Using microsimulation model to get things right: a wage equation for Poland. Preliminary version September 2007 Not for quotation Leszek Morawski, Warsaw University1 Michał Myck, DIW - Berlin Anna Nicińska, Warsaw University Keywords: wage equation, sample selection bias, return to education JEL classification: J24, J30 Abstract We present an application of the Polish microsimulation model SIMPL to estimating the wage equation on data from the Polish Household Budget Survey for year 2005. And yet, research in Poland has so far failed to address two key issues in this area. Because all household level surveys collect information on net incomes some papers analysed net rather than gross wages. Apart from that all known to us estimations of the wages equation using Polish data have so far failed to control for selection, which since Heckman’s seminal paper (1979) has been recognised as a crucial correction in appropriate identification of the parameters of the wage equation. SIMPL allows us to do both: we can compute gross incomes on the basis of net incomes information in the data, and use income in out-of-work scenario generated in the model (together with a set of demographic factors) as an instrument in the selection-corrected equation. The paper demonstrates the degree of bias induced in the approaches taken in the past, presents the first set of selection-corrected wage equation parameters and stresses the importance of the simulated out-of-work incomes as an instrument in controlling for selection. 1 Acknowledgement: Financial support from the EFS by the Polish Ministry of Labor and Social Policy in a project entitled “Model mikrosymulacyjny jako narzędzie wspierające polityki rynku pracy” is gratefully acknowlegded. The data availability from Ministry of Economy, Ministry of Finance, Central Statistical Office, Social Insurance Institution is gratefully appreciated. The usual disclaimer applies. Introduction The tradition of estimating microeconomic wage equation dates back to the paper by Mincer (1974) where both theoretical background and empirical results are provided. Such analyses were popular in 70’s and 80’s (eg. Willis, 1986). However, this hardly concerns Poland. At that time Poland was not a free market economy, and wages were established arbitrary by a planner, thus wages under socialism may be treated as a separated field of economics. On the other hand, it was also possible that despite central planning wages were determined i a similar way to free market economies (Rutkowski, 1994). Once the economical system in Poland transformed, there has not been as much discussion on the determinants of expected wages neither in the Polish economy nor in other ones as in 1980’s since many countries had already investigated the issue in details. In order to properly capture decisions that people make on the labor market one needs to model not only what happens in the labor force, but also what makes people enter or leave labor market. For this reason one needs to be able to predict a wage for everybody regardless whether she or he declares a positive wage. Moreover, the knowledge about potential income outside work for those who work is necessary. Both conditions may be satisfied if there exists a microsimulation model enabling estimation of wage equation corrected for sample selection and simulating incomes from social benefits and assistance if not working. A microsimulation model for Poland (SIMPL2) has been recently developed in cooperation among researchers from Warsaw University, IZA-Bonn and DIW-Berlin (see Bargain et al. (2006)) with financial support by the Polish Ministry of Labour and Social Policy, Ministry of Economy and Ministry of Finances. The additional advantage of SIMPL is a distinction between gross wages, income taxes and benefits from tax and benefit policies. This makes estimation of gross wages possible, thus the impact of wealth distribution within economy is controlled and income taxation is irrelevant for expected wage rate. The way in which wages depend on individual characteristics is the matter of both microeconomic and macroeconomic policies, including inflation, unemployment and labor force participation issues. The knowledge of the way in which wages in Poland are yielded is 2 The model is currently extended in a project called "Microsimulation model as an instrument support labor market policies" financed from the EFS by the Polish Ministry of Labour and Social Policy (see www.simpl.pl). 1 fundamental for understanding the processes that are taking place at the moment and its future consequences. This knowledge seems to be insufficient. This paper aims to provide results of wage estimation using most adequate methodology that has not been employed in such analysis in Poland, as far as we know, and to present basic studies on wages together with most important publications on Poland. First part of this paper describes briefly tradition and methodology of estimating wage equation. Then studies concerning Poland in this field are presented. Following chapter describes methodology and data employed in the research. Than empirical results are provided and interpreted. Final chapter concludes. 1. Review of the most important studies concerning wages Basic studies According to microeconomics, wage is the price of the labor, which is a factor of production, thus wage is equal to the marginal productivity of labor. Keeping in mind all reservations connected with the uniqueness of the production factor supplied by human beings, the wage reflects one’s productivity, which is a function of one’s human capital. There are other factors affecting level of wages, such as inflation rate, trade unions, and regulations such as a minimum wage and so on, but they are not captured directly by the human capital theory. It is said that the level of human capital accumulated is a matter of decision made by a student that can choose between continuing studies for another year subject to forgone earnings and quit schooling. It is assumed that all individuals formulate their human capital in the process of full-time schooling and the cost of each year of schooling related to foregone earnings from that period is constant over time and equal to one for everyone (Becker and Chiswick, 1966). The opportunity cost states a budget constraint for a student maximizing her stream of lifetime earnings conditional of hers human capital. The wage after S years of schooling, assuming constant interest rate is determined in a following way: 2 K Costt const ; r const Waget Wage1 Wage0 rCost1 Wage0 rKWage0 Wage0 (1 rK ) Wage2 Wage1 rCost1 Wage1 rKWage1 Wage1 (1 rK ) Wage0 (1 rK )(1 rK ) ... WageS Wage0 (1 rK ) S ln(WageS ) ln(Wage0 ) ln(1 rK ) S The above equation was used by Mincer (1974) in his empirical research for the US keeping the theoretical log-linear relation between earnings and schooling (Heckman and Polachek, 1974). The assumption of the opportunity cost being a solely cost of education can be relaxed by adding direct costs and cost of student loans (K greater than one) or distracting tax remissions for students (lowering K) (Chiswick, 1997). Moreover, the way in which human capital is generated might be broadened by the inclusion of skills developed at work after finishing formal education. The later paper extends the functional form proposed by human capital theory by the potential experience measured by the time spent potentially at work (one’s age above the age of finishing formal education) (Mincer, 1974) according to the following equation: ln(Wagei ) Const 1Schoolingi 2 Experiencei 3 Experiencei2 i The paper discussed in such detail above was the beginning of a stimulating