Uncertainty, Competence and the Theory of the Firm (Some crucial omissions and misunderstandings of the current debate) by Angelo Fusari Istituto di Studi e Analisi Economica (ISAE) Piazza dell’Indipendenza, 4, 00185 Roma, Italy Email a.fusari@Isae.it Tel. 06 44482877 Paper presented at the second meeting of the European Network on the Economics of the Firm (ENEF), Erasmus University, Rotterdam, 8-9 September 2005 Abstract: This essay aims in particular at remedying one of the major failing of the current state of the analysis on uncertainty, competences and innovation: the lack of a measure of radical uncertainty and of tension in the use of entrepreneurial skill. It shows the possibility of those measures and their importance for the explanation of investment, innovation and some other crucial variables. The shaped model of the firm also flanks transaction costs with productive expenses and emphasizes the monitoring role of profit rate as expression of the firm’s results. Some FIML estimates at the industry level are provided. Keywords: Entrepreneurship, Competence, Uncertainty, Innovation, Decision-making, Estimations Introduction This paper considers the problem of the firm in the perspective of general economics much more than in that of business schools. In fact, it seems to us that a major shortcoming of the good deal of work performed by those schools is the lack of coordination with general economics. In an earlier essay1, we treated entrepreneurship and economic process at length. The present paper complements it by adding a treatment of the firm. Despite the incessant transformations of the economic background, which produce parallel changes in the organization of the firm, some basic features preserve substantial stability. Unfortunately, their meaning is obscured by various misunderstandings; some clarification is accordingly required. A main feature of modern economies is the central and growing role that creativity and innovation play in the context of the process of dynamic competition. They generate uncertainty that makes entrepreneurship, decentralization and market institutions indispensable, being bureaucratic decision making no congenial to uncertainty. Therefore, the treatment of creativity, innovation and entrepreneurship requires a parallel and accurate treatment of uncertainty and a tight theoretical interaction amongst them. At present, economics is afflicted by a sharp division between a line that presumes perfect knowledge, also including known probability distributions, and another emphasizing true or radical uncertainty, i. e. incomplete knowledge and the connected notion of bounded rationality. Unfortunately, the second and more realistic line unanimously supposes, as far as I know, that radical uncertainty is unmeasurable by definition. We shall see, both from a theoretical and empirical perspective, that 1 See A. Fusari (2005) 1 this assumption is wrong, that it deviates attention from the level of uncertainty and its variation and that this condemns in a state of theoretical vagueness some important variables, such as entrepreneurship and innovation as well as decisional criteria. Besides, it prevents a coherent formalization of the dynamic competition process, which is indispensable to encapsulate the theory of the firm in general economics. It will also be shown the way of measuring the degree of radical uncertainty and discussed the importance of such measure for the explanation of innovation, investment, the formation and use of (hence the tension in) entrepreneurial capability. Moreover, it will be pointed out that the refusal of optimization because it would require the irrealistic hypothesis of perfect knowledge is due to the wrong assumption of non measurableness of radical uncertainty; in the presence of that measure, it is perfectly possible to arrange optimization with radical uncertainty and hence to use the approach in decision-making. The paper is organized as follows: Section 1 expounds some very general consideration on organization, capabilities and uncertainty. Section 2 briefly discusses a number of significant aspects of the present debate on the firm. Section 3 is specifically dedicated to the controversy on optimization, relevant for its links with the notions of entrepreneurship and uncertainty. Section 4 presents some developments that give a special importance to uncertainty, entrepreneurial capabilities, innovation, the role of the firm and its decision-making. Section 5 sets out a formalization of the entire theory, and Section 6 presents some estimations of the model. 1. Organization, capabilities and uncertainty The question of the firm is part of the more general topic of organizational and institutional forms and may opportunely be hinged on such a general framework. Man needs organizational forms, as a consequence of his skill limitations that make necessary co-operation and hence its organization. Social systems cannot limit themselves to the establishment of some general rules aimed at allowing common life, trusting for the remainder on individual action. Some more specifical and involving organizational problems must also be faced; otherwise not even the accomplishment of general regulations will be warranted. Human societies have known, in the course of history, two main types of organizations that profoundly differ each other for both contents and implications: a) Closed organizational forms, the nature of which is conservative and bureaucratic; they dominated in tribal societies based on relatives and strongly characterized the administrative structures of ancient great empires. These organizational forms are suitable to face repetitive processes and to operate in the presence of perfect knowledge. Accordingly, they thwart innovation and uncertainty that disconcert them and paralyse their ability to take decisions. In parallel lines, they tend to preserve and perfect the repetitivity of processes, which is congenial to them. b) Open organizational forms, driven by entrepreneurial behavior. They characterize the social systems inclined to innovate and distinguished by high 2 uncertainty. This kind of organization requires and feeds on some decisional skills that are the opposite of those sub a and are characterized by versatility, ability to meet unknown and to engender new situations, in sum, to meet and feed uncertainty. Open organizational forms remained marginal for a long historical time. In the beginning, they came forth in the presence of natural contexts that promoted uncertainty or very aleatory activities (e.g. commercial relations) and/or as part of civilizations that stimulated critical behavior, adventure and evolutionary process. This kind of organization emphasizes, beside the limitation of skills, a more troubling kind of limitation concerning knowledge. Open and entrepreneurial organization has vigorously spread in Western world; the economy has represented the most fertile soil of its development. The firm is a main entrepreneurial organization (sub b) devoted to produce goods or services. Therefore, the problem of its nature and existence is part of the wider field of dynamic and entrepreneurial organizational forms and the growing need of these caused by the acceleration of evolutionary process. In some sense, the firm has accentuated the peculiar traits of open organizations, first of all, the pattern of capabilities requested by true uncertainty. Therefore, in the study of the firm, the insistence on administrative organization may cause some serious misunderstandings, since it is mainly typical of non entrepreneurial forms (sub a) that often show a very sophisticated and well specified administrative organization. It is important to not forget that the firm derives its very nature of entrepreneurial agent from uncertainty. For one side, it causes uncertainty through innovation in a more direct and insistent way than other open organizational forms; for the other side, it is obliged to meet uncertainty caused by other innovators or exogenous accidents. Profit, the main target of the firm, is the result of uncertainty, i.e. the limitations of knowledge and the connected differentials in capabilities; as a matter of fact, only limited and hence differentiated skills can evolve and produce gains. In the absence of exogenous shocks or innovation, the opportunities for profit would disappear. If considered in the perspective of general economics, the firm is the engine of the dynamic competition process, which characterizes the functioning of modern economies. For that process is the result of the entrepreneurial activity of search and discovery of profit opportunities based both on innovation and arbitrage over time and space, with the aim to extract gain from the disequilibria and darkness characterizing evolutionary processes. Therefore, dynamic competition seems to be the most appropriate tool for inserting the theory of the firm in general economics. So, the skills, knowledge, innovation and, more in general, the role of the firm must be considered in relation to uncertainty since in the absence of this one there would be no need of entrepreneurial decisions and organization. But the simple reference to uncertainty is not enough. It is necessary to measure and verify its level that, as we shall see, assumes a central role for the formation and use of capabilities and hence for determining the tension in that use, as well as for explaining innovation, investment and, last but not least, representing dynamic competition, indispensable to conjugate the theory of the firm to general economics. 