CATEGORY ASSORTMENTS, STOCK LEVELS, AND MARGINS: A PARTIAL REPLICATION AND EXTENSION OF A RETAIL MODEL INTO A WHOLESALE CONTEXT Jack Cadeaux and Larry Lee University of New South Wales Track: Distribution and Logistics Issues in Marketing Abstract This is a study of cross-category effects of assortment variety on category performance in a cash-and-carry wholesale operation. In a retailing context, Chiang and Wilcox (1997) explored cross-category effects by examining 209 categories at a US supermarket and examined the relationships between category shelf-space allocation, variety, and retail margins. This study of 146 categories at an Australian cash and carry wholesaler partially replicates and extends Chiang and Wilcox’s analysis, by substituting stock level for space in adapting to the wholesale environment. It finds support for a general positive effect of assortment on stock level and on margin. Development of Theory and Hypotheses The decision on what to stock and how much to stock within a category is not trivial and has uncertain and potentially complex effects on performance for retailers and other merchants, such as wholesalers. There has been much research concerning the relationship of retail assortment variety to shelf-space allocation. More recent studies include those of Borin, Farris, and Freeland (1994); Borin and Farris (1995); and Chiang and Wilcox (1997). Recent research in this area has started to move away from a basic view of assortment variety as such and focused more on (1) the customer decision process for assortments (Fader and Hardie 1996; Broniarczyk, Hoyer, and McAlister 1998; McIntyre and Miller 1999; Koelemeijer and Oppewal 1999; Simonson 1999; Lee and Steckel 1999), (2) the effect of assortments on the competitive relationship across stores (Stassen, Mittelstaedt, and Mittelstaedt 1999; Grewal et al. 1999), and (3) assortment effects across categories in relation to performance (Chiang and Wilcox 1997; Cadeaux 1999). Cash-and-carry wholesaling is in some respects similar to (bricks and mortar) retailing. Some differences include the customers served and the minimal concern about in-store presentation of merchandise. Retailers sell to the ultimate consumer, whereas the cash-and carry wholesaler sells to retailers or other customers who use the products as ingredients or components of a final product that is then sold to consumers. Demand facing a wholesaler, derived from demand facing its customers, can be relatively volatile making performance particularly sensitive to assortment and stocking decisions. Chiang and Wilcox (1997) explored cross-category relationships between assortment variety, shelf-space allocation, and margins. They found that variety is negatively correlated with margin, and that there were lower relative margin percentages in categories where brand loyalty was high. This study replicates their study by also taking a cross-category focus on assortment variety and margin but extends it to the wholesale situation by substituting stock level for shelf-space ANZMAC 2003 Conference Proceedings Adelaide 1-3 December 2003 723 allocation and an indicator of manufacturer brand power for brand loyalty. We assume that these two variables are more applicable to the wholesaling industry. A simple definition of assortment is that it is the number of items in a merchandise category (Levy and Weitz 1995). Manufacturers offer merchandisers a set of product lines which consist of a number of SKUs. In cash-and-carry wholesaling, the main SKUs are those such as flavours and package sizes. Yet the merchandiser only chooses a subset of those SKUs offered, which they feel is the optimal assortment demanded from customers. In general, the assortment of goods that is optimal for a manufacturer to produce will most of the time not be the same as what is optimal for a retailer to stock (Alderson, 1965; Cadeaux, 1992; Cadeaux, 1997). Recent research has shown various and sometimes inconsistent effects of assortment variety. At the manufacturer level, relatively wide assortments attract relatively greater margins (Scherer 1979). This result can be explained both by the relative brand differentiation effect of wide assortments and by their increased retail level shelf space allocations and resulting higher brand shares, which, in turn arguably have a positive effect on brand market power and margin (eg, Porter 1976). However, it is not easy to extend such manufacturer brand level results into a retailing context, let alone a wholesaling context. It has been suggested that assortment variety