discussion. Most controversial issue was raised by Heckman in his paper on a sample selection bias as an omitted variable (1976, 1979). It was claimed that the estimates might be biased, as the expected wage was estimated upon the selected sample of those only, who declare positive wage. It is very likely that those who work are equipped with more human capital than those who fail to find a job due to greater ability that cannot be observed and the selection to the employment is not random. If so, sample on which study is conducted is not random and the estimates are inconsistent as a consequence of an omitted variable. Heckman (1979) extends the wage equation model by the participation equation with an instrumental variable allowing for sample selection correction. His method is connected with the reservation wage concept claiming that if one faces wage that is positive but lower than her reservation wage, one is not going to enter the labor market and her wage will not be observed. The nonrandom selection 3 is revealed by positive statistically significant correlation between the two random terms of the two equations. w *i xi i y *i xi1 zi 2 i y 1 if y * 0 i i 2 s N (0, 1 ) i N (0, 22 ) corr (s , s ) i 1, 2,..., I The proper instrumental variable partially correlated with participation decision but insignificant for the wage is crucial for the identification of an omitted variable in the sub sample of workers and the consistency of whole model (Heckman, 1979). There are not many variables that affect decision of entering or leaving job without posing any impact on the wage. However, there is a number of recognized and widely employed instruments such as a non-labor income of an individual, income of a spouse, household wealth or having children, the later especially for women (Puhani, 2000a). The new techniques have been developed and two-step procedure in sample selection models even thought still used (eg. Shonkwiler and Yen, 1999) may be replaced by more efficient but demanding large sample (Puhani, 2000a) full-information or limited-information maximum likelihood methods (eg. Jensen et al., 2001). The maximum likelihood methods are more sensitive to assumption of linear relationship between random terms in wage and participation equation than two-step procedure. However sophisticated described methods are, it is still easier to predict expected wages of those who work (so called two-part model, see: Duan et al. 1983, 1984a, 1984b) than expected wages for the whole population including those with unobserved wages (Hartman, 1991). The most recent studies in methodology of dealing with non-random selection improve self-selection correction estimation (Cunha and Heckman, 2007) while others develop non-parametric methods (Blundell and Powell, 2004). The discussion has raised not only methodological issues. Many doubts concern the linearity of the relation between human capital and earnings. There is still no unanimity on this topic as there are arguments pro (Heckman and Polachek, 1974; Card and Krueger, 1992) and contra linearity (Heckman et al. 1996; Trostel, 2005). The other way of accumulation human capital, 4 which is experience gained during work, seems to be related to wages in a much more complex way as both third and sometimes even fourth power of potential experience are statistically significant (Lemieux, 2004). This has to do with the imperfection of the measure employed by Mincer as the proxy for potential experience making many assumptions criticized in the literature, namely homogeneity of skills (Willis and Rosen, 1979), differentiation of schooling institutions’ efficiency (Psacharopoulos, 1989), life histories and probability of being unemployed through a lifetime which in fact differ, thus the costs of education (Chiswick, 1997) and consequently the rate of return to education may be treated as a variable changed throughout lifetime (Murphy and Welch, 1992). The question whether education is a proper metric of human capital has been raised often (eg. Kroch and Sjoblom, 1994). Furthermore, there is a controversy about the way in which schooling should be measured as the marginal revenue from different levels of education does not need to be constant over generations (Connelly and Gottschalk, 1995) nor over time for a given cohort thus more popular metric of education became the highest level of education obtained instead of years at full-time education (eg. Trostel, 2005). Studies on Polish wages The price regulation mechanism responsible for production factors market equilibrium was not officially in operation in nationalized and centrally planned economy that was present in Poland since the Second World War till 1989. There are few papers concerning determinants of wages under central planning which is a question raised by Rutkowski (1994). It is claimed there that despite the low variation of wages, their determination does not vary much from those under free market rules. However, this study is not based upon human theory solely as it distinguishes a number of additional explanatory variables such as value of fixed assets per employee, firm size, structure of the industry of the firm, ratio of final profit to sales revenue (Rutkowski, 1994). In 1989 the trade has been liberalized and free market was introduced successfully in Poland. Economy was ruled by few regulations; wages could develop freely. The private sector grew rapidly from 29% of GDP in 1989 to 60% of GDP in 1995 (Keane and Prasad, 2002) which was the result of an immediate and full liberalization. Transition has been a period of many deep adjustments in the economy. However interesting there were from the economists’ point 5 of view, there was little tradition (Rutkowski, 1994) and no urgent need to investigate expected wage determinants. However, the case of Polish economy transformation has been recognized as relatively successful and all processes that took place between 1989 and 1996 (when macroeconomic indicators reached stable level) have been interesting to many scientists. Among studies concerning Polish transformation, there is some focusing on wage dynamics and structure of earnings differentiation (eg. Goh and Javorcik, 2005, Newell and Socha, 2005; Puhani, 2000b). Most of them are recent and usually approach the topic from the macroeconomic perspective. The direct result of a free market introduction was an increase in households’ earnings polarization, which was on average greater in private sector than in public sector by 10% and 20% respectively for small and medium firms (Keane and Prasad, 2002). The stronger impact on private enterprises is explained by the fact that public firms were less vulnerable to free market competition, modern management and marketing. The estimation led by Keane and Prasad (2002) was an extended version of standard Mincer equation, controlling for levels of education, rural or urban area, sex, industry and experience in a quadratic form. However, the research was based on cross-sections individual net income over period 1985-1992 and 1994-1996 without sample selection correction for there was no proper instrument available. The most recent estimation of Mincerian equation for Poland explains determination of monthly gross wages of full-time workers of companies employing 9 and more workers controlling for gender, years in formal education and on-the-job training (Rogut and Roszkowska, 2007). The empirical evidence confirms predictions of human capital theory noticing that in case of men the work experience has greatest impact on their wages while in case of women that would be the formal education (Rogut and Roszkowska, 2007). The analysis of wage inequality by Newell