indicator. Three states have above U.S. average energy consumption, while four are below. The third indicator in subtable (c), the GHG intensity of the economy, is also very relevant in the context of climate change mitigation policies. GHG intensity of the economy (or GHG per GDP) is a measure of greenhouse gas emissions per unit of economic output and reflects both the state’s overall economic structure as well as the level of energy efficiency (Climate Analysis Indicators Tool (CAIT US) version 4.0. 2010). It therefore proxies the abatement costs incurred by each state of either engaging voluntarily in climate change mitigation or from potential nation-wide regulations in this area. We can see that Indiana, again due to its heavy industrial production, leads the table, whereas Minnesota has the least GHG intensive economy. Once again, the U.S. average lies in between the Midwestern states in my sample. The selected states are not extreme outliers on the economic and abatement cost indicators. Instead, they conveniently cover the range of values that would have been obtained from to a more extensive U.S. study. Table 4.1: Comparison of the 7 Midwestern states and the U.S. average (a) GDP in 2007 State MN IL US WI OH IN MI MO $ p.P. 40990 40287 37931 35161 33703 33263 32936 32359 (b) Energy Consumption in 2007 Rank 10 13 – 27 33 35 38 40 State IN MN OH US MO WI IL MI Tonnes Oil p.P. 11.5 9.1 8.9 8.5 8.4 8.3 8 7.6 Rank 10 20 23 – 27 28 34 38 (c) GHG intensity of Economy 2007 State IN MO OH MI US WI IL MN tCO2e/ Mill $ 1189.3 756.2 723.4 573.9 538.5 537.5 483.8 475.7 Rank 8 18 20 24 – 26 32 33 Table 4.2: Climate change related policies on the state-level (Source: Pew Center on Global Climate Change) Action Emission Portfolio E.E. Res. Green Build. Overall Plan Targets Standards Standards Standards (max. 21) IL IN MI MN MO OH WI x x renewable x x x x x x alternative renewable renewable alternative renewable x x x x x x x x 14 9 11 15 7 11 15 112 With respect to present voluntary climate change programs, table 4.2 shows selected climate action efforts at the state level. Generally, we can see that there exists a lot of variation in the implementation of different Green Buildings and Energy Efficiency instruments and policies across the seven states. The instrument that most of the states have introduced is a climate change action plan. Only Indiana and Ohio have not yet drafted such a plan. Illinois, Minnesota, and Michigan even have state-wide emission targets for GHGs in place. Renewable or alternative Portfolio Standards are implemented in all states except Indiana, whereas the related concept of Energy Efficiency Resource Standards, which encourages the more efficient generation and use of electricity and natural gas, is used in only four states so far. Green building standards for state buildings are in force in Indiana, Michigan, Ohio and Wisconsin. Overall, the table on the seven states’ voluntary engagement in climate change policies clearly shows that there is a lot of variation in the voluntary approaches taken by these states. In addition, it emphasizes once more the adequacy of my sample choice. The chosen contiguous subregion of states is, to some extent, representative of the larger U.S. with respect to economic indicators, abatement costs, as well as engagement in voluntary climate change policy. Selection of Cities With respect to the cities within these seven states, I have decided to use a threshold of 10,000 inhabitants for my main analyses. Although this decision increases the number of observations for which I need data considerably, it is crucial for a proper study of the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. Especially in recent years, small to mid-size cities (10,000-30,000 inhabitants) have increasingly signed on to the MCPA. Explicitly accounting for this development increases the generalizability of my findings. However, to corroborate my findings from this large sample, I also generate a second sample that contains only those cities that have 30,000 or more inhabitants. Applying these two cut-offs to data from the National Atlas of the United States (2004), which is based on population figures from the 2000 Census11 , yielded 749 cities over 10,000 inhabitants and 242 cities over 30,000 inhabitants in the seven states.12 Subfigures 4.2(a) and 4.2(b) show 11 Although population estimates on the city level are calculated for each year (large cities) or each five years (small cities), I have decided to use the 2000 Census data instead of the less precise estimates for the 30,000 and 10,000 citizens thresholds discussed above. 12 These are only cities or towns and no census-designated places (CDP). CDP’s are concentrations of population that the U.S. Census Bureau uses for statistical purposes. They resemble smaller incorporated places in size, but lack a separate municipal government, and therefore these places were not considered in this study on the adoption of voluntary climate change policies by local governments. Testing Participation in Space and Time _ [ 113 _ [ _ [ _ [ North Dakota _ [ _ [ Minnesota _ [ _[ [ _ _[ _ [ _ _[ _[ [ _[ [ _ [ _ _[ [ __ [ _ [ South Dakota _ [ _ [ _ [ Wisconsin _ [ _ [ _ [ _ _[ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ _ _ [ [ __ [ _[ [ _ _ _[ _[ [ _[ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ _ _ [ [ _ [ [ _ _ [ _ [ _[ _ [ [ _[ _ [ _[ _ _ _ [ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ Iowa _[ [ _ Nebraska Michigan _ [ _ [ _[ [ _ _ [ __ _[ _ _[ _[ [ [ _[ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ _ _[ [ _ [ _ _ [ _ [ _ _ [ [[ _ _[ [ [ _ ___ [ _ [ _[ [ _ [[ Pennsylvania _ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ _ _[ [ _ [ _ [ Missouri Ohio _ [ _ [ _[ [ _ _ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ Kansas _ [ _ Indiana [ _ [ Illinois _ [ _ [ _ _[ _[ _[ [ [ _ _ [ _[ [ _ _ [ West Virginia _ [ _ [ _ [ Kentucky Virginia Oklahoma Arkansas Tennessee Text (a) 749 cities >=10.000 inhabitants _ [ North Dakota _ [ Minnesota _ _[ [ [ _ _ [ _ _[ [ Wisconsin South Dakota _ [ Michigan [ _ _ _[ [ _ [ Nebraska _ [ _ [ _ [ _ [ Illinois _ [ [[ _ _ Indiana _ [ Missouri _ [ _ [ _ [[ _ _ [ Pennsylvania Ohio _ [ _ [ Kansas _ [ _ [[ _ _[ _ [ [[ _ _[ [ _ [ _ _ [ _ [ _ _ [ _ [ _[ [ _ _ [ Iowa _ [ _ [ _ [ [ _ _[ [ _ _[ [ _ _ [ West Virginia _ [ Kentucky Oklahoma Virginia Arkansas Tennessee Text North Carolina (b) 242 cities >=30.000 inhabitants Figure 4.2: Sample of cities and signatories in the seven Midwestern states all the states and cities in my two samples. Red stars indicate cities that have signed the MCPA, all other cities are displayed as blue dots. This section has introduced two samples of cities. In the following section, I describe how the data that are used to test the observable implications hypothesized in the theoretical part were collected. 114 4.4.2 Data Collection: Date of MCPA Adoption The U.S. Conference of Mayors Climate Protection Center, which administers the MCPA, only provide information about which cities have joined the agreement on their homepage (www. usmayors.org/climateprotection/), but not when they joined. Therefore, one of the main challenges regarding empirical tests of the adoption of voluntary climate change initiatives was to collect data on the mayor’s signature date. Contacting various officials at the Mayors Climate Protection Center multiple times in 2008 and 2009 with regard to these dates was not successful. Most e-mail queries or messages left on answering machines were either not returned or with substantial delay. The first answer that I received, 6 months after my original request and after two reminders, was as simple as: ’About your request, we do not make the signatory dates public’. Luckily, I finally obtained the information I needed thanks to the cooperation of various sources – to whom I am all extremely grateful. The following paragraphs are dedicated to a discussion of the complicated and time consuming, but ultimately successful data collection process. First, in March 2009, professor Dana Fisher, whom I was visiting in New York helped me establish a contact within USCOM, who had also worked for the climate protection center earlier. I was then able to interview him and to discuss with him the possibility of obtaining records of the dates of each city’s adoption of the MCPA. He pointed out that the organization had not even collected the exact days during the first year, when the MCPA was still administered in Seattle. While they started collecting the dates from 2007 onwards, they were not going to release these dates for fear of exposing some of their members to public criticism over their lack of pro-active climate policy action. What he could provide me with, however, was a list with the first 141 cities that had signed the agreement during the initial 5 months in 2005. This list of 141 cities was presented at the 2005 Annual Meeting of the USCOM in Chicago, when the MCPA was officially endorsed by the conference. This provided me at least with a starting point, as I now knew which cities were the first leader cities that signed until June 2005. Second, Toby Warden, who had written her dissertation at the University of California, Irvine about the early years of the MCPA (Warden 2007), kindly shared information on the earlier years with me. Although she did not have enough information about the starting period at the time she wrote the dissertation, she had downloaded some valuable information on who had signed in 2006 and 2007 from the webpage of the Mayors Climate Protection Center. Third, the people I interviewed at the Sierra Club – one of the oldest environmental groups in the United States – fortunately were very cooperative in sharing the data they had collected on Testing Participation in Space and Time 115 the signature dates of various cities. They have a subgroup called the Cool Cities Program, led by volunteers around the U.S. It is a collaboration between community members, organizations, businesses, and local leaders to implement clean energy solutions. One of the steps in becoming a cool city is that the local campaign sends formal letters to the mayor asking him to sign the MCPA and to record when they had done so. Therefore, they also had collected dates when cities joined. The national Cool Cities campaign director, Stephanie Cutts, whom I interviewed in March 2009, was kind enough to share the data they had collected until August 2008.13 Furthermore, the Cool Cities Program now also features a homepage with all cities and – where the Sierra Club knows it – the date of adoption of the MCPA. Last but not least, over the past years, I have downloaded and saved the data provided on the MCPA homepage concerning the signatories to the agreement for each month from August 2008. So if a new member was added to the MCPA homepage, I could observe it and would know the approximate month of signature. Although there is a slight lag between the signature and the upload on the homepage, these nevertheless provided valuable information (as I point out below) when none of the other sources said anything about the participation date. Since the above sources did not provide all the data points necessary for the analysis of MCPA adoption in the seven Midwestern states, I decided to contact each of the 155 cities that were listed to have signed the MCPA by March 2010. To that end, I wrote an e-mail explicitly asking for the month and the year the city had signed the agreement. Furthermore, I drafted a questionnaire that included additional questions about city characteristics, reasons for participation in the MCPA, as well as some question concerning their assessment of the overall initiative. The sample questionnaire as well as the e-mail are provided in the Appendix. For this data collection, a new e-mail address (climateresearch@ethz.ch) and a U.S. phone number were created to give city officials the possibility to call back or ask questions about the research project. It was stressed in the e-mail that priority of the research was to obtain the date of MCPA adoption. Having collected the phone numbers and e-mail addresses for the 155 cities, the first e-mails were sent out in April 2010.14 After one week, we had feedback from about 15 cities, which send us the relevant information, and about 6 or 7 questionnaires. After two weeks, a reminder e-mail was sent to the cities that had not replied, which led to an increase in replies. By the end of April, we then started calling cities and asking whether they had received the 13 Although Ms. Cutts wanted to sent me an updated version in 2009, there was a change of directors in mid-2009 and unfortunately I could never establish contact to the new director 14 Research assistance by Gwen Tiernan in contacting the cities is greatly acknowledged. 116 information concerning the research project and whether they would be interested in providing this information. Whereas most of the e-mail addresses directly went to the mayor, who might have been too busy to answer, the telephone numbers provided by USCOM usually led to the secretary or city clerk, who then referred us to the right person to contact. We then resend our query, since many had not received our request for information. Therefore, the personal contact over the phone led to an increase in information about the date of adoption and by May 2010, we had information from about 60% of the 155 cities. We then sent out a third and last reminder indicating the end of the research project and asked again for the city’s cooperation concerning MCPA adoption. Finally, we filtered out the ones where we had the exact date of adoption from the Sierra Club data and then predominantly called the ones we did not have this information. In the end we had obtained about 85% of the data through our study or the Sierra Club data. To avoid problems caused by potential uncertainty in the recollection of information, I crosschecked the dates indicated by the mayor or city staff with the information I had from the other sources. In most of the cases those were either identical or deviated by about one month. I attribute this difference to the fact that there is a slight time lag, e.g., between the signature of the mayor and the time the information that the city has signed the MCPA is presented on the organization’s homepage. However, in some rare (< 5) instances the information provided was more than two months apart. I then went to the cities homepage or looked at local newspaper posting to see whether there was an announcement about the MCPA and could resolve all inconsistencies in this way. From the remaining circa 15% that never replied to us or were not listed in the Sierra Club data, the month of adoption could be directly taken from the data downloaded from the Mayors climate protection center homepage each month, for the cities that had signed in 2008 and 2009 (11 cities). A potential problem as mentioned earlier is the slight difference with the information of when the Mayor signed the agreement (as reported by the city) and when it was posted on the homepage. I do not regard this as a huge problem for the reliability of the results, since it only applies to a small portion of the data. However, for 15 out of 155 cities, the date of adoption could not be made available or did not lie within two months. Since I had some information regarding their participation with gaps from three to six months, I decided to impute the missing data. A variable impute was created, which indicates whether the information on the record was imputed or not. An example would be that two of the early adopters (the first 141 cities) did not Testing Participation in Space and Time 117 know exactly when they had reacted to Mayor Nickels call to sign the MCPA. Hence, I entered the date May 2005 as a conservative estimate of their signature, since they had definitely signed by the time the USCOM conference took place in June 2005 and the agreement was endorsed by the conference. Correspondingly, if the city did not have any recollection, but the other sources informed me that the local government had not yet signed in February, for example, but was listed to be a participant in May, the month before, April, was entered as the adoption date. The longest period for which I do not have data is the one between August 2007 and February 2008. For the three cities that fall into this 6 months category, I again used a conservative estimate. January 2008 was put down as their date of adoption. Coinciding with the winter meeting of the USCOM, it is likely that these cities actually signed up at the time of the meeting. However, it is also probable that adding these three more cities biases the network participation variable for this event. I return to these issues in the analysis section. Notwithstanding these potential drawbacks, the data gathered through the direct contact with the cities and backed up by other sources allow for a first comprehensive test of the factors influencing cities to engage in voluntary climate change initiatives. The following section now takes a first look at the data generated by this effort. 4.4.3 Dependent Variable The dependent variable of interest indicates whether a city has signed the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement in a given month or not. As mentioned above, basic information about which cities had signed this agreement within the seven Midwestern states was collected using www.usmayors.org/climateprotection/. Table 4.3 shows the distribution of MCPA participant and non-participant cities as of July 2010. As one can see from table 4.3, over all seven states, 165 out of 749 cities or 22.0% have signed the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. The highest percentage of signatories can be found in Minnesota and the lowest percentage in Ohio. Turning to the temporal data concerning the signature behavior of the 749 cities15 , figure 4.3 shows the cumulative number of signatories throughout the seven states over the time period from February 2005 until July 2010. We can see that the cumulative MCPA adoptions approximate the familiar s-shaped curve from studies on the diffusion of innovations (Walker 1969; Berry & Berry 1990; Rogers 1995). Although steadily increasing in all of the years, one can observe a steeper increase starting by 15 Since the larger 749 cities sample constitutes the main sample, the following paragraphs deal especially with this more inclusive sample. 