1 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions Draft notes: not for quotation or attribution without permission of author. “Politics, Institutions and Society: Seeking better results.” Peter Gourevitch UCSD, La Jolla Ca. For 2005-06 Russell Sage Foundation Prepared for World Bank Legal Forum 2005 on “Law, Equity and Development” For session on “Building Equitable and Inclusive Markets.” The World Bank Washington, DC December 1-2, 2005 Revised May 2006 2 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions Abstract We know political processes influence growth and equality, but we disagree on just how. The differing camps in combat can be sorted into three categories of causality: legal family ; political institutions, or de jure institutions; and social forms of power, or de facto institutions. The first stresses the impact of contracting arrangements generated by civil and common law systems, whereby the latter are held to be more encouraging of growth; the second stresses the impact of political arrangements, whereby structures obligating accountability of governments to constituencies inhibit predation and encourage growth; the third stresses the ability of social forms of power (land, media, family, organizational capacity) to bend governments to their will, whereby high concentration of social power undermines the capacity of institutions to restrain predation. These arguments are examined with the specific example of debates about variance in systems of corporate governance: why some countries have patterns of diffuse shareholding while others have concentration and control by blockholders. The legal family school has difficulty explaining variance within countries over time, and variance among countries within the same legal family; the formal political institutions school underplays the role of social forms of power among interest group; the social power school underplays the role of institutions in explaining variance among unequal societies. We have better measurements of the first two categories (formal law and political institutions) than we do of the third. A key ingredient for promoting economic development is consider policies that strengthen those social groups that seek it. 3 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions We know that political processes influence growth and equality. There is indeed a substantial consensus on this, a marked change from the recent past. Indeed so great is the consensus on the importance of politics, that we are able now to disagree on the next big point: just what model of politics do we have in mind? The latest World Development Report 2006 Equity and Development is commendable for exploring political and social variables in shaping policy determination and actual outcomes. Here I wish to draw out some of the issues that appear in discussions of politics. I will use examples from the field of corporate governance: Why do corporate governance systems vary around the world ( diffuse shareholder models in the US and the UK, concentrated blockholder models in most of the world), and what can be done to improve these systems? Once a topic unto itself, the debate about corporate governance outcomes now tightly interweaves with important discussions about economic development and “endogenous institutional change.” What produces “good political institutions” that cause economic growth (and along the way, good corporate governance, equity, freedom and justice)? In these debates about explanation, three arguments contend for primacy: a) the formal rules of law (legal family), associated with the research of La Porta, Lopez di Silanes, Shleifer , Vishny1) ; b) political institutions, or de jure, parchment institutions, associated with constitutions2 ; and c) social forms of power, elements of civil society, such as interest groups, social class, media , professional associations, or de facto institutions. 4 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions Each of these arguments has a different sense of “politics” and political mechanisms. For the legal formalism school, good institutions that promote growth and corporate governance come from legal family, where common law is superior to civil law; improving country performance means improving the codes that regulate corporate and securities law. The political institutions school argues that the implementation of codes, as well as passage of “good” laws, requires support from policy making institutions; “good “ institutions produce good policy, so change has to come from improving political decision-making bodies. The political sociology school argues that institutions themselves express the preferences of groups in society who actually use the institutions and can bend them to their will; good policy requires altering the distribution of power in society. Thus the debate is among three forms of power --legal, institutional , and social -- and thus three models of politics. The rest of the paper explores the debate through the specific prism of corporate governance. The next section sets out corporate governance as a dependent variable: the outcome to be explained, the variance we observe around the world in patterns of corporate governance. Then, the paper looks at the three types of argumentation. Finally, we explore implications for policy and the larger question of development promoting institutions. I. Variance in Corporate governance outcomes. Corporate governance systems are contrasted by the degree of shareholder concentration. In the blockholder models, a few actors (banks, governments, individuals, or other firms) hold a large percentage of the shares. This allows them, as owner principals, to monitor directly, or through agents on the board, the behavior of 5 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions their agents, the managers. They have the means to act ( controlling majority of seats) and the motive (a large ownership share). By contrast, the diffuse shareholder model elects a board of directors who represent the interests of these shareholders without any direct action by them. Minority shareholders are protected in the diffuse system from insider dealing by blockholders, but lack the means and motive to intervene directly or to monitor their mediating agents ( the elected directors) . Minority shareholders are vulnerable to opportunism by insiders in the blockholding model, but can also free ride off the activism of those blocks in watching the managers. Comparative analysis thus begins by describing the difference in shareholder concentration diffusion. 