and Socha (2005, 2007) are based on individual Poles’ net incomes from work. The research investigates hourly wage rates, and states that their differentiation has not changed much after the transition (Newell and Socha, 1998). It is iclaimed that the increase in the household earnings differentiation was caused not by the change of hourly wage rate, but most of all by the drop of labor supplied by a household due to unemployment (in case of older adults) and decision of continuing education (in case of younger adults). This way of reasoning has been confirmed by Newell (2001) and is in line 6 with the empirics showing significantly greater revenue from higher education level after transition than before it (Keane and Prasad, 2002). Moreover, the revenue from education was greater in private sector than public one in Poland in 1995 (Socha and Weisberg, 2002). The issue of revenue from education is still investigated and there are numerous cross-national studies aiming to compare cultural and national differences between educational systems (eg. Trostel, 2005). One of them estimates extended Mincer equation for male full-time full year workers and self-employed aged 30-55 coming from a number of countries, among them also from Poland, based on data on annual earnings gross of taxes and employee’s social insurance contribution (Hartog et al., 2004). The definition of the correct measure of education is crucial for that comparative research. Note also, that the sample covers very limited part of population so it is not random which means that results shall not be generalized over whole society. The expected wage determination is a field where discrimination might be investigated. Many concepts have been developed in order to explain reasons for which gender is important for the wages and the gender pay gap has been widely examined (eg. Plasman and Sissoko, 2004) also for Poland (Grajek, 2001). Empirical studies on net incomes of full-time employees show that there was a decline in female employment outcomes while the average gender gap remained stable at the 22-23 per cent level between 1993 and 1998 in Poland (Adamchik and Bedi, 2003). The paper by Latuszyński and Woźny (2006) applies Oaxacia decomposition method (1973) in order to find determinants of hourly net wages of employees working in 221 private firms in Poland. The region, actual experience (measured in years at an enterprise and in the industry of the enterprise), level of education and number of children are controlled for. The study focuses solely on the decomposition, so it concerns not what has been explained by qualifications, experience, industry and regional differentiation, but just the opposite: on what can not be explained by the observed individual characteristics other than gender. According to Latuszyński and Woźny (2006) the main reason for lower average female wages is the structure of labor supply, where women usually work in low skills occupations whereas man in high skills occupations and the gender gap in earnings vanishes in marketing, research and development. Another question raised in the literature is relation between unemployment and wages. Such analysis for Poland must take into account regional differences in unemployment rate and labor demand structure and that is the case of estimation of Polish wage curve for period 7 1991-1996 (Duffy and Walsh, 2001). According to the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment concept (Stiglitz, 1997), such unemployment rate would not affect level of wages. This macroeconomic perspective involves additional agents to the standard microeconomic framework such as a central bank with its inflation policy and trade unions with their wages rigidity aiming to verify whether the rate of unemployment reached the natural level neutral for inflation or its nature is structural, difficult to remove and unfavorable for the economy as a whole. Results of the Granger causality test suggest that Polish wage level depended on the unemployment rate, thus unemployment in Poland between 1993 and 2004 was of the later kind (Gaweł, 2006). However macroeconomic analysis of inflation, wages and unemployment are common (eg. Commander and Coricelli, 1992; Welfe and Majsterek, 2002), the functional form of the estimated wage equation is not derived directly from the human capital theory and does not tell much about the individual characteristics affecting marginal productivity of labor. The research presented in the following chapters is a unique one in the light of thus far achievements of Polish labor market analysis. None of them covers such wide sample of parttime and full-time both gender individuals employed by all types of companies with their gross incomes nor proper instrumental variable enabling sample selection correction. 2. Methodology and the data According to empirical studies concerning selection to the labor market, decision whether to work or not is logically and statistically significantly correlated with the level of expected earnings from that work. For this reason Heckman two-step procedure is a proper method of dealing with the estimators’ bias. Linear estimators are also provided in order to make possible adequate comparisons. The dependent variable is a logarithm of monthly wage rate in gross and net terms. w *i xi i y *i xi1 zi 2 i y 1 if y * 0 i i s N (0, 12 ) i N (0, 22 ) corr (s , s ) i 1, 2,..., I 8 The instrumental variables used for model identification are: family disposable income if not working, other household members’ equivalized income and whether a household contains more than one family. There are multifamily households and wealth of household members that does not belong to a family may affect participation decision within this family. In order to distinguish between no other families in household income due to lack of income and due to lack of other families, we control whether a household is a one or more family unit. The disposable income of family if not working is generated by SIMPL as a weighted sum of all benefits and social assistance that a family is entitled to, judging from its financial and demographical situation. It is expected that the greater the non-labor income, the lower probability of entering labor market. The disposable income if not working is calculated at the family level, as a spouse income affects participation decision. Moreover, eligibility to some benefits depends on number of not working partners, thus non-labor income is generated for all possible scenarios (both not working, one is working, both are working) and the value of instruments consistent with observation is chosen for given family. The non-labor income for one family households captures all benefits that whole households are entitled to, such as for instance housing benefit. Other household’s memebers disposable income if a consireded family is not working might be more important for two generation families, where grandparents’ income shall also be taken into account while making labor market participation decision that is why number of families in one household is also included. All these instrumental variables are assumed to be uncorrelated with the individual marginal productivity. The dataset comes from the Household Budget Survey (BBGD) 2005 provided by the Central Statistical Office (GUS). The gross wages are generated by SIMPL according to the Polish income taxation patterns from 2005. The grossed up wages contain income tax, employee’s social and health insurance contributions (Morawski, 2007). It is assumed that all part time workers are exactly half-time workers. The sample contains persons that may be treated as a part of labor force, so children, pensioners and persons unable to work due to health conditions are not taken into account. The category of self-employed is also excluded from the sample as their income from employment cannot be distinguished from their profits. That is why their earnings shall not be treated as wages. The sample is composed of individuals aged 18-59 who are neither retired nor unable to work for health reasons nor self-employed. However, all disabled persons that are able to work are included in the sample, regardless from their disability level. 