118 Table 4.3: Signatories (cities > 10k) per state by July 2010 State Illinois Indiana Michigan Minnesota Missouri Ohio Wisconsin Pooled No. of cities 202 69 92 83 64 166 73 749 Signed 45 13 25 28 14 25 15 165 Not signed 157 56 67 55 50 141 58 584 % signed 22.3 18.8 27.2 33.7 21.9 15.1 21.5 22.0 Figure 4.3: Adoption of the Mayors climate protection agreement (2005-2010) June 2006 and increasing especially during the year 2007 until about May 2008. These two years can be thought of as the height of the climate change discourse in the U.S. In 2006, the documentary ’An Inconvenient Truth’ by Al Gore opened at U.S. box offices on May 24, shattering existing visitor box office records for documentaries. Although seemingly belonging in the realm of popular culture, the influence of this movie on people and decision-makers’ perception of climate change and – relevant in this context – the accompanying influence it had on local climate change policies should not be underestimated. Kellstedt et al. (2008) and Boykoff (2007) in the U.S. and the U.K. and, more recently, Sampei & Aoyagi-Usui (2009) in Japan have studied mass media coverage of climate change discourses and its influence on public awareness of the issue, and they find that Al Gore’s movie had a sizeable impact on people’s perception as well as on the media discourse. Furthermore, during these years, popular media Testing Participation in Space and Time 119 outlets, such as Time magazine, featured climate change issues prominently (Kluger 2006; Walsh 2008). Although the release of the Stern Report in September 2006 also had a sizeable impact on the climate change discussion in the U.K., it was not as widely discussed in the U.S. (Boykoff 2007). However, when the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) began to release a series of Fourth Assessment Reports (AR4) from each of their Working Groups (IPCC 2007a) in February 2007, it received huge media coverage in the U.S. These media and scientific events were complemented by news on extreme weather events in the U.S., such as the 2006 drought in the Southwest and the announcement of the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) in January 2007 that 2006 had been the warmest year on record.16 There are certainly other very important events that shaped public opinion, but I consider these to be the main events for the U.S., and a visual inspection of figure 4.3 seems to support the idea that heightened public awareness for climate change during these years considerably spurred participation in the MCPA. However, as argued above, whether this increase was due to a genuine concern on the side of local governments or whether the predominant motive was to gain political benefits by making a local statement against the federal government’s lack of climate policy action is very hard to say. I now divide the adoption propensity over time into further important subgroups. Figure 4.4 shows adoption across the seven Midwestern states in the sample. The y-axis shows the percentage of cities that have signed the MCPA over all cities in that state. We can see that Minnesota has the highest percentage of cities signed from early 2007 onwards and reaches a level of just over 32% by the end of the observation period. Illinois’ trajectory starts out with a comparatively low number of cities that have signed the agreement, but then steadily increases to overtake Ohio in 2007, Wisconsin in 2009, and finally ends up at the similar level as Missouri at around 21%. Whereas Ohio’s percentage of signed cities is just a bit lower until 2007, from 2008 onwards, there is almost no increase, whereas in other states such as Michigan the % of signed states continues to increase. In section 4.3.2, I have claimed that there are two conceptions of peer groups, whose actions on the climate change issue cities closely observe – those of similar income groups and those that are of similar size. Subfigure 4.5(a) depicts the evolution of MCPA signatories for each of the four income quartiles. We can see that the percentage of cities that signed of all cities in the respective income group generally shows a similar pattern over time. Whereas at the beginning, 16 available at http://www.noaanews.noaa.gov/stories2007/s2772.htm 120 Figure 4.4: % of cities who signed the MCPA by state (2005-2010) a relatively higher proportion of cities of the middle-high category signed the MCPA, from 2007 onwards cities from the low-middle income group have the highest %. Overall, one can see that all cities seem to co-evolve in similar patterns. However, a very different pattern of development emerges in subfigure 4.5(b). Here, states are split up into 5 categories, and the evolution of the percentage of cities that signed over the years 2005-2010 is shown. We can see very clearly that each of the population groups follows an individual trajectory and that they only intersect at the very beginning, i.e. in 2005. Also, it can be noted that in the population category of the largest cities, i.e. cities with over 250.000 inhabitants, 12 out of 12 cities or 100% of the cities signed the MCPA by February 2009 – the last one being Detroit. The percentage of cities that have signed increases continuously in all population groups. However, it seems that the proportion of the smallest cities (between 30k and 50k) that have signed does not grow very fast. Just over 10% of this population group had signed by the end of the observation period. This could be first evidence that the population groups do indeed evolve differently. Whether this is due to city-specific factors, e.g., that more specialized knowledge of environmental policies and climate change makes larger cities more susceptible to new policies, or whether cities’ choices are driven by the choices of similar sized cities, cannot be determined, yet. Testing Participation in Space and Time 121 (a) by per capita income group (b) by population group Figure 4.5: % of cities who signed the MCPA (2005-2010) 4.4.4 Independent Variables To test the hypotheses stipulated in the theoretical framework, measurable indicators need to be found for the specified concepts. I briefly discuss the operationalization of the independent variables in the following paragraphs. 122 Internal Factors As proposed in section 4.3, to determine the adoption of voluntary climate change mitigation initiatives on the part of local governments, internal, city-specific factors have to be taken into account. These internal determinants of MCPA participation are hypothesized to either emanate from the demand or supply side. All of the internal variables unless otherwise specified were obtained using City Data (http://www.city-data.com). This webpage provides the Census 2000 data as well as 2008 estimates from the U.S. Bureau of the Census for all cities over 10.000 inhabitants. Since these data are not available in spreadsheet format, a script had to be written to access data of the relevant cities.17 Demand side To proxy demand for climate change policies within the city, I rely on socioeconomic and political indicators that are linked to either a higher or lower demand in section 4.3. Socio-economic and political indicators that are assumed to increase demand for MCPA participation are high levels of education, income, and % of supporters of the Democratic Party within the community. I use the % of people living in the community that have obtained a bachelors or a higher degree (% bachelors & up) as an indicator for education. I proxy the wealth of the community by the median per capita income in the city (p.c. income). To measure ideology within the community, I rely on the county level result for the Democratic Party in the 2004 and 2008 elections % Dem Vote 18 . All of the above variables are supposed to increase demand and, therefore, the likelihood of participation in the MCPA. Determinants that I assume to lower demand for local climate change policies are primarily linked to bad economic conditions in a community. I proxy such bad economic conditions via the unemployment rate in the city (Unemployment) and with the percentage of residents living in poverty (Poverty level ). High abatement costs within a city were also considered to lower demand from the constituency. Abatement costs are measured by the variable Industry dep that takes on the value 1 if the main sector of employment in the city has to do with industrial manufacturing. In chapter 3, I assumed that a higher median age of the population would have a negative impact on the participation in climate change policy initiatives. Therefore, I also add a control variable that measures the median age in the city Median Age and expect a negative coefficient. 17 18 Research assistance by Krzysztof Wojtaniec to collect data for all 749 cities is greatly acknowledged. County level data on %Dem Vote in 2004 and 2008 was collected from the U.S. Election Atlas http: //uselectionatlas.org/ Testing Participation in Space and Time 123 Supply side To test the influence of the form of local government on the likelihood of participation in the MCPA, Mayor-council takes the value 1 for a mayor-council or ’strong mayor’ form and 0 otherwise. Comprehensive data on this variable was not accessible for all cities, but only for the subsample of cities of 30,000 and more inhabitants. Data were obtained from Vasi (2006). For this variable, I assume that a city with a ’strong mayor’ form of government will be more likely to participate in the MCPA. In hypothesis 1c, I stipulate that a higher administrative capacity is associated with a higher propensity of MCPA participation. I measure the concept of administrative capacity with two variables: the percentage of local government employment of total employment in the city % loc gov empl and the size of the city measured by its population Population. While the first measure taps at the essence of administrative capacity by measuring its size in relation to other sectors of employment, the population proxy captures the ’informedness’ about climate change and sustainability issues aspect of capacity that I discuss in the theoretical part. The larger a city, the more specialized is the staff and the more likely they will know about new policy areas and solutions. I therefore expect that both variables are positively linked to MCPA participation. Hypothesis 1d links the existence of a policy entrepreneur within the city to a higher probability of participation in the MCPA. Since it is hard to obtain data on individual mayors and their policy preferences, I therefore proxy policy entrepreneurship through a city’s membership in ICLEI-Local Governments for Sustainability. This association of local governments is committed to advancing climate protection and sustainable development and has worked with cities on these topics since the 1990s. I assume that if a city is already a member in ICLEI (which charges membership dues), the existence of a policy entrepreneur in the city and, linked to that, the likelihood of MCPA participation is higher. Information concerning a city’s membership in ICLEI was obtained from Vasi (2006) and updated to include members from 2006 onwards with data from ICLEI-USA.19 External Factors Neighbors In the empirical literature on diffusion, geographical proximity has always played a major role in explaining policy diffusion (Walker 1969; Berry & Berry 1990). Correspondingly, I suspect that for the units of analysis – the cities in the seven states – contiguity is an important channel of policy diffusion. I therefore test whether the influence of a truly external factor like 19 available at http://www.icleiusa.org/programs/climate/about-iclei/members/member-list 124 Figure 4.6: Neighbor relations within 100km geography explains interdependence in the signature behavior of cities with regard to the MCPA. In order to test hypothesis 3a on policy diffusion via the geographical contiguity of neighboring cities, a point distance weights matrix with a threshold of 100km was first created via ArcGis. This matrix was then transformed into a binary matrix indicating with a 1 if the city is a neighboring city (within 100km) or not. Such a matrix was created for both samples, the one with the 749 cities over 10,000 inhabitants and one including 242 cities over 30,000 inhabitants. Most studies of policy diffusion between cities are rather imprecise as to how exactly they define neighboring cities and mostly use cities in a neighboring county as being neighbors (Krause 2011a; Vasi 2006). However, since counties differ enormously in size, this operationalization is not the same as having a clearly specified area to include the neighbors in for each observation. This area or, more precisely, the connections between neighboring cities within 100km20 are shown in figures 4.6 and 4.7. To obtain a measure for each of the 749 (242) cities that indicates how many neighbors had signed the MCPA up until the last time period, the binary weights matrix was multiplied with the outcome of interest in each of the 66 time periods. In the analysis, 20 I thank Stefan Schuetz for help in visualizing the connections. Testing Participation in Space and Time 125 the count of neighbors for each city that had signed the MCPA up until the time period before (t − 1) is therefore expected to influence a cities’ propensity to participate in the MCPA. Figure 4.7: Neighbor relations within 100km, reduced sample >=30k Peers In the theoretical part, I have assumed that cities interact with one another in multiple policy dimensions and that the choices they make concerning participation in MCPA are dependent on their peers’ actions on the issue. Furthermore, it was supposed that cities are more likely to adopt policies from cities that are ’similar’ to them. Peers are therefore assumed to be cities that are similar in terms of income and size. The underlying concept of ’similarity of interest’ is operationalized as follows. To measure the behavior of other cities in the same income group regarding the MCPA, I have constructed four income groups along income quartiles. The variable % inc group signed then captures how many cities within the same income group had signed the MCPA up until the previous time period. Similarly, the variable % pop group signed informs about the percentage of cities that have signed within the respective population group (10-30k, 30-50k, 50-100k, 100-250k, and over 250k). It is assumed that the more cities within the same income or population group have signed up until the previous time period, the more likely is a city’s signature of the MCPA. 126 Social Networks To proxy the concept of social networks, I downloaded participation lists from the U.S. Conference of Mayors webpage (http://usmayors.org/meetings/) for the biannual meetings between 2005 and 2010.21 The meetings take place in January in Washington, D.C. (Winter Meeting ), and in June at alternate places (Annual Meeting ). At these gatherings, mayors not only meet other mayors, but have the chance to talk to, e.g., Administration officials or Congressional leaders. Generally, a variety of issues that affect cities across the country are discussed in various policy committees, which come up with new resolutions that are then presented to the entire members that attend. There are a lot of social networking opportunities for mayors during the 3-4 days of the meetings. Furthermore, topics relating to voluntary climate change policies, such as energy efficiency or building codes, are regularly discussed. I therefore expect that mayors learn about what other cities are doing and what can be done on the issue at these meetings, and I thus submit that cites that attend bi-annual meeting of the USCOM are more likely to participate in the MCPA. Correspondingly, the variables Winter Meeting and Annual Meeting indicate for each city whether the mayor attended the specific meeting. Events The data on mayoral elections were obtained from the website of the U.S. Conference of Mayors (http://usmayors.org/elections/). These data were downloaded at various points in time and entered into spreadsheets, which were then merged into the data set containing the basic city-level Census data. Since I expect that mayors are generally more likely to engage themselves in voluntary climate change initiative right before an election, the variable Mayoral campaign takes the value 1 for the five months leading up to a mayoral election in the city and is expected to have a positive and significant influence on the propensity to sign the MCPA. To proxy the influence that 2007 legislation on the Energy Efficiency and Conservation Block Grants as well as the 2009 endowment with financial resources for cities had on the incentives of cities to join, I created two variables EECBG July 07 and EECBG Feb 09. These take the value 1 for the five months from the announcement that Congress started debate about these block grants until it became clear that there would be no money appropriated for these block grants in 2008. Similarly, the variable EECBG Feb 09 taps at the effect that the news from the appropriation of financial resources within the American Recovery and Investment Act had on 21 Unfortunately, the participation records from the June 2005 meeting were not available Testing Participation in Space and Time 127 cities’ likelihood to join the MCPA. It takes the value 1 for the 5 months after February 2009 and zero otherwise. I expect a positive and significant coefficient on both variables. In hypothesis 3c, I stipulated that the impact of Obama’s election in November 2008 lead to a different logic of participation. To account for this event, I add a variable that is zero in all time periods before November 2008 and takes on the value 1 afterwards. In accordance with hypothesis 3c, a negative coefficient is expected. This concludes the discussion of my independent variables. The following paragraphs introduce the statistical method that is used to empirically test my theoretical claims. 4.4.5 Statistical Method The unit of analysis used in this paper is the city-month. The time period under analysis are the 66 months from the initiation of the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement in February 2005 to July 2010. For each city-month, the dependent variable signature indicates whether the city has signed the MCPA in this month or not (0/1). If a city becomes a signatory to the MCPA in one month, the event is considered to have occurred and, consequently, the observation leaves the data set. In analyzing the adoption of a policy, many scholars have used event history analysis (EHA) (c.f. Berry & Berry 1999). Event history data for the discrete-time process at hand (adoption of policy or not) would correspondingly denote the dependent variable as a series of binary outcomes indicating whether a city signed the agreement in the time period or not (0 / 1). Therefore, for discrete-time data it can be noted that ’the dependent variable, although different in form from the actual duration time, conveys the same information as the duration time’ (Box-Steffensmeier & Jones 2004, 70). This fact then allows us to estimate such as binary time-series-cross-section (BTSCS) data using standard logit or probit analysis as grouped duration data (Beck et al. 1998). However, as Beck et al. (1998) point out, these techniques consider the observations to be temporally independent. They argue that this assumption is not true for many applications. Estimating standard logit on BTSCS data in the event of temporal dependence leads to estimates that are consistent, but inefficient. The standard errors are wrong and inflate t-values (Beck et al. 1998). They recommend the use of cubic splines to account for potential time dependence. In a recent paper, Carter & Signorino (2010) suggest a simpler alternative, i.e., the use of a cubic polynomial approximation by including time (t), time squared (t2 ), and time cubed (t3 ) in the model. This fix should help to control for time 128 effects in the data that are due to the fact that the propensity to sign the MCPA in one month is related to the city’s behavior and propensity in the past months. I therefore decide to follow Bernauer, Kalbhenn, Koubi & Spilker (2010) and Perrin & Bernauer (2010) in using Carter & Signorino (2010)’s approach. In the following section, I present and discuss the results from my analysis of cities’ adoption of the MCPA from 2005-2010 using my new data set. 4.5 Analysis and Results What are the factors that influence a city’s decision to partake in voluntary climate change agreements like the MCPA? In section 4.3, I have presented three groups of determinants – internal city-specific factors, external factors, and specific events – that are supposed to matter for participation in voluntary climate change initiatives. The first part of this section shows the main results from the statistical analysis. In the second part, I present qualitative evidence from the questionnaires and give an overview over the factors that mayors stress as having been important in their decision to join the MCPA. 4.5.1 Statistical Analysis Main results Table 4.4 presents the main results explaining MCPA participation. Proceeding in the order of the theoretical part, I first test hypotheses 1a-d in model 1 in table 4.4. Internal factors Hypothesis 1a postulates that a higher demand for voluntary climate change policies increases the propensity of a local government to participate in the MCPA. As hypothesized, a higher % of democratic votes significantly increases the likelihood of participation. The effect of the % of people in the city having at least obtained a bachelor degree – a proxy for the exposure to information about climate change – is also positive, but does not reach standard levels of significance. The same is true for the positive coefficient on median per capita income in the city. I now turn to the factors that decrease demand for climate change policies and, correspondingly, are hypothesized to also decrease the propensity for MCPA participation. Here, a high unemployment rate as well as a higher median age have the predicted negative and significant effect, whereas dependence on industry and manufacturing is statistically insignificant. Another indicator that was associated with lower demand is the Poverty level. However, Testing Participation in Space and Time 129 Table 4.4: Main Results (1) Internal Internal Factors p.c. income % Bachelor&up % Dem Vote Population Median Age Unemployment Industry dep Poverty level % loc gov empl ICLEI member 0.00 0.01 0.03*** 0.00*** -0.05** -0.12** -0.26 0.03** 0.04 1.90*** (2) External (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.21) (0.01) (0.09) (0.49) External Factors No.of Neighbors % inc group signed % pop group signed Winter Meet.01-08 Winter Meet.01-07 Annual Meet.06-07 Annual Meet.06-06 -0.04 -0.18*** 0.05*** 2.24** 1.85** 1.40 2.49*** (0.03) (0.06) (0.01) (1.06) (0.78) (1.18) (0.58) Events Mayoral campaign Obama Elected EECBG Feb 09 EECBG July 07 t t2 t3 Constant 0.11** -0.00 0.00 -6.16*** Log lik. Observations -1017.89 43228 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (3) Events (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.01) 0.06 0.00 -0.00 -6.12*** -993.27 42851 (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (0.44) (4) Combined -0.00 0.02* 0.02*** 0.00 -0.03 -0.12** 0.02 0.03* 0.05 1.68*** (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.23) (0.02) (0.11) (0.61) -0.04 -0.18** 0.04*** 1.89 1.62** 1.46 2.51*** (0.03) (0.07) (0.01) (1.22) (0.77) (1.09) (0.63) 1.46*** 0.20 -0.42 -0.08 (0.26) (0.39) (0.40) (0.27) 1.43*** -0.16 -0.42 -0.05 (0.25) (0.42) (0.41) (0.29) 0.06 -0.00 -0.00 -6.47*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (0.39) 0.04 0.00 -0.00** -6.59*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.06) -1054.17 43600 -947.79 42484 130 it is surprising that a higher % of people in the city living in poverty seems to lead to a higher likelihood of signing the MCPA. This counterintuitive result might somehow be due to the fact that a higher number of poor people live in large cities that usually are very active on voluntary climate change policies. Concerning the supply side explanations for MCPA participation, hypothesis 1c stipulates that a higher administrative capacity positively influences the propensity of cities to participate. The two variables proxying the administrative capacity of a city are the % of people working for the local government and the size of the city measured by its population. While both show the theoretically predicted positive influence on the likelihood of participation, only the coefficient on population is statistically significant. Large cities usually have a higher administrative capacity in the sense that they tend to have specialized personnel that knows about recent developments, e.g., with regard to local climate change policies. Testing hypothesis 1d on the local government’s previous engagement with local climate change politics, we can see that a city’s membership in ICLEI is indeed associated with a higher likelihood of joining the MCPA. This confirms the theoretical assumption that cities that already have a background in the local implementation of climate change mitigation policies are more likely to also engage their communities in further initiatives. External Factors I now turn to the external factors that are considered to impact on a local government’s propensity to adopt voluntary policies. In model 2, we can see that – counter to theoretical expectations – the number of neighbors that have signed the agreement already seems to have a negative effect. This result could hint to a free-riding logic with respect to MCPA participation. With an increasing number of neighbors joining, cities may chose to free-ride on the efforts of others. While this would generally be a realistic scenario given the global public good character of environmental quality with respect to global climate change, this seems to be an unlikely scenario in the case of voluntary policies, that might even be purely symbolic. Therefore, another possible explanation might be that political benefits for the local government from MCPA participation decrease the more neighbors have already signed. However, the coefficient on the neighbors variable is not statistically significant at conventional levels and could also be equal to zero. In contrast, the two different conceptions of peer effects between similar income (hypothesis 2b) and population groups (hypothesis 2c) are both significantly associated with MCPA partic- Testing Participation in Space and Time 131 ipation. Regarding the peer similarities through city size, the positive coefficient means that a city is more likely to participate in the MCPA the higher the percentage of cities that had signed the agreement up until the previous time period is. This confirms the influence of similar size on participation. This effect seems to dominate the ’simple’ neighbors effect when testing them together. Testing the robustness of the main results, I will provide further evidence concerning the null finding for the influence of geographic neighbors. Hypothesis 2d stipulates that city governments that actively participate in social networks of cities are more likely to sign up for the MCPA. Proxied by the local government’s attendance record in USCOM biannual meetings, we can see that the participation in the two winter meetings of 2007 and 2008 significantly increased the likelihood of MCPA adoption. The strongly significant result for the winter meeting 2007 might be explained by the fact that the second day of the meeting was specifically dedicated to energy and climate protection issues.22 A related topic on the meetings’ agenda was the call for an ’Energy and Environmental Block Grant.’ One year later, the then called Energy Efficiency and Conservation Block Grants were again discussed at great lengths culminating in a letter to the House of Representatives’ budget committee to appropriate $2 billion for the EECBG Program, signed by about 140 participants.23 These discussions also might have influenced attending cities’ mayors or representatives in their decision to join the MCPA. Furthermore, participating in the annual meeting in Las Vegas in 2006 also increases the likelihood of signing the MCPA. Again, the energy crisis of 2006 and rising fuel prices were the main topics of this meeting, which may again have been pivotal in persuading attending mayors to participate in the agreement. Surprisingly, the attendance of the 2007 annual meeting in Los Angeles does not appear to have spurred MCPA participation despite having ’Global Warming & Climate Protection’ as an agenda item.24 In sum, it can be stated that the hypothesized positive effect of interacting with other cities is strongly supported by model 2. Events Model 3 in table 4.4 includes the four indicators measuring the influence of events on participation. In hypothesis 3a, I have postulated that mayors are more likely to sign the MCPA during the time leading up to a mayoral election to show leadership and initiative. Indeed, the coefficient on Mayoral campaign is statistically significant and positively associated with a 22 Further information accessible at http://www.usmayors.org/75thWinterMeeting/ Further information accessible at http://www.usmayors.org/76thWinterMeeting/ 24 All other network variables were dropped during estimation because they completely determined failure. 23 132 higher participation propensity. Counter to expectations, the Obama Administration leads to a higher likelihood of participation. However, the coefficient is not significantly different from zero. The same applies for the remaining events concerning potential incentives for participation in the form of funding for cities via the Energy Efficiency and Conservation Block Grant. Both coefficients do not reach statistical significance and are negatively related to the adoption of voluntary climate change policies. This counterintuitive effect might be either due to the fact that the time period in which positive effects of these grants kicked in were not correctly specified, or MCPA participation was not seen as an advantage to obtain these grants. Therefore, only hypothesis 3a on the relationship between a mayoral election date and the likelihood to sign the agreement received statistical support in the model that included only the events. Robustness of main results Model 4 in table 4.4 serves as the baseline model and includes all theoretically specified influences for MCPA participation. Combining all factors shows that some of the internal determinants loose in significance while the external factors remain largely unchanged. That is, even when controlling for the effects of city internal characteristics and time-specific events, city-external determinants – the participation behavior of peers in the same population (income) group – are strongly associated with a higher (lower) likelihood of MCPA adoption. A further observation from table 4.4 is that the coefficients on the cubic polynomials (t, t2 t3 ) are hardly statistically significant throughout models 1-4. The question arises whether one might want to exclude them from these models altogether. However, a likelihood ratio test comparing models 1 and 2 of table 4.5 against the hypothesis that all three coefficients on the cubic polynomials are jointly zero led me to come to the conclusion that I need to include them. Furthermore, it can be seen that estimating the combined model without t, t2 t3 does not change the results greatly. The effect of the Obama administration now has a significant and negative impact on the likelihood of adoption. This effect is picked up by the cubic polynomials in the baseline model. Conversely, the negative and significant coefficient on % inc group signed vanishes. Having established the need to control for time effects, 4.8 shows a non-monotonic hazard that first increases and then turns around. The approximated hazard rate indicates how likely ’failure’ or, in this case, the signing of the MCPA is to occur as time progresses (Beck et al. 1998). The non-monotonic shape depicted in figure 4.8 is a common feature in research on the diffusion Testing Participation in Space and Time 133 Table 4.5: Robustness of main results I; exclucding t and reduced model (1) Combined (2) w/o t Internal Factors p.c. income % Bachelor&up % Dem Vote Population Median Age Unemployment Industry dep Poverty level % loc gov empl ICLEI member -0.00 0.02* 0.02*** 0.00 -0.03 -0.12** 0.02 0.03* 0.05 1.68*** (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.23) (0.02) (0.11) (0.61) -0.00 0.02* 0.02*** -0.00 -0.03 -0.10* 0.02 0.03* 0.05 1.74*** (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.23) (0.02) (0.11) (0.61) External Factors No.of Neighbors % inc group signed % pop group signed Winter Meet.01-08 Winter Meet.01-07 Annual Meet.06-07 Annual Meet.06-06 -0.04 -0.18** 0.04*** 1.89 1.62** 1.46 2.51*** (0.03) (0.07) (0.01) (1.22) (0.77) (1.09) (0.63) -0.01 0.00 0.04*** 2.05* 2.04*** 1.61 2.63*** (0.03) (0.03) (0.01) (1.20) (0.78) (1.10) (0.61) Events Mayoral campaign Obama Elected EECBG Feb 09 EECBG July 07 1.43*** -0.16 -0.42 -0.05 (0.25) (0.42) (0.41) (0.29) 1.32*** -0.78** 0.08 0.07 (0.24) (0.33) (0.40) (0.29) t t2 t3 Constant 0.04 0.00 -0.00** -6.59*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.06) Log lik. Observations -947.79 42484 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 -6.24*** -956.83 42484 (1.00) (3) reduced 0.02*** 0.02*** (0.01) (0.01) -0.10* (0.06) 0.04*** (0.01) 1.68*** (0.63) -0.16** 0.04*** (0.07) (0.01) 1.61** (0.78) 2.50*** (0.62) 1.47*** (0.25) 0.06 0.00 -0.00 -8.09*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (0.60) -952.73 42484 0 .01 .02 .03 .04 .05 134 0 20 40 60 time 99% confidence interval expected signature behavior Figure 4.8: Baseline hazard of innovation or policy adoption. The cumulative s-shaped curve of percentage of adopters over time that is usually shown (c.f. figure 4.3) corresponds to the bell-shaped hazard rate (Rogers 1995). Reasons why the underlying hazard in figure 4.8 is not completely bell-shaped could be that, due to right censoring occurring in July 2010, the height of the curve is either not yet reached for the cities in my sample, or is just about to decline. Given that many of the smaller cities were still joining the agreement in 2010, this might be an explanation. Returning to table 4.5, model 3 is a reduced model that includes only significant predictors of the likelihood of MCPA participation from the baseline model. The substantive coefficients remain the same, however, the levels of statistical significance slightly changes for some variables. This might be due to issues of multicollinearity. In the present of such multicollinearity, standard errors are inflated, which leads to more conservative interpretations of an estimates’ significance. Since the coefficient size should not be affected in such a large-N framework (Carter & Signorino 2010) and the inclusion of the variables is theoretically warranted, this should not provide a major problem for the results. However, to be cautious about the potential influences on the substantive results and a check on the robustness of the main results especially concerning the external factors, I have estimated the baseline model and added each of the contingency factors Testing Participation in Space and Time 135 in turns in table 4.6. Model 2 shows that when only the number of neighbors that signed the MCPA is included as the geographical contiguity effect, the coefficient also does not reach statistical significance. Similarly, the coefficients on % inc group signed and % pop group signed do not change at all if included separately into the model. However, the coefficients on some of the city-specific variables change. This might be due to the exclusion of relevant external factors or multicollinearity. Since the fundamental results do not change, this does not warrant further concerns. There are two further checks of the baseline results that are shown in table 4.7. Here I first exclude the variables pertaining to the influence of (social) city networks on the likelihood of MCPA participation. One might argue that in the context of the sample including all cities over 10.000 inhabitants, these networks are not open for smaller cities. This is true in that USCOM usually only represents the interest of larger cities, even though every city can participate in the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. Also, small cities can still be informed about the policies associated with the MCPA even if they do not attend the meetings themselves. Model 2 in table 4.7 confirms that excluding these variables does not change the results at all. In section 4.4.2, it was mentioned that some of the city’s MCPA adoption dates had to be imputed due to lack of precise information. Model 3 now excludes those imputed cities and their values from the estimation. Once again, we can see that the results do not change. As a final check on the baseline models’ ability to account for internal city-specific factors, external determinants, as well as time-specific events, I have reduced the sample size to only include cities over 30.000 inhabitants. For this smaller sample, we can now test the hypothesis 1b, namely that the propensity to sign the MCPA is higher for a city with a mayor-council as compared to one with a council-manager form of government. In model 1, this assumption is confirmed by the positive and significant coefficient on Mayor-Council. In models 1-4 in table 4.8, we can see that the results for most of the other variables are similar to the ones obtained from the larger sample in table 4.4. However, combining the different determinants of MCPA adoption in model 4, some of the coefficients turn insignificant. For example, of the external factors in model 2, only participation in the two meetings is significantly related to an increase in the likelihood of joining the MCPA. None of the contingency or interdependence factors reach conventional levels of significance. Generally, this seems to point to a potentially more important role of the city-specific factors in cities with more than 30.000 inhabitants. We can see in model 4, that although a higher % of college-educated individuals, voters for the democratic party, 136 Table 4.6: Robustness of main results II; external factors (1) Combined (2) Neighbor (3) Income group External Factors No.of Neighbors % inc group signed % pop group signed -0.04 -0.18** 0.04*** (0.03) (0.07) (0.01) -0.02 Internal Factors p.c. income % Bachelor&up % Dem Vote Population Median Age Unemployment Industry dep Poverty level % loc gov empl ICLEI member -0.00 0.02* 0.02*** 0.00 -0.03 -0.12** 0.02 0.03* 0.05 1.68*** (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.23) (0.02) (0.11) (0.61) -0.00 0.01 0.03*** 0.00** -0.04* -0.11** -0.16 0.03** 0.04 1.93*** (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.21) (0.01) (0.09) (0.50) -0.00 0.01 0.03*** 0.00*** -0.04* -0.11** -0.15 0.03* 0.04 1.85*** External Factors II Winter Meet.01-08 Winter Meet.01-07 Annual Meet.06-07 Annual Meet.06-06 1.89 1.62** 1.46 2.51*** (1.22) (0.77) (1.09) (0.63) 2.37* 2.41*** 1.88* 2.93*** (1.23) (0.69) (1.06) (0.62) Events Mayoral campaign Obama Elected EECBG Feb 09 EECBG July 07 1.43*** -0.16 -0.42 -0.05 (0.25) (0.42) (0.41) (0.29) 1.40*** 0.05 -0.41 -0.05 t t2 t3 Constant 0.04 0.00 -0.00** -6.59*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.06) 0.06 -0.00 -0.00 -6.54*** Log lik. Observations -947.79 42484 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (0.03) -0.16** -989.71 43228 (4) Pop group (0.07) 0.04*** (0.01) (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.22) (0.01) (0.10) (0.49) -0.00 0.02** 0.02*** 0.00 -0.03 -0.10* 0.02 0.03* 0.04 1.69*** (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.23) (0.02) (0.11) (0.61) 2.38* 2.17*** 1.91* 2.86*** (1.24) (0.70) (1.06) (0.62) 1.91 1.86** 1.41 2.62*** (1.22) (0.77) (1.10) (0.62) (0.26) (0.40) (0.41) (0.28) 1.44*** -0.16 -0.42 0.01 (0.26) (0.41) (0.41) (0.28) 1.46*** 0.11 -0.37 -0.12 (0.26) (0.40) (0.41) (0.29) (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.01) 0.07 0.00 -0.00* -6.53*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.03) 0.06 -0.00 -0.00 -6.95*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.07) -968.66 42484 -951.79 42484 Testing Participation in Space and Time 137 Table 4.7: Robustness of main results III: networks and impute (1) Combined (2) w/o network (3) w/o impute Internal Factors p.c. income % Bachelor&up % Dem Vote Population Median Age Unemployment Industry dep Poverty level % loc gov empl ICLEI member -0.00 0.02* 0.02*** 0.00 -0.03 -0.12** 0.02 0.03* 0.05 1.68*** (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.23) (0.02) (0.11) (0.61) -0.00 0.02* 0.02*** 0.00 -0.04 -0.13** 0.00 0.03* 0.05 1.67*** (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.05) (0.23) (0.02) (0.11) (0.60) -0.00 0.02** 0.03*** 0.00 -0.04* -0.12** -0.02 0.02 0.06 1.63*** (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00) (0.03) (0.06) (0.24) (0.02) (0.12) (0.63) External Factors No.of Neighbors % inc group signed % pop group signed Winter Meet.01-08 Winter Meet.01-07 Annual Meet.06-07 Annual Meet.06-06 -0.04 -0.18** 0.04*** 1.89 1.62** 1.46 2.51*** (0.03) (0.07) (0.01) (1.22) (0.77) (1.09) (0.63) -0.04 -0.20*** 0.04*** (0.03) (0.07) (0.01) -0.04 -0.22*** 0.04*** 2.22* 1.67** 1.64 0.96 (0.03) (0.08) (0.01) (1.26) (0.80) (1.10) (1.08) Events Mayoral campaign Obama Elected EECBG Feb 09 EECBG July 07 1.43*** -0.16 -0.42 -0.05 (0.25) (0.42) (0.41) (0.29) 1.40*** -0.16 -0.41 -0.12 (0.25) (0.42) (0.41) (0.29) 1.46*** 0.19 -0.39 0.17 (0.26) (0.44) (0.41) (0.30) t t2 t3 Constant 0.04 0.00 -0.00** -6.59*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.06) 0.06 0.00 -0.00* -6.56*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.06) 0.04 0.00 -0.00** -6.34*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.09) Log lik. Observations -947.79 42484 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 -956.81 42484 -858.85 41968 138 Table 4.8: Robustness of main results IV: reduced sample (cities >= 30.000) (1) Internal Internal Factors p.c. income % Bachelor&up % Dem Vote Population Median Age Unemployment Industry dep Poverty level Mayor-Council % loc gov empl ICLEI member -0.00 0.03** 0.02** 0.00 0.04 -0.05 0.08 0.05* 0.39* 0.05 2.21*** (2) External (0.00) (0.02) (0.01) (0.00) (0.04) (0.07) (0.28) (0.03) (0.22) (0.14) (0.38) External Factors No.of Neighbors % inc group signed % pop group signed Winter Meet.01-08 Winter Meet.01-07 Annual Meet.06-07 Annual Meet.06-06 -0.01 -0.17** 0.03*** 2.07** 1.37* 1.49 2.20*** (0.02) (0.08) (0.01) (1.05) (0.82) (1.10) (0.57) Events Mayoral campaign Obama Elected EECBG Feb 09 EECBG July 07 t t2 t3 Constant 0.03 0.00 -0.00 -8.70*** Log lik. Observations -582.87 11674 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (3) Events (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.45) -0.01 0.00 -0.00 -4.76*** -580.32 11564 (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (0.43) (4) Combined -0.00 0.04** 0.02*** 0.00 0.05 -0.02 0.17 0.03 0.37 0.02 2.05*** (0.00) (0.02) (0.01) (0.00) (0.04) (0.09) (0.29) (0.03) (0.23) (0.15) (0.45) -0.01 -0.11 0.01 1.93* 1.23 1.54 2.32*** (0.02) (0.09) (0.01) (1.15) (0.86) (1.05) (0.61) 1.10*** 0.46 -0.85 -0.08 (0.29) (0.49) (0.57) (0.35) 1.31*** 0.13 -0.85 -0.09 (0.30) (0.52) (0.57) (0.37) 0.01 0.00 -0.00 -5.10*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (0.40) -0.01 0.00 -0.00* -8.94*** (0.05) (0.00) (0.00) (1.56) -607.55 11872 -547.96 11369 Testing Participation in Space and Time 139 and former engagement in climate change significantly increase a city’s propensity to sign the voluntary climate change agreement, most of the other coefficients are insignificant. Predicted Probabilities To get a grasp of the substantive effects of some of the indicators on the likelihood of MCPA participation, I display (simulated) predicted probabilities in figure 4.9.25 The subfigures depict the effects of two internal variables, % Democrats and unemployment, and the two external variables that measure the peer effects of similar income and population group. In subfigure 4.9(a), we can see how the likelihood of MCPA participation steadily increases with a higher percentage of democratic votes in the city. Going from the minimum value of % Democratic vote to its maximum value increases the predicted probabilities only by about 0.4%. In subfigure 4.9(b), the probability of participation decreases the higher the unemployment rate in the city is. Here, the confidence interval is discernibly narrower where the center of the data lies. The negative effect on the predicted probability of signing the MCPA decreases only by around 0.3 % from having very low unemployment to very high values of unemployment. As expected in the theoretical part, subfigure 4.9(c) shows the positive impact on participation by increases in the percentage of cities in the same population group that participate in the MCPA. Until about 50% of the cities in the population group have signed, the substantive effect is constantly very small. However, if over 50% in the population group have signed, the predicted probability increase steeply. So going from the mean value of the variable to its maximum value, the predicted probability of joining the MCPA increases by around 6.4 %. A reversed threshold effect can be observed for the % of cities of the same income group that have already joined (c.f. subfigure 4.9(d)). Here, for low values of the % of cities in the same income group the negative effect is very pronounced. However, this effect quickly approaches almost zero as soon as about 10% in the income group have signed. In predicted probability values, this means that the negative effect of income is more pronounced when going from its minimum value to the mean (-2.1 %) compared to going from its mean to the maximum values (-0.2 %). The main results from these graphs are that, first, the predicted probabilities of MCPA participation from the two contingency variables are larger in size compared to the ones from the city internal factors. Second, there are threshold effects concerning the external variables. Recent research has found similar threshold effects in the context of global environmental treaty ratification (Bernauer, 25 Simulations are based on the program CLARIFY by Tomz et al. (2003) 140 Kalbhenn, Koubi & Spilker 2010) as well as for the ratification of Long Range Transboundary 0 0 .002 .002 .004 .004 .006 .008 .006 Air Pollution (LRTAP) Agreements (Perrin & Bernauer 2010). 