3 2. Some significant aspects of the debate on the firm Uncertainty is a dominating trait of the human societies where the economy holds a central position and hence strongly pushes growth and development. Notwithstanding, uncertainty has been turned round by mainstream economics through the hypothesis of perfect knowledge and competition that brings out play entrepreneurial skills. Upon this hypothesis (that includes the case of known probability distribution, i. e. probabilistic certainty)) has grown a theoretical system extremely coherent in the appearance but in effect undermined by a fundamental inconsistency: it is qualified for bureaucratic-conservative organizations typical of repetitive societies or, more in general, of societies that have less to do with uncertainty; nevertheless, it pretends to explain the behavior of open entrepreneurial economies. The perception of the fundamental role that play uncertainty and the limitation of knowledge has progressively entered economics. A number of theoretical approaches have grown on this perception and may be unified under the denomination of “heterodox economics”. In a seminal contribution of many years ago, E. Penrose reacted to the hypothesis of perfect knowledge, which erases entrepreneurial capabilities, through a “Theory of the growth of the firm” that is founded upon the availability and evolution of its managerial capabilities and knowledge and the ability to diversify production. She says: «Thus the availability of ‘inherited managers’ with such experience limits the amount of expansion that can be planned and undertaken in any period of time… Once a substantial increment of growth is completed, however, the managerial services devoted to it become available for further expansions» 2 A shortcoming of this development is the omission that such availability depends on the level of uncertainty, which markedly influences both the formation of entrepreneurship and the quantity of entrepreneurial knowledge used in ordinary activities and to manage the achieved expansion. Penrose attributes great importance to versatility, which avoid that “the market for those products will restrict the firms opportunities of expansion”, and adds: «a versatile type of executive service is needed if expansion requires major efforts on the part of the firm to develop new markets or entail branching out into new lines of production»3. The author insists in depicting the firm as an administrative and planning organization. She does not consider that this kind of organization is mainly typical of bureaucratic-conservative forms sub a. The lack of caution in this matter is an effect of the minor role she attributes to uncertainty. This one is considered as: «the entrepreneur’s confidence in his estimates of expectations», i.e. as a subjective and not an objective fact that influences the firm’s behavior. She adds: «Risk, on the other hand, refers to the possible outcomes of action, specifically to the loss that may 2 3 See E. Penrose (1999), p. xii See E. Penrose (1999), p. 37 4 be incurred if a given action is taken».4 These peculiar notions of risk and uncertainty are useful to Penrose’s analytical purposes, but they are deceitful if considered in a more general sense. She is concerned about the role of information in reducing subjective uncertainty and in the resources necessary to get information, and concludes that risk and uncertainty are final limiting factors only if managerial services are fully used. Again, she forgets to consider that the use and the need of managerial services depend on the level of uncertainty. This level is never considered; uncertainty is simply treated as a subjective entity, rather than an objective one influencing both demand and supply of entrepreneurship. A main shortcoming of Penrose’s analysis seems to be the marginality of the role she attributes to uncertainty. This marginalisation of uncertainty persists in all the theories of the firm that attribute a central role to capabilities; the reason of that is the usual way to intend uncertainty makes difficult to treat capabilities. In order to clarify this aspect, some considerations on the way economics consider uncertainty is required. As is well known, a pioneeristic treatment of uncertainty was provided by F. H. Knight. But his analysis is afflicted by two main errors: First, the idea that uncertainty only implies some deviation from the results of Neoclassical economics of perfect knowledge, but without substantial prejudice for its teaching. Second, the idea that uncertainty is unmeasurable. Heterodox economics that, polemically with mainstream economics of perfect knowledge, underlines the importance of uncertainty, plainly overcomes the first Knight’s error. But it completely shares the second one. In addition, its right perception of the qualitative jump with respect to Neoclassical economics that the introduction of true uncertainty in the analysis implies, has strongly accentuated the consequences of the second Knight’s mistake. Neoaustrian economics gives a clear expression of some misunderstandings caused by this equivocation. Its sharp criticism against Neoclassical economics is hinged on uncertainty. But the assumption of unmeasurableness and impalpability of uncertainty has imprinted on Neoaustrian students an extreme hostility towards organization, leading them to erase the problem of the firm from the agenda of their work. More precisely, the emphasis on unknown and unintentional events has pushed their analysis, mainly in Hayek’s version, toward a prejudicial preference for spontaneous order over organization and command considered as arbitrary interferences obstructing the tendency of social events toward self adjustment. According to this school of thought, general rules, mainly market laws, are enough to allow the harmonization of spontaneous actions and unintentional events. But the emphasis on individual initiative ignores the simple fact that the limitation of skills requires organization. Another main obstacle to a neo-Austrian theory of the firm is that this school sees entrepreneurial capability as an evanescent, non-measurable entity and, as such, not 4 See E. Penrose, ibidem, p. 56 5 liable to rational evaluation and impossible to specify. But skills do exist, and the firm has the duty of evaluating its capabilities with a reliable degree of approximation so as to use them properly. Neo-Austrians’ work on market process, uncertainty, search and discovery can make an important contribution to the theory of the firm. Unfortunately, their prejudice against organization has deprived the analysis of the firm by these neo-Austrians deepenings. J. A. Schumpeter made an opposite error: his attention for entrepreneurial capabilities disregarded uncertainty, notwithstanding this one springs out copiously from his “creative destruction”. This omission, that confirms the difficulty to conjugate capabilities to the usual way to consider uncertainty, induced him to emphasize, in “Capitalism, socialism and democracy”, the role of managerial services and in the absolute error to predict the end of capitalism as a consequence of bureaucratization. It is illuminating on the importance of a proper consideration of uncertainty the fact that the Schumpeterian theoretical effort, full of lightings and contradictions, gives space, in the end, to bureaucratic aspect (sub a) at the expense of the entrepreneurial one (sub b). As a consequence, the building of a general theory of the firm has also been deprived by the support of the branch of dynamic competition process represented by creative destruction, in addition to neo-Austrian (the other branch) refusal of the question of the firm. The effects of these misunderstandings have partially affected evolutionary economics, that has accomplished an interesting analysis on the microfoundations of innovation along Schumpeterian lines. Nelson and Winter’s explanatory models of technical change, search and selection within the firm have represented an interesting starting point. But an important aspect differentiates this school of thought from Schumpeter: the remark it attributes to uncertainty, mainly under the notion of bounded rationality that, as we shall see, is an ambiguous way to call up incomplete knowledge. In a theoretical context marked by the notion of bounded rationality clearly appears the difficulty to treat entrepreneurial capabilities, being uncertainty considered as an unmeasurable, subjective, impalpable entity. In point of fact, evolutionary economics has performed some interesting researches on capabilities that stress the power of learning and tacit knowledge for explaining the behavior, internal organization, boundaries and results of the firm. But significantly, it insists in the identification of capabilities through the notion of decisional routine, as a partial remedy to the analytical vacuity deriving from the idea of unmeasurableness and impalpability of uncertainty. This insistence is coherent with the importance that Schumpeter attributed to managerial bureaucracy and with Penrose’s insistence on capabilities independently on uncertainty. In fact, decisional routines are concerned with the bureaucratic-conservative aspect of organizations. They refer to repetition and hence not to entrepreneurial decision-making since this requires versatility and some skills able to face uncertainty. It must be underlined that a fundamental ambivalence characterizes evolutionary social thought, which is well reflected by evolutionary economics: for one side, this school is inclined to disregard the problem of the firm as a consequence of its tendency to exaggerate the limits in human knowledge and hence to distrust of 6 organization at the advantage of spontaneous behavior; but, for the other side, a branch of evolutionary social thought is greatly attracted by the evolution of institutions, not only in the sense of Menger’s theory of the emergence of money as a result of unintentional events. In economics, this attraction is mainly concerned with the firm and the connected analysis was initially fertilized by Coase’s seminal article on “The Nature of the Firm”. He wrote «The main reason why it is profitable to establish a firm would seem to be that there is a cost of using the price mechanism… It is true that contracts are not eliminated when there is a firm but they are greatly reduced»5. Here the firm appears to be an organization that substitutes command for the price and market mechanism in the allocation of resources. This Coasian perspective has promoted useful investigations on the firm. Precisely, it has stimulated two lines of research directed towards explaining the nature and the role of the firm as an organization, now unified as the “contractual perspective”. One is derived from O. Williamson, who has developed Coase’s intuition on transaction costs and hence emphasized the distinction between “markets and hierarchies”; the other is Alchian and Demsetz’s approach on the “nexus of contracts”. Williamson writes: «The two behavioral assumptions on which transaction costs analysis relies –and without which the study of economic organization is pointless are bounded rationality and opportunism»6. The incompleteness of contracts due to the limits of human knowledge, in conjunction with asset specificity (site, physical and human specificity), is said to permit opportunism in market contracting, mainly the threat of a unilateral termination of contract that will reduce the value of specific assets. This would generate costs depending on the frequency of transactions, uncertainty and the specificity of investment. So the key role of the firm, it is held, is reducing those costs by substituting a command mechanism to contracts and the market. The consideration of transaction costs, in addition to production expenses, permits significant analytical improvement on the boundaries of the firm and its governance structure; but these ones mainly depend on the availability of capabilities and uncertainty, that limits the degree of understanding and hence the potential of skills. Therefore, uncertainty limits the impact of transaction costs in stimulating the size of the firm. In fact, it requires versatility, flexibility and promptness that