INCORPORATION OF PUBLIC HOSPITALS: A “SILVER BULLET” AGAINST OVERCAPACITY, MANAGERIAL BOTTLENECKS AND RESOURCE CONSTRAINTS? CASE STUDIES FROM AUSTRIA AND ESTONIA. Armin H. Fidler1, Reinhard R. Haslinger 2, Maria M. Hofmarcher3, Maris Jesse4 and Toomas Palu5 October 2005 1 Health Sector Manager, Europe and Central Asia Region, The World Bank Consultant, Human Development Network, Europe and Central Asia Region, The World Bank 3 Senior Health Economist, OECD, Paris 4 Senior Health Specialist, Europe and Central Asia Region, The World Bank 5 Senior Health Specialist, East Asia and Pacific Region, The World Bank 2 2 ABSTRACT This paper presents a new approach for incorporating public hospitals by contrasting the experience from an “old” EU country (Austria) with a new EU member state (Estonia). In the EU (including the new member states) hospital overcapacity is a serious problem, from a technical, fiscal and political perspective. Few countries have succeeded in establishing an appropriate framework for resource management and for guaranteeing long-term financial viability of their hospital network. Many countries are in search of effective policies for improved hospital management and more cost-effective resource use in the health sector. Over the past decade, experiences in Austria and Estonia have emerged as innovative examples which may provide lessons for other EU countries and beyond. This paper describes the evolution of public hospitals from public budgetary units and public management to incorporated autonomous organizations under private corporate law, resulting in a contractual relationship between (public) owners and private hospital management. Outdated and inefficient public sector structures were replaced by more agile corporate management. The arrangement allows for investments, operating costs and budgeting according to strategic business goals as opposed to political “fiat”. Shielding hospitals from local political influence is an important aspect of this concept. Horizontal integration through networking of public hospitals and introducing private management helps create a new corporate culture, allowing for more flexibility to achieve efficiencies through downsizing and economies of scale. Based on contracts the new balance between ownership and managerial functions create strong incentives for a more business-like, results-oriented and consumer-friendly management. This was achieved both in Austria and Estonia in a politically sensitive way, adopting a long-term vision and by protecting the interests of hospital owners and staff. KEYWORDS Health service delivery, hospital, public hospital, hospital reform, incorporation, corporatization, privatization, autonomization, organization, organizational reform, institution, innovation, performance, management, governance, new public sector management, public sector ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The authors are grateful for comments, insights and other intellectual contributions provided by Harald Maikisch, Engelbert Theurl, Silvia Oechsner, Heinrich Birner, Jutta Koenig, Harald Geck, Harald Weissenböck, Harald Maier, Franz Sonnberger and Josef Kastl. DISCLAIMER The findings, interpretations and conclusions expressed in the paper are entirely those of the authors and do not represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. CORRESPONDENCE DETAILS Armin Fidler, Europe and Central Asia Region, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC, 20433, USA; Mail Stop H7-700; Phone: (202) 473 0162; Fax: (202) 477 0574; Email: afidler@worldbank.org; Web: www.worldbank.org 3 INTRODUCTION Advances in medical technology, less invasive surgical procedures and effective new drugs have dramatically reduced the need for long hospital stays. New incentives in management and in resource allocation, such as prospective payment systems (DRGs 6) have reduced the average length of stay (ALOS) and engendered efficiency gains, but have done little to address the problem of overcapacity in most hospital markets. Nevertheless, the number of inpatient care beds has declined over the last decades across Europe, indicating higher productivity measured by declines in the average length of stay and by increases in patient turn-over rates. Further pressure to contain costs in the face of limited resources and the everincreasing demand for cutting-edge health care services is forcing countries to look for innovative ideas to right-size the hospital sector, which accounts for the lion’s share of health expenditures in most countries. This is even a bigger problem for the new EU member states from the former socialist bloc that have inherited double the hospital capacity compared to the West, but less than a quarter of the resources that OECD countries are spending to support it. Entry into the EU and the need to comply with Maastricht Macroeconomic Stability Pact criteria is putting pressure on transition economies and create the need for health systems modernization, including hospital reforms. However, the reform path is plastered with formidable obstacles. The biggest stumbling block is the political economy of hospital reform. Such reforms are highly sensitive political issues, health being an important concern for consumers and voters. Furthermore, hospitals are typically large employers, and traditionally enjoy the lobbying power and political influence of the medical profession. The resulting political debate often ends in stalemate and stagnation. Some countries, however, have shown encouraging progress in designing and implementing reforms of health service delivery despite such obstacles. Successful reforms include the incorporation of hospitals, horizontal integration and the use of private sector management while maintaining strong public oversight and continued public ownership of assets. We take a closer look