3 Drawing on the foundational work of the La Porta et. al, the World Bank, and many others, , Gourevitch and Shinn show national differences in in Figure 1 , “Ownership Concentration” by country 4; 6 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions 7 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions We see considerable variance across countries While Japan and China are at the top, these merit important qualifications. In China only a small portion of the economy lies in listed stocks, the rest is state owned. In Japan, we find extensive cross shareholding, so that there can be no effective market for control. No one would regard either country as exemplifying the diffuse shareholder model. Thus the most diffuse country is the US, the least is Chile. There is not substantial disagreement on this description. The battle heats up over explanation. Why does this divergence in blockholding take place? II. Explaining the Variance: Three Models of Politics We can sort the contenders into three camps: legal family ; political institutions; and interest groups. They differ most on what shapes law and regulation: If law and regulation protect investors from exploitation by insiders, what explains the supply of 8 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions these laws and regulations?. There is an additional debate over whether law matters and which laws matter; we incorporate that debate into our discussion below. A. Legal family – the formal rules approach. For diffusion to occur, an investor must accept a minority position in the firm , as outsiders coming in , or as blockholders selling down. In so doing, these investors risk exploitation by insiders. To so, argues a rich literature , they must obtain some kind of protection from insider abuse. Law and regulation provide this -- Minority Shareholder Protections.5 These measures include: information (disclosure and audit), oversight (board independence), control rules (voting processes), and managerial incentives (executive pay). The higher the level of MSP, the more supervision of managers, the more reassured are investors (who buy) and blockholders (who sell to diversify) and the deeper will markets become --at least that is the core assumption of the “law matters” school.6 Laws about insider trading, the composition of boards, the issuance of shares, providing information about the firms finances, take overs and the market for control – these allow outsiders to judge the value of their investment and take action: buy, sell, or take over. The prediction of this approach is that where MSP is strong, diffusion occurs. . Comparative research measuring various components of MSP was pioneered by LaPorta , et al, thereby helping to create a field of study. Initially they measured issues about firm governance , but they and others7 have broadened the terrain to include other elements. Our index, Table 1, combines several measures , drawn from these authors and our own evaluations. 9 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions (NOTE TO EDITORS: Please correct the label of this table to Table 1: Table 1 Minority shareholder protections index 10 MSP index G/S 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions 11 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions In the legal approach, high levels of MSP should correlate positively with shareholder diffusion: the stronger the MSP, the more investors are willing to be minority shareholders. Figure 2 correlates Blockholding with MSP.8 Figure 2 Blockholding and Shareholder Protections 12 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions So, MSP and corporate governance patterns do connect, as expected. Some relationship exists – though the correlation is not strong, which suggest other variables are at play. We come back to these other variables, but first we address the “hot spot” of arguments about politics. To the extent MSP (law and regulation about shareholder) accounts for diffusion, what explains the provision of MSP? La Porta et. al argue it is “legal family” – whether a country has civil or common law. Common Law systems, they suggest, have higher MSP than do Civil Law countries. Having measured MSP in a large number of countries, La Porta et. al then correlate levels of MSP with legal family. La Porta et. al provide evidence that confirms the intriguing “eyeball” observation that the UK, and its former colonies including the US, are heavily grouped in the shareholder diffusion and high MSP quadrant, while France, Spain and their former colonies tend toward the blockholder and low protection pattern. This is a striking pattern and deserves thought. And yet, closer inspection reveals problems with the legal family explanation. On the empirical side, we observe substantial variance in corporate governance patterns within countries over time, while their legal family stays constant, and we observe substantial variance among countries within the same legal family. In their important paper, “The Great Reversals ” 9 Rajan and Zingales track within -country change extensively, showing France and Japan developing considerable stock markets prior to WW I, then showing a sharp swing toward bank dominance. The US looked much like Germany prior to WWI, but policy changes created the regulatory system of anti-trust, banking regulation and MSP which produced the system we know today. 