can affect consumer utility and value (Cadeaux, 1992; Cadeaux, 1999). Boatwright and Nunes (2001) examined the effect on sales of a reduction of assortment and find that sales are affected by changes in the available number of SKUs, by the market share of items that are eliminated, and by the number of brands eliminated. They further find that decreasing the number of SKUs tended to increase category sales, yet this effect decreased as more SKUs were deleted (Boatwright and Nunes 2001). Yet that study was conducted on an online grocer, and thus the implications to the bricks and mortar retail environment or cash and carry wholesale environment may be questioned. Grewal et al. (1999) suggest that assortments are a way to attract and retain customers, as well as to appeal to variety seekers. Bergen, Dutta and Shugan (1996) argue that by increasing the number of SKUs within a category, there will be an increase in shoppers who may face increased search costs. Thus, retailers of high variety categories may provide higher levels of service (Bergen, Dutta and Shugan 1996). This differs from the argument of Cadeaux (1992), who claims that variety reduces search costs. Chiang and Wilcox (1997) find that a greater category variety has a positive effect on sales, but a negative effect on retail margin. Ryzin and Mahajan (1999) show that a larger assortment has a positive impact on performance when it is likely that customers will not purchase when the item that they want is not available (ie, when SKU demand rigidity is high). Ryzin and Mahajan (1999) also suggest that higher margins create incentives for retailers to stock a wider variety of products. These differing results of Ryzin and Mahajan (1999) and Chiang and Wilcox (1997) are possibly due to the fact that Chiang and Wilcox (1997) did not factor the total number of SKUs into the total number of brands and the total number of SKUs per brand. Further, Ryzin and Mahajan’s (1999) study implies that retailers who offer greater assortments will expect greater margins, since they are providing a service to customers who in return pay greater prices. Assortment variety affects stock level. As the number of variants (SKUs) within a category increases, category stock levels need to increase in order to gain sufficient sales volume (Pessemier 1980). It can be easily assumed that a larger assortment requires increased inventories because of the need to avoid stock-outs and due to variability of sales (Pessemier, 1980). Hise et al. (1983) have shown that total Distribution and Logistics Issues in Marketing Track 724 storewide stock levels have a positive effect on total storewide sales across chain branch stores. To replicate and extend Chiang and Wilcox (1997), we replace shelfspace with stock level, in order to make it more applicable to the wholesale cash-andcarry industry. Stock level may be more critical to wholesaling due to larger lot sizes and more severe advance ordering requirements (Pessemier 1980). In order to control for the effect of assortment variety on retailer margin, Chiang and Wilcox (1997) employed a measure of category-level consumer brand loyalty. They argued that in some categories consumers are relatively more brand loyal than in others. Chiang and Wilcox (1997) find that retailers receive lower margins in categories where consumers have relatively higher brand loyalties. This is because items which have high brand loyalties are less risky for merchandisers to stock. Thus, to the extent that margin can be seen as the reward gained from merchandising risk, retailers gain lower margins. Yet, in the wholesale situation, customers of cash-and-carry stores (e.g., retail store buyers) are not likely to exhibit their own brand loyalties in an analogous manner to consumers, but rather purchase on the basis of what they feel their own downstream customers require. Yet, there may be a similar pattern of category-varying relative manufacturer brand power. Thus, as a substitute factor that might influence margin in a wholesale situation, we substitute a broader construct of category-level manufacturer brand power for category-level brand loyalty. Cadeaux (1999) has argued that retailers are more dependent on brands that have relatively higher sales or category share levels. Further, Pessemier (1980) argues that manufacturers have power to force margins down due to an items’ popularity and its fast turnover. Thus, broadly speaking, brand loyalty is related to brand differentiation and manufacturer brand power, all of which should be regarded in relation to retailer