Market Convergence & Firm Strategies: Towards a systematic analysis Johannes M. Pennings Professor, Management Department, Wharton Pennings@wharton.upenn.edu Phanish Puranam Doctoral Candidate,Management Department, Wharton puranam@management.wharton.upenn.edu The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania 2000 Steinberg-Dietrich Hall Philadelphia, PA 19104-6207 Phone:215-898-7755 or 898-1228,fax:215-898-0401 January/February, 2000 Keywords: convergence, digital imaging, network methods Paper presented at the Organization Science Winter Conference Keystone, CO Market Convergence & Firm Strategies: Towards a systematic analysis Abstract This paper seeks to explore the phenomenon of market convergence- a process by which markets become increasingly similar over time. The impact of this process is to erode market boundaries, and create strategic challenges for firms by causing them to face up to new sets of technologies, needs and customers. In this research we try to develop a framework to understand the drivers of convergence and the role that firm strategies play in convergence processes. Firms are prone to fall into a competency trap as they accumulate intangible assets, which have conferred a competitive advantage. Some strategies for learning will aggravate the consequences of path dependence, while other might diminish or even suspend that dependence. We review acquisitions and strategic alliances, which differ in their irreversibility, flexibility and level of commitment to new and remote technologies and customers. We also review drivers of convergence and include swift triggers such as deregulation and delayed ones such as socio-economic developments and technological breakthroughs. To complement our theory building, we present preliminary results from the analysis of a particular industrydigital imaging, which is being created out of the convergence of photography, computer hardware & software and electronics, in an attempt to show how the convergence phenomenon may be measured and investigated using network methodologies. We explore the growing centrality and density in a network of four-digit SIC industries in order to isolate the speed, and progression of technological convergence. Market Convergence & Firm Strategies: Towards a systematic analysis Introduction In this paper we undertake an attempt to systematically map out the convergence in technologies and markets. After outlining a framework we provide some empirical analysis to illustrate some issues. We seek to answer three questions: What is the convergence phenomenon, why does convergence occur, and how do firms cope with its implications strategically? We believe that the convergence phenomenon should take center stage in the research and theory on technological change, innovation and corporate strategy, as it constitutes a major impetus for growth, development and renewal, while also causing much upheaval, market disequilibria and firm mortality. We explore the nature of convergence and differentiate between the supply and demand side of the market that undergoes convergence. Convergence can be viewed as the unbundling and repacking of technologies or their commercial application into product-market concepts. Convergence between previously disjointed markets can be viewed as the erosion of boundaries that define and isolate industry-specific knowledge. That knowledge resides in the firms who collectively combine their firm-specific knowledge into industry specific knowledge. We observe that process on both the supply side—for example bundling or fusion of technologies, as well as on the demand side when previously heterogeneous sets of customers become similar, or there is a pull towards satisfying multiple needs in a single transaction. We propose a taxonomy of convergence processes that embraces both producer and consumer issues. Next we attempt to identify a range of drivers that trigger the onset of convergence. Sometimes, we witness a sudden surge ofconvergence—for example after the deregulation of the telecommunication and financial services sectors. In other cases, the trigger has delayed effects—for example socio-economic developments such as globalization, or homogenization of customer segments due to changing demographics. In still other cases the driver might be a technological innovation whose speed may depend on underlying technological oportunity. We also examine the strategic implications of convergence. The dominant paradigm in strategic management and innovation has centered around the resource based view of the firm (Penrose, 1959), wichh has a major implication that firms need to be “coherent” (Teece et al., 1994) in their accumulation of intangible assets. They face limits in the quest for diversification. That very accumulation renders firms path dependent. As a contrast to the coherence imperative, convergence might wreak havoc with the firm and its coherent bundle of intangible assets. When convergence takes hold, firms are forced to abandon a strict adherence to coherence, and seek to suspend the competency trap that comes with path dependence. We thus observe a tension between coherence and adaptiveness to convergence. In their corporate development activities, firms may choose between internal development, acquisitions and strategic alliances to suspend the path dependence and branch out to other markets that undergo convergence. Studying convergence empirically presents several problems. For analytic purposes, we need to arrive at a demarcation of market boundaries before we can study any changes in them over time, and this constitutes a fairly serious challenge to any theory of market convergence. At the heart of the problem is the fact that stable market boundaries are definable only in an equilibrium situation, whereas convergence is by nature a disequilibriating process. Hence, our approach to the empirical study of market convergence will necessarily involve some assumptions