at a decade of experiences in Austria and Estonia in re-structuring and re-organizing hospital care. The paper poses the question whether the combination of incorporation and market incentives combined with public ownership has the potential to introduce more cost-efficient and flexible management of hospitals while offering at the same time a politically acceptable solution to stakeholders. Austria and Estonia, represent the typical context of an “old” and a “new” EU member state, respectively. Over the past decade in both countries the hospital sectors have undergone fundamental restructuring and continue to face further organizational changes in order to reduce costs, achieve efficiencies and improve service quality. In Austria, the primary focus was horizontal integration through the establishment of hospital holding companies in most of the nine states, allowing participating hospitals a limited degree of independence. In Estonia, all hospitals (public or private) are incorporated under a company or foundation (trust) law and several hospitals were merged into larger integrated organizations. The paper will describe in each country the pre-incorporation situation and the principal reasons for change. This will be followed by a more detailed discussion of the evidence available for each model. Results from qualitative research including interviews with stakeholders and hospital managers as well as quantitative data highlighting changes over time help understand the characteristics and potentials of the two models. The use of control groups or the comparison of single variables was not practical or applicable. External factors such as the introduction of DRG systems in both countries have had their independent share in changing hospital performance. BACKGROUND – HOSPITAL BEHAVIOR AND ORGANIZATIONAL REFORM Hospital behavior is covered extensively in the literature. In the first generation of models in the literature, hospitals are considered as organic entities whereas the central focus of this group of models is the systematic and balanced integration of both quality and the quantity of services provided (Newhouse 1970, Lee 1971, Feldstein 1971). The central implication of the model of Newhouse (1970) is that hospitals may 6 Diagnosis Related Groups 4 tend to provide “too much” quality: if competition in the hospital market is monopolistic, hospitals purchase too many devices and too many services will be provided. The second type of model considers hospital behavior as a result of the interaction between different groups of decision makers (Harris 1977): Doctors are treating patients and they need management to provide them with the appropriate scope and quality of resources. The independence of both groups is important as the trust relation between patient and doctors requires that doctors do not ration service provision. Generally doctors avoid rationing and thus demand more resources. Consequently they may have an incentive to work on the capacity limit in order to add more resources, which in turn may also lead to a bias towards “too much” quality. Thus, in many developed countries health technology assessment is used and capacity and equipment plans exist to support hospital management to right-size inputs. Even if optimal capacity plans exist, the quality bias may prevail as politicians may derive utility from expensive, high quality care and generous equipment provision, because they can capitalize this politically from their constituency. Having excessive resource inputs as a presupposition for hospital behavior raises the question whether hospitals’ traditional organizational structure or ownership model can function as an incentive for steering hospital behavior towards improved incentives and encourage cost-efficient management of resources. A second question is which model features strong incentives to allow both, financially sustainable hospital care and at the same time comprehensive service provision at the highest level of quality. The literature on organizational structures of hospital markets suggests a predominance of nonprofit organizations, irrespective whether institutions are state owned or owned by a private providers such as religious orders. Among the reasons for this predominance is asymmetric information in the health care market, where consumers are generally not able to judge the quality of service provision and thus tend to be more trusting in non-profit than for-profit entities (Arrow 1963, Dranove, Shatterthwaite 2000). Other reasons include the supposition that nonprofit hospitals are likely to be a more efficient instrument for the provision of public goods (Frank, Salkever 1994, Weisbrod 1989 in Feldstein 1999). Generally, the literature suggests that non-profit organizations are the response to the combination of both, market and government failures, which are particularly pronounced in health care markets (Badelt 1997, Sloan 2000). However, a non-profit status may also be restrictive and lead to waste of resources because decision makers without a profit motive have little incentives to produce at minimal cost. Throughout the world governments are reassessing the role of the public sector for sustainable health service delivery and hospital management. Some successful approaches include organizational reforms that try to build in market forces. Because of the danger of market failures, governments are generally reluctant push for full privatization but want to reap the benefits of private sector behavior within public hospitals. An other option is the incorporation of hospitals discussed in Preker (2003), Jakab (2002), Rethelyi (2002), Eid (2001) and McKee (2001) a concept ranging from increased management autonomy or autonomization to full privatization. Expected to minimize the impact of the inherent quality bias in hospital service provision, the