9 The shape of employees’ gross wage distribution presented in graph 1 is typical, similar to log-normal, which is in line with a theoretical assumption of the econometric model. The income from self-employment does follow this pattern, which is another reason for which self-employees are not taken into account. However, information form Ministry of Finance reveal that the grossing up does not match official data for highest centiles. This makes our estimation biased for individuals with highest wages. .0003 .0002 0 .0001 Density .0004 .0005 Graph 1. Distribution of employees’ gross wage in Poland in 2005 0 5000 10000 d_ipermemp 15000 20000 Source: Authors’ own calculation based upon BBGD 2005. The sample contains 49 593 individuals, among which 26 656 are female, which states 53.75% of the labor force. Education structure within genders is presented in table 1. There are six levels of completed education and three age groups distinguished: - low, aged 18-26 - medium, aged 27-38 - high, aged 39-59. The number of women with tertiary level of education exceeds the number of men with the same education level by 16.44 percentage points in the 27-38 age group, while in other cohorts there are fewer women with higher education than man on average. The fraction of persons without education or those who have finished primary school is greater for the oldest 10 age group and equals 13% in whole population. The gymnasium graduates are underrepresented due to the innovation in schooling system that was introduced in 1999 and it concerns only individuals younger than 22. In general, the majority of whole population has completed secondary technical education and here share of all cohorts and both genders is symmetric. The second most numerous group are vocational education graduates, but here domination of elderly male labor force is very strong as in highest age group almost half of men declares this education level. This category becomes less numerous as age decreases. Table 1. Education structure of Polish labor force for genders within age groups in 2005. Age group 18-26 27-38 39-59 General Male Female Male Female Male Female % % % % % % % Completed education level: - none or primary - gymnasium - vocational - secondary academic - secondary technical - post-secondary professional - higher 10.38 16.05 24.19 17.16 24.40 1.71 6.11 6.95 9.82 13.94 0.00 14.01 43.17 29.61 4.66 21.28 23.76 3.11 1.68 11.11 16.90 9.02 12.62 0.03 0.01 29.62 49.36 9.62 2.67 24.20 24.35 4.17 1.10 33.34 9.88 15.85 0.03 29.50 9.87 26.53 4.77 13.45 13.27 2.90 24.32 11.80 31.98 4.41 11.32 Source: Authors’ own calculation based upon BBGD 2005. The sample consists mostly of employees, who state 62% of whole population examined. In the highest age group 80% of men and 67% of women are employed and similar pattern of male majority in employment holds for all age groups. This is the most popular category in all age groups for both genders, however in case of youngest labor force members, it is less numerous as more individuals seek for work due to the lack of experience, fresh start at the labor market and greater mobility. The group of unoccupied is greatest in youngest age group and levels 44% in case of men and 55% for women. Traditionally, there are more women than men unoccupied for the reason of taking care of house or children, and that is why women are more often inactive as the fractions of non-participants for other than family reasons are similar for both genders. 11 Table 2. Employment status structure of Polish labor force for genders within age groups in 2005. Age group 18-26 27-38 39-59 General Male Female Male Female Male Female % % % % % % % Current employment status: - employee - seeking work and available to start work - waiting to start job already obtained - unoccupied – takes care of house or family - unoccupied – other reason 38.68 30.52 85.23 64.60 79.21 66.67 61.66 16.15 13.86 10.91 11.95 11.40 9.47 12.02 0.93 0.54 0.56 0.59 0.41 0.34 0.53 0.13 44.12 9.12 45.96 0.43 2.87 20.22 2.64 0.44 8.54 12.95 10.57 7.63 18.16 Source: Authors’ own calculation based upon BBGD 2005. Table 3. Family situation of individuals in Polish labor force within age groups in 2005. 18-26 Age group 27-38 39-59 General % 41.48 % 18.54 % 11.89 % 22.42 4.19 26.10 18.40 6.75 6.40 28.13 32.94 10.24 27.92 27.80 21.57 7.67 15.01 27.39 23.77 8.11 3.08 3.75 3.16 3.30 Family composition: - singles without children - individuals in couples without children - individuals with 1 child - individuals with 2 children - individuals with 3 children - individuals with 4 and more children Note: Child is a person aged less than 18 or full time student aged less than 26 and not married. Source: Authors’ own calculation based upon BBGD 2005. The sample consists of 11 118 singles without kids, 7 446 married individuals without children and remaining 31 029 observations are persons with al least one child. Among youngest age group persons without children state 45%. In case of the highest age group, almost 40% of all individuals do not have a dependent child, but among them are usually married persons whose children are aged more than 18. Note that child is defined as a not married person younger than 18 years old or full time student aged less than 26. The most popular family composition is one child family (27%) and two children family (24%). 12 3. Results and discussion The estimated wage equations employ a set of explanatory variables controlling for the highest level of formal education obtained in terms of dummies and age in a cubic form as a proxy of potential experience. The voyevoidships are included as well as town size, which captures local differences, such as a probability of being unemployed. Individuals at the same age coming from regions with different unemployment rates have different work experience, so the geographic measures improve efficiency of age as an instrumental variable. Also disability level is important for the wage received. The age and number of children are significant as far as marginal productivity is concerned, especially if there is a young child that needs care. Marital status is also taken into account as it captures new roles that individuals start to play with starting a family that cannot be explained by the fact of having children. The results of estimations are provided in following tables. Table 4 presents estimates of net wage determinants using ordinary least squares linear regression and two step Heckman model with sample selection. The outliers defined as wages greater than 99.5 centil are excluded from estimations. Wages lower than first centil are replaced with the first cetile’s value. The linear regression is based upon 26 872 observations and employs 40 explanatory variables, which is not much as for such big sample, thus all statistics have relatively high degree of freedom. All of them are statistically significant at least at 5% significance level except from the dummies for second, third, fourth and young child. The fit of the model is high, as it reaches almost 30%, which confirms together with the F statistic that the set of explanatory variables is statistically