large firm usually lack and that only partly may be stimulated by setting up a decentralized structure. However, transaction costs are not essential for explaining the firm’s existence and nature, which can be referred to some more general consideration on organization, as we saw in the previous section. Of course Williamson’s developments centered on bounded rationality are inconsistent with Neoclassical economics that neverthless Williamson prefers, while are coherent with our previous considerations on entrepreneurial open organizations. Alchian and Demsetz considered contracts from a different point of view. Their work on the firm signalled the benefits that input owners may achieve through contractual cooperation and hence the need of monitoring of costs. Moreover, they 5 See R. H. Coase (1937), p. 390 See O. E. Williamson (1981), p. 154 6 7 argued that cooperation necessitates of measuring the productive contribution of each member of the “team” (to avoid free riding and shirking). They accordingly focused on the consequent organizational problems, mainly concerning monitoring and incentives. Probably, the most important insight here is the acknowledgement that the monitoring of the monitor requires that the overseer has a residual claimant status. Actually, though, it is inappropriate to treat the firm as a “team” of entrepreneursresource owners. The firm is a unitary structure, and its results must refer to that structure as a whole. It is the task of the responsible for the firm’s performance, who is therefore entitled to a control power, to monitor the productive contribution of every component of the organization, through incentives or otherwise, in order to improve efficiency. But to make accountability effective one needs a precise indicator of the firm’s success. This indicator can only be the profit rate, as all others are partial and misleading. Some insights on the problem of incentives have been provided by the principalagent approach. However, the strong insistence on the crucial role of property rights, and hence of private ownership7, as indispensable to the efficient use of resources and hence to long-term economic growth, appears misplaced. Monitoring based on the last-claimer principle does not require private ownership but only a clear and precise attribution of responsibility for results (profits). True in small firms, with their serious problems of accountability, efficiency may require private ownership with its implicit automatic monitoring, reflecting an immediate interest in economic results. But in larger ones efficiency does not require property rights; all that is needed is the clear and inescapable attribution of responsibility for the results (in terms of profit rate), accompanied by appropriate powers of control. This does not necessarily mean the ownership of resources. In conclusion, contractual approach has provided important results on the internal organization of the firm. Besides, it attributes to uncertainty, or incomplete knowledge, an important role, mainly through the notions of transaction costs and residual claimant. But the computations it proposes express an evident ambiguity as long as uncertainty is considered an unmeasurable entity. Another most serious limitation of contractarian theories is their disregard for the firm’s competence and skills and, more precisely, the lack of an interest in one key task of firms: searching for and discovering profit opportunities, which is the principal driving force of innovation and hence development and growth. On this front the contractual theories, in both the versions sketched out here, have made no advance. There is now a growing perception among students of the necessity to consider capabilities as a key explanatory factor of the firm’s boundaries, behaviour and organization. N. J. Foss and R. N. Langlois have focused on this aspect. Against the dominant theory centered on contracts and incentives, they contend that: «the 7 See, for instance, O. Hart and J. Moore (1990). The one-sidedness of this position is well stated by Holmström and Roberts, who write :«But this approach also needs to expand its horizon and recognize that power derives from other sources than asset ownership and that other incentive instruments than ownership are available to deal with the joint problems of motivation and coordination» See B. Holmström and J. Roberts (1998) p. 92 8 capabilities perspective is much more conscious of the production side of the firm and represents the nature of production in a way that is potentially complementary to the transaction cost approach»8. An important characteristic of their approach is their insistence on the need to integrate the capability and transaction cost perspectives into a unitary approach, indispensable to the analytical revitalization of the production costs side. But the main flaw is, again, an undervaluation of uncertainty and its links with capabilities. Probably, this is mainly due to the supposed non measurableness of uncertainty, implying a theoretical vacuity that makes embarrassing the reference to this variable In my own opinion, some main, most paralyzing shortcomings of the current theories of the firm are rooted in the way the key notion of uncertainty is considered and used, mainly in the mistaken idea that by definition uncertainty does not admit of quantification but is a sort of impalpable entity. The consideration of the level of uncertainty and its variations is indispensable to appropriately consider entrepreneurial capabilities and to conjugate innovation and adaptation and hence to the specification of dynamic competition process9. On the contrary, the disregard in principle of the level of uncertainty and its variations precludes proper specification of the formation and use of entrepreneurial capabilities and hence the enunciation of the important notion of excess (or tension in the use) of entrepreneurial skills, as well as the explanation of innovation and investment. Sections 4 and 5 seek to remedy this defect. 3. Optimization in the presence of true uncertainty The controversy on optimization is important for our topic, in that can help clarify the rather similar notions of bounded rationality, true uncertainty, limits to knowledge and other aspects of heterodox economics. As is well known, the success of the notion of bounded rationality is mainly due to its help to the criticism to the principle of rational behavior and optimization. But this critique may result misleading. Man is limited by nature; a variety of bounds are always inherent in any kind of decision; under this respect, the notion of bounded rationality is little more than a truism. Within the boundaries of his knowledge, though, man is obliged, mainly by competition, to do his best to implement the efficiency of decisions. Man and society need to act rationally; a task of science is to stimulate rationality in decision making. The critique of the postulate of rational behavior, and in particular of the optimization principle, does not take this need fully into account. Probably the terms “uncertainty” and “incomplete knowledge” would be preferable to “bounded rationality”. But this terminological change does not provide decisive clarification; in fact, the growing hostility to optimization and some major impediments to a stringent formalization of an alternative to the Neoclassical theory of the firm spring from ambiguities in the notion of uncertainty that have precluded, as previously seen, a more satisfactory elaboration on capabilities and other theoretical advances. The exposition of some of the main objections to the optimum 8 9 See R. N. Langlois and N. J. Foss (1999) p. 202 See A. Fusari (2005) 9 principle may illuminate this subject. Kirzner writes: «The decision, in the framework of the human-action approach, is not arrived at merely by mechanical computation of the solution to the maximization problem implicit in the configuration of the given ends and means». Later he adds:«In other words, where the circumstances of a decision are believed to be certainly known to the decision-maker, we can “predict” what form that decision will take merely by identifying the optimum course of action relevant to the known circumstances. Now this “mechanical” interpretation of decision-making would be entirely acceptable for a world of perfect knowledge and prediction».10 Kirzner’s reasoning is referable to Neoclassical approach, which excludes uncertainty; but it cannot be generalized. The optimum principle is a mathematical tool that may be applied to various theoretical contexts. It is mistaken to presume that it is not applicable in the presence of limited knowledge; such a mistake derives from the presumption that uncertainty cannot be measured by definition. But we shall see soon that the distinction of uncertainty from measurable probability does not imply the non measurability of the degree of uncertainty. As a consequence of the absence of a measure of that degree, various authors have pretended to place uncertainty in the optimization approaches in the form of some known distribution of probabilities, which as such do not express uncertainty; this defect has strengthen the propensity of heterodox economists to refuse optimization. A different and more cautious critique to the application of the optimization principle has been expressed by Nelson and Winter. They write: «Orthodoxy treats the skilful behavior of the businessman as maximizing choice, and “choice” carries connotation of “deliberation”. We, on the other hand, emphasize the automaticity of skillful behavior and the suppression of choice that this involves». And later: «Formal orthodox theory, on the other hand, does not rate solutions as maximizing because they are better than some other observed solutions, but because they are the best feasible solutions. It thus premises a standard of performance that is independent of the characteristics of performers; the attribution “skilled driver” involves no such premises»11. This critique does not express a radical refusal of optimization in economics; simply maintains that decision making is based on tacit knowledge and automaticity instead of deliberate choice. Nelson and Winter’s reprimand to Neoclassical pretention to define the best feasible solution ignoring the skills of performers is by itself unexceptionable; and it has strongly influenced the evolutionary economics refusal of optimization. In our opinion, even though many decisions are based on non-optimizing methods, it is mistaken and excessively limiting to exclude optimization for improving decision-making and theoretical formalization. However, the appropriate use of optimization requires a joint specification of the degree of true uncertainty and the associated entrepreneurial skills, as in the absence of uncertainty entrepreneurial skill is inconceivable. Such a specification would allow us to express entrepreneurial