0 20 40 Democrats 99% confidence interval 60 80 0 expected signature behavior 5 10 15 Unemployment 99% confidence interval 25 expected signature behavior .02 0 0 .05 .1 .04 .06 (b) Unemployment .15 (a) % Democratic vote 20 0 20 40 60 % of population group that has signed 99% confidence interval 80 expected signature behavior (c) % of same population group already signed 100 0 5 10 15 20 25 Inc_Group 99% confidence interval expected signature behavior (d) % of same income group already signed Figure 4.9: Predicted Probabilities (Baseline model); other variables are kept at their mean; binary variables at their median From Table 4.9, we can see the predicted probabilities of joining the MCPA from the explanatory variables that take either the value 0 or 1. We can see that being a member of ICLEI increases the probability to sign by 1.3 %. The strongest effect on the probability can be observed from having participated in the Annual meeting of the U.S. Conference of Mayors in June 2006. An attending cities’ probability to sign is over 3.1 % higher than that of comparable cities that did not attend. To further illustrate substantive effects, I have simulated probabilities of joining for five Midwestern cities based on selected covariates (while keeping all others at their means) at the beginning of the observation period (in May 2005) in table 4.10. I have included Testing Participation in Space and Time 141 Table 4.9: Simulated predicted probabilities Min to max ICLEI member Annual Meet.06-06 Winter Meet.01-07 Mayoral campaign .0126 (.0097) .0315 (.0203) .0131 (.0129) .0072 (.0022) the largest city in the sample, Chicago, as well as two other large cities, Cincinnati and Detroit. These are joined by two mid-size cities, Duluth and Champaign. Whereas Duluth and Champaign are quite comparable on many of the variables shown, Duluth is a member of ICLEI while Champaign is not. Furthermore, while Champaign has a higher % of educated people in the city, Duluth had a higher percentage of democratic votes in their county in 2004. The predicted probabilities from these constellations can be seen in the first column. Duluth, possibly due to its membership in ICLEI, has a predicted probability of joining the MCPA that is about 6 times higher than that of Champaign. This higher simulated probability for Duluth matches the real life developments. While Duluth joined the MCPA already in July 2005, Champaign has still not signed on to the voluntary initiative. A similar observation can be made for the three larger towns. Also being an ICLEI member, Chicago’s probability of signing is considerably higher than that of the other towns. Indeed, Chicago joined in August 2005, whereas Cincinnati signed up in June 2006 and Detroit – as I already mentioned above – only became a member in February 2009. 142 City Chicago Detroit Cincinnati Duluth Champaign 44.3 28.2 26.6 11.0 25.5 %bachelor&up 18671 18969 19964 14711 20168 p.c income 50.37 65.20 47.09 69.39 70.25 % Dem Vote 7.1 7.5 7.3 13.8 10.1 Unempl 0 0 16.667 16.667 16.667 % of pop group 0 1 0 0 1 ICLEI 67518 86918 331285 951270 2896016 Population Table 4.10: Simulated Probabilities, City Examples (for May 2005) Simulated probability* 0.050 (0.070) 0.002 (0.001) 0.002 (0.001) 0.012 (0.007) 0.002 (0.001) Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses; *PR(signature = 1) Testing Participation in Space and Time 143 4.5.2 Qualitative Evidence This part of the analysis now looks into evidence gathered from the mail questionnaires. Table 4.11 lists the 23 cities that have returned the questionnaire (c.f. 4.7). Although this sounds like a very low rate of response given it was sent to 150 cities, it has to be borne in mind that the priority of the data collection effort was given to the date of signature. The questionnaire, which is included in section 4.7 contains questions about the MCPA, asking for example how the community had first heard about the initiative and what the main factors were that influenced the mayors decision to sign the agreement. I also ask a battery of questions about the MCPA, the city and some personal and demographic information about the mayor. Table 4.11: Qualitative evidence is based on returned questionnaires from the following cities State Name IL IL IL IL IL IN IN IN MI MI MN MN MN MN MN MN MN MO OH OH OH OH WI Rolling Meadows Wilmette Evanston Hoffman Estates Schaumburg Bloomington Evansville Michigan City Marquette Southgate Austin Bemidji Hutchinson Rosemount Burnsville Eagan Roseville Saint Louis Alliance Cincinnati Parma Warren Madison Mayor or Representative Kenneth A. Nelson Christopher S. Canning Elizabeth Tisdahl William D. McLeod Al Larson Mark Kruzan Jonathan Weinzapfel Chuck Oberlie John Kivela Joseph G. Kuspa Thomas A. Stiehm Richard Lehmann Steve Cook Bill Droste Elizabeth B. Kautz Mike Maguire Craig Klausing Francis G. Slay Toni E. Middleton Larry Falkin Dean E. Depiero Michael J. O’Brien Dave Cieslewicz Pop >=30k 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 % Dem 70.25 70.25 70.25 70.25 70.25 53.43 40.72 49.56 53.60 69.39 60.99 50.13 36.45 48.48 48.48 48.48 63.04 80.29 50.59 47.09 66.57 61.65 66.02 The following brief overview of the mayors’ and city representatives’ answers fulfills two functions. First, qualitative in-depth evidence is given to corroborate the findings from the large-N analysis and to illuminate these results with anecdotal evidence. In providing evidence, all three determinants of voluntary action considered in the theoretical part – internal factors, external 144 factors as well as events – are considered. Second, beyond the explanation concerning the attribute, spatial, and event data from the above analysis, the answers of the questionnaires allow to a certain extent an interpretation of the deeper motivational forces that led mayors to sign the MCPA as well as their evaluation of the effects this signature had concerning their reputation. On the level of mayoral characteristics, there are seven mayor who indicate that they consider themselves a Democrat, five consider themselves as Independent whereas four mayors see themselves as Republicans.26 Asking what the impact of their decision to sign the agreement was first on public sentiment towards them as a mayors and second on their chances for reelection, one can see that while only two out of four republicans indicate that their participation had a positive effect on public sentiment, all indicate that it had no effect on their chances for reelection. For the Democratic mayors, however, this looks different. While all except one of the Democrats indicate a positive effect of their joining on their communities sentiment, four even see a positive effect from participating in the agreement on their chances for reelection. I now to the question concerning the factors that led the mayors to sign the MCPA. Here again, one can see a slight difference between Democratic mayors and their Republican counterparts in the sense that Democrats more often relate their reasons for signature to the failure of the federal government whereas Republican mayors never name this as a reason. This perceived failure is formulated by Mayor Kruzan of Bloomington, IN: ’Instead of joining 141 nations that ratified [the Kyoto Protocol], the US adopted wait and see attitude. Wait and see is a choice. And it’s a choice that led this nation into energy dependence, a degraded economy, and I would argue, war ’. In total, inaction on the federal level was given as a reason by three Democrats and two of the Independent mayors. Notably Democratic mayors not only give the inaction of the federal government as main factor for signing the agreement, they also answer the question of why the initiative got so successful with this argument. With regard to the four Republican mayors, they indicate personal concern (Alliance, OH), the city’s former engagement in environmental and sustainability issues (Burnsville, MN) and quality of life and health issues (Rolling Meadows, IL and Bemidji, MN). Although not backed up by data on the actual implementation of local climate change policies in these cities, the fact that such a high percentage of Democratic mayors name federal inaction as their main reason might suggest that political benefits were reaped due to action against the federal government. Comparing the actions implemented in these communities with the ones 26 The remaining had not provided information on this question. Testing Participation in Space and Time 145 implemented in the communities where the mayors indicated that they joined out of personal concern for the environment would be an interesting extension to gain evidence on whether policies are symbolic or substantive. Overall, the two main factors that were named to have an positive effect on the decision to sign the agreement were on the one hand environmental concerns (on a personal level (Alliance, OH; Hutchinson, MN), due to general preferences of the village (Hoffman Estates), or from environmental comissions (Evanston, IL)) and interlinked with that, on the other hand a desires to increase quality of life in the city. The quality of life arguments ranges from arguments of community design (’This Agreement dovetails perfectly into promoting healthier living by walking, biking and enjoying our beautiful natural environment’ Mayor Kivela, Marquette, MI) to the minimization of industrial effects (’The majority of our local electricity is generated by a coal fired plant within our city limits and we are constantly reminded to the need to clean that production within regulated utility’ Mayor Oberlie, Michigan City, MI). This confirms studies such as Betsill (2001); Warden (2007); Kousky & Schneider (2003) on the importance of local co-benefits from voluntary climate change policies on the local level. Interestingly, one factor which was named several times as main factor for signing was the future economic well-being of the city. As stated in the theoretical framework, this is a counterintuitive result in the realm of global climate change. However, some communities expect future gains due to energy savings through green policies (Mayor Droste, Rosemount, MN: ’With a lowdown in the economy we are looking at ways to save money. We were looking at efficient lighting and heating in our older buildings. We were also making assessments regarding all of the lawn mowing and watering we were doing’). As mentioned above, the notion that the initiation of the EECBG program in 2007 was decisive for the participation of communities in the MCPA – though not backed by the statistical analysis – was an incentive for at least two of the communities in the sample. Mayor Depiero of Parma, OH stated as his main reason for participation that: ’HR2447 was designed to create the Energy and Efficiency Block Grant, which at the time of passage of legislation, would have provided the City of Parma over $1.000.000 to use toward energy efficiency projects for our businesses and residents. Signing the agreement was the first step towards advocacy of the legislation’. Furthermore, Mayor Oberlie of Michigan City also refers to the EECBG legislation as an incentive for participation. Shifting focus now on the question how mayors initially heard about the MCPA, it becomes obvious, that the network effects that came out of the statistical analysis as one of the main 146 finding, indeed play an important role for mayors. Nearly half of all respondents first came in touch with the initiative through the Conference of Mayors (actual attendance of conferences or through the newsletter), the National League of Cities or other local mayor’s networks. Local and national media as well as direct contact to citizens or political entrepreneurs (Commissioners, the Sierra Club) were also mentioned as bringing the MCPA to the mayor’s attention. The mayors’ answers as to why the agreement spread so quickly are overwhelmingly based on the opinion that the climate change topic recived increased attention in the public and the media. This greater awareness is in the mayors’ opinion linked with the aforementioned inability of the federal government to act and the threat of rising fossil fuel prices, which again lead to more media attention and hence gave feedback to rising public concerns about the climate change topic. Mayor Weinzapfel of Evansville, IN notes the predominant view in his answer why the MCPA spread so quickly: ’National public focus on climate change and greenhouse gas emissions. Rising concerns about air quality and public health. Rising fossil fuel prices and international oil-related issues’. This shall only be completed by the statement of Schaumburg’s Mayor Larson who sees one of the main factors in the public’s ’realization that global warming is a real threat’. Besides the mayors of Rosemount, MN, who experienced opposition against his signature of the MCPA from ’a council member of a neighboring city’ and Alliance, OH, where opposition came from individuals of the community, no other mayor experienced opposition against joining the agreement. Concerning the influence of other cities on the city in question, mayors usually state their geographically closest neighbors alongside the next larger city in the region when asked about with which cities they have the closest ties. However, Larry Falkin, the Director of the city’s office of environmental quality in Cincinnati, OH27 , when asked about peers answered that Cincinnati benchmarks itself against, Cleveland, Pittsburgh, Indianapolis, Lexington and Louisville, which are all cities between 250.000 inhabitants and nearly 800.000 inhabitants located within about 250 miles. This supports the argument that cities see peers within their similar size group or those larger. 27 Since Cincinnati was also part of the U.S. sample for which I conducted interview, they were asked whether they want to fill out a questionnaire or conduct an interview and they decided for the interview. Therefore, information on Cincinnati emanates from an interview asking all questions on the questionnaire and a few more. Testing Participation in Space and Time 147 The notion of policy entrepreneurship of cities and how it might pay off for the city can also be illustrated with the city of Cincinnati in Ohio. Cincinnati has a long history of environmental leadership and had its first office for environmental management from the early 1990s. It signed the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement in June 2006. The answer to cooperations of Cincinnati in the realm of climate change policies is the following: ’We’ve been sort of contacted by a variety of other cities who are interested in different pieces of what we are doing. Columbus, Ohio, our capital city is one that we sort of coached quite a bit, because they are making some great strides there, but they are a little bit newer to the game than we are, and being our capital city they have a lot to do with how state politics happen so greening Columbus has some special advantages for us in terms of the state policies that it helps produce’. To conclude this brief overview of the qualitative evidence, it can be said that as expected, one overall motivation for a cities’ participation does not exist, but we can see indeed that the mayor as the decision-maker can also act as a policy entrepreneur and on its own agenda. This has served as a first analysis to uncover the temporal and spatial pattern in signing the MCPA. The following section provides suggestions for further research and concludes this paper. 4.6 Conclusion In this paper I examined the determinants of cities’ willingness to join the MCPA in cities over 10,000 inhabitants in seven Midwestern states. I developed arguments on how various factors influence local governments’ decision to voluntarily contribute to climate change mitigation efforts by joining the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. These factors were considered to be city-specific internal factors, external factors, and time-specific events. As far as internal factors are concerned, I have argued that there are specific determinants leading to a higher demand for voluntary climate change policies within the city, e.g. a higher percentage of voters supporting the Democratic Party, which then make governments more likely to participate in voluntary efforts. I further assumed that the initiative to join the MCPA may emanate from the supply side of local government. Here, the existence of a policy entrepreneur and a mayor-council form of government were considered to increase the propensity to participate. Interdependencies between cities were conceptualized as emanating from geographic linkages to other jurisdictions, peer group effects, as well as from participation in social networks. The consideration of certain time-specific events, such a mayoral election within the city, 148 complemented my theoretical framework. To test my claims, I have used a unique new data set on monthly signing behavior of 749 Midwestern cities from February 2005 to June 2010. The analysis has shown that to explain the participation of voluntary climate change initiatives, it does not suffice to look at city or local government characteristics only. While favorable conditions, such as a more liberal and well-educated populace as well as the existence of a policy entrepreneur, measured by former engagement in climate change policies, do increase the probability of an MCPA signature, other factors also have to be taken into account. I find that a city’s participation in social networks as well as the MCPA participation of cities within the same population group increases, whereas the joining of cities within the same income group decreases a city’s likelihood to participate. Although internal characteristics, such as the % of Democratic votes in the city or the human capital endowment, are also significantly related to a higher propensity to sign, the substantive effects of these variables are much smaller. As far as pivotal events are concerned, I find that the likelihood of participation significantly increases in the months leading up to a mayoral election in the city. Insights gained from this large-N study are further supported by qualitative evidence from the analysis of questionnaires. I have argued that the cities’ decision to join the voluntary climate change effort would depend on the participation of geographic neighbors, cities within the similar income or population group, as well as on the participation in social networks. Whereas the impact of networks that diffuse knowledge about the initiative and, thereby, increase participation by those cities, which are part of them, is one of the strongest findings in both the quantitative as well as the qualitative part of this analysis, the impact of neighboring cities is not found to be relevant for a city’s membership in the MCPA. This contradicts some of the findings of studies by Vasi (2006) and Krause (2011a), who both found a significant effect of neighbors on participation in voluntary climate change initiatives. On the county level, Brody et al. (2008) and Schaffer (2010) have also pointed to such interdependence based on geographical contiguity. A theoretically expected and substantively large influence for a cities’ decision to join emanates from whether cities that have a similar size have already joined. The finding from the statistical analysis that the population group seems to matter for participation in the MCPA was further backed by qualitative evidence suggesting that cities pay attention to what their peers (in terms of population size) do. In conjecture with the non-finding for the influence of geographical neighbors, future research might construct even more fine-grained geographic measures of influence that are contingent on population sizes and may account for asymmetric influences. This would allow small cities to Testing Participation in Space and Time 149 be influenced by geographically close small and large cities, whereas large cities would be only influenced by similar sized or larger cities. As highlighted above, a further notable finding that emerged out of the analysis is a persistently strong and significantly positive influence of a mayoral campaign in the city on MCPA participation. An assumption that could be tested in future research is whether this effect is conditional on demand. Given that there is demand for local climate change policies within the community, one could imagine that even a local government or mayor that is usually not an advocate of climate change policies might need to succumb to public demand and sign the MCPA to signal cooperation on the issue in the face of an upcoming election. Another extension deals with the possibility of structural breaks in the data that might have changed the process. To this end, one could look into more detail whether there was a structural difference between the process before and after the election of Barack Obama in November 2008. Many potential differences in the reasons for participation in the two time periods are thinkable. For example, whereas one might have expected more liberal and democratic localities to sign before this election as a sign of dissatisfaction with the Bush Administration, one might expect that with the new administration from 2009 onwards, local governments in areas with relatively high Republican votes would decide to sign on to the agreement in preparation for possible changes to national climate change policies. A further question that emerges from the observation of the hazard rate as well as from descriptive statistics on the adoption rates of groups of cities of different population size deals with the possible end of this process. The membership figures provided by the Mayor’s Climate Protection Center have only change by two new members from July to November 2010 nationwide. It is not clear whether the trend will continue to decline or whether we might see another rise in membership. One scenario could be that the national government continues to withhold nationally binding legislation, but offers generous financial incentives to local government. But how this impacts on the MCPA as a whole, i.e., whether it ceases to exist or is replaced by a new agreement, remains to be seen. Finally, future research should also consider the implementation of actual climate change policies as a consequence of this agreement in a large-N context. This would allow us to disentangle purely symbolic participation of cities from cases, where cities have actually made progress on the mitigation of GHG emission and have reduced their carbon footprint. 