10 Berkowitz and Pistor show a “transplant effect” , that local conditions influence considerably how 13 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions countries alter efforts to import legal structures from outside.11 Within the same legal family, considerable variance exists among countries in what they do. On the conceptual side of the legal family argument, the mechanism of causality remains unclear: just why does legal family produce the claimed effect? Legal family, a formal characteristic, does not explain the content of the actual laws which are passed, and , even more important, the pattern of enforcement. Nothing about common law guarantees that countries will enact vigorous MSP’s , nor that they will enforce them. Nothing about civil law systems prevent countries from enacting strong MSP, nor from enforcing them. Laws are passed and sustained because of political processes: the demands of various groups in society and the institutions that process them. It is to these we turn. B. Political institutions – de jure power: Laws are made, and enforced, by political systems. Variation in the content of laws, regulation and enforcement, might then be the product of variation in political systems. In this respect, formal legal system ( civil vs. common law) can be differentiated from political institutions and from social structures. Acemoglu , Johnson and Robinson call the legal systems “ contractual institutions,” while labeling political structures as ” property rights institutions.”12 Contractual processes, they argue, do differ according to legal family, but do not predict economic development. Property protection institutions don’t correlate with legal family and do correlate with economic growth. We find similar results for corporate governance. What are property protecting institutions? In formal terms, they are the structures which organize power in political systems. Here Acemoglu , Johnson and Robinson 14 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions make another quite important distinction: between de jure institutions, formal structures that shape the way “preferences” (interests, ideas, goals) are aggregated, 13 and de facto institutions (forms of power in civil society , such as land, guns, money. We know that different methods of counting the votes yield different outcomes because of cycling and agenda control. The same applies to other aspects of political system. This insight generates an important literature comparing countries along different dimensions of their political institutions, including electoral laws, the structure of the executive and the legislature, and press. federalism, courts and the independence of the judiciary, free speech Countries are compared with categories such as Presidential vs Parliamentary systems, Majoritarian vs. Consensus systems, high or low number of veto gates or veto players. Important World Bank research by Beck, Kiefer and others has made an important contribution to this literature, for a number of years, building a valuable data base 14 ; other research projects have added substantially to our knowledge.15 The institutionalist approach – the focus on de jure institutions-- provides leverage in accounting for variance in MSP provision and corporate governance outcomes. In stable democracies, for example, Gourevitch and Hawes and Gourevitch and Shinn 16 show that MSP and corporate governance outcomes correlate with the Majoritarian/Consensus distinction. Majoritarian systems are more likely to have high MSP and diffuse shareholder patterns. The logic has to do with the impact institutions have on the bargains among groups in each system. Majoritarian systems have wider policy swings, which undermines the corporatist foundations of a particular set of arrangements around blockholding, which then induces actors to seek autonomy through 15 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions arms length economic relationships, and thus to MSP and shareolder diffusion; conversely, “Consensus” systems reinforce the bargains in corporatism and sustain blockholding arrangements.17 Pagano and Volpin18 stress the impact of electoral systems: countries with proportional representation are more likely to have high shareholder protection rules and diffuse shareholding patterns than are countries with once-past the post single member plurality districts. The impact of veto players and stable institutions may be different between stable democracies and authoritarian regimes. Strong regimes can enforce rules but can also predate on economic life, undermining incentives to invest; weak regimes can’t enforce rules, which also undermines incentives. Blockholding may arise out of either extreme. Having many veto points can create policy paralysis. Having few veto points lessons the chances of policy paralysis, but increases the threat of predation. The confidence of investors may be highest at some intermediate point on a U shape curve, some “just right” balance, between inaction and too much. We do know that for some periods, investment in authoritarian regimes can be high; such regimes are able to signal some kind of commitment to investors that predation will be limited.19 C) Social forms of power, de facto power. In contrast to this stress on de jure political institutions, another literature looks at de facto forms of power – control of land, guns, people—which enables social groups to manipulate the political process to their advantage. 20 Constitutions seek to constrain later generations by structuring the political game on behalf of whoever is writing the documents; the constitution is thus a commitment techology. But groups with social power are able to undermine these restrictions, capturing the formal structures, altering their usage, or even changing the 16 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions constitution. The history of Latin America, Africa, indeed Europe and the US are full of examples of this kind. Acemoglou and Robinson cite the American South after the civil war, Colombia, and Liberia as examples where landed elites blocked formal political efforts that sought to limit their power. In the American South, the 14 th amendment providing equality to freed slaves was rendered meaningless by cutting the voting rolls, terrorism from the Klu Klux Klan, and Jim Crow exclusion from education, jobs and many social practices. In Colombia, the landed elite made a bargain to rotate power and exclude most of the population from participation in politics. In Liberia, the descendents of American slaves did the same. In France, the authors of the Third Republic’s Constitution planned for a strong executive hoping for a return to monarchy. When the President lost a fight with the National Assembly, the system developed rapidly into Parliamentary dominant, weak Presidential model.21 Stasavage critiques the influential North Weingast essay on the English political settlement of 1688, by noting the limits on the crown came not only from formal changes in Parliamentary oversight, but from the goals of the particular majority that dominated Parliament at that time, so that a different majority would have led to a different outcome, as in France. 