economic power and retailer margin (Porter 1976). If we can plausibly extend these ideas directly into the wholesaling context, we can conclude that higher levels of manufacturer brand power tend to have a negative effect on margin percentages. Figure 1 summarises the implications of theory and research Merchandising Actions Control Variable Assortment Variety Category Performance (Dependent Variable) Manufacturer Brand Power Margin Stock Level discussed to this point: Figure 1: Preliminary Framework based on Chiang and Wilcox (1997) Chiang and Wilcox (1997) found that assortment variety had a negative effect on category margins. Yet, as argued previously, increasing assortment variety should have positive effects on customer retention and attraction (Grewal et al., 1999). Arguably, merchandisers who offer greater variety will expect greater margins in ANZMAC 2003 Conference Proceedings Adelaide 1-3 December 2003 725 return through charging higher prices (Cadeaux, 1992). We can visualise this as the price customers pay for being provided with a larger assortment and for reducing their search costs. Thus we hypothesise that: H1: Greater category assortment variety will lead to higher category margins. Customers pay a price for increased stock levels and the risk merchandisers, who will expect an appropriate reward, take in the form of perishability of inventory assets (Pessemier, 1980; Cadeaux, 1992). The relationship between stock levels and margins can also be viewed as an indirect effect of assortment variety, since margin expectations of assortment variety will have factored in increased stock level costs. Thus we hypothesise that: H2: Greater category stock levels will lead to higher category margins. From the previous discussion of the stock level variable, assortment variety will directly influence stock levels due to need to avoid stock outs (Pessemier, 1980), although quick response systems may have helped lessen this effect in more recent times. Thus, levels. H3: Greater category assortment variety will lead to higher category stock Chiang and Wilcox (1997) took brand loyalty into account in their study in order to control for margin effects and found it to have a negative relationship to margin. We take a similar approach, but instead use manufacturer brand power as discussed before. We believe that manufacturers who have higher brand power in categories can effectively increase merchandise costs since merchandisers are limited in their ability to raise prices proportionately. Thus, the merchandisers’ margins associated with categories that contain high manufacturer brand power are ‘squeezed’. In order to control for these effects, we hypothesise that: H4: Greater category-specific manufacturer brand power will lead to lower category margins. Research Method and Measurement of Variables To test the proposed model, we analysed one cash-and-carry wholesaler over the period of one year (2002). We were allowed full access to sales reports over a three month period, which reported sales at price for all SKUs, and the stock valuation reports, which reported the total assortment variety and stock levels at cost at one particular point in time. The sales report showed all sales for each SKU over the months of May, June, and July. Four stock valuation reports were used in order to be able to average out re-ordering and purchasing effects and gain a more accurate and meaningful picture of merchandising decision making. The data consisted of 146 categories, which were pre-defined by the wholesaler. The total number of SKUs stocked across the store was approximately 7700. Customers of the wholesaler included convenience stores and food service outlets. The types of products stocked Distribution and Logistics Issues in Marketing Track 726 included foods (frozen fish, confectionary, sauces, spices, etc.) as well as nonfood convenience goods (stationery, insecticides, toiletries, etc.). Assortment Variety Assortment variety is defined as the principle merchandising decision, and is measured by the average number of SKUs stocked in a given category. This is the same variable as that of Chiang and Wilcox’s (1997). The average in this measurement refers to the averaging of assortments over the four stock valuation reports, in order to control for product volatility (item additions and deletions). The preliminary analysis of one test stock valuation report showed at the outset that there would be enough variance in category’s assortments to justify a category level of analysis. This can be seen in Figure 2. 