significant. Moreover, the high number of independent variables raises the fit of the model. As far as the linear regression of net monthly wages, the most important variable affecting wage rate in a positive way is education. In comparison to person with primary or none education, wage rate of an employee with high education grows by 72%, while wage of an employee with post-secondary degree by 42%. Secondary education brings similar benefit regardless whether one has an academic or technical nature and raises net wage growth by 34%. Linear regression is in line with the theoretical relation between wage that is positive but diminishing with age. In comparison to inhabitants of biggest towns, other individuals earn less and this impact is the stronger the smaller the town is. Similar pattern is observed for 13 persons living in another than capital voyevoidship. This reflects general local economy condition of regions with heterogeneity within them controlled by the town size. Disability may affect productivity in a negative way, and the more severe disability is the greater negative impact on net wage it has. However, negative coefficients on disability levels might also reflect discrimination. Women’s earnings grow slower than men by 22% and married people’s wages grow faster than singles by 10%. The estimates described above are inconsistent, as the t-Student test for correlation between participation and wage equations states that the hypothesis of a lack of such correlation is rejected with probability equal to 1. The correlation is high (almost 83%) and positive which confirms theoretical expectations that unobserved characteristics affect both wage and participation decision is a positive way. The statistical significance of rho estimate and of coefficients on instrumental variables suggests that they state a proper way of identification of the Heckman two equation model. According to results corrected for sample selection bias, the impact on net wage of education is stronger than predicted by simple linear regression. The estimate on higher education is higher now by 23 percentage points and equals 0.95. The second strongest factor increasing net earnings is post-secondary professional education with coefficient 0.60. Heckman selection estimation reveals that secondary technical education might seem slightly more beneficial than the secondary academic as far as net wage is concerned, as coefficient on first one is 0.48 while the other one is 0.43. The remaining levels of education do not bring dramatic change to net wage and the gymnasium seems to lower expected net wage. One shall remember that gymnasium is relatively new element of Polish schooling system thus persons declaring it are usually very young. Gymnasium does not form human capital that affects directly one productivity by developing skills and knowledge necessary for further education but irrelevant for employers. If education is not continued after graduating from gymnasium, this schooling does not make any difference. Moreover, school is relatively costly, as full time education prevents from gaining work experience without bringing any benefit. For these reasons finishing education after gymnasium does not make much sense. 14 Table 4. Estimators of log net wage determinants with and without sample selection correction. Heckman two-step Wage Participation constant higher education post-secondary professional secondary technical secondary academic vocational education gymnasium age age squared age cubed/1000 town size 200,000 - 499,999 town size100,000 - 199,999 town size 20,000 - 99,999 town up to 19,999 village one child two children three children four children five or more children child aged less than 7 dolnoslaskie kujawsko-pomorskie lubelskie lubuskie lodzkie malopolskie opolskie podkarpackie podlaskie pomorskie slaskie swietokrzyskie warminsko-mazurskie wielkopolskie zachodniopomorskie married significant disability medium disability low disability female 3.41190** .94838** .59843** .47845** .42964** .21859** -.31462** .19838** -.00381** .02367** -.07557** -.12278** -.16026** -.18773** -.18665** .02875** .02649* -.03426* -.07024* -.14517** .02319* -.15934** -.22800** -.21592** -.16044** -.15486** -.13922** -.06674** -.20950** -.20587** -.11110** -.12516** -.25459** -.18324** -.11853** -.12258** .22611** -.55326** -.28772** -.26827** -.32184** family non-labor income household income multifamily household Number of observations Rho Adjusted R2 Lambda -3.18703** 1.2944** .89276** .67432** .45555** .33893** -.28871** .18365** -.00201** -.00320 -.01148 -.05986 -.10997** -.14502** -.09135** -.04408* -.13686** -.24090** -.30430** -.41736** -.15410** -.24587** -.20184** -.24592** -.08441 -.07132* -.11674** -.11290* -.26456** -.19147** -.16519** -.21922** -.32054** -.20473** .00484 -.18568** .74963** -.61502** -.19442** -.05364 -.56467** OLS Wage 5.08180** .72574** .42417** .34572** .34630** .14136** -.12182 .11047** -.00212** .01391** -.07798** -.11841** -.14585** -.16979** -.17727** .04923** .06728** .02458 .00229 -.04891 .04736** -.11763** -.19441** -.17561** -.14917** -.14880** -.12219** -.04663* -.16943** -.17590** -.08283** -.08977** -.20511** -.15081** -.11946** -.09342** .10164** -.41902** -.23823** -.25358** -.22160** -.00014** -.00006** -.08916** 26872 .829** 39300 26872 .302 .44976 Note: ** statistically significant at 1% significance level; * statistically significant at 5% significance level. Source: Authors’ own calculation based upon BBGD 2005. 15 Potential experience increases with age, however capacity of skills and knowledge adaptation is limited and starting from certain age, one’s productivity does not increase despite cumulated time spent at work is growing. In some cases this might even cause a drop in productivity, especially in occupations where fresh attitude and new technologies are crucial. The estimation confirms that marginal productivity reflected by net wage grows at pace 15% per year at the beginning of career then this rate is diminishing. The magnitude of potential experience was underestimated in the linear regression. Results presented in table 4 are in line with other estimations stating that third power of age is statistically significant as far as wage rates are concerned. The last factor increasing wages is marital status, which is also underestimated in linear regression as it reaches 0.10 while under Heckman 0.23 respectively. The fact of being married lowers one’s mobility, as such family situation affects flexibility in a negative way. Similar reasoning explains positive coefficients on having a young child, but the later mechanism is relatively weaker than pure fact of being married. Employers’ perception of such individuals is favorable, as now they are perceived as more reliable, loyal and more stable. That makes employers more willing to invest more in trainings for this group of employees. In the following estimations the distinction between marital status of women and men is made. The application of Heckman’s selection correction allows identification of factors affecting decision whether to work or not. The estimates provided in table 5 are calculated on the basis of gross monthly wage rates. The higher family non-labor income prevents persons living in one family household from entering labor market as there are lower financial incentives to earn additional money. Similar mechanism holds for households with more than 1 family. Severely disabled persons are substantially less likely to work than healthy individuals whereas medium and low disability level does not affect participation as the coefficients are statistically insignificant and low. The fact of being married