150 4.7 Appendix 4.7.1 Questionnaire Dear Mayor XX, My name is Lena Schaffer, I am a Research assistant and 3rd year PhD student in Political Economy at the Swiss Federal Institute of Technology (ETH) in Zurich, Switzerland. I am writing my PhD thesis on voluntary climate change commitments across U.S. cities and states with a special focus on the U.S. Mayors Climate Protection Agreement (US-MCPA). According to my records, your city is listed as being a participant in this agreement. As far as my research is concerned, I am interested in how action and commitment by actors at the local level spread across the United States, specifically in the Midwest, and how one can explain the dynamics behind this process. To be able to test specific theories of the diffusion of successful practices across time and space, I need the approximate date when you signed the US-MCPA. This is the primary reason why I am contacting you, and an estimate as close as possible to when the agreement was signed would be of great assistance to my research. Because of the limited number of cities in my study, your participation is extremely valuable. I am resending also the questionnaire on basic information about participation in the agreement, as well as a few questions about personal and city demographics. I know that you are very busy, however if you could find the time to fill this out it would be greatly appreciated. If you would be interested in knowing the results of my study, let me know and I would be happy to send them to you in an email as soon as they are available. If you have any further questions regarding this study, or would like additional information, please contact me at (202-559-0677) or via email at climateresearch@ethz.ch. Thank you very much in advance! Best regards, Lena Schaffer Testing Participation in Space and Time 151 Center for Comparative and International Studies (CIS) Institute for Environmental Decisions (IED) ETH Zürich Weinbergstrasse 11, WEC C18 8092 Zürich Switzerland Lena Schaffer Ph.D. Student +41 44 632 0261 schaffer@ir.gess.ethz.ch Questionnaire for the Research Project no. 20329 ETH-RDB “Voluntary Climate Change Initiatives in the United States: Testing Spatial Dependence in Participation” Lena Schaffer and Prof. Dr. Thomas Bernauer When did you / your city join the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement (MCPA)? Day Month Year How did you first hear about this initiative? Before signing, did you know of cities around you that had joined the initiative? If yes, could you name them? Comments: Seite 1/6 152 What were the main factors that influenced your decision to sign the agreement? Was your decision to sign the agreement influenced by any particular incentives offered by the initiative? If yes, could you identify them? Comments: Other than you personally, what people or groups (e.g. environmental NGO’s) within the community were involved in getting the initiative started in your city? Comments: Seite 2/6 Testing Participation in Space and Time 153 Did you encounter opposition against your plans to sign the initiative? If yes, which groups opposed this initiative? What were their main objections? Group Objections Comments: With which of the cities in your county / state do you have the closest ties? What would be the main reason(s)? Cities Reasons Comments Have you implemented any new practices / city resolutions since joining the MCPA? If yes, name and shortly describe 1-2 of the new practices / city resolutions. New Practices / City Resolutions Describe Seite 3/6 154 Initiative as a whole: In your opinion what were the most important factors that made this agreement spread so quickly during its first years? Are you a member in any other networks of mayors? If yes, name the one or two most important ones. Lastly Do you think that your decision to sign the agreement has a positive, negative or no effect on the public sentiment towards you presently? Positive effect No effect Negative effect Comments: Do you think that your decision to sign the agreement might have a positive, negative or no effect on your prospects for reelection? Positive effect No effect Negative effect Comments: Seite 4/6 Testing Participation in Space and Time 155 Personal and Demographic Information Age: How old are you? What is your marital status? Do you have children? What is your educational background? What is your profession? How long have you been in politics? How long / how many terms have you been a mayor of this city? In politics, do you consider yourself a Republican, a Democrat, an independent or of some other party? Republican Democrat Independent Other In economics, do you consider yourself a liberal or a conservative? Liberal Conservative neither Are you or have you been an active member within the U.S. conference of mayors, the National League of Cities or any other national or state level organization? If yes in what capacity? Seite 5/6 156 Is your city vulnerable to natural disasters such as hurricanes/floods/droughts/tornadoes or other natural disasters, and which? If yes: Has your city suffered from any major natural disaster during the last 5 years or since you became the mayor of the city? Seite 6/6 157 5 ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ Understanding the Mechanisms Leading to Cities’ Participation and Non-Participation in the MCPA Lena Maria Schaffer 5.1 Introduction The previous chapters of this dissertation on local climate change policies have continuously reduced their focus. Starting from a general overview of global climate change governance, I have then concentrated on subnational units within the U.S. and have tried to explain countylevel participation patterns in the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement as well as city-level diffusion effects of the initiative in a temporal setting. In these papers, mayors have been implicitly assumed to be the ones that make the decision to participate in the MCPA, but have not been explicitly asked for their reasons to participate or the reasons not to participate. How did they hear about the initiative, and when? Did they have personal motivations to act on the climate change issue or was there demand by citizens or industry to either participate in the effort or not? This chapter, therefore, provides three distinct contributions that relate to questions already raised in the two chapters on the MCPA. First, I finally open the black box of the decision-maker and ’let the mayors speak ’. I contrast the results obtained from my two quantitative large-N analyses in chapters 3 and 4 with empirical findings from semi-structured interviews. To that end, I have randomly selected 60 cities with more than 10,000 inhabitants, 30 of which are signatories and 30 of which have not signed the MCPA, from the pool of 2700 cities throughout the United States. Second, I focus on the unique circumstances of the initiative as a whole and its potential impact on climate change policies within the U.S. Third and most importantly, I further add to the literature on voluntary climate change policies by specifically asking about reasons for non-participation. If we conceptualize the MCPA as a voluntary agreement that 158 inflicts virtually no cost upon the city who signs it, the question is: why have not even more communities participated? Evidence from the interviews with decision-makers confirm some of the findings of chapters 3 and 4 and add relevant new insights. Furthermore, talking to the mayors shed some light on the question concerning the symbolic politics vs. genuine green activism debate discussed in chapter 4. A result that can also be confirmed is that mayors, who regularly attend national mayoral conferences, are more likely to sign voluntary agreements. One result that came out of the previous chapters and that is strongly supported by the interviews is that decision-makers in larger cities are more aware of the problem and are more likely to take action, whereas smaller towns care more about distinctly local problems that are ’where the rubber meets the road’ (Mayor Bush, Winter Spring, FL). A notable finding concerning the mayors, who have not signed, is that some of them actually see the initiative as a declaration without real effects and as nothing more than ’jumping on the climate change bandwagon as the road to political prosperity’ (Representative from Californian city). The chapter is organized as follows: I first introduce the research design of the study, highlighting how this study was conducted. In the analysis section, I then look at the assessments from the interviews with a focus on reasons for non-participation and contrast them with those for participation and with my earlier findings from the large-N studies. Finally, I briefly discuss mayors’ evaluations of the MCPA initiative as a whole and the effects it has had on national policy. 5.2 Research Design The collection of qualitative interview evidence for this empirical section involved different steps. The following paragraphs will deal with the sampling procedure, the preparation of the semistructured interviews and the actual interviews. 5.2.1 Sampling The target population for this last dissertation chapter are cities with over 10.000 inhabitants. From these 2.700, I have decided to draw a random sample of cities for which I would contact the mayors to gain more information on their MCPA participation or non-participation. This avoids bias on the side of the researcher in potentially selecting cases that are extreme or those known to the researcher (Schnell et al. 2008). However, as we have seen from chapter 3 and chapter ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ 159 4, MCPA non-participation is far more frequent than participation (23 %). Drawing a random sample would probably overrepresent cities that have not signed. Schnell et al. (2008) suggest the use of stratified random sampling in this case. I therefore added one strata (MCPA) along which the elements from the random sample were drawn.1 Since I targeted to conduct around 15-20 interviews, I drew a sample of 60 cities, 30 of which had signed the MCPA. This higher number of elements in the sample was needed to avoid resampling in case of non-response by the units. The final sample therefore included 60 cities throughout the U.S. The map in figure 5.1 depicts these 60 sampled cities and their distribution throughout the U.S.. Cities in the sample that have signed the MCPA are shown with red points, whereas those who are not members of the MCPA are in violet. We can see that the sampling is somehow representative of actual population concentrations with more cities having been sampled on the two coasts and in the Midwest compared to the less populous western states. From table 5.1 it can be seen that not each state was present in the sample. For example, Florida and California each had 8 cities in the sample, Texas and Illinois had 7, while there was no city from Wyoming in the sample. Figure 5.1: Random sample of 60 cities from 2700 cities according to their participatory status 5.2.2 Conduction of the Study The main part of the study was conducted in April and May of 2010. All the 60 cities belonging to the stratified random sample were then contacted via e-mail, informed about the study and 1 Stata 10’s sample command was used to execute the sampling. 160 Table 5.1: Distribution of states in the sample STATE No. % AL 2 3.3% CA 8 13.3% CO 2 3.3% FL 8 13.3% ID 1 1.7% IL 7 11.7% IN 1 1.7% KS 1 1.7% MA 1 1.7% MI 1 1.7% MO 1 1.7% NC 2 3.3% NE 1 1.7% NJ 2 3.3% NY 1 1.7% OH 3 5.0% OR 1 1.7% PA 3 5.0% SC 1 1.7% TN 1 1.7% TX 7 11.7% VA 1 1.7% WA 1 1.7% WI 3 5.0% Total 60 100.0% ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ 161 asked whether they would be willing to participate. A study information sheet (c.f. section 5.5.2) was sent along with the e-mail (c.f. section 5.5.1) and informed the mayors about the duration of the interview and stated that, if they would give their consent, the interview would be audio-recorded and used for an analysis. Furthermore, it also gave them the option to stay anonymous. After having sent out these first information sheet, we then contacted the cities via telephone a few days later to ask whether they had seen the mail and were willing to participate in the study.2 We managed to arrange 17 interviews with mayors and representatives, 7 of which had not signed the agreement and 10 who were participants in the MCPA. We heard back from 12 other cities that their mayor or representative did not want to participate in our study or was currently unavailable. The map in figure 5.2 now depicts those cities in which the mayor or a city representative were interviewed with a star. The questions for the interview firstly included personal characteristics of the mayors and secondly some city-specific questions. The third bloc of question then dealt exclusively with the MCPA. The interview sheet is presented in section 5.5.3. Finally, the interviews with the mayors from the sample were done via Voice over IP (Skype). According to Diekmann (2004) interviews over the phone generally do not differ from face-to-face interviews in terms of data quality. Figure 5.2: Interviewed cities from sample according to their participatory status 2 Research assistance by Gwen Tiernan is greatly acknowledged. 162 Table 5.2: List of Interviewees State City Name Ideology Size CA CA CA CO FL FL IL MI MO NE NJ OH PA TN TX TX WI Redding San Luis Obispo Santa Rosa Boulder Gulfport Winter Springs Normal Westland Saint Peters Fremont Princeton Cincinnati Hanover Ê Elizabethton Harker Heights McKinney Wisconsin Rapids Anonymous* Dave Romero Susan Gorin Matt Appelbaum* Mr. O’Reilley* John F. Bush Chris Koos William R. Wild Ron Darling* Robert Hartwig* Bernard P. Miller Larry Falkin* Ben Adams Anonymous* Ed Mullen Brian Loughmiller Mary Jo Carson Independent Republican Democrat n.a Apolitical Republican Independent Democrat Democrat n.a. Democrat n.a. Republican n.a. Republican Republican Independent 80865 44174 147959 94673 12527 31666 45386 86601 51381 25174 14203 331285 14535 13372 17308 54369 18435 Note: * indicates if city official instead of mayor was interviewed MCPA 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 0 ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ 163 5.3 Results The following part provides an overview of the interviews and leads through the different issues that mayors mentioned and that are especially relevant in view of the two previous dissertation papers. Throughout this section, I deliberately give the statements a close reading and let the mayors speak. Table 5.2.2 provides some information on the interview partners and the city. 5.3.1 Reasons for Non-Participation The reasons for non-participation are an understudied area within local climate change policies. Therefore, this research makes a substantial contribution to the existing literature. In the following two paragraphs, I will first consider the two main reasons for non-participation in the agreement that emerged out of the interview. First, mayors either do not see the need to do something at this point in time and prioritize other issue (supply side), or second, they stress that there simply is no demand for climate change policies within the community (demand side). Some mayors that have not signed the agreement stress that although there is no opposition against climate change policies and the MCPA in their communities, these policies were not identified as having a high priority on the city’s agenda. Mayor Carson (Wisconsin Rapids, WI) stated that there were no community factors due to the presence of which she would not have signed the agreement. Instead, ’it was just the case of having too much on my plate with economic development to get it done. [. . . ] So it was just about timing’. Mayor Bush (Winter Springs, FL) emphasized the priorities of local government more metaphorically: ’Well, it’s just not the priority of our commission. I mean, you gotta realize at the city level, we’re involved where the rubber meets the road, the police department, the fire department, the water, the roads, the sewers, that’s what we do’. He further emphasized that ’[p]eople at the local level are interested in their taxes and their safety. And they don’t think it’s the city’s responsibility to worry about climate change’. Chapter 4 hypothesized that a city’s likelihood to sign the MCPA increases with a higher demand for climate change policies within the city. Robert Hartwig, the city administrator of Freemont, NE, when asked about the city’s reason for non-participation, confirms this in stating that ’there hasn’t really been a decision to sign or not to sign, but there is no real pressure from the community to sign’. One reason might be the lack of explicit demand. However, there are also cities in which such a signature might be very unpopular. Mayor Ed Mullen of Harker 164 Heights, TX went so far as to say that: ’If I did that [signing the MCPA], they would run me out of town’. However, he continued that this has only to do with the political issue of climate change. He claimed that: ’I have one of the largest recycling efforts in the central Texas area [. . . ], but I don’t do it necessarily for environmental reasons, I do it for economic reasons, because recycling reduces the costs of waste management’. A representative of a large Californian city mentioned that ’if he [the mayor] had signed it, it would have been in the newspaper and it would have a negative effect, the fact that he did not sign means that it had no effect’. He further clarified: ’So the idea of voluntarily joining an agreement like that is just not something a politician that wants to get elected would consider here’. It therefore seems that mayors are aware of their constituency’s position on the issue and act accordingly. 