350 No. of SKUs 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 0 50 100 150 Number of Categories Figure 2: Assortment across categories Stock Level Stock level is defined as the average amount of inventory dollars for a given category. The average refers to averaging stock level dollars over the four stock valuation reports in order to account for obvious sales and re-ordering of goods over the period of analysis. Also, the dollar unit of analysis is taken since we want to portray stock levels as the risk that merchandisers take for having a higher variety. Margin Chiang and Wilcox (1997) define margin as the average category retail margin expressed as a percentage of price. This is basically a standard measure for margin, and our study uses the same measure. Thus margin is equal to average category price minus the average category cost, all over the average category price. Average in this case refers to averaging margin over the four stock valuation reports. Manufacturer Brand Power ANZMAC 2003 Conference Proceedings Adelaide 1-3 December 2003 727 Here manufacturer brand power measures the extent to which a category was dominated by a manufacturer’s brand, in terms of customer purchases. This was found by attributing whether a category is wholesaler dominated/no brand dominance, or multi-brand dominated, or single brand dominated. These categories were given a score of 0, 1, or 2, respectively. Single brand dominance was a brand that had greater than 50% market share in the category, multi-brand dominated categories had a few main brands that had greater than 20% market shares, and wholesaler/no brand dominance had shares of less than 20% or the wholesaler had own-brand dominance. Findings Figure 3 summarises the main results of tests for Hypotheses 1, 2 and 3. The coefficient from the path analysis is shown adjacent to each hypothesis with the respective t-value shown in parentheses. Assortment Variety H3 0.74 (13.14) H1 0.24 Margin (1.92) H2 - 0.32 (- 2.56) Stock Level (n=146, critical t=1.66 with 144 d.f.; p<.05) Figure 3: Path Model to test H1-3 Finally, a one-way ANOVA revealed that the level of manufacturer brand power in the category did not have an effect on margin as hypothesised by H4. Discussion The result supports Hypothesis 1. This basic result disconfirms Chiang and Wilcox’s (1997) finding that a greater category assortment variety leads to lower margins. However, the indirect effect on margin through stock level and the resulting total net effect implied in Figure 3 actually lends some support to an extension of their finding to cash and carry wholesaling. Hypothesis 2 claimed that greater category stock level will lead to higher category margins in that a greater stock level increases risk and thus expected margin reward. The findings from the path model show that this direct relationship was instead negative. One explanation could be that relatively greater stock in a category creates a “volume” rather than margin orientation for the wholesaler’s marketing effort in a category. However, such an inference is hard to validate in a study of one wholesaler. Distribution and Logistics Issues in Marketing Track 728 Hypothesis 3 claimed that greater category assortment will lead to greater category stock levels. This argument was based on the need to avoid stock outs (Pessemier, 1980). This hypothesis was strongly supported. Thus, Pessemier’s (1980) argument of the positive relationship of retail assortment variety to retail stock level seems to extend to the wholesale context, at least at the category level. In spite of the use of quick response systems, wholesalers may still have to increase total stock in categories with larger numbers of SKUs, in that that they face relatively volatile derived demand. Hypothesis 4 claimed that greater category-specific manufacturer brand power will lead to lower category margins. This was based on the belief that margins would be squeezed. This was not supported. Perhaps the effect of brand power on margins does not extend so well into the wholesaling area. That is, to the extent that brands may generally have a stronger effect on consumers’ buying at the retail level than on retail and organisational buying at the wholesale level, margin outcomes at the two levels may similarly differ. A basic limitation of this study is that it is limited to one wholesaler, although as a replication and extension, it shares this scope limitation with Chiang and Wilcox (1997) who examined only one retailer. This study also potentially contributes to the retailing literature because