22 These examples suggest that to understand just how formal institutions work, we need to know who uses them and for what purposes. 23 In the case of corporate governance, these considerations compel a look at the interest group politics that surround policy toward MSP. Laws regulating corporations and shareholders express the demands of groups acting through politics, whose support politicians and bureaucrats need create and enforce legislation. Finance theorists begin analysis of governance moral hazard issues by positing the goals, or interests, of investors 17 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions and managers: how, they ask, are investors, the principles, able to monitor the behavior of the managers, the agents, given their principal’s great need of the expertise and initiative of the agents. This helps model incentives inside the firm, but to explain public policy, we need to examine how the goals of those inside the firm are translated into public policy processes outside the firm. To that we need to think about interest groups and their actions through political parties, elections, lobbying regulators and the familiar trappings of political life. We can specify key social actors by drawing on finance theory’s concern with owners and managers. To this we add workers, an important group in society as well as in the firm. These can combine in various ways to generate alternative support (or opposition) to laws that influence corporate governance outcomes, such as MSP. These coalitional possibilities and realities can be shown graphically, as in Table 2.324. 18 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions Table 2 Political Coalitions and Governance Outcomes Predicted Coalitional Lineup Winner Model Name Outcome Investor Diffusion Labor Blockholding Social Bargain Blockholding Owners Oligarchy Blockholding Owners + Workers Transparency Diffusion Managers Managerism Diffusion Pair A: Class Conflict Owners + Managers vs. Workers Owners + Managers Owners + Managers vs. Workers Workers Pair B: Sectoral Owners vs. Managers + Managers + Workers Workers Owners vs. Managers + Workers Pair C: Property and Voice Owners + Workers vs. Managers Owners + Workers vs. Managers 19 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions Each “pair” is based on a different force of political cleavage, separating society into alternative policy views. The first pair pits workers against owners and managers. Roe25 provides evidence that labor related groups oppose strong MSP, so that where they are politically strong, we have weaker MSP. This mirrors the frequently made argument that capital movement forces convergence around high MSP, as investors demand legal protections for their stock purchasing.26 This model of political differences explains the supply or absence of high MSP by the distribution of votes on a left-right continuum: the bigger the labor vote (left) the weaker are MSP, and the bigger the conservative vote the stronger are MSP. The second alliance pair sees political divide along cross class, or sector patterns, where workers, managers and inside owners support a mutually reinforcing regime of blockholding. The coalition members prefer stability of existing arrangements of employment, investment and leadership to the fluid relationships of the high MSP systems. Minority shareholders are seen as outsiders, seeking to uproot stable relationships built up over time. That stability sustains a distinctive pattern of production which saves in transactions costs and specializes in high quality products and producer goods. 27 Germany is the most well known examples of this corporate governance pattern. It involves extensive collaboration among members of the system through a set of arrangements frequently labeled as corporatist. While both of these coalition patterns have received considerable attention in literature on political economy, the third has not. The third coalition puts external 20 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions investors in alliance with workers against blockholders and managers in defense of high levels of MSP and transparency generally. Pension funds are a key ingredient of this coalition. The growth of pension funds may be causing an historical shift in the coalitional patterns around public policy concerning MSP and corporate governance. 28 Reversing the expectation that that workers and investors are in conflict, we can see motives that draw them together. Employee pension funds see MSPs as a way of protecting an investment, and lobby parties dependent on labor support to get them. The result is “left” governments doing more for investors than do the supposedly capital friendly right wing governments which are more beholden to insiders and managers. 29 This pattern has been observed in Germany, where the SPD supported legislation that strengthened shareholder protection and lowered the tax on capital gains from selling shares, while the supposedly more business friendly CDU opposed these moves.30 The greater the share of country’s pension funds in private hands, rather than in public Pay-Go systems, the higher is the level of MSP31, and the more likely we see demands to strengthen them further. Just how actively pension funds use MSP powers to impact corporate governance can be substantially affected by the micro-institutional details of financial intermediaries. We know pension systems around the world have troubles, in all countries rich and poor, highly developed and not. Much of the debate about solutions has focused on the rate of return – do people do better with public or private systems, taking into account the degree of risk? Of course the rate of return is hugely important. But that issue, and impact of pension funds on corporate governance, is connected to the micro details of the institutional investors which actually manage these privatized funds: who controls those, are they in the hands of the same people who 21 