5.3.2 Reasons for Participation At a first glance, it can be observed that many mayors, who signed the agreement, declare that they want to improve the quality of life in their cities. Some mayors mentioned that their decision to participate does not depend on whether climate change is real or not. Rather, the goals and policy instruments that are suggested by the agreement have local co-benefits in the area of, e.g., public health. Republican Mayor Romero (San Luis Obispo, CA) stated that ’I believe many communities, whether or not they believe that global warming is caused primarily by man’s actions, will recognize that the actions proposed are good governance’. In a similar vein, the deputy director of the same city, Mrs. Murry argued that ’even if it [climate change] is a big hoax, this is still the right thing to do in terms of using less energy, making a better community, making it more walkable, all of those things, it’s just good practice’. Although many studies (Betsill 2001; Engel & Orbach 2008) have found that local co-benefits are an important issue to frame climate change policies on the local level, the question remains why communities would sign local climate change agreements in the first place if their primary reason is co-benefits. In chapter 4, I have argued that larger cities are more active in local climate change policies since they have a higher administrative capacity. However, another aspect of the size of a city was mentioned by Mayor Loughmiller (McKinney, TX), who relates an emerging awareness of green reasoning to population growth. McKinney has been the fastest growing city in the U.S. for three consecutive years and has grown from 20,000 in 1990 to around 55,000 in 2000. Latest estimates from the 2010 Census now see it at 126,000 inhabitants. With this dramatic development in mind, he provided the following example from his city: ’Obviously McKinney ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ 165 at 126,000 is different than when I moved here and it was only 19,000. You know, McKinney at 19,000, people really, I don t think you would have gotten a lot of support to participate in initiatives that were more nationally known or globally, having a global impact, because at that point you are a small town and everything is more focused just on your own little corner of the world. But as you grow and you become part, you know, we became part more of the Dallas Metropolitan area complex and we’re more involved in regional issues, like cities’ national groups, I think that s when you start to gain that awareness, so I think that’s probably a large part of it. I haven’t seen the list but I would guess that it probably started out with the larger cities and worked its way down to the smaller communities that were suburbs of these cities and so on’. This last observation by Mayor Loughmiller actually fits my large-N data on the adoption rates of different population groups in chapter 4. Whether this effect of size on participation is manifest also in this sample, one can take a look at table 5.2.2. We can see that the range of population sizes of cities that have signed goes from 12.527 until 331.285, whereas those for cities that have not signed goes from 13.372 until 80.865. This in itself does not seem to differ, especially for smaller cities, however, if we then exclude the cities that have especially favorable conditions, such as Princeton (highly educated population, much information about climate change, see the discussion below) and Gulfport (waterfront community, directly affected; see discussion below), we can see that the there is a tendency as also found within the two other papers, that size seems to matter for participation. A similar observation concerning city size came from Larry Falkin (Cincinnati, OH): ’The larger cities are the ones that are more likely to have professional staff involvement in national networks and awareness of the larger issues’. This statement pertains to the nexus between the administrative capacity of a city and its awareness of climate change policies but also hints to the importance of networks to spread information concerning new policies or solutions to given problems. Similar to the pattern in the Midwest questionnaires in chapter 4, a divide was observable along partisan lines. Democratic mayors tend to interpret their signature as a critique of the inaction of the federal government during the Bush Administration. For example, Mr. Falkin from Cincinnati, OH, not having indicated a party affiliation, stated: ’I think a lot of it was the federal government’s failure to exercise leadership. That you know really a lot of people thought climate protection should have been an issue where the main leadership should have come from Washington. And because during the Bush Administration the leadership was not coming from there, it was a good opportunity for people at the local level to sort of step up and in a way show 166 their disagreement with the national policies by establishing local policies’. Interestingly, the same logic may work in reverse for the Obama Administration’s effect on MCPA participation. A public official from the South justified the non-signing of the MCPA as resistance to ’leftwing international socialist pressure through our federal government’. In his view, this reflects a view frequently expressed by southern mayors, who still doubt the reality of climate change, seeing it more as a ’hullaballoo just to make some special interest groups or friends of some liberal politician rich at our expense’. In a similar vein, Mayor Mullen from Harker Heights, TX stated that: ’The agreement you’re speaking of, i.e., for the political piece, much of that is considered in Texas to be simply politics and propaganda and not accepted as a proof of science really’. Following from this, most of the non-signing mayors do not ascribe any real change in policy output to the signing of the agreement; instead they consider it as merely a symbolic act against the former government. I have already hinted at the discussion on the symbolic vs. substantive interest in signing the MCPA in the theoretical part of chapter 4. Mayors can use their participation in climate change initiatives to position themselves against the federal government or other cities’ in the area. With the climate change issue as a relatively new topic and a high coverage by national media, it is an attractive agenda issue for local governments (Krause 2011a). Media coverage increases the visibility and popularity of politicians not only among their own constituencies, but could also signal leadership and entrepreneurial capabilities for other offices that might be future career options for mayors. A representative from a large town in California stated on this topic that ’[signing] is absolutely a key to admission to move to a higher level politically. [. . . ]. [T]hey all have aspirations to go to the legislature or to some state commission like the California Energy Commission; and that’s part of their credentials to show how environmentally responsible they are’. Although the particular situation in California differs from the rest of country, we generally cannot dismiss the notion that there may be a lot of cities that did sign only to give a signal against the Bush Administration which brought them support from their constituencies, but did probably not result in direct policy output. I will briefly return to this discussion again below when talking about the initiative as a whole. While these were the main reasons that were mentioned by a majority of the mayors as influential for their decision (not) to join the MPCA, there were additional issues that came up in the interviews and that are relevant to this research. Therefore, the following section looks at each of these in turn. ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ 167 5.3.3 Further Issues In the previous two dissertation papers, it was stipulated – and supported by the statistical analyses – that the level of education matters for MCPA participation. This finding is also confirmed by mayors from university cities. Council member Matt Appelbaum (Boulder, CO) admitted that for enacting local climate change policies, ’it helps to have a community on board, Boulder is a University town, it’s a pretty liberal place. People get it’. Mayor Miller (Princeton Township, NJ) further pointed out the role that education and the position of a community has with respect to the reception and use of information about global warming: ’I think you probably have to make adjustments for the fact that Princeton is a university town, we have a very high percentage of residents in town that have undergrad and grad degrees. The university is engaged in a very, very strong sustainability program and we see that all the time, we work closely with the university in that area. And we are also in between two major metropolitan areas, New York and Philadelphia, we are about half way in between of them and there is a lot of information in the press you know from the major cities, and national press. Probably the most read newspaper here - other than local newspapers- is the New York Times’. Some support for the Nature argument, which I introduced in chapter 3.1, was provided by city manager O’Reilley (Gulfport, FL), who believes that the main reason for the mayor’s signature was that ’we’re on a waterfront community, so we’re very environmentally conscious’. The same holds true for Mayor Gorin (Santa Rosa, CA), who gave a similar reason for signing: ’Especially we have a number of roads, sea port, trains and housing developments that could be underwater in the next 50 years, so we are very concerned about that’. I now turn to evidence mentioned concerning the effects of networks and peers. Whereas many mayors (and increasingly those who signed) say that they either heard from the MCPA through the Conference of Mayors, or that they were active members, meaning that they also regularly attend conferences, only Mayor Wild of Westland, MI explicitly stressed the importance of the meetings for his participation. He stated that he had a background in recycling, but then ’when we were in Miami for the conference [the U.S. Conference of Mayors annual meeting 2008 in Miami] about two years ago, I really had a chance to see a lot of the initiatives that the city of Miami had implemented and I guess I was hooked at that point. I kind of saw what Miami was doing and realized that we could do that in our own city on a smaller level’. This confirms the importance of these network meetings as such but further hints to the peer effects. 168 The possibility of federal grant money for cities through the Energy Efficiency and Conservation Block Grant (EECBG) program was seen as a major incentive for cities to join the agreement in the previous paper. However, the effect of the EECBG introduction turned out to be statistically insignificant. An example from my sample is McKinney in Texas, that received 1 million $ out of this program. Mayor Loughmiller (McKinney, TX) links the success of obtaining federal money to participation in the MCPA. He stated: ’I think, really, the impact of being a participant in that is that a lot of the things cities do in this area are tied to grant opportunities as you’re developing your city, you know, you have more grant opportunities if you are doing development that is tied to environmentally friendly initiatives, so I think really the benefit of being a participant probably is more in the nature of - if you’re applying for a federal grant you are part of that pool of cities that have come on from a national standpoint and agreed to do things that fall within this initiatives’. The opinion that green policy entrepreneurship has an significant influence on people’s attitudes towards environmental politics is confirmed by Mr. Darling (Saint Peters, MO). He states that the local climate change initiatives were mostly initiated by Mayor Len Pagano, ’Our mayor is awful green. Meaning that he believes in green activities, for instance he drives a little moped-like motorcycle, he is very environmentally conscious’. He stresses the importance for local government to create positive incentives with regard to local climate change policies such as giving out rewards for people who recycle instead of penalizing those that fail to recycle. Concerning the reaction of the community to Mayor Pagano’s Green policies, he gives the following image: ’it s like feeding a hungry bear - you feed em more food and they want more food. You energize the people on incentives to recycling and now you have to take incentives to the higher level, and the higher level and the highest level in order to achieve the same amount, it s pretty greedy in that regard’. This underscores the importance that also the supply side of local government can have given there is a policy entrepreneur. Also, there is some indication that local industry has an influence on either facilitating or hindering the participation of cities. This relates to the hypothesis on abatement costs for local industry due to the city’s engagement in voluntary climate change policies. Mayor Adams (Hanover, PA), who has not yet signed the MCPA, admitts that ’I would probably say that there is an interest [for climate change policies] in the community. I would have to ask the local industry though’. Freemont in Nebraska, a city that has not signed the MCPA, has made a different experience with industry’s attitude towards local climate change policies. Mr. Hartwig ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ 169 (Freemont, NE) sees an emerging demand for green energy from the business side: ’A lot of businesses that come to the city these days are asking what we have in the way of renewable power, and can they participate in renewable energy credits and things like that. [This] is basically why we’ve been exploring the wind power and the solar power. We don’t want to do anything that would cause a business to say no to Freemont’. In a similar vein, Mayor Gorin (Santa Rosa, CA) sees an economic competitive advantage for cities if they engage in green policies: ’The business side, I emphasize it makes sense economically. We have positioned to our community and our county as this green hub and we are winning awards all over the place for innovative programs. So this is the way that we are going to solve our economic development challenges, by making sure that we nurture and recruit green businesses to come and locate in our community’. This concludes the discussion about the city and its main reasons to join and experiences with the MCPA. I now turn to the question about the success of the agreement as a whole and what mayors thought were the main reasons for the development of the MCPA. 5.3.4 Success of the Agreement as a Whole The question concerning explanations for the success of the MCPA as a whole is answered uniformly with reference to increased public and media attention to the topic of climate change. However, depending on whether a locality has signed or not, the answers concerning the effect of this agreement vary. Mayor Carson (Wisconsin Rapids), who is not an MCPA signatory, observed that ’a lot of cities signed on because it was the thing to do. It was the subject matter of many coffee klatsches [sic!]and many public meetings’. Republican Mayor Adams (Hanover, PA) points to the link between the public discourse and its effects: ’It’s an outcry that people are finally starting to care. Most definitely there has been a shift in people’s mindset’. Democrat Mayor Wild (Westland, MI) confirms this observation and states that ’global warming now is, it’s on TV, it’s in the newspapers, I mean it has become common, you know, the average household now understands global warming at least to some level, so I would think that recycling and the green agenda, it has become more mainstream now’. This change in people’s mindset lead some respondents to the assumption, that mayors sign the agreement to increase their probability of re-election. A Californian representative states that politicians assume that ’jumping on the climate change bandwagon is a path to political prosperity’. This, he mentioned, holds not only for direct public sentiment but also for financial support for campaigns by the ’well financed 170 and organized special interest group, this environmental activist group, that thinks very highly of these types of initiatives and plans and if you become associated with them you receive some benefits’. In contrast to this, a very consistent finding for mayors that signed the agreement is that most cities actually were engaged in climate-friendly policies before they joined the MCPA. Mr. Darling’s (Saint Peters, MO) comment is representative for many other mayors that stated that signing the agreement was just logical given their environmental record: ’I think the mayor signed that because he was saying, you know, I believe in that, we’re already doing these things, that assist in saving CO2 in the atmosphere [. . . ] so signing the agreement is essentially saying it’s not that we’re doing that, meaning that we will do it, but we’ve done that and it makes sense in that regard’. Mayor Koos (Normal, IL) expresses the same opinion: ’It was just about ratifying, those things that we were trying to do anyway and to join a larger group with a larger voice I thought was pretty important’. This leads him to the conclusion that ’the climate protection agreement is probably as much a declaration as anything. You know it is unifying of people making a statement of common cause and so I think it helps build awareness and I think it makes it a little easier for me to do in my community’. Therefore it seems that many mayors who signed the agreement take the global warming topic very seriously manifesting in already implemented policies they mention. For them, joining the MPCA is therefore seen as an essential step in fighting global climate change by joining a larger coalition that might have the potential to change things. However, they are aware of the fact that joining the MCPA without implementing green policies is just a symbolic gesture . Mayors who signed the agreement refute this view by showing a reflected and distinct evaluation about the range and the practices of the agreement. Council member Matt Appelbaum (Boulder, CO) hints at the usefulness of networks to learn about best-practices and about the notion of cities of cities as policy laboratories and mentions that ’we are a test bed for certain policies and programs, we’ll see how they work, other cities will pick up on some other things and we’ll learn some other things. This is what you have to do, you can be more innovative at the city level, because we are smaller. [. . . ]. And so, all of some technologies can transfer, the mechanisms and the programs don’t necessarily transfer, and that’s even true from state to state. Cause different states have different regulations, cities have different authorities, and states have public utility commissions that really separate structure’. He further emphasizes the limitation of an all-encompassing policy solution for all communities. In the opinion of Mayor ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ 171 Wild (Westland, MI) these different instruments and policies share the common denominator of being small and flexible: ’T]he one thing about it is that most of our green initiatives that we’ve been implemented, they’re not that hard. There are a lot of small things that you can do that when you add them together make a difference’. To conclude, in Matt Appelbaum’s (Boulder, CO) opinion, the motivation of the mayors to join the agreement does not matter as long as they join and expand the movement. He observes that ’some people may come out of the climate change or environmental issue, some perhaps come out of money issues, some perhaps come out of global political issues, but I think all of those together finally reached enough of a mass that people get it’. Through the participation of many mayors, the initiative gained and sustained momentum of public attention and helped to bring about a change in people’s mindset. The question about what impact it had on the federal government is dealt with in the following section. 5.3.5 Impact on the Federal Government Concerning the impact the initiative had on the federal level, the population of mayors who signed the agreement is in consent that the signature of the agreement sends a signal to the federal government. For example, Mrs. Murry (San Luis Obispo, CA) sees the signaling ’in terms of showing kind of a sea change or a grassroots movement of peoples believe. Having that come from a local level was kind of important to say ’You blowing it, federal government. You need to do something and you need to participate and you need to be willing to commit and we need levels of measures on the federal level, because the local level can only do so much, and so much of this comes from the federal level, or the state level”. Also Mayor Gorin (Santa Rosa, CA) sees the movement from a bottom-up perspective with the cities as driving forces, acknowledging that ’it’s really interesting that President Obama and so many others and even our own Governor, our leaders have acknowledged that these kind of actions start at the local level. And it is the mayors who are really moving forward. They get it, they understand the impacts for their communities and they understand how important it is, both from an economic development perspective as well as preparing our communities for whatever the future may hold for us, that we take these actions. [. . . ] It’s worldwide, think globally act locally and our county and our community truly believes this’. The assessment of cities that have signed the agreement is – on this issue – backed up by the peers that did not sign. A representative of a Californian city finds that the MCPA ’probably 172 has some effect on states and the national government to say there is more consensus on climate change so it is time to pass comprehensive legislation, that we try this at the national level too’. 5.4 Conclusion This last chapter served as a complement to the full-fledged analysis papers presented in the previous chapters. The qualitative paper delivered additional evidence that on the one hand can be taken as a validation of the former analysis and on the other might add meaningful insights into the different motivational forces of mayors in signing or not signing the MCPA. Further support could be gathered for some of the most influential structural factors for joining the MPCA: The average level of education in a city, the city size in terms of population, as well as its vulnerability to natural disasters clearly makes a difference for the likelihood to join. Mayors from either a university city, a big city or an especially vulnerable area name these factors as decisive influences to engage in policies against global warming and to sign the MCPA. The partisanship of mayors has played a role for Democrats during the Bush Administration and for Republicans to some extent since the election of President Obama. This might lend to the assumption that generally signing and not signing the agreement has the function of showing the dissatisfaction with the sitting administration. A new aspect that could be added to the overall framework through the analysis of the interviews was the differentiated look on the evaluation of the MCPA. Many of the mayors that have not signed view the whole endeavour as mere symbolic politics which possibly has an effect on the general public mood and the relevant political career but produces no significant climate change policy output. On the other hand, mayors who signed the agreement look at the topic from another angle: a predominant part of the mayors who signed started implementing green policies already before joining the initiative. They thereby indicate that they care about the threat of climate change or are generally interested in environmental politics. Their motivation to join the MPCA is twofold. First, they partly affirm the symbolic component critisized by the non-signer, presenting it in another light. They state the opinion that symbolic politics raise public awareness for the topic, which in turn increases public demand for these policies. Second, mayors join the MCPA because they are aware of the network effects that emerge in terms of exchanging information and experience with certain policy instruments. ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ 173 5.5 Appendix 5.5.1 Email Dear Mayor XX, My name is Lena Schaffer, I am a Research assistant and 3rd year PhD student in Political Economy at the Swiss Federal Institute of Technology (ETH) in Zurich, Switzerland. I am writing my PhD thesis on voluntary climate change commitments across U.S. cities and states with a special focus on the U.S. Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. I am contacting you because I am interested in conducting a brief informal interview with you. In order to improve confidence in my quantitative analysis, I am doing semi-structured research interviews with mayors and representatives of cities with over 10,000 inhabitants. I have randomly selected 30 out of all U.S. cities. Therefore the participation of every city, regardless of its stance on the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement, is very valuable for an in-depth understanding of voluntary climate change commitments. By taking part in a brief informal interview, which would take place over the course of the next 4 weeks, you would be providing us with valuable feedback and information. As far as my research is concerned, I am interested in how action and commitment by actors at the local level spread across the United States and how one can explain the dynamics behind this process. The main questions that I will be addressing are what makes local governments voluntarily implement certain policies, and which internal factors lead to the adoption of climate change mitigation initiatives. I have attached a letter of consent and further information about the procedure. If you would be willing to be interviewed, please let me know a date and time when I or a member of the research group can reach you, how you would like the interview to be conducted, and whether or not you would like to remain anonymous. One of us will be contacting you shortly, however if you have questions we can be reached by phone at 202-559-0677, or via e-mail (climateresearch@ethz.ch). Thank you very much in advance! Best regards, Lena Schaffer 174 5.5.2 Study Information Sheet ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ 175 Center for Comparative and International Studies (CIS) Institute for Environmental Decisions (IED) ETH Zürich Weinbergstrasse 11, WEC C18 8092 Zürich Switzerland To whom it may concern Lena Schaffer Ph.D. Student +41 44 632 0261 schaffer@ir.gess.ethz.ch Information Sheet for the Research Project no. 20329 ETH-RDB !"#$%&'()*+ ,$-.('/+ Change Initiatives in the United States: Testing Spatial Dependence in Participation! Lena Schaffer and Thomas Bernauer You are being asked to participate in a research study about if and how cities and other sub national units are involved in local policy measures with respect to global climate change. The specific focus of the study is the U.S. Mayors Climate Protection Agreement. The goal is to better understand the factors leading to participation or non-participation within this policy initiative. Participation in this study is voluntary. It will involve an interview of approximately 30-45 minutes in length and will be conducted over the phone. With your permission, the interview will be audio recorded to facilitate collection of information, and later transcribed for analysis. You will be asked questions regarding three broad areas: personal and demographic questions, questions about your city, and questions regarding your city's participation or non-participation in the MCPA. The only foreseeable discomfort associated with the study is the invasion of your privacy. You will not be paid for participation in this research. There are no direct benefits from participation in the study. However, this study may help explain innovations in local policy measures to address global warming and how these measures are adopted and implemented at the municipal level. You may refuse to participate or discontinue your involvement by advising the researcher at any time without penalty. You may choose to skip a question as well as decline to be audio taped. We will take notes or record your responses simply to ensure accuracy in our analyses. If you do not wish to be recorded, or would like your answers to be anonymous, please inform the researcher at the beginning of the interview. If you choose to be recorded, the tapes will be erased at the completion of the study. If you are a public official or have played a publicly visible role in your organization, your identity may be discernible in the reporting of this research. If you would like details that identify you to be omitted from reports developed from this interview data, please tell the researcher. All research data collected will be stored securely and confidentially in a locked office at ETH Zürich. Furthermore all material will be destroyed 12 months after the completion of the study. If you have any questions regarding this study, or would like additional information to assist you in reaching a decision about participation, please contact me at (202-559-0677) or via email at climateresearch@ethz.ch or !"#$%&'($))"*+,*%-"&&%".(/%'(% You can also contact my supervisor, Professor Thomas Bernauer at +41 44 632 64 66. Seite 1/1 176 5.5.3 Interview Template ’Where the Rubber Meets the Road’ Questions for Interviews with Mayors/ City representatives Lena Schaffer 1) Personal information o o o o o o o o o o o Age: How old are you? What is your marital status? Do you have children? What is your educational background? What is your profession? In politics, do you consider yourself a Republican, a Democrat, an independent or of some other party? (if other party, ask him/her to identify it) In economics, do you consider yourself a liberal or a conservative? How long have you been in politics? How long / how many terms have you been a mayor of this city? Are you or have you been an active member within the U.S. conference of mayors or the National League of Cities or any other national or state level organization? If yes in what capacity? Do you have any aspirations for a future political career beyond your present one at the county, state and/or national levels? 2) Information regarding your city (Name of city) has around (take population from dataset) inhabitants, what is the main sector of employment in your city? o What is the main source of revenue in your city? o o Is there a university / college in your town? What type of university / college is it? o Is your city vulnerable to natural disasters such as hurricanes/floods/droughts/tornadoes or other natural disasters? o if yes: Has your city suffered from any major natural disaster during the last 5 years or since you became the mayor of the city? o What are the three cities nearest to your city? o With which of the cities that you just mentioned do you have the closest ties? why? 3) MCPA Climate Information As you know, there exists an initiative called the Mayors Climate Protection Agreement (MCPA). Is (/ or has) your city (been) a member of this initiative? If more information is needed… (Seattle Mayor Greg Nickels launched this initiative in early 2005 to advance the goals of the Kyoto Protocol through leadership and action by American cities. After 141 cities had signed on to the agreement, it became an initiative under the umbrella of the US conference of Mayors. And since then, more than 1000 cities now have joined this agreement. “Strive to meet or beat the Kyoto Protocol targets in their own communities, through actions ranging from antisprawl land-use policies to urban forest restoration projects to public information campaigns”) 177 178 If Yes: How did you first hear about the initiative? When did you join the MCPA (month / year) If No: How did you first hear about the initiative? What were the main factors that influenced your decision to sign the agreement? PROBE: Any other reasons? What were the main factors that influenced your decision to not sign the agreement? PROBE: Any other reasons? Was your decision to sign the agreement influenced/affected by any particular/specific incentives offered by the initiative? If yes, could you identify them? Have you implemented any new practices / city resolutions since joining the MCPA? If yes, name 1-2 of the new practices / city resolutions. Do you know mayors around you that have joined the initiative? Other than you personally, what people or groups within the community were involved in getting the initiative started in your city? Do you know mayors around you that have joined the initiative? Initiative as a whole: In your opinion what were the most important factors that made this agreement spread so quickly during its first years? In your opinion what were the most important factors that made this agreement spread so quickly during its first years? In your opinion has the MCPA been successful in effectively addressing the climate change issue at the local level? In your opinion has the MCPA been successful in effectively addressing the climate change issue at the local level? In your opinion has (or could) the MCPA been successful in affecting the federal government's position on the climate change issue? In your opinion has (or could) the MCPA been successful in affecting the federal government's position on the climate change issue? Are you a member in any other networks of mayors? Lastly Do you think that your decision to sign the agreement has a positive, negative or no effect on the public sentiment towards you presently? Are you a member in other networks of mayors? Do you think that your decision to sign the agreement might have a positive, negative or no effect on your prospects for reelection? ! Do you think that your decision to not sign the agreement has a positive, negative or no effect on the public sentiment towards you presently? Do you think that your decision to not sign the agreement might have a positive, negative or no effect on your prospects for reelection? 179 Bibliography Adger, W. N. (2010), ‘Climate Change, Human Well-Being and Insecurity’, New Political Economy 15(2), 2–16. Aldy, J. (2005), ‘An Environmental Kuznets Curve Analysis of U.S. State-Level Carbon Dioxide Emissions’, The Journal of Environment & Development 14(1), 48–72. Allen, M. (2003), ‘Liability for Climate Change’, Nature 421(6926), 891–892. Allen, M., Frame, D., Frieler, K., Hare, W., Huntingford, C., Jones, C., Knutti, R., Lowe, J., Meinshausen, M. & Meinshausen, N. (2009), ‘The Exit Strategy’, Nature Reports Climate Change pp. 56–58. Anselin, L. (1988), Spatial Econometrics Methods and Models, Kluver Academic Publishers, Dordrecht etc. Anselin, L. (2004), Advances in Spatial Econometrics Methodology. Tools and Applications, Springer, Berlin. Baettig, M. B. & Bernauer, T. (2009), ‘National Institutions and Global Public Goods. Are Democracies More Cooperative in Climate Change Policy?’, International Organization 63(2). Baettig, M. B., Wild, M. & Imboden, D. (2007), ‘A Climate Change Index: Where Climate Change may be most prominent in the 21st Century’, Geophysical Research Letters 34, 1–6. Barrett, S. (2003), Environment and Statecraft. The Strategy of Environmental Treaty-making, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Baumol, W. J. & Oates, W. E. (1988), The Theory of Environmental Policy, Cambridge University Press. Baybeck, B. & Huckfeldt, R. (2002), ‘Urban Contexts, Spatially Dispersed Networks, and the Diffusion of Political Information’, Political Geography 21(2), 195–220. 180 Beck, N., Gleditsch, K. S. & Beardsley, K. (2006), ‘Space is More than Geography: Using Spatial Econometrics in the Study of Political Economy’, International Studies Quarterly 50(1), 27– 44. Beck, N., Katz, J. & Tucker, R. (1998), ‘Taking Time seriously: Time-series-cross-section Analysis with a binary Dependent Variable’, American Journal of Political Science 42(4), 1260– 1288. Bernauer, T., Kalbhenn, A., Koubi, V. & Spilker, G. (2010), ‘A Comparison of International and Domestic Sources of Global Governance Dynamics’, British Journal of Political Science 40(03), 509–538. Bernauer, T. & Koubi, V. (2009), ‘Effects of Political Institutions on Air Quality’, Ecological Economics 68(5), 1355–1365. Bernauer, T., Koubi, V., Kalbhenn, A. & Ruoff, G. (2010), Climate Change, Economic Growth, and Conflict, in ‘Climate Change and Security’, Trondheim, Norway. Bernauer, T. & Schaffer, L. M. (2010), ‘Climate Change Governance’, CIS Working Paper 60, 1–29. Beron, K. J., Murdoch, J. C. & Vijverberg, W. P. M. (2003), ‘Why Cooperate? Public Goods, Economic Power, and the Montreal Protocol’, Review of Economics and Statistics 85(2), 286– 297. Berry, F. & Berry, W. (1999), Innovation and Diffusion Models in Policy Research, in P. A. Sabatier, ed., ‘Theories of the Policy Process’, Westview Press, pp. 169–200. Berry, F. S. & Berry, W. D. (1990), ‘State Lottery Adoptions as Policy Innovations: An Event History Analysis’, The American Political Science Review 84(2), 395–415. Berry, W. D. & Baybeck, B. (2005), ‘Using Geographic Information Systems to Study Interstate Competition’, American Political Science Review 99(04), 505–519. Betsill, M. (2000), ‘Localizing Global Climate Change: Controlling Greenhouse Gas Emissions in U.S. Cities’, Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs (BCSIA) Discussion Paper 2000-20, 1–52. 181 Betsill, M. & Bulkeley, H. (2006), ‘Cities and the Multilevel Governance of Global Climate Change’, Global Governance 12(2), 141–159. Betsill, M. M. (2001), ‘Mitigating Climate Change in US Cities: Opportunities and Obstacles’, Local Environment 6(4), 393–406. Betsill, M. M. & Bulkeley, H. (2004), ‘Transnational Networks and Global Environmental Governance: The Cities for Climate Protection Program’, International Studies Quarterly 48(2), 471–493. Boehmke, F. J. & Witmer, R. (2004), ‘Disentangling Diffusion: The Effects of Social Learning and Economic Competition on State Policy Innovation and Expansion’, Political Research Quarterly 57(1), 39–51. Boehringer, C. & Helm, C. (2008), ‘On the Fair Division of Greenhouse Gas Abatement Cost’, Resource and Energy Economics 30(2), 260–276. Boehringer, C. & Jochem, P. (2007), ‘Measuring the immeasurable. A Survey of sustainability Indices’, Ecological Economics . Box-Steffensmeier, J. & Jones, B. (2004), Event History Modeling: A Guide for Social Scientists, Cambridge University Press. Boykoff, M. (2007), ‘Flogging a Dead Norm? Newspaper Coverage of anthropogenic Climate Change in the United States and United Kingdom from 2003 to 2006’, Area 39(4), 470–481. Braun, D. & Gilardi, F. (2006), ‘Taking Galton’s Problem Seriously. Towards a Theory of Policy Diffusion’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 18(3), 298. Brody, S., Zahran, S., Grove, H. & Arnold, V. (2008), ‘A Spatial Analysis of Local Climate Change Policy in the United States: Risk, Stress and Opportunity’, Landscape and Urban Planning 87, 33–41. Brueckner, J. K. (2003), ‘Strategic Interaction Among Governments: An Overview of Empirical Studies’, International Regional Science Review 26(2), 175–188. Buchinsky, M. (1998), ‘Recent Advances in Quantile Regression Models. A Practical Guideline for Empirical Research’, Journal of Human Resources 33(1), 88–126. 182 Buhaug, H., Gleditsch, N. P. & Theisen, O. M. (2008), Implications of Climate Change for Armed Conflict, in ‘Social Dimensions of Climate Change’, The World Bank, Washington, D.C., pp. 5–6. World Bank Workshop on the Social Dimensions of Climate Change, The World Bank, Washington. Burke, M. B., Miguel, E., Satyanath, S., Dykema, J. A. & Lobell, D. B. (2009), ‘Warming increases the Risk of Civil War in Africa’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 106(49), 20670–74. Buttel, F. H. (1979), ‘Age and Environmental Concern: A Multivariate Analysis’, Youth and Society 10(3), 237–56. Carter, D. & Signorino, C. (2010), ‘Back to the future: Modeling Time Dependence in Binary Data’, Political Analysis . Climate Analysis Indicators Tool (CAIT US) version 4.0. (2010). Cline, W. R. (1999), Discounting for the very Long Term, in P. R. Portney & J. P. Weyant, eds, ‘Discounting and intergenerational equity’, Resources for the Future, Washington, pp. 131– 140. Collier, P. (2010), The Plundered Planet: Why We Must and How We Can Manage Nature for Global Prosperity, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Congleton, R. D. (1992), ‘Political Institutions and Pollution Control’, The Review of Economics and Statistics 74(3), 412–421. Cornes, R. & Sandler, T. (1996), The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods, second edn, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Daley, D. M. & Garand, J. C. (2005), ‘Horizontal Diffusion, Vertical Diffusion, and Internal Pressure in State Environmental Policymaking, 1989-1998’, American Politics Research 33(5), 615–644. Dasgupta, S., Laplante, B., Wang, H. & Wheeler, D. (2002), ‘Confronting the Environmental Kuznets Curve’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(1), 147–168. Davis, M. L. & Hayes, K. (1993), ‘The Demand for Good Government’, The Review of Economics and Statistics 75(1), 148–152. 183 de Bruyn, S. M. & Heintz, R. J. (1998), The Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis, in ‘Handbook of Environmental Economics’, Blackwell Publishing, Oxford. Dell, M., Jones, B. F. & Olken, B. A. (2008), ‘Climate Shocks and Economic Growth: Evidence from the last half Century’, NBER Working Paper 14132. Dellink, R., Elzen, M., Aiking, H., Bergsma, E., Berkhout, F., Dekker, T. & Gupta, J. (2009), ‘Sharing the Burden of Financing Adaptation to Climate Change’, Global Environmental Change 19(2009), 411–21. Den Elzen, M. G. J., Schaeffer, M. & Lucas, P. L. (2005), ‘Differentiating Future Commitments on the Basis of Countries’ relative historical Responsibility for Climate Change. Uncertainties in the ’Brazilian Proposal’ in the Context of a Policy Implementation’, Climatic Change 71(3), 277–301. Diekmann, A. (2004), Empirische Sozialforschung, Vol. 11, Rowohlt. Dinda, S. (2004), ‘Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis. A Survey’, Ecological Economics 49(4), 431–455. Dunlap, R. E. & Mertig, A. G. (1992), American Environmentalism. The US Environmental Movement, 1970-1990, Crane Russak & Co. Economist (2010), ‘Let it be - The Democrats abondon their Efforts to limit Emissions through legislation’, Economist . Engel, K. (2009), ‘Whither Subnational Climate Change Initiatives in the Wake of Federal Climate Legislation?’, Publius: The Journal of Federalism 39(3), 432. Engel, K. & Orbach, B. Y. (2008), ‘Micro-Motives and State and Local Climate Change Initiatives’, Harvard Law & Policy Review 2, 119–137. Feiock, R. C., Jeong, M. G. & Kim, J. (2003), ‘Credible commitment and Council-Manager Government. Implications for Policy Instrument Choices’, Public Administration Review 63(5), 616–625. Fisher, D. R. (2006), ‘Bringing the Material back in. Understanding the U.S. Position on Climate Change’, Sociological Forum 21(3), 467–494. 184 Franzese, R. J. & Hays, J. C. (2006), ‘Strategic Interaction among EU Governments in Active Labor Market Policy-making: Subsidiarity and Policy Coordination under the European Employment Strategy’, European Union Politics 7(2), 167–189. Franzese, R. J. & Hays, J. C. (2007), ‘Spatial Econometric Models of Cross-Sectional Interdependence in Political Science Panel and Time-Series-Cross-Section Data’, Political Analysis 15(2), 140–164. Franzese, R. J. & Hays, J. C. (2008a), Empirical Models of Spatial Interdependence, in ‘Oxford Handbook of Political Methodology,’, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Franzese, R. J. & Hays, J. C. (2008b), ‘Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory, Empirics, Substance’, Comparative Political Studies 41(4-5), 742–780. Fredriksson, P. G. & Millimet, D. L. (2002), ‘Strategic Interaction and the Determination of Environmental Policy across US States’, Journal of Urban Economics 51(1), 101–122. Fredriksson, P. G. & Millimet, D. L. (2004a), ‘Comparative Politics and Environmental Taxation’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 48(1), 705–722. Fredriksson, P. G. & Millimet, D. L. (2004b), ‘Electoral Rules and Environmental Policy’, Economics Letters 84(2), 237–244. Freudenberg, M. (2003), ‘Composite Indicators of Country Performance: A Critical Assessment’, OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 16, 1–34. Fuessel, H. M. (2010), ‘Modeling Impacts and Adaptation in Global IAMs’, Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Climate Change 1(March/April), 288–303. Galeotti, M., Lanza, A. & Pauli, F. (2006), ‘Reassessing the Environmental Kuznets Curve for CO2 Emissions: A Robustness Exercise’, Ecological Economics 57(1), 152–163. Germanwatch (2010), ‘Klimaschutzindex 2010’, accessed at www.germanwatch.org/ksi . Gilardi, F. (2010), ‘Who Learns from What in Policy Diffusion Processes?’, American Journal of Political Science 54(3), 650–666. Glaeser, E. & Kahn, M. (2010), ‘The Greenness of Cities: Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Urban Development’, Journal of Urban Economics 67(3), 404–418. 