capabilities and the related notion of incomplete knowledge as the constraints of 10 11 See I. M. Kirzner (1973), pp. 33 and 35 See R. R. Nelson and S. G. Winter (1982), p. 94 10 optimization approach, thus removing the bounded rationality criticism to optimisation. This seems to be a major challenge for the theory of the firm. But it is crucial, for that specification, to define some indicator of the lack of knowledge and to express it in quantitative terms. At the end of a review on optimization and evolution, G. Hodgson writes: «Usefully, modern evolutionary theory immediately suggests a variety of circumstances in which the validity of the maximization idea is under strain. Only further detailed theoretical investigation can tell us more»12. In this stage, it may be said that the perceived strain is, for a large part, a result of misunderstandings. As far as I know, nobody has pointed out the great importance of a measure of the degree of true uncertainty that can be broken down according to firm, sector, area, at global level and over time. A central purpose of this essay is to demonstrate the importance, both theoretically and empirically, of such measure. Among other things, it would enable us to formalize optimization in a realistic non-orthodox way and to represent the natural inclination and interest of the firm to choose the best among different opportunities. It is not correct to counter that the existence of a measure of the degree of uncertainty would imply the possibility of taking out an insurance policy against bad economic results, hence the negation of entrepreneurship. In fact, that measure is not a risk estimation, giving a probabilistic certainty, but just a measure of the lack of knowledge, i.e. of ones distance from a state of complete knowledge. On the other hand, uncertainty implies the strong influence of entrepreneurial skills on results, and it is impossible for insurance companies to measure those skills and results from outside. Finally, the insurance of entrepreneurial results would stimulate inconsiderate entrepreneurial decision-making, thus increasing insurance costs and jeopardizing entrepreneurial role 4. Preliminaries for a model of the firm in the perspective of general economics a) The close link between the firm’s capabilities and uncertainty The firm without entrepreneurship typical of mainstream economics is pointless. Probably, the lack of consideration by economics for entrepreneurial capabilities depends on the difficulty of quantifying the firm’s skills from outside. They are known only to the firm, and always in highly approximate manner. But this inconvenience does not warrant relegating capabilities to a secondary role as an evanescent entity. In fact, one of the most important prerequisites for the firm’s success is the knowledge of its capabilities, even if approximate, which allows one to consider available opportunities accurately. This essay shows that in the absence of a clear formalization on capabilities it is impossible to model a realistic theory of the firm, and that such formalization needs a gauge of the degree of uncertainty; in fact, one characteristic of the firm is the daily confrontation with uncertainty, understood as lack of knowledge. 12 See G. M. Hodgson (1999), p. 195 11 Truth to tell, uncertainty permeates every aspect of human life; but with respect to the firm’s activity the situation is special, not only because the level of uncertainty is particularly high but also because firms professionally and insistently generate uncertainty through innovation. This implies the existence of an unbreakable link between capabilities and uncertainty, so that they simply cannot be treated separately. Knight has shown that in repetitive processes, and hence in the absence of limitations to knowledge, there would be no space either for entrepreneurs or for profit, since entrepreneurial capability is mainly skill in coping with uncertainty. It is precisely this distinctive mark of entrepreneurship that makes the related capabilities evanescent, unless a measure of the degree of radical uncertainty can be defined. Unfortunately, all the schools of thought (e.g. the Keynesian and neo-Austrian) that emphasize the role of uncertainty, and such leading economists in this field as Shackle, Lawson and Davidson, have neglected the crucial importance of a measure of the lack of knowledge. The non measurability of uncertainty is presumed on the grounds that the definition of some probabilistic distribution of uncertainty would imply a probabilistic certainty. But it is quite natural to try to measure the degree of absence of knowledge (or the Keynesian state of confidence), i.e. the distance from a complete state of knowledge; this is, after all, what the entrepreneur does in his daily confrontation with uncertainty. At any rate, we can define some indicators of the degree of uncertainty for industries, geographical areas and the whole system. A natural choice as indicator of the sectoral, global or territorial degree of uncertainty is the variance (or standard deviation) of profit rates across firms. As a matter of fact, in the absence of uncertainty, profit (and hence its variance) would be zero. It is the existence of limits to knowledge (uncertainty) that allows differentials in capabilities and the associated profits to arise. This seems to imply that the variance of profit rates across firms gives an expression of the limits to knowledge, i.e. of uncertainty. Another way to specify a proxy of the degree of uncertainty by industry may consist in some appropriate survey for a sample of firms, asking them to assess their degree of “ignorance”. Another method is discussed in Section 6 on estimation. b) On the role, behavior and decision-making of the firm However important or unimportant the role attributed to individual initiative, social life needs organization. The main organizational entity concerning economic life is the firm. Many economists have insisted on the explanation of the existence of the firm. As previously seen, this insistence is mainly attributable to the celebrated virtue of market rules in coordinating and hence giving full value to the autonomous initiative and creativity of individuals, which induces many to dislike organization, as well as to the increasing role of uncertainty in economic life and therefore of trial and error, reinforcing the focus on spontaneous order and processes. But even if the trial and error method is unavoidable given the limits to human skills and knowledge, it is still necessary to reduce the dimension of error by appropriate organization. And the cornerstone of an open economic organization is the firm. The importance of studying its behaviour, dimension and some other peculiarities is clear. But there is not much to explain about its existence, it is almost self evident. 12 This paper will not insist on the internal organization of the firm. It is enough, for the present study, to show that those important fields can be perfectly and coherently integrated in general economics. But this integration appears to have been well accomplished only by mainstream economics, while it is a main shortcoming of heterodox economics. Every organization needs some clear, well-defined term of reference for its action. For the firm, this term is profit. At the top of the firm’s concerns there is (and there must be) the profit rate. More specifically, the main engagement of the firm is to discover available and new opportunities for profit, as well as to determine which commodities to produce and how much, with the objective of profit. In the absence of institutional monopoly, the profit rate is the only reliable and meaningful expression of a firm’s success, and hence the best indicator for determining responsibility (and accountability). This implies that the importance of profit goes well beyond private initiative. In public firms, however, the role of profit as a gauge of success must be strongly stated, since in this case profit is not automatically pursued as an effect of private interest. In sum, the most effective monitoring instrument for the firm’s activity is the last-claimer principle. Only by placing profit at the top of the firm’s objectives, it is possible to explain the firm’s behavior: its search and discovery, its size, organizational form, activity levels and some other minor questions. A concise representation of the firm’s decision-making must concentrate on: First, the choice of investment (and hence of activity levels), that may be based on the maximization of total profit. Second, the search for profit opportunities, mainly through the introduction of new techniques With reference to the optimization model used to explain investment, it must be made clear, mainly for the benefit of heterodox economists, that it is not a mere mechanical computable tool, disregarding human creativity, as it includes available entrepreneurship that incorporates, among other things, the stock of “creativity” of each firm. On the other hand, the firm’s optimizing behavior represented in the next section depicts a part of entrepreneurial process, while a non optimizing decisional procedure will be utilized to represent the technological search. Many authors have pointed out that firms’ decisions follow much simpler rules than profit optimization (see the pioneeristic study of R. M. Cyert and S. C. March 1963). M. Polanyi’s (1962) teaching on tacit knowledge has added some powerful weapons to this argument. Neverthless, the hypothesis that the firm optimizes the distribution of its initiative among different profit opportunities seems to express a rigorous and general interpretation of its behaviour, irrespectively from the various decisional routines characterizing each firm organization. In fact, it is quite natural for the firm to use its limited skills and other resources in such a way to get the maximum benefit, even more than a similar attitude is natural in consumer’s spending. In point of fact, consumers that do not like worldly delights will disregard such a maximization; instead, the firm is obliged to maximize by competition and 13 uncertainty on the potentialities of its rivals, otherwise it will be defeated by optimizing firms13. With reference to the search for profit opportunities based on technological search, we explain this search (and technical progress) as a decreasing function of uncertainty, and an increasing function of the excess of entrepreneurial skill (as defined below). The former discourages the introduction of new techniques and makes it difficult to see some better solution to imitate, while the latter represents the talent that the firm may dedicate to search. This makes immediately evident the great importance of uncertainty, entrepreneurial skill and the links between them. For completeness, “technology” is intended as inclusive of all aspects of the firm’s organization. 