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions control the firms where the money gets invested, what is the fee structure, how are these Institutional Investors regulated, how much competition, what control to investors have over the funds and their money, what powers to Institutional Investors have to challenge management? These details influence both the rate of return and the impact of privatized funds on corporate governance.32 What brings these coalitions together, causing some to win at some points, lose at others? Institutionalists stress the role of formal structures in shaping the way clusters of preferences aggregate: thus the argument that it is the electoral law or Majoritarian structures which shapes the victory of different coalitional patterns among countries. The de facto power approach looks instead at the resources various groups have to mobilize for political action ( votes, organizations, the ability to strike). Variance among countries in outputs expresses differences in the political strengths of these various interest groups. Historical context , path dependence, and comparative political economy: The interest group approach can help clarify the role of historical context and path dependence in shaping outcomes. The demands of interest groups vary across countries in part because of incentives shaped by prior choices in pubic policy, the results of earlier conflicts. Rajan and Zingales’s33 description of the “great reversals” can be seen as noting the impact of interest groups to economic dislocations after 1914: domestic groups reacted against the disruptive effects of free trade and sought stability via regulation. Among the effects was a shift toward bank influence and away from open equity markets. Similarly, the “transplant effect” analyed by Berkowitz and Pistor34 can be interpreted as the impact of interest groups within each country toward the costs, and benefits, of adopting foreign practices. Roe35 explores the impact of war on interest group 22 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions alignments; countries which experienced considerable damage from the World Wars shifted toward blockholding. Perrotti and von Thadden36 look at the impact of hyperfinflation during the 1920s: countries whose middle class investors were wiped out shifted toward preferring the regulatory bank centered model. Rogoswki, Hiscox, Frieden, Gourevitch examine the impact of world trading patterns on policy choices: contractions in the economy produce demands for protection, while prosperity prepares the ground for free trade. 37 These policy choices, made in response to trade or war or depression, generate mutually reinforcing patterns of regulation and interest groups preferences. Hall and Soskice 38 stylize market economies in two contrasting models, or production systems: Liberal Market Economies (LMEs, which have fluid labor relations, vigorous anti -trust, general skill -oriented educational systems, strong product market competition, and diffuse shareholder oriented corporate and governance systems), and Coordinated Market Economies (CMEs , which have highly structured labor relations, limited domestic competition, price and market coordination, specific skill oriented educational training, and blockholding governance systems.) Drawing on Milgrom and Roberts,39 they see strong “institutional complementarity”—placement on one dimension of the economy reinforcements its complement on another. Thus investing in worker training makes sense if there is low market fluidity in market share and employment and patient capital shielded from shareholder pressures. Once systems of this kind start, at some point in the past, the pieces reinforce each other. Management, blockholders and labor generate reasons to cooperate around preservation of the firm. The interests and politics of each production factor are thus strongly influenced by context. What labor, 23 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions management or capital want depends in part on which national production system they operate in. Institutional complementary leads to a criticism of the sufficiency of MSP levels as an explanation of corporate governance patterns. So far, we have emphasized alternative explanations of the provision of Minority Shareholder Protections-- legal family, formal political institutions, and interest group politics. But the logic of institutional complimentarity challenges the sufficiency of MSP more broadly. Investors willingness to take minority positions is affected not only by the formal rules of MSP, however these are generated, but by the rules that shape labor relations, product market competition, price setting, and labor training. Roe notes where labor is strong, investors may prefer blockholding to maintain stronger bargaining posture with labor, and labor in turn may sustain militancy to deal with blockholding management. Power relationships and policy regulation out side the strict domain of corporate governance as defined by MSP thus have an impact on corporate governance patterns. This may explain the limited power of correlating MSP with shareholder concentration: other variables are at play40 . Another critique of the MSP approach moves away from regulation and law altogether, Shareholder diffusion began, argue several specialists41, before regulations: the listing requirements of the London and New York stock exchanges provided “private bonding” reassurances. In the UK, mergers occurred among local elites, who knew each other well. The demand for formal shareholder protections occurred later, as shareholding spread. In addition to the historical evidence for this pattern, it is reinforced by a political logic: who would lobby for shareholder protection if there were no shareholders? The social foundations of markets can be quite important, worth more analysis. 