about prior period equilibrium, and the validity of certain industry classification schemes, in particular the Standard Industrial Classification scheme. An additional problem is the measurement of the relationships between industries, and how they change over time. In the empirical part of this paper, we present preliminary results from the analysis of a particular industry- digital imaging-, which is being created out of the convergence of photography, computer hardware & software and electronics. Using data on the incidence of inter-organizational relationships such as joint ventures, alliances, and acquisitions, and well established measures of network structure, the changing patterns of linkages between industries is used to demonstrate convergence, and suggest possible means to measure the phenomenon. We do not present any formal tests of hypotheses in this paper, but restrict ourselves to developing a systematic approach to understanding and describing an important phenomena which is actively shaping today’s economic landscape. Market convergence: conceptualization and definitional clarity In this section, we present a basic, definitional framework, which will aid in the subsequent analysis of the market convergence phenomenon. We conceptualize a market to be composed of five sets of elements, i.e, firms that use technologies to create products that satisfy needs of customers. This enumeration constitutes little more than an elaboration of the conventional economic definition of markets as the aggregate of buyers and sellers who come together for the determination of the price for a product (Pindyck and Rubenfeld 1998); we have merely made explicit two features of the market which are usually unobservable, i.e, needs and technologies. To make the discussion clearer, we present a simple representation, which might be called a “convergence map”. (See Diagram 1) This map simply indicates that at any given point in time, the configuration of firms (Fi), technologies (Tj), products (Pk), customer needs (Nl) and customers themselves (Cm) may be represented as a series of mappings (oneto many, many-to-one or many to many). There exists an underlying mapping from a given technology to the needs set, which is exogenous to the decisions by firms and customers (as shown by the box around the technology-needs mapping) i.e. each technology satisfies a certain need or set of needs.1 Typically only the set of firms, products and customers is directly observable. Technologies and needs are only indirectly measurable. In particular, we conceptualize products as being embodiments of technology-need mappings. We believe that neither firms nor customers can treat the others’ needs or technologies respectively as exogenous; firms can, and do manipulate the motivation of customers through advertising (Pennings and Kim, 2000). Similarly, by signaling unfulfilled needs consumers can influence the direction of technological development (Schmookler 1966). For conceptual clarity however, our discussion of convergence phenomena will treat endogenous changes in customer needs (or firm technologies) as different from those influenced by firms (or customers) and will focus on the former. The convergence map is a "snapshot" representation at a single point in time. Over time, the mappings are likely to change. In fact, it is particular kinds of change in these mappings, which we identify as market convergence. Given that the mapping from technologies to needs is invariant, changes only occur when the elements in the set of firms or customers change, the mapping from firms to technologies change or the mapping from 1 Our conceptualization builds on notions of local search in solution spaces employed by organizational scholars in the behavioral tradition (Cyert and March 1963, Nelson & Winter 1982) We assume that technologies exist "out there" which do not reside in any firm but are gradually discovered by firms. Also, some technologies are proximate to each other while others are distant. customers to needs change. Our representation allows us to offer a clear discussion of various cases of market convergence. Broadly speaking, market convergence may occur on the demand side or on the supply side. Demand side One archetype of demand side convergence can be inferred from the growing similarity of needs across groups of consumers. This is a phenomenon, well known in the marketing literature, which is sometimes termed the convergence of markets. Levitt (1983) for instance in an award winning article argued that globalization of world markets could be inferred from local, national markets becoming homogeneous across the world, with customers across these markets evolving to a uniform set of needs. Socio-economic developments towards global diffusion of transportation, telecommunication, FDI and foreign trade have contributed to the convergence of needs of customers across the world. In contrast, de-regulation produces a second archetype of demand side convergence, which may be termed “product bundling.” If the avoidable transaction costs of customers are sufficiently high, there may be a pull from the customer’s side for “one stop shopping,” i.e. a desire to obtain in a single transaction a product which satisfies multiple needs. The financial services and telecommunication industries illustrate this convergence. De– regulation permits the bundling of formerly disparate products such as commercial, consumer and investment banking, or local and long distance and wireless telephony, or even power, gas and internet connectivity. While de-regulation was the driver, what is critical in these industries is customers recognizing a set of distinct, though related set of needs as capable of being satisfied in a single transaction, thus reducing transaction costs. Hence the location of this kind of convergence on the demand side. An important aspect of convergence brought about by de-regulation is its high speed; de-regulation removes