facilitates work, but having children, especially more than 2 or at least one aged less than 7, prevents from working. That is because children demand care and it is often more expensive to hire a babysitter than take care of home alone. Probability of being employed is the lower, the smaller the town is. Due to migration from villages to towns, the fact of living at the countryside does not affect participation decision in a way it does in small towns. The most unwilling to enter 16 Table 5. Estimators of log gross wage determinants with and without sample selection correction. Heckman two-step Wage Participation constant higher education post-secondary professional secondary technical secondary academic vocational education gymnasium age age squared age cubed/1000 town size 200,000 - 499,999 town size100,000 - 199,999 town size 20,000 - 99,999 town up to 19,999 village one child two children three children four children five or more children child aged less than 7 dolnoslaskie kujawsko-pomorskie lubelskie lubuskie lodzkie malopolskie opolskie podkarpackie podlaskie pomorskie slaskie swietokrzyskie warminsko-mazurskie wielkopolskie zachodniopomorskie married significant disability medium disability low disability female 3.30089** 1.05668** .67457** .54096** .48000** .24928** -.35432** .22262** -.00426** .02604** -.07913** -.12949** -.17258** -.20341** -.20260** .01774 .01390 -.05569** -.09675** -.19092** .01644 -.17716** -.24942** -.23709** -.17307** -.16654** -.15098** -.07392** -.22983** -.22369** -.12584** -.13989** -.28189** -.19939** -.12648** -.13472** .25791** -.61535** -.33363** -.31153** -.35673** family non-labor income household income multifamily household Number of observations Rho Adjusted R2 Lambda -3.18703** 1.29436** .89276** .67432** .45554** .33893** -.28871** .18365** -.00202** -.00320 -.01148 -.05986 -.10997** -.14502** -.09134** -.04408* -.13686** -.24090** -.30430** -.41735** -.15410** -.24587** -.20185** -.24593** -.08441 -.07132* -.11675** -.11290* -.26456** -.19147** -.16519** -.21922** -.32054** -.20473** .00485 -.18568** .74963** -.61502** -.19442** -.05364 -.56467** OLS Wage 5.25367** .79633** .47081** .38574** .38255** .15897 -.12886** .11982** -.00228** .01462** -.08194** -.12437** -.15573** -.18243** -.19163** .04168** .06160 .01311 -.01192 -.07836** .04471** -.12838** -.21014** -.18996** -.15989** -.15945** -.13108** -.05041* -.18298** -.18865** -.09173** -.09850** -.22402** -.16147** -.12757** -.10061** .11235** -.45837** -.27576** -.29436** -.23950** -.00014** -.00006** -.08916** 26872 .850** 39300 26872 .309 .50606 Note: ** statistically significant at 1% significance level;* statistically significant at 5% significance level. Source: Authors’ own calculation based upon BBGD 2005. 17 labor are inhabitants of Swietokrzyskie, Podkarpackie and Kujawsko-Pomorskie voyevoidships while the most willing are in Mazowieckie, Lubuskie and Wielkopolskie. The participation and gross wage equations are strongly positively correlated and the hypothesis of no correlation between them is again rejected with probability 1. Similarly to the net wage regressions, the linear estimates are underestimated due to the sample selection bias. As far as the gross wage rate is concerned, the impact of all explanatory variables is not interfered by the progressive taxation and health insurance. That is why the estimates from Heckman two equation model presented in table 5 reflect impact of explanatory variables on the expected gross wage in an adequate way. However, there are only minor differences between results for net and gross specifications. The coefficients of education levels are underestimated in case of net wage regressions, only gymnasium and vocational training estimates do not differ between the two alternative dependant variables. The revenue from higher education reaches 1.06, while contribution to gross wage from post secondary professional schooling equals 0.95 and the difference in estimates’ values is statistically significant. The positive difference between benefits coming from secondary technical than academic education is slightly greater than in case of net wages. Higher revenues from education for gross wages are in line with the progressive tax system, as better educated persons pay higher taxes as their wages are greater due to productivity driven by high qualifications. The potential experience affects the gross wage rate in a slightly different way than net wages, however dynamics remain similar, and the starting point is lower and equals 0.22 at the beginning of working life. All regions other than Warsaw value labor less, especially in smaller towns. The lowest gross wage rates in comparison to capitol voyevoidship are observed in Swietokrzyskie and Kujawsko-pomorskie, as the unemployment rates there are relatively high. The smallest gap in gross wages between Mazowieckie is present in Opolskie, but if we take into account the fact that in that region there are usually towns smaller than 200000 inhabitants the difference between Warsaw gross wage rates becomes more significant. 18 Table 6. Estimators of log gross wage determinants with sample selection correction in genders. Men Wage constant higher education post-secondary professional secondary technical secondary academic vocational education gymnasium age age squared age cubed/1000 town size 200,000 - 499,999 town size100,000 - 199,999 town size 20,000 - 99,999 town up to 19,999 village one child two children three children four children five or more children child aged less than 7 dolnoslaskie kujawsko-pomorskie lubelskie lubuskie lodzkie malopolskie opolskie podkarpackie podlaskie pomorskie slaskie swietokrzyskie warminsko-mazurskie wielkopolskie zachodniopomorskie married significant disability medium disability low disability 3.28402** .88628** .48764** .47242** .39563** .23216** -.65947** .23206** -.00499** .03458** -.03270 -.10048** -.12033** -.16935** -.16196** .04899** .07023** .04233 .01890 -.03752 .03184* -.11540** -.23402** -.22843** -.14917** -.15515** -.11994** -.05884 -.20327** -.24948** -.09260** -.05664** -.27825** -.17200** -.09056** -.08693** .52159** -.61843** -.38306** -.40913** family non-labor income household income multifamily household Number of observations Rho Lambda Participation -4.9945** .83797** .48166** .47751** .16874** .29438** -.48515** .35304** -.00742** .04665** .03575 .01256 -.03612 -.09137* .05663 -.07892** -.19343* -.10751 -.11642 .18251 .21758** -.18483** -.17090** -.23812** -.04265 -.07745 -.12600* -.10008 -.23525** -.27208** -.06144 -.07320 -.29604** -.19469** .09613 -.11136 1.22796** -.46451* -.19461* -.15317 Wage Women Participation 3.40200** 1.0465** .66293** .53263** .48953** .18359** .03087 .21183** -.00406** .02523** -.11862** -.14412** -.21481** -.23051** -.22907** -.03852** -.05064** -.14906** -.19559** -.30627** -.03259* -.20910** -.24657** -.22364** -.18017** -.17464** -.16206** -.05541 -.23102** -.18692** -.12819** -.19906** -.24430** -.21302** -.15258** -.15913** .08738** -.43227** -.24489** -.20279** -.00005** -.00008** -.06542* 18842 .850** .49957 14305 -3.52312** 1.48533** 1.03010** .80033** .57413** .32787** -.03022 .16765** -.00102 -.01608 -.04162 -.11021* -.17365** -.19391** -.19685** -.14951** -.21844** -.39500** -.48759** -.79758** -.36704** -.28584** -.22851** -.27236** -.11516 -.09099* -.09205* -.09038 -.29775** -.15624* -.21934** -.29751** -.29369** -.19186** -.06508 -.22170** .50658** -.64288** -.23958* .01784 -.00018** .00001 -.09501** 12567 .660** .34185 20458 Note: ** statistically significant at 1% significance level; * statistically significant at 5% significance level. Source: Authors’ own calculation based upon BBGD 2005. 