of the closeness of the cash-and-carry wholesaling situation to that of supermarket retailing, although the total number of SKUs (7700) that this cash and carry wholesaler stocks only represents about 17% of the 45,000 SKUs that Chaing and Wilcox (1997) cite as being stocked by a typical supermarket such as the one they examined. Nevertheless, these findings represent a step towards understanding how some basic retail merchandising relationships might extend into the much less well-understood field of cash and carry wholesaling. References Alderson, Wroe, (1965), Dynamic Marketing Behaviour, Irwin, Homewood, IL. Bergen, Mark, Shantanu Dutta, and Steven M. Shugan, (1996), “Branded Variants: A Retail Perspective,” Journal of Marketing Research, 33 (February), 9-19. Boatwright, Peter and Joseph C. Nunes, (2001), “Reducing Assortment: an AttributeBased Approach,” Journal of Marketing, 65 (July), 50-63. Borin, Norm, Paul W. Farris, and James R. Freeland, (1994), “A Model for Determining Retail Product Category Assortment and Shelf Space Allocation,” Decision Sciences, 25, 359-383. Borin, Norm and Paul Farris, (1995), “A Sensitivity Analysis of Retailer Shelf Management Models,” Journal of Retailing, 71, 153-171. Broniarczyk, Susan M., Wayne D. Hoyer, and Leigh McAlister, (1998), “Consumers’ Perceptions of the Assortment Offered in a Grocery Category: The Impact of Item Reduction,” Journal of Marketing Research, 35, 166-176. Cadeaux, Jack M., (1992), “Industry Product Volatility and Retailer Assortments,” Journal of Macromarketing, (Fall), 28-37. ANZMAC 2003 Conference Proceedings Adelaide 1-3 December 2003 729 Cadeaux, Jack M., (1997), “A Closer Look at the Interface between the Product Lines of Manufacturers and the Assortments of Retailers,” International Journal of Retail & Distribution Management, 25, 197-203. Cadeaux, Jack (1999), “Category Size and Assortment in US Macro Supermarkets,” Internal Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 9 (October), 367377. Chiang, Jeongwen and Ronald T. Wilcox, (1997), “A Cross-Category Analysis of Shelf-Space Allocation, Product Variety, and Retail Margins,” Marketing Letters, 8, 183-191. Fader, Peter S. and Bruce G. S. Hardie, (1996), “Modelling Consumer Choice Among SKUs,” Journal of Marketing Research, 33, 442-452. Grewal, Druhuv, Michael Levy, Anuj Mehrotra, and Arun Sharma, (1999), “Planning Merchandising Decisions to Account for Regional and Product Assortment Differences,” Journal of Retailing, 75, 405-424. Hise, Richard T., J. Patrick Kelly, Myron Gable, and James B. McDonald, (1983), “Factors Affecting the Performance of Individual Chain Store Units: An Empirical Analysis,” Journal of Retailing, 59, (Summer), 2. Koelemeijer, Kitty and Harmen Oppewal, (1999), “Assessing the Effects of Assortment and Ambience: A Choice Experimental Approach,” Journal of Retailing, 75, 319-345. Lee, Jack K. H. and Joel H. Steckel, (1999), “Consumer Strategies for Purchasing Assortments within a Single Product Class,” Journal of Retailing, 75, 387-403. Levy, Michael and Barton A. Weitz, (1995), Retailing Management, 2nd ed., Chicago: Irwin. McIntyre, Shelby H. and Christopher M. Miller, (1999), “The Selection and Pricing of Retail Assortments: An Empirical Approach,” Journal of Retailing, 75, 289-293. Pessemier, Edgar A., (1980), “Retail Assortments – Some Theoretical and Applied Problems,” Report #80-111 (December), Cambridge, MA: Marketing Science Institute. Porter, Michael E., (1976), Interbrand Choice, Strategy, and Bilateral Market Power, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Ryzin, Garrett Van and Siddharth Mahajan, (1999), “On the Relationship Between Inventory Costs and Variety Benefits in Retail Assortments,” Management Science, 45, 1496-1509. Scherer, Frederic M. (1979), “The Welfare Economics of Product Variety: An Application to the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry,” Journal if Industrial Economics, 28 (2), 113-134. Distribution and Logistics Issues in Marketing Track 730 Simonson, Itamar, (1999), “The Effect of Product Assortment on Buyer Preferences,” Journal of Retailing, 75, 347-370. Stassen, Robert E., John D. Mittelstaedt, and Robert A. Mittelstaedt, (1999), “Assortment Overlap: Its Effect on Shopping Patterns in a Retail Market When the Distributions of Prices and Goods are Known,” Journal of Retailing, 75, 371-386. Urban, Timothy L., (1998). “An Inventory-Theoretic Approach to Product Assortment and Shelf-Space Allocation.” Journal of Retailing, 74, 15-35. ANZMAC 2003 Conference Proceedings Adelaide 1-3 December 2003 731