artificial barriers between industries almost overnight, as opposed to gradual convergence across customer groups which is driven socio-economic developments as illustrated by the above mentioned globalization of markets. These examples represent respectively the convergence of needs –either across consumers, or within consumers. In the former case, different consumers acquire the same needs, whereas in the latter, the same set of consumers see distinct needs as closely related, which they can satisfy in a single transaction. Supply side One archetype of convergence on the supply side occurs when new technologies are discovered which map onto needs already being satisfied by existing technologies. This implies that the needs satisfied by different technological capabilities begin to overlap to a greater extent (note the analogy with convergence of needs across customers) and creates a situation where one technology supplants another by offering the same benefits, eventually, perhaps at lower costs. Examples of this sort of convergence abound in the popular press; specifically in computers and communication industries, digital imaging and photography industries, as well as some sectors of biotech and pharmaceuticals. Underlying many of the examples in the IT industry is the presence of an integrative technology platform – digital computing- which is enabling activities in other industries (such as photography and communications ) to be performed more efficiently. The preceding archetype of convergence should be distinguished from another that has been termed “technology bundling“ or “fusion” (Teece 1996). Fusion involves recombination of existing technologies in new and innovative configurations. In other words, firms must see some possible economies of scope/synergy effects when bundling various technologies. Examples would include the coming together of technologies such as optics and electronics, and biology and instrumentation to create opto-electronics and bioengineering respectively. The two archetypes of convergence on the supply side represent the convergence of technologies – in the first case , different technologies become similar in terms of the needs they can satisfy, and in the second, different technologies come together to create new functionality or improve efficiency of existing products. While the drivers of both kinds of technological convergence are technological innovations, they are likely to differ in terms of whether they occur in the same firm or in different firms.2 The speed of convergence in either of these cases is largely a function of technological popportunity. (See the research based on the Yale & Carnegie studies of appropriability and technological opportunity, for instance Klevorick et al 1992).All the instances of convergence, whether on the demand side or the supply side share the same common attribute- formerly distinct markets become similar, eroding the boundaries between them. Before concluding this brief overview, we must point out that our taxonomy of convergence phenomena has centered around the initial causes and patterns of convergence; in reality, convergence is a dynamic and often a self re-inforcing phenomenon . Thus, as convergence progresses, we may witness multiple kinds of convergence, which may also occur at increasing rates. Computer hardware and software is almost always sold today as a bundle. Innovations in each realm are increasingly targeted to exploit innovations in the other- improvements in quality, breadth and speed of computer hardware enable more powerful software to be designed, and improvements in software programming enable 2 For instance, technology fusion requires close co-ordination- this would imply the sort of incentive alignment and low powered incentives offered by a hierarchy. On the other hand, the creation of technological innovation which cannibalizes existent technologies, is unlikely to be taken up by a firm internally, and is more likely to be introduced in a competing firm, often an entrepreneurial entrant from another industry. optimal utilization of hardware, and hence design improvements. Biotechnology, which was initially seen as being in competition with conventional pharmacology because of its abilities to satisfy the same broad class of needs, has evolved into an integral part of the pharmaceutical industry. Every large pharmaceutical firm has its host of biotechnology partners, and its propriatary R&D and product developments are geared towards managing these relationships. In retrospect, the final outcome in these computer and biotech examples looks like technology fusion, though neither of the two convergence cases originated as technology fusion-the first started out as a case of product bundling (demand side convergence) and the second as technology substitution ( supply side convergence). Summarizing, we have identified convergence on both the demand and supply side, and have spelled out some of the drivers that trigger the process. On the demand side we mentioned socio-econmic developments and deregulation. On the supply side we referred to technological innovation as the prime driver. In the next section we complete the elements of a framework and spell out some strategic implications regarding convergence on both sides of the market. Firm strategies and market convergence: A framework The typology presented in the last section was meant to be useful in identifying the various archetypes of convergence and their possible antecedents. We now turn to a discussion on the strategic implications of various kinds of convergence. In the first part of this section, we develop an axiomatic framework to classify the archetypes of market convergence and study the role that firms play in driving and responding to them. Apart from distinguishing convergence as occurring on the demand side or on the supply side, another approach is to distinguish between substitute and complement effects from the perspective