incorporation of public hospitals has been on the health policy agenda in many countries (Strehl 2002). It is an attempt to combat government and market failures and to promote rational decision-making in hospital service provision through contractual incentives. The central idea of incorporation is to remove public hospitals as budgetary units from the public domain and transform them into more independent entities responsible for their performance. As opposed to material privatization, formally privatized or incorporated hospitals include organizations which are still owned by public authorities but run by private entities (Strehl 2003). The arrangement is similar to private business practices, where resources, investments in personnel, operating costs, budget and goals are planned according to strategic business goals, as opposed to political ”fiat”. Independence from local political influence is an ultimate goal of this concept. In doing so hospitals are removed from public administration and incorporated under private law. The government remains as the one and only shareholder and is represented by a supervisory board that ensures the compliance with its strategic goals such as comprehensive provision of services and universal access to health care as well as cost-efficient management. Furthermore, the administrative function is transferred into a corporate management function which enjoys a large degree of independence and flexibility in managing available capacities and resources as well as exploiting economies of scale. This contractual 5 relationship and the balancing between the ownership and the managerial function create strong incentives for a cost-conscious management. It incorporates both market forces of the private sector as well as compliance with a public mandate into one service delivery function. Moreover, it was envisioned that this concept would help create a new corporate culture, allowing for enhanced managerial flexibility, a large degree of autonomy as well as efficiencies and economies of scale. AUSTRIA In Austria, a federal master plan prepared by the Federal Austrian Health Institute (ÖBIG7) and introduced by ministerial decree by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women’s Affairs provides a general framework for the provision of medical care. However, ultimately responsible for the provision of health care are Austria’s nine State governments. This responsibility includes the financing and provision of hospital care and has been a great challenge in the past two decades as the performance of Austrian hospitals has greatly changed. Structural deficits as well as extremely high expenditures on inpatient services led to the change from an input-based financing system, based on bed numbers and length of stay to an output-based prospective payment system in 19978 (LKF9 – Austrian DRGs). The introduction of the new system as well as advances in medical technology created a situation where hospitals faced a decline in the rates of average length of stay (ALOS) from 7.2 days in 1995 to 6 days in 2003, in turn leading to an oversupply of beds and facilities. In addition, Austria joined the European Monetary Union during this very period which required the consolidation of budgets and the compatibility with the economic indicators of the Maastricht Criteria. Fig. 1. Average Length of Stay, Austrian Hospitals Source: Ministry of Health, Austria 6,9 6,7 6,74 6,59 6,5 6,45 6,31 6,3 6,1 6,19 6,08 5,9 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 5,97 2003 This new reality and a dramatically changing environment advanced the need for more flexibility in managing resources. Reforms intended to move away from pure public administration of hospitals but to use market incentives and to establish an enterprise culture that follows modern management principles. For that reason the idea of hospital holding companies or hospital management organizations was introduced starting in the early 1980ies. By now, hospital holding organizations10 have evolved in the majority of the nine Austrian States and are currently responsible for the administration of around 50 7 Österreichisches Bundesinstitut für Gesundheitswesen Currently 874 DRGs are being reimbursed including intensive care service delivery and psychiatric care. 45 percent of those are reimbursed on a fee for service basis (Medinische Einzelleistungen) und 55 percent on DRGs. In the course of time credit points allocated to individual hospitals have been re-weighted towards hospitals with higher specialization. 9 Leistungsorientierte Krankenanstaltenfinanzierung 10 The creation of hospital holdings in Austria corresponds to formal privatization. As opposed to material privatization, formally privatized hospitals include organizations, which are still owned by public authorities but run by a private entities (Strehl R.: Privatisierungswelle im deutschen Krankenhauswesen?, in: Arnold M., Klauber J., Schnellschmidt H. (Hrsg.): Krankenhaus-Report 2002, Schwerpunkt: Krankenhaus im Wettbewerb, 2003, S. 113-129) 8 6 percent of all hospital beds (Hofmarcher et al. 2001). The second largest group of hospital owners includes religious orders that largely follow a similar practice as the inpatient services of religious order hospitals are fully integrated and funded by the same public financing scheme. Regional governments also cover deficits accrued in these hospitals. For that reason, non-profit hospitals of religious orders are regarded to be public hospitals. Together with the hospitals owned by the government they make up the vast majority of hospitals in Austria. The innovative concept of incorporation in holding structures was based on the idea of creating a contractual relationship between State governments and hospital management. It requires the removal of all publicly owned hospitals from the