5. The formalization of the model Now a synthetic model of the firm is set out14. The prominent importance of profit both in private and public firms, as an indicator of their degree of success, suggests to derive investment from profit optimization of firms: ∞T Max j ∫ ∫s=t {1je-s-ujsrj (t,s) Ij (t,s) + 2Ē (t,s) }ds (Ut) t=0 Ē (the part of entrepreneurial skill depending, as we shall see soon, on the firm’s policy) acts as control variable in the above objective function, while I stays for gross investment. The integral over the life period of investment ∫ Ts=t {1je-s-ujsrj (t,s) Ij (t,s)}ds expresses expected profit as discounted by uncertainty indicated by u (that in this case may consist in a subjective evaluation operated by the firm plus an objective sectoral indicator determined in the way we shall see in section 6) and interest rate (). indicates the impact of other factors influencing expected profitability. represent weights. This objective function assumes that the firm distributes its skills and resources among sectors with the aim of exploiting at the best the market opportunities of profit. One of the weakest aspects of economics is the way it considers investment that, when is not simply represented as exogenous, is explained for the most through the accelerator principle, i.e. as a consequence of the decisions on output level. Our development overturns the terms of the question: we start from the explanation of investment, that represents a major challenge for the firm and may be deduced by the above objective function, and hence derives output, as we shall see soon. I agree with Hodgson’s criticism of the idea that evolution implies maximization and to some other aspects of the optimization principle ; but this author would not deny that, for instance, the participants to an examination for, say, a limited number of grants are induced by their ignorance of the worth of rivals to do their best to pass the examination. 14 The empirical analysis that will follow obliges to consider uncertainty as exogenous. This precludes the formulation of dynamic competition process. That was done in A. Fusari (2005) along with some simulation experiments. 13 14 Now we need a survey of the system of motion of the optimum problem. All equations will be expressed in explicit form, as an anticipation of the formalization for estimation. The specification of an indicator of uncertainty allows us to overcome the present vacuous stage of the analysis of entrepreneurial capabilities. More precisely, it permits to endogenize both the formation and use of the firm’s skills, as tightly linked to uncertainty. As is well known, these skills constitute, for the major part, a kind of tacit knowledge (in the sense of M. Polanyi), resulting from learning by doing, by watching, using etc. Therefore, their accumulation over time may be expressed by the integral below: 0 E = ∫-∞ (jgsjujXj1 + 1jDj - E)ds that, by taking the derivative, may be written as: DE = jgsjujXj1 + 1jDj - E (1) giving the increase in entrepreneurial capabilities at time t. E stays for entrepreneurial skill and u for uncertainty. D is an expression of technical progress (see the equation 3 below); uX indicates output weighted with uncertainty (remember that, in the absence of uncertainty, no entrepreneurial skill is requested and hence no entrepreneurial learning is possible); gs is a parameter of the learning. D is a differential operator d/dt and j indicates industry. It is presumed that entrepreneurial skill grows at a decreasing rate with the increase in the activity level, mainly because this increase causes a reduction in adaptive skills (0 < 1 < 1). The term E refers to the decay of skill due to the “obsolescence” over time of knowledge, with indicating the rate of obsolescence. Some increases in the firm’s capabilities may also be achieved through restructuring: for instance, the building of a managerial organization or merger. This kind of capability is considered as a control variable in the optimum problem specified above, and indicated by Ē Various types of the firm’s skills may be defined, simply through the specification of more than one explanatory equation15. Some sort of semientrepreneurial capabilities may be considered as a part of the organizational structure of the firm: the trade-off between incentives and insurances, as in the principal-agent theory, gives an example of semi-entrepreneurial role. More drastically, P. F. Drucker has written «The most important caveat is not to mix managerial units and entrepreneurial ones. Do not ever put the entrepreneurial into the existing managerial component. Do not make innovation an objective for people charged with running, exploiting, optimizing what already exists»16. Now an explanation of the use of entrepreneurial capabilities must be set out. It may be expressed as an increasing function of the product of uncertainty by the activity level i.e. u*X2 (remember that, in the absence of uncertainty, no 15 For instance, evolutionary economics insists on the distinction of innovative skill, as the result of the cumulation of successful R&D. See U. Cantner, H. Hanusch and A. Pyka (1998). Also the skills deriving from the so called network relationships among firms should be taken into account. 16 See P. F. Drucker, 1985. 15 entrepreneurial skill would be required), with 0 < 2< 1, indicating that the use of skills grows at a decreasing rate with the activity level (a kind of scale economy in that use). This gives the entrepreneurship absorbed by the firm’s ordinary activity. Its knowledge permits to get, by difference with respect to the availability of entrepreneurial skill, an excess of skill to be dedicated to innovation if that be the case. So an excess of entrepreneurial skill may be expressed as the difference between the capability formation and the skill used in ordinary activity: Ec = E + Ē – jgjdujXj2 (2) c This notion of excess (E ) expresses the link between uncertainty and entrepreneurial skill or, more precisely, the variation with uncertainty in the tension in the use of skills; it plays a crucial role in the theory that will follow. gd is a parameter of the use of entrepreneurial skills to produce X units of output in the presence of uncertainty. Of course, the entrepreneurship employed is, as a rule, much higher than the learning due to the corresponding use of entrepreneurship, i.e. gd > gs For the sake of simplicity, an equation explaining technical progress may refer to the variation in labor productivity and expressed as follows: Dj/j = 2e3(1-uj)Ij/Kj +4e5EcjIj/Kj -6uj + 7Ecj (3) where is the productivity of labor per standard unit, e indicates exponential, I gross investment and K the capital stock. D is a differential operator d/d t, so that Dj/j is a variation rate. In this peculiar function of technical progress, the exponentials of u (uncertainty) and Ec (the excess of entrepreneurial skill), both weighted with the share of gross investment in capital stock I/K (or the share of R&D expenditure in GNP), express the innovative effect of investment as dependent on the excess of entrepreneurial skill (which encourages innovation) and uncertainty (which discourages innovation). The exponentials express the fact that, as a rule, innovation cannot cause a decrease in productivity since a worse technique than the one in use will not be adopted. The third and fourth terms, u and Ec, refer respectively to the negative and positive effect that uncertainty and the excess of entrepreneurial skill may have on productivity through their influence on the efficiency of factor combinations, management and the accuracy of decision-making. Capital stock may be expressed by the following identity: DKj/Kj = Ij/Kj - (4) K indicates capital stock, I is gross investment and a rate of capital depreciation. Activity levels may be broadly understood as a consequence of investment. More precisely, the rate of variation in output by firm and industry (DX j/Xj) may be indicated as proportional to the variation in capital stock. But we must also consider the influence of uncertainty, which discourages output17. Besides, in the case of noncompetitive market, one must also consider the influence of demand on output, which may cause a variation in the capital/output ratio. Therefore, the equation for the firm’s output may be written as follows: 17 Variations in profit rate may encourage, (if positive) or discourage (if negative) production through larger (or smaller) use of variable factors; so that also those variations should appear in the right hand side of equation 5. 16 DXj/Xj = 8DKj/Kj - 9uj + 10 log(Xdj/Xj) (5) d d with X j indicating industry demand. Both u and X j/Xj are referred to the sector, not the firm, while the other variables refer both to firm i and industry j. Transaction costs per unit of output may be explained by: the size of the firm, as expressed by its total output, which reduces the frequency of transactions (this implies that transaction costs stimulate the scale of production); the degree of uncertainty; and an indicator of the degree of specificity of assets. So the equation may be written as follows: TCj = - 11jXj + 12uj + 13j (6) where TCj indicates transaction costs per unit of output and asset specificity. What is evident, in all the equations specified, is the great importance of an indicator of the degree of uncertainty. This clearly shows the limitations that heterodox economics suffers due to its concept of uncertainty as a generic atmosphere permeating reality and resistant to any quantification. It also appears evident, from equation 3, the great importance of an indicator of the tension in entrepreneurial capabilities, as expressed by the notion of excess of entrepreneurial skill. Finally, profit rate is given by the following identity rj = {[1 – wj/(pjj) –TCj]Xj/Kjpkj}– ( -Dpkj/pkj) (7) Where wj is the industry money wage. wj/pjj gives the unit labor cost that also includes the cost of independent labor. TCj indicates transaction costs per unit of output, pj indicates industry price, pk capital price and interest rate. To simplify notations, the above identity intends X as value added (but this affects the appropriateness of jXj in equation 6 for transaction costs) that implies the elimination of intermediate goods. Interest rate has been expressed in real terms with respect to pk and indicated as -Dpkj/pkj The compact formulation of the proposed maximization problem is: ∞T Max j ∫ ∫s=t {1je-s-ujsrj (t,s) Ij (t,s) + 2Ē (t,s) }ds (Ut) DKj/Kj DXj/Xj Dj/j TCj rj DE Ec t=0 = Ij/Kj - = 1DKj/Kj - 2uj + 3(Xjd/Xj) = 4e5(1-uj)Ij/Kj + 6 e7logEcIj/Kj - 8uj + 9Ec = - 10jXj + 11uj + 12j = {[1 – wj/(pjj)-TCj]Xj/Kjpkj}– (-Dpki/pkj) = jgsjuj Xj1 + 12jDj - E = E + Ē – jgdjujXj2 The above intertemporal objective function allows us to derive an expression for gross investment. The crucial variables of the model are the available skill and the associated degree of uncertainty, which influence productivity and profit and hence investment. The very low skill and competence (high gdj) of each firm in many activities reduces 17 its area of interest. Schumpeter pointed out that a successful (a skilful) firm may obtain all the capital it needs from the banking system18 and hence buy on the market all the other resources requested by production. This statement is exaggerated. Each firm knows the difficulty of raising capital but this should be considered neither as a constraint nor as unlimited. A natural way of expressing capital limitation is to refer to profit rate in investment (and hence production) decisions so that the resulting profit implies the capital requirements. Clearly, the boundaries of the firm depend on available capabilities, the dimension of transaction costs and the possible presence of scale economies. 