of firms (Khanna & Greenstein 1997). On the demand side, the convergence of needs across consumers implies that different groups of consumers become substitutable with each other, as they grow similar in terms of needs. The convergence of related products into a single product bundle implies that there are complementarities between multiple needs- the value to serving them together is higher than serving them individually. On the supply side, convergence across technologies which causes one technology to offer the benefits of the other illustrates technological substitution.The convergence between technologies caused by technology fusion or bundling exemplify complementarities. These ideas are summarised in Diagram 2. All convergence processes have the impact of eroding boundaries between industries, and thereby posing stratgeic challenges to firms, causing them to face new technologies, consumers, and needs. To reiterate, the common aspect among multiple forms of convergence is to degrade or render obsolete current organizational capabilities. However, the ability of firms to refashion them to new demands is inhibited by path dependence (Teece Pisano and Shuen 1997). Thus, convergence and path dependence produce a unique tension: firms should abide by the coherence imperative (Teece et al 1994) and “stick to the knitting,” while convergence induces them to diversify by venturing into new and uncharted markets. It is this dichotomy between coherence and convergence that must be resolved through corporate strategy. Faced with this dilemma, firms attempt to extend their capabilities from external sources through a menu of corporate development activities. These activities include alliances, joint ventures, R&D partnerships and mergers and acquisitions (M&A). (Chesbrough & Teece 1996, Nagarajan and Mitchell 1998, Pisano 1990). Due to the uniqe aspects of each convergence form, such as its drivers, rate of convergence, or substitute/complement effects, we expect that different strategic responses might occur in different convergence scenarios. Depending on the extent and speed of adaptation required, firms favor either internal development, technology “grafting” through mergers and acquisitions (Puranam 1999), or relational development through alliances and joint ventures. Some guidance on likely choices is to be found in the literature. Kogut and Zander (1992) argue, for instance, that firms will diversify into (technologically) related areas through internal development and into remote areas through joint ventures. They outsource activities which are complex and difficult to learn, or will buy other firms when under survival pressure. Chesbrough and Teece (1996) and Monteverde (1995) suggest that when joint technological development activities, or technology transfer requires close collaboration between parties, a hierarchical governance structure with well-aligned, low powered incentives is optimal. Recall that convergence on the demand side is usually induced through growing similarity of needs among diverse customers. In this form of convergence with concomitant substitutability of consumer groups, firms must modify their current product offering to keep pace with the trend. They can accomplish this through internal development or interorganizational relationships, depending on how "far" the new product configuration is from their current configuration. Such practices are widely documented for multinatiuonal corporations pondering the alternative of wholly owned subsidiaries versus joint ventures when entering new markets with their existing product line (e.g., Barkema, Douma and Pennings, 1996). For demand side convergence involving complementarities in product bundling, possible responses include product/service bundling, enhancement of corporate scope through diversification and inter-firm liaisons. First, intermediary firms may arise which aggregate the services of other firms e.g., mortgage service providers typically bundle products (credit ratings, mortgage servicing, loans and other financing services) for customers in a manner which is useful to them. Second, when real economies of scope prevail firms extend the realm of proprietary knowledge through internal development or M&A. The recent entry of Bell Atlantic into long distance telephony illustrates this strategic move. The telecommunication infrastructure can be exploited by adding new services to local telephony and other services already provided through that infrastructure. Finally, absent such economies, firms resort to inter-organizational relationships including alliances, cross selling agreements etc. The recently announced alliance between Microsoft and Nokia shows how inter-firm arrangements rather than outright acquisition or internal development allow two firms to merge product offerings—in this case email software and cellular based Internet connectivity. While insufficient real economies of scope to joint operation exist which would justify merging these firms, there are clear complementarities to providing a bundle of these products to consumers. In the case of technology convergence of the substitution variety, firms face a daunting scenario. Technology substitution represents the classic instance of a competence destroying change. Incumbents are unlikely to be responsive to the technological changes which allow entrants to intrude into their product space. If on the other hand, incumbent firms become aware of this threat at an early stage, they are likely to form alliances with firms which embody the new, substitute technology. As the pace of the convergence picks up, survival pressures render acquisition mandatory (Kogut & Zander 1992). Entrants, on the other hand may mostly grow through internal development and perhaps occassionally through alliances, if the distribution channels or other key complementary asets are controlled by the incumbents. Biotechnology firms often commercialize their knowledge by