185 Gleditsch, K. S. (2002), All International Politics is Local. The Diffusion of Conflict, Integration, and Democratization, University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor. Gleditsch, K. S. & Ward, M. D. (2001), ‘Measuring Space: A Minimum-Distance Database and Applications to International Studies’, Journal of Peace Research 38(6), 739–758. Gore, C. (2010), ‘The Limits and Opportunities of Networks: Municipalities and Canadian Climate Change Policy’, Review of Policy Research 27(1), 27–46. Gray, V. (1973), ‘Innovation in the States: A Diffusion Study’, American Political Science Review 67(4), 1174–1185. Greene, W. H. (2003), Econometric Analysis, fifth edn, Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River. Grossman, G. M. & Krueger, A. B. (1995), ‘Economic Growth and the Environment’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics . Gurney, K. R., Mendoza, D. L., Zhou, Y., Fischer, M. L., Miller, C. C., Geethakumar, S. & de la Rue du Can, S. (2009), ‘High Resolution Fossil Fuel Combustion CO2 Emission Fluxes for the United States’, Environmental Science & Technology 43(14), 5535–5541. Hainmueller, J. & Hiscox, M. (2006), ‘Learning to Love Globalization: Education and Individual Attitudes toward International Trade’, International Organization 60(02), 469–498. Hao, L. & Naiman, D. Q. (2007), Quantile Regression, Sage Publications, Inc. Hardin, G. (1968), ‘The Tragedy of the Commons’, Science 162, 1243–1248. Hayhoe, K., VanDorn, J., Wuebbles, D., Cherkauer, K., Schlegal, N. & Vavrus, S. (2009), ‘Regional Climate Change Projections for Chicago and the Great Lakes’, Journal of Great Lakes Research . Hays, J. C. (2009), Globalization and the New Politics of Embedded Liberalism, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Hill, R. J. & Magnani, E. (2002), ‘An Exploration of the Conceptual and Empirical Basis of the Environmental Kuznets Curve’, Australian Economic Papers 41(2), 239–254. Holtz-Eakin, D. & Selden, T. (1995), ‘Stoking the Fires? CO2 Emissions and Economic Growth’, Journal of Public Economics 57(1), 85–101. 186 Hornback, K. E. (1974), ‘Orbits of Opinion: The Role of Age in the Environmental Movement’s Attentive Public’, Unpublished PhD dissertation, Department of Sociology, Michigan State . Huang, W., Lee, G. & Wu, C. (2008), ‘GHG Emissions, GDP Growth and the Kyoto Protocol: A Revisit of Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis’, Energy Policy 36(1), 239–247. ICPSR (1984), ‘Higher education general information survey (hegis) xviii: Institutional characteristics of colleges and universities,1983-1984’. ICPSR (2008), ‘County characteristics, 2000-2007 [united states]’. Institute, Hazards & Vulnerability Research (2009), ‘The spatial hazard events and losses database for the united states, version 7.0 [online database].’. IPCC (2007a), Climate Change 2007: The Physical Science Basis; Summary for Policymakers, IPCC, Geneva. IPCC (2007b), Summary for policymakers, in M. Parry, O. Canziani, J. Palutikof, P. van der Linden & C. Hanson, eds, ‘Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaption and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Forth Assessment Report of the Intergovernemental Panel on Climate Change’, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 7–22. Jacobson, M. Z. (2010), ‘Enhancement of Local Air Pollution by Urban CO2 Domes’, Environmental Science & Technology 44(7), 2497–2502. Jaenicke, M. (2005), ‘Trend Setters in Environmental Policy: The Character and Role of Pioneer Countries’, European Environment 15(2), 129–142. Jahn, D. (2006), ‘Globalization as the Missing Link in the Analysis of Diffusion Patterns in Welfare State Development’, International Organization 60(02), 401–431. Johnson, S. (2009), ‘Climate Change and Global Justice: Crafting Fair Solutions for Nations and Peoples’, Harvard Environmental Law Review 33, 297–301. Kafalenos, R. S., Leonard, K. J., Beagan, D. M., Burkett, V. R., Keim, B. D., Meyers, A., Hunt, D. T., Hyman, R. C., Maynard, M. K. & Fritsche, B. (2008), What are the Implications of Climate Change and Variability for Gulf Coast Transportation, in M. Savonis, V. Burkett & J. Potter, eds, ‘Impacts of Climate Change and Variability on Transportation Systems and 187 Infrastructure: Gulf Coast Study, Phase I’, U.S. Department of Transportation, Washington, pp. 4–1–4F–27 (104). Kahn, M. (2006), Green Cities: Urban Growth and the Environment, Cambridge University Press. Kamal-Chaoui, L. & Robert, A. (2009), ‘Competitive Cities and Climate Change’, OECD Regional Development Working Papers . Karl, T. R., Melillo, J. M. & Peterson, T. C. (2009), Global Climate Change Impacts in the United States, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Kellstedt, P., Zahran, S. & Vedlitz, A. (2008), ‘Personal Efficacy, the Information Environment, and Attitudes toward Global Warming and Climate Change in the United States’, Risk Analysis 28(1), 113–126. Kern, K. & Gotelind, A. (2009), Governing Climate Change in Cities: Modes of Urban Climate Governance in Multi-level Systems, in ‘ed.) OECD, OECD Conference Proceedings, Paris, pp. 171’. Klinsky, S. & Dowlatabadi, H. (2009), ‘Conceptualizations of Justice in Climate Policy’, Climate Policy 9(1), 88–108. Kluger, J. (2006), ‘Global Warming Heats Up’, Time Magazine . Knuth, S., Nagle, B., Steuer, C. & Yarnal, B. (2007), ‘Universities and Climate Change Mitigation: Advancing Grassroots Climate Policy in the US’, Local Environment 12(5), 485–504. Koenker, R. & Bassett, G. (1982), ‘Robust Tests for Heteroscedasticity Based on Regression Quantiles’, Econometrica 50(1). Kolstad, C. (1996), ‘Learning and Stock Effects in Environmental Regulation: The Case of Greenhouse Gas Emissions’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 31(1), 1– 18. Konisky, D. M. (2007), ‘Regulatory Competition and Environmental Enforcement: Is There a Race to the Bottom?’, American Journal of Political Science 51(4), 853–872. Kousky, C. & Schneider, S. H. (2003), ‘Global Climate Policy: Will Cities Lead the Way?’, Climate Policy 3(4), 359–372. 188 Krause, R. (2011a), ‘Policy Innovation, Intergovernmental Relations, and the Adoption of Climate Protection Initiatives by US Cities’, Journal of Urban Affairs 30(1), 45–60. Krause, R. (2011b), ‘Symbolic or Substantive Policy? Measuring the Extent of Local Commitment to Climate Protection’, Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 29(1), 46– 62. Kwon, M., Berry, F. & Feiock, R. (2009), ‘Understanding the Adoption and Timing of Economic Development Strategies in US Cities using Innovation and Institutional Analysis’, Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory . Lee, T. (2009a), Global City and Climate Change Networks, in ‘Annual Meeting of the International Studies Association (ISA)’, New York. Lee, T. (2009b), ‘Why Do Cities Participate (or not) in the Global Climate Change Network(s)?’, Paper presented at the ISA’s 50th Annual Convention, New York . Leitner, H. & Sheppard, E. (2002), ‘”The City is Dead, Long Live the Net”: Harnessing European Interurban Networks for a Neoliberal Agenda’, Antipode 34(3), 495–518. Lempert, R., Scheffran, J. & Sprinz, D. (2009), ‘Methods for Long-Term Environmental Policy Challenges PolicyChallenges’, Global Environmental Politics 9(3), 106–133. Levinson, A. (2003), ‘Environmental Regulatory Competition: A Status Report and Some New Evident’, National Tax Journal 56, 91–106. Levy, J. T. (2007), ‘Federalism, Liberalism, and the Separation of Loyalties’, American Political Science Review 101(03), 459–477. Li, Q. & Reuveny, R. (2006), ‘Democracy and Environmental Degradation’, International Studies Quarterly 50, 935–956. Lindseth, G. (2004), ‘The Cities for Climate Protection Campaign (CCPC) and the Framing of Local Climate Policy’, Local Environment 9(4), 325–336. List, J. A., Millimet, D. L., Fredriksson, P. G. & McHone, W. W. (2003), ‘Effects of Environmental Regulations on Manufacturing Plant Births: Evidence from a Propensity Score Matching Estimator’, Review of Economics and Statistics 85(4), 944–952. 189 Long, J. S. (1997), Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables, Sage Publications, Inc. Lubell, M., Feiock, R. & De La Cruz, E. (2009), ‘Local Institutions and the Politics of Urban Growth’, American Journal of Political Science 53(3), 649–665. Lutsey, N. & Sperling, D. (2008), ‘America’s Bottom-up Climate Change Mitigation Policy’, Energy Policy 36(2), 673–685. Maddala, G. S. (2001), Introduction to Econometrics, 3. edn, Wiley, Chichester. Manski, C. F. (1993), ‘Identification of Endogenous Social Effects: The Reflection Problem’, The Review of Economic Studies 60(3), 531–542. Mayors Climate Protection Center (2007), ‘Block Grant Legislative Updates’, http://www.usmayors.org/climateprotection/EEBG.htm . Mendelsohn, R. (2001), Global Warming and the American Economy: A Regional Assessment of Climate Change Impacts, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. Meyer, S. M. (1995), ‘The Economic Impact of Environmental Regulation’, Journal of Environmental Law and Practise 3, 4–15. Meyer, S. M. & Konisky, D. M. (2007), ‘Adopting Local Environmental Institutions: Environmental Need and Economic Constraints’, Political Research Quarterly 60(1), 3–16. Midlarsky, M. I. (1998), ‘Democracy and the Environment: An Empirical Assessment’, Journal of Peace Research 35(3), 341–361. Miguel, E., Satyanath, S. & Sergenti, E. (2004), ‘Economic Shocks and Civil Conflict: An Instrumental Variables Approach’, Journal of Political Economy 112(4), 725–753. Millimet, D. L. (2003), ‘Assessing the Empirical Impact of Environmental Federalism’, Journal of Regional Science 43(4), 711–733. Millimet, D. L., Fredriksson, P. G. & List, J. A. (2002), Strategic Competition in Environmental and Fiscal Policies: Theory and Evidence from the United States, Kluwer Academic Publishers. 190 Mintrom, M. (1997), ‘Policy Entrepreneurs and the Diffusion of Innovation’, American Journal of Political Science 41(3), 738–770. Mitchell, R. B. (2006), ‘Problem Structure, Institutional Design, and the Relative Effectiveness of International Environmental Agreements’, Global Environmental Politics 6(3), 72–89. Molotch, H. (1976), ‘The City as a Growth Machine: Toward a Political Economy of Place’, American Journal of Sociology 82(2), 309. Mooney, C. & Lee, M. (1995), ‘Legislative Morality in the American States: The Case of Pre-Roe Abortion Regulation Reform’, American Journal of Political Science 39(3), 599–627. Mueller, D. C. (2003), Public Choice III, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. National Atlas of the United States (2004), ‘Cities and towns of the united states: National atlas of the united states’. Neumayer, E. (2002a), ‘Can Natural Factors Explain any Cross-Country Differences in Carbon Dioxide Emissions?’, Energy Policy 30(1), 7–12. Neumayer, E. (2002b), ‘Do Democracies Exhibit Stronger International Environmental Commitment? A Cross-country Analysis’, Journal of Peace Research 39(2), 139–164. Nicholson-Crotty, S. (2009), ‘The Politics of Diffusion: Public Policy in the American States’, The Journal of Politics 71(01), 192–205. Nordhaus, W. (2010), ‘Economic Aspects of Global Warming in a Post-Copenhagen Environment’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 107(26), 11721. Oates, W. E. (1998), The Economics of Fiscal Federalism and Local Finance, Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. Oates, W. E. (2002), A Reconsideration of Environmental Federalism, in M. Kunce, S. Gerking, W. Morgan, J. A. List & A. de Zeeuw, eds, ‘Recent Advances in Environmental Economics’, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 1–32. Oates, W. E. & Schwab, R. M. (1988), ‘Economic Competition among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Enhancing or Distortion Inducing?’, Journal of Public Economics 35, 333–354. 191 O’Brien, R. M. (2007), ‘A Caution Regarding Rules of Thumb for Variance Inflation Factors’, Quality and Quantity 41(5), 673–690. O’Connor, R. E., Bord, R. J., Yarnal, B. & Wiefek, N. (2002), ‘Who Wants to Reduce Greenhouse Gas Emissions?’, Social Science Quarterly 83(1), 1–17. Olsen, M. (1971), Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Harvard University Press. Olson, M. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action, Cambridge University Press. Ostrom, E., Gardner, R. & Walker, J. (1994), Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources, University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor. Oye, K. & Maxwell, J. (1995), ‘Self-Interest and Environmental Management’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 6(4), 593. Pagoulatos, A., Goetz, S. J., Debertin, D. L. & Johannson, T. (2004), ‘Interactions Between Economic Growth and Environmental Quality in U.S. Counties’, Growth and Change 35(1), 90– 108. Paterson, M. (2001), Principles of Justice in the Context of Global Climate Change, in U. Luterbacher & D. F. Sprinz, eds, ‘International Relations and Global Climate Change’, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 119–126. Perrin, S. & Bernauer, T. (2010), ‘International Regime Formation Revisited: Explaining Ratification Behaviour with Respect to Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution Agreements in Europe’, European Union Politics 11(3), 405. Pew Center (2010), http://www.pewclimate.org/what s being done/in the states/ state action maps.cfm. Pluemper, T. & Neumayer, E. (2010), ‘Model Specification in the Analysis of Spatial Dependence’, European Journal of Political Research 49(3), 418–442. Posner, E. A. & Sunstein, C. R. (2007), ‘Climate Change Justice’, Georgetown Law Journal 96, 1565–1612. Potoski, M. & Woods, N. D. (2002), ‘Air Pollution Regulation in the United States’, Policy Studies Journal 30(2), 208–226. 192 Rabe, B. (2004), Statehouse and Greenhouse: The Emerging Politics of American Climate Change Policy, Brookings Institution Press. Rabe, B. (2008), ‘States on Steroids: The Intergovernmental Odyssey of American Climate Policy’, Review of Policy Research 25(2), 105–128. Rappaport, J. & Sachs, J. D. (2003), ‘The United States as a Coastal Nation’, Journal of Economic Growth 8(1), 5–46. Rincke, J. (2005), Policy Innovation in Local Jurisdictions: Testing the Neighborhood Influence Against the Free Riding Hypothesis, Zentrum fuer Europ. Wirtschaftsforschung. Ringquist, E. J. (1994), ‘Policy Influence and Policy Responsiveness in State Pollution Control’, Policy Studies Journal 22(1), 25–43. Rogelj, J., Nabel, J., Chen, C., Hare, W., Markmann, K., Meinshausen, M., Schaeffer, M., Macey, K. & Haehne, N. (2010), ‘Copenhagen Accord Pledges are Paltry’, Nature 464(7292), 1126–1128. Rogers, E. (1995), Diffusion of Innovations, Free Press, New York. Rouphail, N., Coelho, M. & Farias, T. (2006), ‘Effect of Roundabout Operations on Pollutant Emissions’. Sampei, Y. & Aoyagi-Usui, M. (2009), ‘Mass-media Coverage, its Influence on Public Awareness of Climate-change Issues, and Implications for Japan’s National Campaign to Reduce Greenhouse Gas’, Global Environmental Change . Sandler, T. (1997), Global Challenges an Approach to Environmental, Political, and Economic Problems, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge etc. Sattler, T. & Bernauer, T. (2011), ‘Gravitation or Discrimination? Determinants of Litigation in the World Trade Organisation’, European Journal of Political Research 50(2), 143–167. Schaffer, L. M. (2010), ‘Nature, Nurture, Or Neighbors? Testing Participation Patterns in Voluntary Initiatives in U.S. Counties’, Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Swiss Political Science Association, Geneva . Schnell, R., Hill, P. & Esser, E. (2008), Methoden der empirischen Sozialforschung, Oldenbourg Wissenschaftsverlag. 193 Schreurs, M. A. (2008), ‘From the Bottom Up: Local and Subnational Climate Change Politics’, The Journal of Environment & Development 17(4), 343. Schreurs, M. A. & Epstein, M. (2007), ‘Environmental Federalism in the United States and the Swing of the Pendulum from the Federal to the State Level’, AICGS Policy Report 31, 33–52. Schwartz, P. & Randall, D. (2003), ‘An Abrupt Climate Change Scenario and its Implications for United States National Security’, Prepared for the Department of Defense by the Global Business Network . Selin, H. & VanDeveer, S. (2007), ‘Political Science and Prediction: What’s Next for U.S. Climate Change Policy?’, Review of Policy Research 24(1), 1–27. Shipan, C. R. & Volden, C. (2006), ‘Bottom-Up Federalism: The Diffusion of Antismoking Policies from US Cities to States’, American Journal of Political Science 50(4), 825–843. Shipan, C. R. & Volden, C. (2008), ‘The Mechanisms of Policy Diffusion’, American Journal of Political Science 52(4), 840–857. Simmons, B. A. & Elkins, Z. (2004), ‘The Globalization of Liberalization: Policy Diffusion in the International Political Economy’, American Political Science Review 98(01), 171–189. Simmons, B., Dobbin, F. & Garrett, G. (2008), The Global Diffusion of Markets and Democracy, Cambridge University Press. Singh, R., Murty, H., Gupta, S. & Dikshit, A. (2009), ‘An Overview of Sustainability Assessment Methodologies’, Ecological indicators . Sprinz, D. & Vaahtoranta, T. (1994), ‘The Interest-based Explanation of International Environmental Policy’, International Organization 48(01), 77–105. Stavins, R. N. (2003), Experience with Market-based Environmental Policy Instruments, in K.G. Maeler & J. R. Vincent, eds, ‘Handbook of Environmental Economics’, Vol. 1, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 355–435. Stern, N. (2008), ‘The Economics of Climate Change’, American Economic Review 98(2), 1–37. Stern, N., Peters, S., Bakhshi, V., Bowen, A., Cameron, C., Catovsky, S., Crane, D., Cruickshank, S. & Dietz, S. (2006), ‘Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change’. 194 Tang, Z., Brody, S. D., Quinn, C., Chang, L. & Wei, T. (2010), ‘Moving from Agenda to Action: Evaluating Local Climate Change Action Plans’, Journal of Environmental Planning and Management 53(1), 41–62. Theisen, O., Holtermann, H. & Buhaug, H. (2010), ‘Drought, Political Exclusion, and Civil War’, Paper presented at International Studies Association Annual Convention, New Orleans . Theodori, G. L. & Luloff, A. E. (2002), ‘Position on Environmental Issues and Engagement in Proenvironmental Behaviors’, Society & Natural Resources 15(6), 471–482. Tobler, W. R. (1970), ‘A Computer Movie Simulating Urban Growth in the Detroit Region’, Economic geography 46, 234–240. Tol, R. S. J. & Yohe, G. W. (2006), ‘A Review of the Stern Review’, World Economics 7(4), 233– 250. Tomz, M., Wittenberg, J. & King, G. (2003), ‘CLARIFY: Software for interpreting and presenting statistical results’. Urpelainen, J. (2009), ‘Explaining the Schwarzenegger Phenomenon: Local Frontrunners in Climate Policy’, Global Environmental Politics 9(3), 1–24. Vanderheiden, S. (2008), Atmospheric Justice: A Political Theory of Climate Change, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Vasi, I. (2006), ‘Organizational Environments, Framing Processes, and the Diffusion of the Program to Address Global Climate Change Among Local Governments in the United States’, Sociological Forum 21, 439–466. Volden, C. (2006), ‘States as Policy Laboratories: Emulating Success in the Childrens Health Insurance Program’, American Journal of Political Science 50, 294–312. Volden, C. (2007), ‘Intergovernmental Grants: A Formal Model of Interrelated National and Subnational Political Decisions’, Publius: The Journal of Federalism 37(2), 209. Von Stein, J. (2008), ‘The International Law and Politics of Climate Change: Ratification of the United Nations Framework Convention and the Kyoto Protocol’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 52(2), 243. 195 Walker, J. L. (1969), ‘The Diffusion of Innovations among the American States’, American Political Science Review 63(3), 880–899. Walsh, B. (2008), ‘Wind Shift’, Time Magazine . Ward, H. (2008), ‘Liberal Democracy and Sustainability’, Environmental Politics 17(3), 386– 409. Ward, M. & Gleditsch, K. S. (2008), Spatial Regression Models, Sage Publications, Los Angeles. Warden, T. (2007), The Engagement of U.S. Cities and the Global Warming Issue, 2005-2007, PhD thesis, University of California. Wasserman, S. & Faust, K. (1994), Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications, Cambridge University Press. Watson, R. (2009), The Interlinkage of Global Climate Change, Economy and Poverty, Technical report. White, H. (1980), ‘A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity’, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 48(4), 817– 838. Winkelmann, R. (2008), Econometric Analysis of Count Data, Springer Verlag. Wooldridge, J. M. (2009), Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, South Western Cengage Learning. Young, H. (2009), ‘Innovation Diffusion in Heterogeneous Populations: Contagion, Social Influence, and Social Learning’, The American Economic Review 99(5), 1899–1924. Zahran, S., Brody, S., Vedlitz, A. & Grover, H. (2008), ‘Vulnerability and Capacity: Explaining Local Commitment to Climate-Change Policy’, Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 26, 544–562. Zahran, S., Grover, H., Brody, S. & Vedlitz, A. (2008), ‘Risk, Stress, and Capacity: Explaining Metropolitan Commitment to Climate Protection’, Urban Affairs Review 43(4), 447–474.