6. Econometric estimations The model has been estimated at the industry level. It would be possible to derive an expression for the growth of capital by optimization of the above intertemporal objective function, interpreted in the light of the motion system. At any rate, the objective function implies that I = f(r ,u, ,, Ē). The solution of this expression for r gives r*=f(I,u, , , Ē). r* may be intended as the profit rate required to invest I units of capital for given values of u, , , Ē. So, an expression for the rate of variation in gross investment may be written as follows: DIj/Ij = (rj - rj*). This equation explains the variation rate in investment through the adjustment of actual profit rate towards the desired profit rate. If the first exceeds the profit rate (r*) required to invest I units of capital, investment grows, and vice versa. may be interpreted as the entrepreneurial alertness in taking advantage of the market opportunities. So, the compact formalization of the model, in the version for estimation, is: DlogI = (r – r*) with r* = 1I + 2u +3 +4logEc + 1 DlogK = I/K - Dlog = 5e6(1-u) I/K + 7 e8logEcI/K - 9u + 10logEc + 2 DlogX = 11DlogK - 12u + 13 log(Xd/Xj) + 3 Dri= (Xp/Kpk)(DlogX+Dlogp-DlogK-Dlogpk)–(wL/ Kpk )(Dlogw+DlogL -DlogK-Dlogpk) – D(-Dlogpk) DlogL = DlogX - Dlog c E = Z/uX (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) The equation for transaction costs has been eliminated, since it has no meaning at industry level. D indicates the differential operator (d/dt) and log natural logarithms. Therefore Dlog indicates the rate of variation of the corresponding variable. stays for intercept. X indicates value added at factor costs and Z is the trend (calculated outside the model) of value added. L indicates total employment, expressed in standard labor units. All the remaining variables preserve the previous notations. The identity for the profit rate has been expressed as a first derivative. 18 See J. A. Schumpeter (1934) 18 The model remedies the lack of a data series on entrepreneurial skill (E) through identity 7 defining the excess of skill. Bear in mind, in interpreting this identity, that uncertainty (u) has been expressed as the ratio to its average over the estimation period, i. e. as a deviation from the average. Thus, in identity 7, uncertainty does not appear in the numerator (this should be multiplied by the average of uncertainty that, divided by itself, gives one). The deviation of ordinary activity and the relative uncertainty (in the denominator) with respect to their trend (Z), gives the strain on entrepreneurial skill. If X and u grow, the strain on entrepreneurial skill rises; if the two variables diminish, it decreases. The data series on uncertainty have been obtained through the elaboration of the answers to a monthly survey of business conditions for a sample of firms representative of all industrial sectors and Italian geographical areas by ISAE 19. The answers refer to expectations over the next three or four months, are discounted by all seasonal factors and concern the probable behavior of: delivery orders, production, prices, cost of financing and liquidity assets. These variables are defined by three modalities: modality 1 expresses “increase” (in the rate of change in the variables), modality 2 indicates “no change”, modality 3 indicates “decrease”. The answers of two consecutive months have been compared, taking the number of those that differ from the previous month’s and dividing them by the total answers available. This expression of firms’ “secondthoughts” can be taken as a measure of the industry degree of uncertainty. The data series run from 1986 to 2003. A FIML estimator has been used. The estimates are derived by an asymptotically exact Gaussian estimator of a differential equation system using discrete data. As there is no equivalent of a just-identified model for non-linear systems, there is no systemwide test such as the Carter-Nagar R2 or likelihood-ratio. In order to give an idea of the efficiency of estimations, also the means and standard deviations of the estimated endogenous variables are reported. But firstly it is indispensable to expose some warning on the use of econometric methods. Social reality, being the product of human action and creativity, and hence characterized by qualitative jumps, can be understood and explained with difficulty simply on the basis of observation. In general, econometric estimations may be referred to the past, to the observation period, not to the future. But their extension to the future may have some foundation if there exists some a priori knowledge on the durability over time of the considered phenomena. One possibility to assess such durability may consist in the verification that the observed phenomena reflect some organizational necessity of social systems that derives from long lasting aspects of the considered reality, for instance, from the general conditions of development. Well, dynamic competition and its constituent elements represented by entrepreneurship, uncertainty and innovation embody some fundamental and long lasting aspects of the modern dynamic economies. This justifies, at the aggregate and industry level, some econometric estimation on the matter. 19 Institute of Studies and Economic Analysis 19 Table 1 Manufacturing industry. Estimated parameters, their asymptotic standard errors, endogenous variables and residuals. Parameters 0.207 1 0.070 2 0.107 3 0.473 4 0.899 5 0.023 6 -4.349 7 0,077 8 15.140 9 0.025 10 0.105 11 0.914 12 0.006 1 0.060 2 0.492 3 -0.111 Asympt. Stand. Error 0.0373 0.0013 0.0022 0.0119 0.0461 logI 0.0310 logK 0.0149 log 0.0305 logX 2.6537 r 0.00006 logL 0.0076 0.0741 0.0031 0.0111 0.0069 0.0206 Endogenous variables Estimated Observed Mean 10.751 13.012 3.683 12.264 0.103 8.584 Stand. Deviation 0.092 0.071 0.079 0.054 0.022 0.036 Mean 10.748 13.012 3.680 12.260 0.102 8.583 Stand. Deviat. 0.096 0.072 0.082 0.062 0.024 0.035 Errors in estimation Mean 0.003 0.0005 0.0029 0.0038 0.0010 0.0005 Stand. Deviat 0.041 0.004 0.016 0.026 0.010 0.019 All parameters have reasonable values and are significantly different from zero at the 1 per cent level. Table 2 Food staff industry Estimated parameters, their asymptotic standard errors, endogenous variables and residuals. Parameters 0.992 1 0.061 2 -0.003 3 0.445 4 1.515 5 0.0273 6 9.347 7 0,0229 8 10.443 9 0.045 10 0.0112 11 1.807 12 0.074 1 0.060 2 0.492 3 -0.111 Asympt. Stand. Error 0.0038 0.0078 0.0512 0.0198 0.0631 logI 0.0011 logK 5.0455 log 0.0013 logX 0.3592 r 0.0084 logL 0.0008 1.5971 0.0347 0.0111 0.0069 0.0206 Endogenous variables Estimated Observed Mean 8.338 10.412 3.649 9.829 0.144 6.180 Stand. Deviation 0.128 0.107 0.063 0.059 0.023 0.024 Mean 8.346 10.412 3.652 9.833 0.146 6.181 Errors in estimation Stand. Deviat. Mean 0.137 0.110 0.080 0.076 0.021 0.026 -0.008 -0.0004 -0.0033 -0.0043 -0.0020 -0.0007 Stand. Deviat 0.015 0.009 0.028 0.031 0.019 0.027 The results are no worse than in manufacturing industry, but the parameter 2 has wrong sign and is not significant. The estimations over other 13 industrial sectors, giving results no worse than the previous, have been excluded for space reasons. 20 More extensive comments (and comparisons) on and among the above results have been omitted for space constraints. 6. Dynamic competition, development and growth: specification and econometric estimation The elements that this paper notes as essential to a realistic theory of the firm are also central to the analysis of the entire economic system. In particular, the interaction between innovation and uncertainty is at the heart of the mechanism of growth and development and may be intended as expressive of the process of dynamic competition, i. e. the competition based both on innovation and the opportunities deriving from market disequilibria (Schumpeterian and neo-Austrian competition). Therefore, it will be interesting to specify a formalization to represent that interaction and subject it to econometric testing. So that, this section goes beyond the theory of the firm and, unlike previous sections, considers uncertainty as endogenous and expressed as the standard deviation of profit rates across firms, which also gives an expression of market disequilibria. Section 4 has shown that uncertainty reduces innovation, both directly and because of its negative influence on the excess of entrepreneurship. This stimulates the concentration of entrepreneurs’ search for profit on adaptive strategies (the search according to neo-Austrians), since innovation feeds the standard deviation of profit rates across firms (as a proxy of market disequilibria and uncertainty). But the reduction in that standard deviation, as a consequence of adaptive competition, causes a rise in innovation, both directly and because of the increase in the excess of entrepreneurship; and so on, with a cyclical behaviour and alternation between innovation and adaptation (or structural organization). This suggests representing, at the aggregate level, the relation between innovation and adaptation through a Lotka-Volterra predator-prey system, with innovation acting as the prey and the standard deviation of profit rates across firms as the predator. The estimated differential system is, therefore, the following: DPA = b1PA - b2VR*PA (1) DVR = -b3VR + b4PA*VR (2) where: PA = Patent applications (intended as an indicator of innovation). VR = Standard deviation of profit rates across firms. D = Derivative d/dt. Equation 1 may also include a term DE for the variation of entrepreneurial skill displaying on innovation (the prey) a propulsive role similar to that of stocking in the predator-prey models used by studies on food chains20. The parameter b1 is a constant exponential rate of growth of innovation, expressing the autonomous push to innovate due to entrepreneurial aggressiveness; its impact on DPA is reduced by the increase in the standard deviation of profit rates 20 Alternatively, a three equation predator-predator-prey model could be specified, with innovation that preys entrepreneurial skill and is preyed by uncertainty, that