contracting with pharmaceutical firms to penetrate a market, or increasingly with Clinical Research Organizations (CRO’s) such as Quintiles. Finally, in the case of technology bundling due to complementarities, we would expect the rise of technology consortia and other strategic inter-organizational relationships to jointly "search" for the new, combined technology. However, as Chesbrough and Teece (1996) , and Monteverde (1995) suggest, if differences between the underlying knowledge bases of different technologies is substantial, close collaboration become essential, and therefore a hierarchical form of governance (acquisition or internal development) is best suited to the organization of this transaction. Further, if the nature of research needed for combining technology is basic rather than applied, we should expect it to be carried out by, or under the charge of govermental agencies and univeristies. For example, NIST’s AMP (National Institute of Standards and Technology’s Advanced Technology Program) is a good example of both these effects; the program is geared to the funding of risky forms of technology bundling with the objective of commercializing them eventually. Part of NIST’s contribution is simply the funding of risky, basic research which is not commercially viable for firms, but the creation of a new entity (consortia that have representatives from NIST) which approximates a hierarchical governance mode also serves to align incentives and imrove co-operation.The implication from these observations is that different patterns of inter-firm arrangements are bound to surface under these various forms of convergence. In the rest of this paper, we apply this framework to the digital imaging arena which has arisen from the convergence of photography, computing, and electronics industries. Originating in 1984 with the release of the first commercial digital camera by Eikonix, the arena has matured over the years with participants entering from computing, electronics, and photography. The digital imaging arena has also seen considerable M&A and alliance activity , beginning with Kodak’s acquisition of Eikonix in 1984 to the recent series of technology consortia between computing and photography firms. We therefore view this arena as having great potential for describing and explaining convergence. Digital Imaging: A brief history and an overview of the technology The essence of digital imaging is that it involves devices that take pictures and develop them using electrons instead of film and then transmit, store, and process these images electronically, as if they were files of data. NASA developed digital imaging technology in the early 1970’s for its space program; this technology was closely tied to computer technology, and as costs of computer processing fell, the technology began diffusing into other areas. From the realm of consumer electronics, the development of video cameras had an impact on the way initial digital cameras were configured. Video technology had already shown that it was possible to dispense with film, though that industry remained rooted in analog technology till the late eighties. Prior to 1990, the usage of digital photography was largely restricted to a few scientific (medicine and satellite imaging) and commercial (publishing and real estate marketing) applications. The primary advantages of this technology were the ability to manipulate and edit pictures on computers and the ease and speed of development, storage, recall and transmission. With decreasing costs and increasing functionality in many of the component technologies of digital imaging, particularly semiconductors, computer hardware and software, it has since been making steady inroads into conventional film based imaging, as well as spawning new products and services. Historically, digital imaging is an arena which contains participants from multiple industries. One group came from traditional film based imaging (eg. Kodak), to whom digital imaging represents a competence destroying innovation. Another group came from the consumer electronics industry (eg. Panasonic), and typically attempted to leverage their experience with video cameras into digital imaging, particularly in the early stages of digital imaging. Yet another group of firms originated in the graphic arts and printing industry (eg. Scitex) which had pioneered the use of electronic scanning. Finally, there were entrants from the computer hardware, software and semiconductor industries (eg. Intel, Hewlett Packard) as digital cameras began to be accepted as computer peripherals.Digital imaging today draws on technological competencies from the semiconductor and electronics industries, computer hardware and software industries, and conventional film based imaging industries. An enumeration of the components of a standard digital camera illustrates this. The basic image capture technology is based on the CCD (Charge Capture Device) sensor, which serves the function of converting light energy into a digital data file. The CCD technology has remained virtually dominant till recently, when CMOS (Combined Metal oxide Semiconductor) based technology has begun to replace it; sensors using CMOS sensors are about ten times as energy efficient as CCD’s, and cost substantially less. The earliest versions of digital cameras did not have any storage device, thus severely constraining the portability of the instrument as it meant attachment via cables to a computer. Today, there are two major competing formats for the storage of digital photo files; removable PCMIA cards and micro drives. These are removable media, which effectively function like a roll of film. The file format in which the digital images are transferred to a computer, and then further undergo manipulation is another critical aspect of the digital camera industry. Today, there are competing alternatives available for the format in which digital imaging files can be stored, as well as