42 24 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions Historical patterns, earlier choices, path dependence, and institutional complimentarity provide a way of understanding the context of political choices connected to corporate governance and economic policy outcomes. Policy choices at a given moment reflect the interaction of interest group preferences, ideology and political institutions. These reinforce each other – policy sustains the interests of those who put it through. Along come shocks or changes in incentives: changes in the terms of trade, for example between agriculture and industry, or recession; war and the development of political obstacles to trade; economic depression, inflation. These change incentives and alter political coalitions; they may change formal political institutions, creating a more open political game. Policy may congeal around a new policy framework, which reinforces itself again—till the next change in conditions or external shocks. Conclusion: Political variables --- the interaction of preferences and institutions to produce policy outputs – shape the way formal laws, rules and procedures work. An account of law without a model of politics seems limited in predictive power and policy utility. A strong model of politics is a difficult but vital goal. Several points can be drawn from this discussion. 1. One size does not fit all. will work the same way everywhere. We can’t assume that the same formal institutions We should be cautious therefore about telling countries to adopt the same codes and laws on corporate governance, when they have such greatly differing contexts with which to enforce and apply them. The best practice codes on corporate governance call for strong MSP, but these rely on enforcement mechanisms which lack support in much of the world. The diffuse shareholding model takes more regulation, not less, and as the US Enron et. al scandals show, can be hard to 25 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions do even in highly developed legal systems. Blockholders , or various forms of private bonding, may thereby do a better job under certain circumstances. We know a lot about the ability of private bonding mechanisms to substitute for weak formal enforcement.43 These insights can be built into policy advice. 2. Formal rules and practice--- Don’t confuse formal rules with what happens. It is commonly understood that formal law is not the same as practice. That laws and codes are adopted does not mean we have actually changed the incentives social actors have nor what they actually do. In the field of corporate governance, for example, countries around the world have adopted good governance codes following recommendations from OECD, and many other groups. Good codes are better than bad ones. But codes by themselves are not practice. We cannot measure changes in corporate governance activities by noting the adoption of these codes. We can see if codes get translated into laws, but even then we cannot be sure the laws are enforced. 3. Enforcement requires a “politics” committed to those goals. Without political support, good laws and codes are not enforced. Studies of the “transplant” effect 44 show this well: adopting codes does not produce the desired effect if the conditions for the transplant -- a politics receptive to it --- are lacking. 4. Law is made by political process. Courts and lawyers operate in a context of legislation and enforcement policy generated by political choices. The actual content of law expresses political realities. Good or bad codes can be generated out of the same intellectual roots. 26 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions 5. Political processes are shaped by formal political institutions. The de jure forms of political process influence outputs, including the content of laws and enforcement. De jure political processes trump legal formalism. 6 “ De facto “ power trumps “de jure” power. Informal mechanisms of social power are able to adapt formal political institutions to their purposes. Thus de facto power trumps de jure power which trumps legal formalism. It is surely the case that these variables interact ---- law, formal institutions and social power all operate in a complex system of interaction. But it is helpful to push at the endogeneity of that interaction and tease out ways in which these interactions nestle. This reasoning leads to a compelling research project: a World Bank Handbook of de Facto Forms of Power. The important work on de jure institutions needs a counterpart on social forms of power – on the distribution of landholding, on private armies and guns, on clientalist networks, on cross-holding and overlapping patterns of ownership, on interest group structures, on press concentration and control, on families45 and private bonding mechanisms. This sort of material can help make progress in unraveling the interaction of legal formalism, formal political institutions and the social distribution of de facto power. Several policy implications flow from these observations. MSP and diffuse shareholding models require extensive law and regulations; the liberal market economy rests on rules. Without the strong foundations of social support for these rules and their enforcement, this model cannot work; blockholding may be a serious alternative. Investing resources into legal training may not be effective if it is not combined with analysis of political power balances. Investing in mechanisms of free speech, responsible 27 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions politics, economic journalists, trade union leaders, and business experts may be more effective. Allowing variety of treatment across countries may be essential. Thanks to both the Russell Sage Foundation where this paper was written on a fellowship 2005-06, and to the Guggenheim Memorial Fellowships for support. Thanks for comments on earlier drafts to Stijn Claessens, Simon Johnson, James Shinn, and Christopher Woodruff, and thanks to Lauren Porzelt for editorial assistance. 1 The problem of managers escaping the control of investors was famously observed by A.A. Berle and Gardner Means, The Modern Corporation and Private Property ( McMillan 1933). While country specialists knew the US pattern was by no means universal, La Porta et. al, helped develop recent awareness of the variance: R. La Porta , F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer & R. W. Vishny, Legal Determinants of External Finance, 52 The Journal of Finance 1131 (1997); La Porta, et. al. , Law and Finance, 106 Journal of Political Economy 1113 (1998); La Porta, et. al , Investor Protection and Corporate Governance 58 Journal of Financial Economics 3 ( 2000); La Porta, et. al , Investor Protection and Corporate Valuation. 