also preys entrepreneurial skill 21 across firms (according to parameter b2). b3 is an exponential rate of growth of the standard deviation of profit rates across firms; the negative sign on b 3 expresses the compressing effect coming from adaptive competition on the standard deviation of profit rates. Innovation is the field of pasture of the standard deviation of profit rates across firms (the proxy of uncertainty): in the absence of innovation, the term with b 4 would disappear and such a standard deviation would become null because of the adaptive search for profit. When innovation intensifies, the standard deviation of profit rates across firms (predator) grows, thus causing the contraction in innovation (the prey), and hence the predator, with a cyclical alternation. The system parameters give the dimension of the disequilibrating (b1 and b4) and equilibrating (b2 and b3) push expressed by dynamic competition (the combination between innovative and adaptive competition).21 It may be useful to underline in this regard that the measures of dynamic competition based on the rapidity of contraction of the standard deviation of profit rates across firms (as, for instance, in D.C. Mueller and others or H. Odagiri22), only consider adaptive competition or, more precisely, parameter b 3 of the above system. They ignore the other parameters, giving a poor approximation to the intensity of competition and economic dynamism, as dynamic competition consists both in innovation and adaptation. The estimation below refers to three main European industrial countries: The United Kingdom, France and Germany. The data on patent applications and grants come from the USA Department of Commerce. The data on the standard deviation of profit rates across firms come from D.C. Mueller (1990) for France and Germany; while those for the United Kingdom come from H. Odagiri (1994). The data for France give pre tax profit, those for the United Kingdom and Germany give after tax profit. Their reliabilities are affected by their derivation from some firms’ balance sheet based on dissimilar and not well-established procedure. The results shown below must be judged in the light of the deficiencies of the appropriate data series. Nevertheless, confirmation of the theory is encouraging. But the improvement of quantitative analysis in the crucial fields of innovation and dynamic competition needs a great deal of statistical research. A FIML estimator was used to preserve the tight interaction between (1) and (2) above, i.e. innovation and adaptation, which is a crucial point of the theory of dynamic competition presented in this essay. A system which differs from Volterra in that the second equation uses only PA instead of the term PA*VR in the right hand side, has also been estimated. As a matter of fact, it may be assumed that the “reproduction” hypothesis typical of Volterra’s study on population plainly operates only in the equation of innovation in that each innovation is strongly influenced by the state of knowledge resulting from previous innovations. In the equation of the standard deviation of profit rates, however, it may operate only backwards as large disequilibria stimulate adaptation. This means that in equation 2 the 21 A ponderous author's research on social and historical process, from primitive ages to the beginning of modern dynamic society, shows the important role played by the binomial innovation-adaptation in historical evolution. (See A. Fusari, Human adventure; an inquiry on the way of people and civilizations, Ed. SEAM, Roma 2000, pages 760. 22 See D. C. Mueller (1990); H. Odagiri (1994) 22 cross product term of Volterra, the encounter between predator and prey, may be replaced by the prey (innovation) only. Data on patent have been divided by thousand, for uniformity of their scale with respect to VR. UNITED KINGDOM. Table 3. Model in the Volterra form. b1 b2 b3 b4 PAt VRt Estimate of parameters 0.519 0.082 1.716 0.367 Mean 4.7876 6.4006 Asymptotic standard errors 0.099 0.016 0.504 0.105 Endogenous variables Observed Standard deviation Mean 0.2189 4.7925 0.7898 6.3773 t values 5.25 5.19 3.41 3.48 Estimated Standard deviation 0.2982 0.9747 The model with the term PA in equation (2), instead of PA*VR, does not converge. FRANCE. The data series of the standard deviation of profit rates for France has two out-lying observations in 1974 and 1977. The first has no justification and is probably due to inaccuracy of the data; the second is largely determined by the revaluations, in 1977, of the assets of mergers that consistently depressed profit rates. We have substituted to those anomalous data an interpolation with the contiguous data23. “Take in Table 4” Table 4. Model in the Volterra form. b1 b2 b3 b4 Estimate of parameters 0.318 0.048 0.558 0.192 Asymptotic standard errors 0.121 0.019 0.244 0.080 PAt VRt Endogenous variables Observed Estimated Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation 3.0316 0.2261 3.0295 0.2302 6.3311 0.7627 6.3183 0.8061 23 t values 2.61 2.46 2.29 2.40 The fact that only two observations were out liers, that the model is dynamic, and that there is no reason to assume that the cause, if any, of these anomalies were the same, suggested that the use of a dummy variable was inappropriate 23 Table 5. Model with the term PA in equation (2), instead of PA*VR. b1 b2 b3 b4 Estimate of parameters 0.252 0.037 0.608 1.320 Asymptotic standard errors 0.158 0.252 0.348 0.722 t values 1.59 1.48 1.75 1.83 PAt VRt Endogenous variables Observed Estimated Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation 3.0316 0.2261 3.0263 0.2418 6.2933 0.7637 6.3072 0.5024 GERMANY Table 6. Model in the Volterra form. b1 b2 b3 b4 Estimate of parameters 0.316 0.090 0.089 0.128 Asymptotic standard errors 0.115 0.037 0.177 0.023 t values 2.74 2.45 0.50 0.56 PAt VRt Endogenous variables Observed Estimated Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation 7.7933 1.4829 7.7608 1.6193 3.1622 0.3524 3.1554 0.3401 Table 7. Model with the term PA in equation (2), instead of PA*VR. b1 b2 b3 b4 Estimate of parameters 0.333 0.096 0.221 0.095 Asymptotic standard errors 0.124 0.039 0.164 0.066 PAt VRt Endogenous variables Observed Estimated Mean Standard deviation Mean Standard deviation 7.7933 1.4829 7.7603 1.5898 3.1622 0.3524 3.1588 0.2810 24 t values 2.69 2.43 1.35 1.43 For Germany, the model in the Volterra form provides a worse estimate of the equation of the standard deviation than the model where the term PA is substituted to PA*VR in (2); the contrary happens for France and the United Kingdom. It would seem, therefore, that in the first country disequilibria do not generate disequilibria, while a self-reinforcing tendency of disequilibria appears in the United Kingdom and France, i.e. VR contributes to stimulate its own growth through the term PA*VR. All parameters have the correct signs, have reasonable values and are significantly different from zero around the 1 percent level in the estimation of the model in the Volterra form for the United Kingdom and France, and in the pseudo Volterra form for Germany. The models were also estimated utilizing data on patent grants instead of patent applications but the results have not been presented as, in all cases, patent applications gave better estimates. This is not surprising since patent applications provide a better expression of the innovative propensity of firms, i. e. their intention to innovate. It may be interesting to compare the estimated parameters relative to various countries, taking present that parameter b1 gives the innovative dash, parameter b3 the adaptive push, while parameters b1 and b4 represent the disequilibrating forces and parameters b2 and b3 express the equilibrating ones. The United Kingdom shows the highest innovative dash (b1) and also the highest adaptive push (b3), i.e. the strongest dynamic competition. Germany shows a strong innovative dash and a low adaptive push, while France presents an innovative dash a little lower than Germany, but a much higher adaptive push. Relatively to Germany, France has a lower parameter on the term in equation (1) braking innovative dash and a higher parameter on the term in equation (2) braking adaptive push. These offsetting values of b1 and b3, and b2 and b4 tend to partly compensate the differences in the innovative dash and the adaptive push, making the disequilibrating-equilibrating process closer in those two countries. The United Kingdom shows such offsetting behavior only with reference to the adaptive push (but the difference between b3 and b4 is large), while the parameter b2, braking the innovative dash, appears higher than France and lower than Germany, implying for this aspect a widening of the disequilibrating forces relatively to this country. Conclusion This research points out the close relation between entrepreneurship and uncertainty, their crucial and opposite influence on growth and development, the importance of a measure of the degree of radical uncertainty. A large part of economics, precisely the so called mainstream economics, ignores uncertainty and pretend to hide this omission through the inclusion in its analysis of known probability distributions that, as such, only express probabilistic certainty. But the modern dynamic economies, characterised by growing endogenous uncertainty, fully contradicts the economics of perfect knowledge and stimulate a more and more diffuse perception among economists of the crucial role of uncertainty properly understood in the representation of economic process. Unfortunately, some fundamental misunderstandings afflict the way true uncertainty is considered and 25 treated by heterodox students. It is our opinion that an improvement of heterodox theories requires an accurate criticism of their current state. One main misunderstanding seems to be represented by what I call the postulate of unmeasurability, that is, the general assumption that true uncertainty is, by its nature, an unmeasurable entity. This greatly damages the possibility to explain some crucial economic variables such as entrepreneurship, innovation, investment and the specification of the theory of the firm. In particular, the consideration of uncertainty as a subjective, unmeasurable and hence evanescent phenomenon makes entrepreneurial capabilities an evanescent entity, as strictly linked to evanescent uncertainty. This has engendered a propensity of the theories of the firm that give importance to entrepreneurial capabilities, from E. Penrose to the present time, to dedicate little consideration to uncertainty and hence to consider the firm as a bureaucratic, managerial structure much more than an entrepreneurial one. Significantly, an important example of this propensity is given by a father of entrepreneurship, J. A. Schumpeter. His well known lack of consideration for uncertainty, notwithstanding this one springs out copiously from the Schumpeterian notion