19 The situation of women in terms of gross wages is slightly worse than in net wage, as the coefficient on gender for gross and net wage equals respectively 0.36 and 0.32 in favor for men. The fact of being married controlling for children remains at the similar level for gross and net wage. Also estimates on number of children in family and the presence of a child younger than 7 years old are not affected by the change in dependent variable because personal tax and health insurance system does not differ much for different number of children. This does not hold for disability levels, as the net wage estimates on them are underestimated. A person with severe disability is paid less and his or hers gross wage is lower by 61 percentage points in comparison to not disabled. This negative impact is weakened with the less significant disability, but even persons with low level receive gross wages lower by 41 percentage points than others’. It is not trivial to distinguish whether these differences occur due to actual difference in productivity or due to discrimination. Such decomposition may be conducted as far as female labor force is concerned. In order to distinguish more precisely where does the difference between genders gross wage comes from, two separated regressions are made. The results are presented in table 6. The correlation between participation and expected gross wage is positive and statistically significant for both genders, however in case of women is greater by 19 percentage points than in case of men, for whom it equals 85%. The strongest impact on decision whether to work comes from formal qualifications and the greater schooling one has completed, the greater incentives to work. Formal education affects male’s work decision weaker than female especially with high education levels, because in case of man the experience is substantially more important than for women. That is probably due to the labor force division in so called male and female occupations. The jobs traditionally taken by men demand usually more responsibility and formal qualifications are relatively less important than experience. The coefficient on age, which is a proxy for potential experience, is substantially greater for men than women. The most evident difference between genders is the traditional role in growing children up. Women are usually expected to provide care, while men salary. The fact of having child aged less than 7 prevents women from working while facilitates men’s labor supply. Such behavior might be Pareto optimal if female expected hourly wage rate is lower than male and professional child care is more expensive than potential net earnings of a carer. Moreover, 20 once a family is eligible for child care suplement, decision of taking a job is connected with a loss of the benefit. For women each child makes her less likely to work not only for the child care reason, but also due to interruptions to work experience. The fact of being married makes women more prone to work and impact of marriage is twice as big in case of man. In fact, marital status is even more important for participation decision for men than higher education completed. The expected gross wage for women with higher education level grows faster by 16 percentage points than for man with the same characteristics. The same pattern of greater female than male revenues from education holds for all its levels, except from vocational as the group of occupations where vocational training is needed are usually perceived as better performed by men. These mechanisms would explain relatively great number of highly educated women. The age reflecting potential experience does not favor any gender, as the coefficient on age variables are similar for men and women. The dynamics are similar, as the second and third power of age have similar impact on gross wages. One shall remember that despite more experienced women are more likely to earn more than men; they are also less likely to work. Disability affects men stronger than women for all disability levels, which also may be credited to male occupations usually demanding specific skills. The favorable revenues from qualifications and experience of women remains at the same level regardless from their marital status as long as they do not have children. The coefficient on being married for women equals 0.09 whereas for men reaches 0.52. This major difference results from different expectations towards married man and women. The later one is expected to give a birth while the former one to work hard for his family. That may result in a different perception of productivity according to gender with the change of marital status. All coefficients on number of children and having a young child are negative for women while for men are positive. However, the constant in wage equation for women is actually greater than for men. If we neglect wage difference coming from potential experience the expected gross monthly log gross wage of a single women without children and no education living in Warsaw is estimated at the 3.40 level while for men with the same remaining characteristics it reaches 3.28.. The place of living does matter more for women than men, due to their lower mobility, as they are expected to stay with family once father or husband may work outside his place of 21 living. The other explanation is that discrimination of women is greater in smaller towns and villages than in cities. The same disproportion in magnitude of place of living holds as far as regions are concerned as for almost all voyevoidships except from two, negative coefficients are lower for women than men. Conclusions The estimations described in this paper confirm that the selection to work is not random and wage determinants obtained by ordinary least squares method are inconsistent. The application of Heckman two-step procedure eliminates this bias as estimates are corrected for the sample selection treated as an omitted variable. The instrumental variables employed in identification of two-equation models are family non-labor income and income of other household members controlling whether a household consists of one or more families. Positive and statistically significant estimate on correlation between wage and participation equation for all specifications confirm that these instruments are correct. Results obtained in Heckman model are in line with theory and also with other empirical results in the field. Positive returns to education grow with its level. The gymnasium is an exception as it includes also cohort effect, as it is observed only for persons aged less than 22 as it has been introduced in 1999. Potential experience behaves according to theory and brings positive but diminishing marginal return to productivity. Married persons and public sector workers earn on average more than private sector while disabled individuals earn less according to their disability level. The family situation affects productivity in different way for different genders. The number of children makes women less willing to work while fathers are more likely to work than childless men. Children make men more productive, which is true for women only for her first and second child. Controlling for family composition, female wages are lower than those of men. The regression of gross wage determinants ran separately for men and women reveal that women benefit more than men from formal education, which is especially strong for its high levels. The estimates on explanatory variables corrected for sample selection reveal that returns to education, especially for it high levels, were underestimated in linear models. Also the impact of disability on expected earnings is stronger than predicted using ordinary least squares models. The discrimination of women on labor market is observed in lower wages on average 22 and corrected estimates suggest that gender gap is greater if we take into account whole population, not only individuals whose wages are observed. Another conclusion derived from the research is that distinction between gross and net wages is important as results obtained for the two alternative specifications of explanatory variables are significantly different. 