public administration and their incorporation in a holding organization fully owned by the State government but managed by privately employed professional hospital managers (Theurl 2004). Holding companies are established under Austrian corporate law and feature just like any other business corporation a board of directors, which represents the owner(s) and oversees management. All assets of the hospitals such as medical equipment, facilities and infrastructure were transferred into this new corporation (Oechsner 2004). Independence from local political influence was ultimately necessary and one of the goals of incorporation. This not only puts hospital matters at arms-length from local politics but ensures the integration of administrative regulations and responsibilities in one hand. Before the creation of holding companies various departments of the state government were responsible for different hospital matters such as infrastructure, human resources etc. For profit management was never a goal for the creation of holding organizations. Rather it was expected that more flexibility and autonomy would put hospital management in a better position to manage resources and to achieve efficiency gains from economies of scale. This includes the “right-sizing” of infrastructure, the consolidation of medical departments and specialties and strict adherence to the Austrian Hospital Master Plan with regard to investment in high-end equipment. Holding organizations were founded as nonfor-profit entities, with a binding mandate to provide comprehensive secondary health care for the population and to meet high quality standards by ensuring financial sustainability at the same time. The regional government as owner of the holding company still assumes the residual liability for any debts the holding may incur. The first hospital holding was founded in the Austrian State of Vorarlberg, in 1979. 11 The establishment of the Krankenhausbetriebsgesellschaft – KHBG (hospital operating company) was facilitated by the fact that most municipal hospital owners were in deep debt and were not keen to maintain ownership of their local hospital which was seen more and more as a large liability for the municipality. The KHBG is now the largest provider of health care in the State of Vorarlberg and has a market share of 84%, serving around 450.000 people in a geographical area of around 2600 km2. The KHBG is legally owned by the Government of Vorarlberg (96%) and the towns (and former hospital owners) of Feldkirch, Bludenz, Bregenz and Hohenems (each of them 1%, which secures them a seat on the board). It manages five public hospitals with around 1700 hospital beds at eight different locations. With a total of about 3100 employees, it is the largest employer in Vorarlberg (KHBG Annual Report 2002). The various centralized services such as IT services are based in the LKH12 Feldkirch, which is Vorarlberg’s largest hospital (677 beds, 1500 employees) and the State’s only tertiary facility, affiliated with the University clinic of Innsbruck as a teaching facility. Focusing on its core competencies, the KHBG encourages the outsourcing of ancillary services such as facility management, laundry, and consumer services such as restaurants, banking, and shops, maintenance services (medical equipment and general maintenance) and partly IT services. In addition, there are plans to convert central sterilization services into a public- private partnership project (Maikisch 2004). Three hospital sites were closed over a 10 year time period, their beds eliminated and their technical capacity merged into more specialized sites. This first hospital holding project turned out to be politically viable and economically successful, as acknowledged in 1992 by the Court of Accounts, Austria’s supreme auditing authority. Over the past 11 12 Krankenhaus- Betriebsgesellschaft m.b.H. Landeskrankenhaus (State Hospital) 7 decade the same concept became the key model for hospital restructuring in Austria, by transferring hospitals ownership from local governments and private operators (largely religious orders) into an independent holding organization. Since then, seven of the nine Austrian States have established holding organizations to generate efficiency gains in the hospital sector. (Maikisch 2004). In Upper Austria with the size of around 12.000 km2 and a population of around 1,4 million (2001) among Austria’s largest states, the newly established holding covered 12 public hospitals until then owned by the State Government. Established in 2002 as a holding corporation 13, the GESPAG14 has a market share of around 50% and is with around 8.500 employees Upper Austria’s largest health care provider. It runs 12 hospitals at 16 different locations; 9 of those are general public hospitals and three are mono-profile, specialized hospitals. The creation of this holding led to several changes in structure and capacity of the Upper Austrian hospital landscape. Mirroring the experience in other states, some hospitals of the network will be closed and beds partially transferred to more appropriate sites, resulting in improved efficiency and substantial cost reduction, especially of management costs. In 2005 two more hospitals, will have merged into the holding and will contribute to the network’s specialized internal medicine and psychosomatic medicine services (Geck et al. 2004). Qualitative research has shown that the incorporation in a holding structure has allowed for faster decision making and more managerial flexibility. Compared to stand-alone hospitals, resources can be managed in a more efficient way, leading to synergies, economies of scale and risk-sharing of large capital investments for medical equipment. In addition, individual hospitals in the same geographical area specialize in certain areas to avoid redundancy and overlapping, resulting