of “creative destruction”, downrightly induced this author in the absolute error to foresee the disappearance of entrepreneurship in favour of bureaucratic organisation. Some other students strongly concerned about true uncertainty have been induced, by the consideration of this one as an unmeasurable result of a flow of unintentional events, to prefer spontaneous order to organisation and hence to disregard the theory of the firm, as is typical of the neo-Austrian school of thought. A growing number of heterodox economists have eluded the difficulty to deal with uncertainty intended as a fleeting, subjective, unmeasurable variable by putting it under the notion of bounded rationality. Accordingly, they have put forward a notion of capabilities amended by uncertainty: the notion of decisional routine that, as implying repetition, may be referred to managerial bureaucratic structures, not to entrepreneurial decision-making, having to do with uncertainty. A main aspect of bounded rationality economics’ is the analysis of entrepreneurial behaviour drawn by this school of thought and, in particular, its critique of optimisation. This gives a clear example of some serious misunderstanding caused by the assumption of unmeasurability and impalpability of uncertainty. In effect, in the absence of a measure of uncertainty and consequently of a quantification of entrepreneurial capabilities properly understood, that is, the capabilities to meet uncertainty, it is impossible to specify some sensible optimisation model at the service of the theory of the firm and it remains to appeal to some other more vague decisional criteria, for instance, the Simonian satisfying behaviour, or more stringent decisional routines that, however, deny, as just seen, entrepreneurial versatility. On the contrary, if the bound to rationality, as represented by the level of uncertainty and capabilities, is specified in the constraints of an optimisation problem, the bounded rationality criticism against optimisation drops out and the theory of the firm may preserve optimisation tool. 26 In the contemporary studies on the firm, uncertainty frequently emerges through the explanation of “transaction costs”. But this reference to uncertainty, even if interesting, is not so much important as it is sometimes considered to be. In fact, the explanation of the existence of the firm does not need transaction costs; it may be based on some more general organisational necessities consequent to the limitations in human skills. Besides, it seems important to take present that the stimulus of uncertainty to the firm dimension through transaction costs is flanked by the opposite effect of uncertainty to favour little firms, with their versatility and flexibility. In effect, a main cause of the boundaries of the firm is probably represented by the availability of entrepreneurial capabilities and the associated level of uncertainty, that limits the degree of understanding and hence the power force of capabilities Finally, it is our firm belief that a major deepening of the coordination between the theory of the firm and general economics is indispensable to make heterodox economics more attractive. In fact, a main reason of the survival of the Neoclassical theory of the firm and its large number of followers (notwithstanding its complete inability to consider some crucial aspects of the economy such as innovation, entrepreneurship and uncertainty) is its perfect coordination with general economics. Unfortunately, the current idea of true uncertainty as an unmeasurable entity prevents the coordination of the heterodox theories of the firm with general economics, for instance, through a specification of dynamic competition, representing economic process with entrepreneurship, innovation and uncertainty. As a matter of fact, dynamic competition may be expressed as a result of entrepreneurial search for profit based both on innovation and the exploitation of market disequilibria, that is, the combination of neo-Austrian market process and Schumpeterian creative destruction. But this combination needs the consideration of the level of uncertainty and its variation, as indispensable to explain the rise of innovation when uncertainty falls, and the intensification of market adaptive process when disequilibria and uncertainty rise. The unmeasurable uncertainty of neo-Austrians and the Schumpeterian lack of consideration of uncertainty have prevented the combination of the two approaches and hence the formalisation of dynamic competition, so that an important frame for the insertion of the theory of the firm in general economics has got lost. The paper presents a formulation of the theory of the firm that has some substantial differences with respect to usual formulations, mainly on the explanation of capital accumulation, the role of the profit rate and technical progress. In particular, it points out the close relation between entrepreneurship and uncertainty, their crucial and opposite influence on growth and development, the importance of a measure of the degree of radical uncertainty. A FIML econometric testing at industry level of the equations derived at the firm level has been provided. Moreover, a short formalization and estimation on the whole economic system has been added, which stresses the importance of uncertainty and its measure. Since uncertainty is largely endogenous to the economic process (mainly as an effect of creative destruction) and requires the use of entrepreneurship, it follows that the promotion of growth mainly needs the stimulus of entrepreneurial skills. 27 Starting from this approach, a more complete model of the economy may be specified simply by adding equations for demand, wages, interest rates, prices, and so on. But this is beyond the scope of the present essay, which concerns the theory of the firm. The introduction into the model of new products is a further, unavoidable challenge because, in the end, it is product innovation that prevents stagnation. Another planned extension will be the presentation of estimates at firm level, on the basis of panel data. 28 References Alchian, A.A. & Demsetz H., (1972) ‘Production, information costs, and economic organization’, American Economic Review, 62, p. 777-95 Bolton P. & Scharfstein D. S., (1998) ‘Corporate finance, the theory of the firm, and organizations’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 12, n° 4 , p. 95-114 Cantner, U. Hanusch H. & Pyka A., (1998) ‘Routinized innovations: Dynamic capabilities in a simulation study’, in O. Eliasson, et al. (eds), The microfoundations of economic growth, University of Michigan Press, Forthcoming Coase H., (1937) ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica, 4 , 386-405 Cyert R. M. & J.C. March J.C., (1963),A Behavioral Theory of the Firm(Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, Prentice Hall Dosi G. & Teece D. J. , (1998), ‘Organizational competences and the boundaries of the firm’, in R. A. Arena & C. Longhi (eds), Market and Organization, Springer, Berlin Dosi G., Nelson R. R. & Winter S. G., (2000) Introduction: The nature and dynamics of organizational capabilities, Oxford University Press, Oxford Drucker P. F.,(1985), Innovation and entrepreneurship, (Heinemann, London Foss N. J., (1997), Resources, firms and strategies, Oxford University Press Fusari A., (1989), Simulations of economic policies and strategies with a macrodynamic model of the Italian economy, Proceedings of Beijing International Conference, Pergamon Press Fusari A., (1992), ‘Entrepreneurship, Market Process and Economic Development. Some Theoretical and Empirical Insights useful for Managing the Transition Period’, In: Transition to advanced market economies, Edited by W. Owsinski, J. Stefanski & A. Straszak, The Association of Polish Operational Research Societies Fusari A., (1996) ‘Paths of economic development: modelling factors of endogenous growth’, International Journal of Social Economics, Vol. 23 n° 10/11, p.164-191 Fusari A., (2005), ‘A model of the innovation-adaptation mechanism driving economic dynamics. A micro representation’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Vol. 15, n° 3 p. 297-333 Grebel T., Hanusch H. & Pyka A., (2001), ‘An Evolutionary Approach to the Theory of Entrepreneurship’, EAEPE Conference of Siena Griliches Z., (1990), ‘Patent statistics as economic indicators: a survey’, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXVIII December: 1661-1707 Hodgson G. M., (1999), Evolution and Institutions, Edward Elgar Cheltenham, UK, Northampton, MA, USA Hart O. & Moore J., (1990), ‘Property rights and the nature of the firm’, Journal of Political Economy, 98, p. 11191158 Holmström B. & J. Roberts, (1998), ‘The boundaries of the firm revisited’, Journal of Economic Perspective, vol. 12 Number 4-Fall, p. 1273-94 Kirzner M. I. (1973), Competition and Entrepreneurship, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago and London Knight F. H., (1921), Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, Houghton Mifflin, New York Langlois R. N. & Robertson P. L, (1995), Firms, markets and economic change, Routledge, London Langlois R. N. & Foss N. J., (1999), ‘Capabilities and Governance. The Rebirth of Production in the Theory of Economic Organization’, Kyklos, vol. 52, p.201-218 Morroni, M. (2005), Knowledge, scale and transactions in the theory of the firm, Cambridge University Press Mueller D. C. & others, (1990), The dynamics of company profits, Cambridge University Press Nelson R. R. & Winter S.G., (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge Mass., London Odagiri H. (1994), Growth through competition, competition through growth, Clarendon Press, Oxford Penrose E. (1995), The theory of the growth of the firm, Oxford University Press, Oxford Polanyi, M. (1966), The tacit dimension, Garden City, NY, Doubleday Richardson, G. B., (1972), ‘The organization of industry’, The Economic Journal, vol. 82, p. 883-96 Saviotti, P. P, (1996), Technological evolution, variety and the economy, Cheltenham, E. Elgar Schumpeter, J. A. (1934), The theory of economic development, Cambridge Mass., Harvard University Press Schumpeter, J. A. (1954), Capitalism, socialism and democracy, George Allen and Unwin, London Scott, M. F., (1989), A new view of economic growth, Clarendon Press, Oxford Schakle, G.L.S. (1990), Time, expectations and uncertainty in economics. Selected essays, J.L. Ford editor Aldershot, Edward Elgar Shell K., (1967), ‘A model of inventive activity and capital accumulation’, In: Essays on the Theory of Optimal Economic Growth, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA Williamson O. E., (1981), ‘The Modern Corporation: Origins, Evolution, Attributes’, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. XIX December, p. 1537-1568 Wymer C. R., Escona program, manual and documentation (mimeo), 1993, and WYSEA Systems Estimation and Analysis (computer package). 29