23 References Adamchik V. A., Bedi A. S., (2003), Gender Pay differentials During Transition in Poland, Economics of Transition, Vol. 11, 2003 Bargain O., Morawski L., Myck M., Socha M., (2006), Raport końcowy. Projekt Polski Model Mikrosymulacyjny, Warsaw, 2006 Becker G. S., Chiswick B. R., (1966), Education and the Distribution of Earnings, American Economic Review, Vol. 56, May 1966 Blundell R., Powell J. L., (2004), Censored Regression Quantiles with Endogenous Regressors, http://www.columbia.edu/~ev2156/_seminarpapers/BlundellPowellCRQ.pdf, November 2004 Card D., Krueger A., (1992), Does School Quality Matter? Returns to Education and the Characteristics of Public Schools in the United States, Journal of Political Economy, 100, February 1992 Chiswick B. R., (1997), Interpreting the Coefficient of Schooling in the Human Capital Earnings Function, The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series, No. 1790, April 1997 Commander S., Coricelli F., (1992), Prace-Wage Dynamics and Inflation in Socialist Economies: Emporical Models for hungary and Poland, World Bank Economics review, Vol. 6, No. 1, 1992 Connelly J., Gottschalk P., (1995), The Effect of Cohort Composition on Human Capital Accumulation acros Generations, Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, January 1995 Cunha F., Heckman J., (2007), A New Framework for the Analysis of Inequality, IZA Discussion Paper No. 2565, January 2007 Duan N., Manning W. G., Morris C. N., Newhouse J. P., (1983), A Comparison of Alternative Models for the Demand of Medical Care, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 1, No. 2, 1983 Duan N., Manning W. G., Morris C. N., Newhouse J. P., (1984a), Choosing Between SamleSelection Model and the Multi-Part Model, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 2, No. 3, 1984 Duan N., Manning W. G., Morris C. N., Newhouse J. P., (1984b), Comments on Selectivity Bias, Advances in Health Economics and Health Services Research, Vol. 6, 1984 24 Duffy F., Walsh P. P., (2001), Indicidual Pay and Outside Options: Evidence from the Polish Labor Survey, Trinity College Working Paper No. 364, March 2001 Gaweł A., (2006), Wymuszony czy dobrowolny charakter bezrobocia w Polsce, http://ekonom.univ.gda.pl/mikro/konferencja/pdf/Gawel%20Aleksandra1.pdf, (2006) Goh C., Javorcik B. S., (2005), Trade Protection and Industry wage Structure in Poland, World bank Policy Research Working Paper 3552, March 2005 Grajek M., (2001), Gender Pay Gap in Poland, Discussion Paper FS IV 01-13, Wiessenschatszentrum Berlin, 2001 Hartman R. S., (1991), A Monte Carlo Analysis of Alternative Estimators in Models Involving Selectivity, Journal of Business & Statistics, Vol. 9, No. 1, January 1991 Hartog J., Bejdechi S., van Opheim H., (2004), Investment in Education in Nine NationsReturn and Risk, Univeristy of Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute, March 2004 Heckman J. J., (1976), The Common Structure of Statistical Models Truncation, Sample Selection and Limited Dependent Variables and a Simple Estimator for Such Models, Annals of Economic Social Measurement, Vol. 5, No. 4, 1976 Heckman J. J., (1979), Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error, Econometrica, Vol. 47, No. 1, 1979 Heckman J. J., Layne-Farrar A., Todd P., E, (1996), Human Capital Pricing Equations with an Application to Estimating the Effect of Schooling Quality on Earnings, Review of Economics and Statistics, 78, November 1996 Heckman J. J., Polachek S., (1974), Empirical Evidence on the Functional Form of the Earning-Schooling Relationship, Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 69, 1974 Jensen P., Rosholm M., Verner M., (2001), Comparison o Different Estimators for Panel Data Sample Selection Models, University of Aarhus, Economics Working Paper No.2002-1, December 2001 Keane M. P., Prasad E. S., (2002), Changes in the Structure of Earnings During the Polish Transition, IZA Discussion Paper No. 496, May 2002 Kroch E. A., Sjoblom K., (1994), Schooling as Human Capital or a Signal, Journal of Human Recources, Vol. 29, 1994 Latuszyński K., Woźny Ł., P., (2006), Zróżnicowanie wynagrodzeń kobiet i mężczyzn na polskim rynku pracy w 2004 roku, Warsaw, 19 March 2006 Lemieux T., (2004), The Mincer Equation. Thirty Years after ‘Schooling, Experience, and Earnings’, Center For Labor Economics Working Papers, University of Berkeley, 2004 25 Mincer J., (1974), Schooling Experience, and Earnings, New York, Columbia University Press, 1974 Morawski L., (2007), Ubruttowienie dochodów z BBGD2005 na potrzeby modelu SIMPL05, http://www.simpl.nazwa.pl/mambo/download/Ubruttowienie_dochodow.pdf, Warsaw, 2007 Murphy K. M., Welch F., (1992), The Structure of Wages, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1992 Newell A. T., (2001), The Distribution of Wages in Transition Countries, Economic Systems, Vol. 25, No. 4, 2001 Newell A. T, Socha M. W., (2005), The Distribution of Wages in Poland 1992-2002, IZA Discussion Paper No. 1485, February 2005 Newell A. T, Socha M. W., (2007), The Polish Wage Inequality Explosion, forthcoming in Economics of Transition, 2007 Oaxacia R., (1973), Male-Female Wage Differentials in Urban labor Markets, International Economic Review, Vol. 14, 1973 Plasman R., Sissoko S., (2004), Comparing Apples with Oranges: Revisiting the Gender Wage Gap in an International Perspective, IZA Working Paper No. 1449, 2004 Psacharopolous G., (1989), Time-Trends of the returns to Education: Cross-National Evidence, Economics of Education Review, Vol. 8. Issue 3, 1989 Puhani P. A., (2000a), The Heckman Correction for Sample Selection and Its Critique? A Short Survey, Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 14, Issue 1, February 2000 Puhani P. A., (2000b), On the Identification of Relative Wage Rigidity Dynamics. A Proposal for a Methodology on Cross-Section Data and Empirical Evidence for Poland in Transition, IZA Discussion Paper No. 226, 2000 Rogut A., Roszkowska S., (2007), Wages and Human Capital in Poland, January 2007 Rutkowski J., (1994), Wage Determination in Late Socialism: The Case of Poland, Economics of Planning, Vol. 27, 1994 Shonkwiler S. J., Yen S. T., (1999), Two-step estimation of a censored system of equations, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, November 1999 Socha M. W., Weisberg J., (2002), Labor market transition in Poland: changes in the public and private sectors, International Journal of Manpower, Vol. 23, No. 6, 2002 Stiglitz, (1997), Reflections on the Natural Rate Hypothesis, Journal of Economics Perspectives, Vol. 11,1997 26 Trostel P. A., (2005), Nonlinearity in the Return to Education, Journal of Applied Economics, May 2005 Welfe A., Majsterek M., (2002), Wage and Price Inflation in Poland in the period of Transition: The Cointegration Analysis, economics of Planning, Vol. 35, Issue 3, 2002 Willis R. J., (1986), Wage Determinants: A Survey and Reinterpretation of Human Capital Earnings Functions, in: O. Aschenfelter and R. Layard, Handbook of Labour Economics, Vol. 1, 1986 Willis R. J., Rosen S., (1979), Education and Self-Selection, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 87, Issue 5, 1979 27