in reduced overall costs (Kastl 2004). In some states, such as in the case of Styria, the networking was preceded by elaborate hospital master plans, factoring in variables such as emerging burden of disease as well as future trends in epidemiology and demography. In addition, the master plan recognized international evidence that in some specialties a minimum service volume must be observed to comply with international quality standards. This led to the merging of specialties and transfer of staff to generate centers of excellence for certain medical specialties. The newly created holding companies have few employees of their own, in most cases only its management board. Hospital employees, such as nurses and doctors are contracted under state employment law. Earlier, the civil servant status of hospital employees which included special rights such as flexible working hours and protection from lay-offs was abolished and for newly hired staff replaced by employment regulations similar to ones under private law. Still, employment policies were some of the most sensitive concerns in the transformation process as hospital employees are formally employed under state law but required to report to management of a private holding corporation. For that reason hospital employees employed under state laws are contractually transferred to the holding company by means of a special law. This arrangement gives the holding company similar rights like a private employer, including hiring and firing. Additionally, it assures that only one type of employment contract is in place. Compensation schemes are exclusively based on the employment law of the state government. As a result, staff selection and hiring procedures are much shorter and more flexible, as they are at arms-length from political influence and are directly processed by the holding company. Time consuming selection procedures that had to be approved by local and state governments can now be avoided and hospital directors can independently select doctors, nurses and other staff. However, managerial selection needs to be cleared by senior management of the holding company (Oechsner 2004). 13 14 Aktiengesellschaft Oberösterreichische Gesundheits- und Spitals-AG 8 Fig. 2. Yearly Cost Increase, Austrian Hospitals Source: Ministry of Health, Austria 9,5 9,05 % 7,5 5,5 5,23 4,1 3,5 4,38 4,27 3,65 2,84 1,79 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 1,5 2,31 3,11 Performance: Available data thus far demonstrate that Austria’s restructured hospital sector has achieved stated performance goals. Recent analysis shows that the incorporation of hospitals15 together with other reforms such as new payment systems resulted in improved resources management, better service quality and reduced costs. Compared to 1994 when hospitals were still part of a large public bureaucracy annual cost increase reached unsustainable dimensions (9,05% in 1994). In recent years this annual increase was successfully contained at a much lower levels (3.65% in 2003). This could largely be attributed to a changed incentive structure after incorporation, economies of scale and improved internal cooperation within the holding structure. Signals stemming from the newly introduced prospective payment mechanism (DRG) and advances in medical technology resulted in a significant reduction in average length of stay (ALOS). Data show a continuous downwards trend and a dramatically reduced need for bed capacity. In 1997 average length of stay was over 7 days, it dropped until 2003 to under 6 days with continued downward tendencies. The combined elements of hospital reform exposed overcapacities and increased political pressure to reduce fixed costs. Downsizing or closure of hospitals remains a politically charged and highly sensitive issue. Nevertheless, data from the Austrian Ministry of Health show a significant reduction of bed capacity of over 8% between 1997 and 2003. After the introduction of the holding company concept, the Austrian hospital sector has demonstrated to be more flexible after restructuring and better prepared to adapt to a changing business environment. At the same time there is evidence that the sector has improved financial sustainability while achieving one of Europe’s highest patient satisfaction rates (In the EU Commission Patient Satisfaction Survey 1999a, Austria came in second behind Finland in the EU). 15 This is also true for the hospitals owned by religious orders. Orders have followed similar practices and do not manage hospitals any longer on their own but feature similar non-profit hospital management organizations. 9 Fig. 3. Inpatient Bed Capacity, Austria ~8% Reduction between 1997 and 2003 Source: Ministry of Health, Austria 54000 -1,18% 53000 -1,84% 52000 -1,51% 51000 -1,30% --0,92% 50000 49000 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 -0,69% -1,19% 2002 2003 Fig. 4. Patient Satisfaction, Austria Source: Eurostat (European Commission) and Dietmar Mueller, 1999 Finland 29,0 49,0 Austria 34,8 Netherlands 7,9 France 61,8 11,0 Belgium 48,7 9,9 Great Britain in percent 35,8 46,4 13,1 Denmark 36,2 14,1 Sweden 34,1 13,3 Luxembourg 32,6 12,9 Germany 36,8 10,8 32,4 Spain 25,6 Ireland 18,8 Italy 13,6 Greece 8,6 Portugal 5,1 EU-15 9,2 0 32,1 10 20 very satisfied satisfied 30 40 50 60 70 80 ESTONIA Estonia established a market economy in 1991, after 50 years of socialism, but inherited a significant overcapacity of hospital bed stock stemming from Soviet times. To serve a population of 1.4 million, Estonia had 120 hospitals with more than 17,000 beds. By 1996, the number of hospitals had declined to 78, mainly through administrative closures of small rural hospitals that did not meet the new licensing requirements. The number of hospitals in bigger urban areas remained almost unchanged. However, hospitals had been given semi-autonomous