57 Journal of Finance 1147 (2002); R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes & A. Shleifer, Corporate Ownership Around the World, 54 The Journal of Finance 471 (1999). For an extensive review of the literature see Marco Becht, Patrick Bolton & Ailsa Röell, Corporate Governance and Control, in Handbook of the Economics of Finance, (Elsivier, 2005). 2 This particular use of the terms de jure and de facto derive from Daron Acemoglu & Simon Johnson, Unbundling Institutions, 113 Journal of Political Economy 949 (2005). See also Daron Acemoglou & James Robinson, The Persistence of Power, Elites and Institutions, Mimeo (2006); Daron Acemoglou, Simon Johnson, James Robinson, Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth (2005), in Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1A, (North-Holland 2005); Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson & James A. Robinson, The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation, 91 American Economic Review 1369 (2001). Daron Acemoglu, Constitutions, Politics and Economics; A Review Essay on Persson and Tabellini’s "The Economic Effects of Constitutions", 43 Journal of Economic Literature 1025 (2005). 28 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions 3 Earlier work looked at bank debt vs. equity ratios. This is still the dominant form for comparing patterns in earlier periods, as shareholder concentration is hard to document. See Raghuram Rajan & Luigi Zingales, The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial Development in the 20th Century, 69 Journal of Financial Economics 5 (2003). 4 Japan ranks high on this list because the system of cross shareholding renders meaningless the diffusion pattern of ownership—there is no effective market for control there. China ranks high because the stock market captures only a small portion of its economy, most of which remains in state hands. 5 This passage draws on Peter Gourevitch & James Shinn, Political Power and Corporate Control: The New Global Politics of Corporate Governance (Princeton University Press 2005), especially chapters two and three. 6 Historical research questions the causal sequence: do shareholders precede MSP or does MSP come ahead of shareholder. Private bonding arrangements via stock exchanges or mergers, may have created a group of shareholders who then demanded MSPs. That makes political sense (why create something for which there is no constituency), and may be historically accurate, but it is not clear how it handles the present: can formal MSP regulations and their enforcement induce shareholding. See Brian Cheffins, Does Law Matter?: The Separation of Ownership and Control in the United Kingdom, 30 Journal of Legal Studies 459 (2001); Brian Cheffins, Corporate Law and Ownership Structure: A Darwinian Link?, 25 University of New South Wales Law Journal 346 (2002); Brian Cheffins, Putting Britain on the Roe Map: The Emergence of the Berle-Means Corporation in the United Kingdom, in Corporate Governance Regimes: Convergence and Diversity, 147-174.(Oxford University Press 2002 ); Randall Morck, ed., History of Corporate Ownership, (University of Chicago Press 2006); John Coffee, The Rise of Dispersed Ownership: The Roles of Law and the State in the Separation of Ownership and Control, 111 The Yale Law Journal 1 (2001). 7 The ranks are a composite constructed by the authors from numerous sources. See Gourevitch & Shinn, supra note 5, p. 48, the sources for Table 3.1. 8 Gourevitch & Shinn, supra note 5, p 51, and Table A-4, p. 301. The correlation is strongest for developed countries, at –.42 ** (p<.05) at significance of .03 at, while reversed in sign and weak significance for developing countries (.29). 9 Raghuram Rajan & Luigi Zingales, The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial Development in the 20th Century, 69 Journal of Financial Economics 5 (2003). 10 Mark Roe, Strong Managers, Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American Corporate Finance (Princeton University Press 1994). 29 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions 11 Daniel Berkowitz, Katharina Pistor & Jean-Francois Richard, Economic development, legality and the transplant effect 47 European Economic Review 165 (2003). 12 Daron Acemoglu & Simon Johnson, supra note 2; Christopher Woodruff, Measuring Institutions (2005) in Handbook on Corruption (forthcoming); Luc Laeven & Christopher Woodruff, The Quality of the Legal System: Firm Ownership and Firm Size, Mimeo (2005). 13 Glaesar et.al make important warning about the need to be sure measures of institutions are independent from those of the outputs they produce. E. Glaeser, R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, Do Institutions Cause Growth?, 9 Journal of Economic Growth 271 (2004). 14 See Acemolgu, Johnson & Robinson, supra note 2; C. Douglas North, Structure and Change in Economic History (W.W. Horton 1981); S. Haber, A. Razo, and N. Maurer, The Politics of Property Rights: Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico 1876-1929 (Cambridge University Press 2003). 15 Thorsten Beck, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer & Patrick Walsh, New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions 15 World Bank Economic Review 165 (2001). Arend Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy: Governmnent Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries (Yale University Press 1999); Torsten Persson & Guido Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions: What do the Data Say? (MIT Press 2003); Matthew S. Shugart & John M. Carey, Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics (Cambridge University Press 1992); Stephan Haggard & Mathew C. McCubbins, Presidents, Parliament and Policy (Cambridge University Press 2001). 16 Peter Gourevitch & Michael B. Hawes, The Politics of Choice among National Production Systems, L’Année de la regulation, Presses de Sciences Po 2002) ; Gourevitch & Shinn, supra, note 5. 17 Peter Hall and David Soskice , Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Foundation , (Oxford University Press, 2001); Torben Iversen & David Soskice, Electoral Institutions, Parties, and the Politics of Class: Why Some Democracies Redistribute More than Others, 96 American Political Science Review, forthcoming (2006); Torben Iversen & David Soskice, An Asset Theory of Social Policy Preferences , 95 American Political Science Review 875 (2001); Isabela Mares, The Politics of Social Risk (Cambridge University Press 2003). 