status granting management full employer rights, including hiring-and firing of personnel. All medical staff lost its civil service status and began to work under private labor regulations starting in 1992. Due to new medical technologies, improved financial incentives and pressure from the Estonian Health Insurance Fund average length of stay (ALOS) decreased in the Estonian hospital sector by 30% from 1993 10 to 1998. The number of hospital beds decreased by 20% during the same period. However, the reduction of overall hospital bed capacity was not as significant as the reduction of ALOS, the reason why acute bed occupancy remained below 70% in 1999. Several attempts by the Ministry of Social Affairs and the municipality of Tallinn to consolidate services in some hospitals, to achieve more efficiency and to vacate remaining buildings failed, due to provider resistance supported by negative media coverage. Inefficiencies in the hospital sector in urban areas increased over the years and became even more acute during the 1998/1999 economic down-turn. Fig. 5. Average Length of Stay, Estonia Source: own research 17,0 15,0 15,4 13,0 11,0 9,9 9,0 8,7 8,5 8,2 7,0 1993 1999 2001 2002 2003 A new approach to increase efficiency in the hospital sector was formulated by the Estonian Government in 1999 and included the development of a long-term national hospital master plan; the provision of autonomous legal status for hospitals, including management rights and responsibilities conducive for costeffective management decision-making; and the exposure of hospitals to appropriate financial incentives to reward efficiency. During 1999-2000, the “National Hospital Master Plan 2015” was developed, which featured a vision for hospital capacity needs in the year 2015. To avoid conflicts of interest and local biases, an international consultant team was contracted through an international tender process. Criteria used for planning hospital capacity included sufficient population pools to support minimum service volume for quality and efficiency, development of medical technology, demographic and epidemiological projections and a requirement that a hospital should not be further away than 60 minutes travel time by car (70 km). This master planning exercise resulted in a proposed future hospital configuration of 13 hospitals by 2015 (instead of 78 in 1999) including two university level teaching hospitals, four multi-profile sub-regional central hospitals and 7 county hospitals. The Government endorsed the proposal of such master plan in 2003, but included several changes after a series of political negotiations. The target of only 13 hospitals as overall number of acute hospitals proposed by the consultant team was changed to a total of 21 acute hospitals including three regional hospitals with tertiary care (catchment population: 600,000 – 800,000), four central hospitals (catchment population: 100,000 – 150,000), 11 county hospitals (catchment population: 10,000 – 50,000), and in addition three local hospitals with smaller catchment areas. This plan included the proposition to turn many of the remaining hospitals into long-term care providers. At the same time, new regulations for health care organizations were established under the 2001 Health Care Services Organization Act which required all public hospitals in Estonia to be incorporated under private law as foundations (trusts) or joint-stock companies by 2003. This led to a situation where hospitals remain in the public sector but are being run as companies according to private law, granting them full managerial rights over assets, full residual claimant status and access to financial markets. Supervisory boards govern newly established public hospital companies through supervisory boards for which members are appointed by the owners (joint-stock company model) or founders (foundation model). The owners or founders are the central government, local governments, other public bodies (e.g. university) or a 11 combination of the above. Subsequently, the board appointments reflect to large extent current political preferences. The legal transition of hospitals into either trusts or joint-stock companies allowed for the implementation of the Hospital Master Plan 2015 and resulted in several mergers of individual hospitals. In the period from 1999 to 2001, 41 hospitals and outpatient clinics in urban areas were merged into six networks. During this process management teams and supervisory boards were created and given operational responsibilities within the merged hospitals. The newly appointed hospital management teams were expected to realize efficiencies from economies of scale and to free hospitals from fixed costs by further restructuring buildings and bed capacity. Four of the networks were able to restructure their services and close seven facilities. The number of beds decreased in all merged hospitals, while bed occupancy increased to 7080%. Hospitals, Beds (in 100) Fig. 6. Reduction of Capacity, Hospitals and Beds Source: own research 140,0 14380 120,0 115 1993-2001 Hospitals ~33% Beds ~ 36% 10360 100,0 9160 80,0 78 60,0 8020 51 50 40,0 1993 1999 2001 Table 1: Performance indicators, Estonian hospitals. National statistics* North-Estonia Regional Hospital 2002 8450 67 Change from 2000 n.a. 12% -10% -1.5% -7% 2003 Change from 2000 -3 0% -19% 10% 22% 2002 2003 Tartu University Hospital Trust Children Hospital Trust, Tallinn 2003 2003 Change from 2000 -4 -28% -10% 16% -1% Change from 2000 -2 -30% -12% 20% -7% No of buildings n.a. 12 15 2 No of beds 8248 1472 929 241 ALOS 8.5 9.3 6.6 5.3 Bed occupancy 65% 77% 81% 75% No of 261.3 40.6 41.5 12.2 hospitalizations (in .000) Annual turnover 181.5 31% 45.3 62% 50.8 44% 8.8 6% (mill €) ** Source: Ministry of Social Affairs, Medical Statistics, Estonia, 2004. Source*: National Statistics, Ministry of Social Affairs, Estonia, 2004 Source**: Total hospital sector revenue (HP.1). Estonian National Health Accounts, 2000 and 2003. In the capital Tallinn, the Children’s Hospital Trust was created by merging two pediatric hospitals and a policlinic, a total of four hospital and ambulatory buildings in three different locations. Only two years after the merger, two buildings were vacated. Also, there was a significant reduction in numbers of administrative personnel. The merger, including the closure of infrastructure was widely accepted by patients as well as staff. An information campaign addressed the efficiency and quality gains from downsizing and created the necessary knowledge and understanding. Additionally, staff was actively involved in the restructuring process and widely consulted on interior design for refurbished departments. Also, savings of fixed costs were re-directed to increase salaries of medical personnel. For other mergers 12 such as the North Estonia Regional Hospital a different approach was chosen. Unlike the Children’s Hospital Trust this merger process was prepared by a relatively small group at the central level. This approach lead to a lack of communication trust between hospital staff and the management board and resulted in negative media attention. Overall, the Estonian model of incorporating public hospitals and merging several individual facilities into larger legal entities helped to implement politically and administratively challenging hospital reforms. The transfer of administrative decisions from publicly elected officials to corporate management has allowed for a significant restructuring of services and efficiency gains. This includes efforts to meet salaryexpectations of medical personnel, to increase quality of health care services and infrastructure while stabilizing public hospital expenditures at the same time. However, during the reform process it became also clear that too little attention was paid to better define roles and functions of hospital supervisory boards. In several cases, Government and municipalities in their role as owners failed to state clear objectives and terms of reference for these boards and expected in turn the board to define its own responsibilities. This led to a situation where boards focused largely on financial issues and financial sustainability only. This was essential during the first few years after the mergers, however, at a more stable stage, owners and their representatives in the supervisory boards should address wider interests including those of patients and the community. CONCLUSION The experience in Austria and Estonia demonstrates that the incorporation of hospitals and horizontal integration through the creation of holding companies or hospital networks is a viable tool to combine market incentives for management while maintaining public ownership, and at the same time achieving efficiency gains. The hospital sector is the largest expenditure category in any health system; cost escalation and user dissatisfaction with the quality of services are common features in many countries. Incorporation aims at expanding autonomy and decision rights with the ultimate goal to shift control (over inputs and outputs) from a public supervising agency to the hospital itself. Incorporation also intends to make hospitals earn revenue under market conditions as opposed to rely only on public budget allocation. The independence of an incorporated hospital holding or network not only allows for more flexibility for its management but also compels managers to focus on the financial liability of their institutions. Both, Austria and Estonia, can be considered success stories when it comes to putting the hospital sector on a more sustainable footing. Both countries developed hospital master plans that provide the framework for the planning of hospital services. Both countries have separated health services financing from provision, introduced contracting and put in place financial incentives for hospitals that reward efficient service provision, maximizing the potential of prospective payment systems (DRGs). Both countries have essentially incorporated public hospitals by re-establishing them under private law, but preserving public ownership. This concept has provided a framework where public hospitals are run as business entities, management is empowered to ensure good clinical practice and efficient financial performance. And it has put hospital management issues at arms lengths from political influence. As a consequence, both countries have used hospital incorporation as an instrument to realize efficiency gains in accordance to a long-term facilities master plan. The key principle was to network individual hospitals, achieve horizontal integration, downsizing of excess capacity, in line with efficiency and quality objectives. Experience in both countries demonstrated that management changes inside those newly established hospital networks led to optimization of staffing and resource management. Interestingly, both country cases, while considered national best practice, have received little international attention thus far. A number of other countries in Central and Eastern Europe (including some of the new EU member states) and some countries of the former Soviet Union (FSU) are considering introducing hospital autonomy, networks and hospital mergers as a measure to optimize performance in the hospital sector. In 2004, Armenia began to implement a hospital services master plan in the capital city of Yerevan where a population of 1.2 million has been historically served by 43 hospitals. The basic elements of the reform are similar to the one featured in Austria and Estonia: A rational master plan was developed; financing and 13 provision of care were separated; and public hospitals have been incorporated under corporate law. The