18 Marco Pagano & Paolo Volpin, The Political Economy of Corporate Governance, 95 American Economic Review 1005 (2005). Marco Pagano and Paolo Volpin, Workers, Managers, and Corporate Control 60 The Journal of Finance 841(2005); Marco 30 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions Pagano & Paolo Volpin, The Political Economy of Finance, 17 Oxford Review of Economic Policy 502 (2001). 19 Gourevitch & Shinn, supra note 5; Raymond Fisman, Estimating the Value of Political Connections, 91 American Economic Review 1095 (2001); Andrew McIntyre, Institutions and Investors: The Politics of the Financial Crisis in Southeast Asia, 55 International Organization 81(2001). 20 Acemoglou and Johnson, supra, note 2. 21 A similar concern with social forms of power can be found in Raghuram Rajan & Luigi Zingales, Creating Constituencies for Reform, Mimeo (2005). 22 David Stasavage, Credible Commitment in Early Modern Europe: North and Weingast Revisited, 18 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 155 (2002). 23 Rajan & Zingales, supra note 21. 24 Gourevitch & Shinn, supra note 4. 25 Mark Roe, Political Determinants of Corporate Governance (Oxford University Press, 2003). 26 Paul MacAvoy & Ira Milstein, The Recurrent Crisis on Corporate Governance (Palgrave 2003); Henry Hansmann & Reiner Kraakman, The End of History for Corporate Law (Harvard University Press 2000). 27 W. Carl Kester, American and Japanese Corporate Governance: Converging to Best Practice? In National Diversity and Global Capitalism, Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, es, (Cornell University Press, 1996) ; Peter Hall and David Soskice , supra , note 17 28 Predicted by Peter Drucker, The Unseen Revolution: How Pension Fund Socialism Came to America (Harper Collins 1976). 29 Hoepner Martin, European Corporate Governance Reform and the German Party Paradox, Max-Planck-Institute for the Study of Societies Program for the Study of Germany and Europe Working Paper Series 03.1 (2003); John W. Cioffi & Martin Hoepner, The Political Paradox of Corporate Governance Reform: Why the Center-Left is the Driving Force Behind the Rise of Financial Capitalism. Paper presented at the 2004 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, September 2-5, in Chicago, Illinois. . 30 Hoepner & Cioffi, supra, note 29. 31 31 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions See Gourevitch & Shinn, supra note 5. 32 See Gourevitch & Shinn, supra note 5; Peter Gourevitch & Jacob Allen, Chilean Pension Reform and Corporate Governance, Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, UCSD, Mimeo, (2006); Fernando Lefort & Eduardo Walker, Ownership and Capital Structure of Chilean Conglomerates: Facts and Hypotheses for Governance. 3 Revista ABANTE 3 (1999). 35 33 Rajan and Zingales, supra , note 3. 34 Berkowitz and Pister, supra, note 11. Mark Roe, Legal Origins and Stock Markets in the Twentieth Century, Mimeo (2006). 36 Enrico Perotti & Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden, The Political Economy of Corporate Control and Labor Rents, 114 Journal of Political Economy 145 –174 (2006); Enrico Perotti and Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden, Dominant Investors and Strategic Transparency, 21 Journal of Law and Economics 76 ( 2005) ; Enrico Perotti and Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden, Corporate Governance and the Distribution of Wealth, 162 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 204 (2006). 37 Ronald Rogoswki, Commerce and Coalitions (Princeton 1989); Peter Gourevitch, Politics in Hard Times, (Cornell 1986); Michael Hiscox, International Trade and Political Conflict: Commerce, Coalitions, and Mobility, (Princeton University Press 2002); Jeffry Frieden, Global Capitalism (Norton 2006). 38 Hall & Soskice, supra, note 17. 39 Paul Milgrom & John Roberts, The Economics of Modern Manufacturing: Technology, Strategy and Organization, 80 American Economic Review 511 (1990). 40 See Gourevitch & Shinn, supra, note 5; Hall & Soskice, supra, note 17 ; and Mark Roe, supra, note 10. 41 See Cheffins, supra note 6; Julian Franks, Colin Mayer & S. Rossi, Spending Less Time with the Family: The Decline of Family Ownership in the UK, in The History of Corporate Governance Around the World: Family Business Groups to Professional Managers (University of Chicago Press 2005); Julian Franks, Colin Mayer & Hannes Wagner, The Origins of the German Corporation – Finance, Ownership and Control, Mimeo, unpublished, (2005). See Randall Morck, Daniel Wolfenzon & Bernard Yeung, Corporate Governance, Economic Entrenchment and Growth, 43 Journal of Economic Literature 655 (2005). 32 3/2/16 world bank , Gourevitch revisions 42 Avner Greif, Paul Milgrom & Barry Weingast, Coordination, Commitment and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Gild, 102 The Journal of Political Economy 745 (1994); Avner Greif, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders' Coalition, 83 American Economic Review 525 (1993). For an evaluation of how decision-maker understanding of their options shapes behavior, see Pepper D. Culpepper, Institutional Change in Contemporary Capitalism: Coordinated Finacial Systems since 1990, 57 World Politics 173 (2005). 43 44 45 John McMillan & Christopher Woodruff, The Central Role of Entrepreneurs in Transition Economies,16 Journal of Economic Perspectives 153 (2002); Simon Johnson, John McMillan & Christopher Woodruff, Property Rights and Finance, 92 American Economic Review 1335 (2002). Daniel Berkowitz, Katharina Pistor & Jean-Francois Richard, supra, note 11. See for example Marianne Bertran, Simon Johnson, Krislert Samphanthrarak & Antoinette Schoar, Mixing Family with Business: A Study of Thai Business Groups and the Families Behind Them, Mimeo (2004); Stephen Haber, Noel Maurer, and Armando Razo, When Law Does Not Matter: The Rise and Decline of the Mexican Oil Industry, 63 Journal of Economic History 1 (2003); Alfred Stepan, Rethinking Military Politics: Brazil and the Southern Cone (Princeton University Press 1988).