first step merged 37 public hospitals and policlinics into 10 newly incorporated public hospital joint-stock companies. The selected hospital merger groupings contain a significant proportion of the multi-profile hospitals. There is a significant potential for initial fixed cost reduction from downsizing the existing network. Remaining facilities would feature higher utilization, improved efficiency and would be quality health care providers for Yerevan. Until now, four pilot project mergers representing about 25 percent of total hospital bed capacity in Yerevan were selected and two are ready for implementation. The hospitals will have a chief executive supported by a management team. The new networks will feature improved governance and management arrangements, new financial management systems and accounting practices; consolidated budgets (private and public revenues); strategic development and performance plans for executive management; publication of annual reports; and independent audits. Armenia would be the first country where hospital incorporation would be put to a test in a low income, non EU country featuring a highly resource constrained health sector. 14 REFERENCES 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. Arnold, M., Klauber J., Schnellschmidt H. (Hrsg.): Krankenhaus-Report 2002, Schwerpunkt: Krankenhaus im Wettbewerb, 2003, S. 113-129 Birner H.: Personal Communication, June 8, 2004 Busse R.,Wörz M.: Marktorientierung von Krankenhaeusern: Ein Überblick über Reformen im europischen Vergleich, in: Arnold M., Klauber J., H. (Hrsg.): Krankenhaus-Report 2002, Schwerpunkt: Krankenhaus im Wettbewerb, 2003, S. 21-30 Eid, F.: Applying the Decision Rights Approach to a Case of Hospital Institutional Design. The World Bank, 2001. Eid, F.: Hospital Governance and Incentive Design. The Case of Corporatized Public Hospitals in Lebanon. The World Bank, 2001. Embacher, G.: The Austrian DRG System. Presentation for Study Tour. Austrian Ministry of Health, 2005 (unpublished). Estonian Ministry of Social Affairs, National Health Accounts 1998-2003: www.sm.ee. Estonian Ministry of Social Affairs: Estonia Hospital Masterplan 2015. Technical Report. http://www.sm.ee/est/HtmlPages/HMP2015/$file/HMP2015.pdf Estonian Ministry of Social Affairs: Estonian Health Statistics 2000-2002. Estonian Ministry of Social Affairs: Social sector in numbers. Tallinn, 2004. Geck, H., Koblmüller, M.: Personal Communication, June 8, 2004 Gespag Geschäftsbericht (Annual Report) 2002, 2003, 2004 Harris, J.: The Internal Organization of Hospitals: some Economic Implications, Bell Journal of Economics, 8, 1977, p. 467-482. Hofmarcher M. M., Kraus M., Riedel M. (2004) Finanzierungsmodus der Fondskrankenanstalten nach Bundesländern, Mimeo Institute for Advanced Studies, IHS HealthEcon Wien 2004 Hofmarcher M.M., Riedel M.: Health Expenditure in the EU: No Public Sector without the Private One. Focus: The Austrian Hospital Sector - One System or Nine? Health System Watch I-2001: http://www.ihs.ac.at/departments/fin/HealthEcon/watch/hsw01_1e.pdf: June 20, 2004 Hofmarcher M.M., Lietz, Ch., Schnabl, A., Weichselbauer, M.: Effizienzanalyse im intramuralen Bereich, Study commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Social Affairs and Generation, Wien July 2003. Hofmarcher M.M., Weichselbaumer, M. (2004): The impact of Austria’s EU-accession on the health sector labor market. Wirtschaftspolitische Blätter 1/2004 Hofmarcher, M.M., Riedel, M.: Impact of Case-Mix Hospital Payment Reforms on Health Systems – Case Study Austria, Research Report commissioned by the World Bank, Institute for Advanced Studies, April 2003. Jakab, M., Preker, A., Harding, A., Hawkins, L.: The Introduction of Market Forces in the Public Hospital Sector. From New Public Management to Organizational Reform. The World Bank, 2002. Jesse, M.: Evaluation of Estonian hospital reform. Draft report, 2005 (unpublished). Kastl, J.: Personal Communication, June 14, 2004 KHBG Geschäftsbericht (Annual Report) 2002, 2003 Lakdawalla, D., Philiplson, T.: Nonprofit Production and Competition, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 6377, 1998, http://www.nber.org/papers/w6377. Lee, M.: A Conspicuous Production Theory of Hospital Behavior, Southern Economic Journal, 38, 1971, p.48-58. Maikisch, H.: Personal Communication, June 8, 2004 Müller, D.: The Health Care System in Austria. Presentation, 2005. Newhouse, J.: Toward a Theory of Nonprofit Institutions: An Economic Model for a Hospital, American Economic Review, 60, 1970, p.64-74. Öchsner, S.: Personal Communication, June 15, 2004 Palu, T., Kadakmaa R.: Estonian Hospital Sector in Transition. Eurohealth, Vol 7 No 3 Special Issue 2000. 15 30. Preker, A., Harding, A.: Innovations in Health Service Delivery. The Corporatization of Public Hospitals. The World Bank, 2003. 31. Rechnungshofbericht (Report of Central Auditing Authority), Wien 1992 32. Rethelyi, J., Miskovits, E., Szocska, K.; Organizational Reform in the Hungarian Hospital Sector. Institutional Analysis of Hungarian Hospitals and the Possibilities of Corporatization. The World Bank, 2002. 33. Strehl R.: Privatisierungswelle im deutschen Krankenhauswesen?, in: Arnold M., Klauber J., Schnellschmidt H. (Hrsg.): Krankenhaus-Report 2002, Schwerpunkt: Krankenhaus im Wettbewerb, 2003, S. 113-129 34. Strehl R.: Privatisierungswelle im deutschen Krankenhauswesen?, in: Arnold., M., Klauber, J., Schellschmidt, H. [Hrsg.]: Krankenhaus-Report 2002, Schattauer Verlag, Stuttgart/New York, 2002, S. 113- 129 35. Sudy, R.: Von der Vision zur Realität. Die Managementorientierung der steirischen Landeskrankenhäuser. KAGES, (unpublished). 36. The World Bank: Case Study: Estonian Hospital Reform. Reorganization of Tartu University Hospital. World Bank Consultant Report, 2003 (unpublished). 37. Theurl, Engelbert: Personal Communication, June 15, 2004