for the software used to manipulate and use these data image files. Finally, there is a microprocessor chip, which controls the operation of the camera. Its key metric is speed, and size. (In addition, most present day digital cameras have an LCD display, and a lithium battery to meet the power requirements.) Related components of the architecture are printers, computers and other visual display devices. An empirical investigation of convergence in the digital imaging arena The convergence of the computing, electronics, and photography industries to create digital imaging is an instance of convergence steming from the supply side. A series of technological innovations in semiconductors, electronics, computer hardware and software have cumulatively provided a viable alternative to film based imaging, and one which has already surpassed it on several parameters. In doing so, the boundaries between these industries have become weakened. There is an interesting asymmetry between the perspectives of firms in electronics and computing, and those in photography, on convergence in digital imaging. For firms in the photography industries, digital imaging represents a technology substituting convergence prcess, and is potentially capable of being competence destroying, but for firms in the computing and electronics, digital imaging represents an oportunity to exploit technology complementarities between their competence in electronics and digital computing, and conventional photography. In this section, we attempt to provide a description of the process of convergence between the industries associated with digital imaging, and demonstrate how network methodologies may be useful for this purpose. In keeping with our earlier discussion, we rely on the observed corporate development activities of firms to understand the linkages between industries. 3 To identify the industries associated with digital imaging, we started out with a list of all companies, which have ever introduced a digital camera to the market 4. We assume that the SIC codes which describe the parent industries of the firms which introduced digital cameras was an accurate classification system prior to the emergence of digital imaging technology. We uncovered 76 firms, which have announced the product launch of a digital camera, the first documented launch being in 1984. There were 20 principal SIC codes and these broadly fell into four sub-groups of firms- computing (hardware, software, design and peripherals), consumer & other electronics (household audio and video equipment, electrical appliances, semiconductors), photography (optical instruments, equipment and supplies) and miscellaneous (news services, holding companies, dolls and stuffed toys etc.). We could not obtain the primary SIC codes for 9 firms, presumably because they were startups. This group of 20 SIC codes is henceforth referred to as the “digital group”. [Tables 1 & 2] Trends in inter-firms activity We obtained data on corporate development activity (i.e. alliances, including joint ventures, and acquisitions) by all firms in these 20 SIC industries from SDC Platinum. Figure 1 & 2 highlight some of the important trends in these activities. Numerically, alliancing activity within the “digital group” rose to a peak of about 30% of all alliances involving firms in the digital group in 1989 and again in 1995. Separating these within “digital group” inter-firm links into within SIC and across SIC transactions, it appears that The data for this exploratory study come from Security Data Corporation (SDC), which include among other things annual data on mergers and acquisitions and strategic alliances, and S&P’s COMPUSTAT. 4 This list was compiled from issues of the Future Image Report as well as Lexis-Nexis. whereas up to 1994 the within SIC dominated the across SIC transactions, since 1994, the difference between these types of links have been sharply reduced. This implies that since 1994, alliances with firms in other “host” industries than the “home” industry have been as important as alliances within the home industry by firms in the digital group, which is one indicator of convergence among these industries. The alliances within the digital group as a percentage of all alliances shows a cyclical pattern. Perhaps these trends represent alternating patterns of exploration and exploitation, as firms within the digital group alternately build relationships with firms outside and inside the group. (Figure 1) Acquisitions within the group display a relatively straightforward upward trend. While initially, the number of acquisitions outside the group was higher than acquisitions within the group, by the late eighties this trend was reversed. Till the early nineties, acquisitions within the group were almost equally divided into within-SIC and across-SIC transactions, but subsequently, within-SIC transactions have dominated other categories. (Figure 2) These trends are broadly consistent with a period of convergence and consolidation. The differences in the trends seen in alliances and acquisitions may be attributable to the fundamental differences between alliancing and acquisition activity- Kogut and Zander (1992) suggest that alliancing and joint venturing activity is more likely for exploratory development. Thus the farther the domain of knowledge from the current one, the more likely that alliances are used instead of acquisitions in expansion efforts. Acquisitions are more drastic, irreversible investments. Alliances, in contrast are more prone to occur across SIC industries, entailing diversification that is inherently more risky and unknown, and therefore more suitable in view of their flexibility. Alliances amount certainly to less of a commitment of corporate resources, and resemble therefore the notion of ”real options.” (Kogut and Kulatilaka 1994). Inter-industry networking While examining the transactions of the “digital group” as a whole offers some preliminary, interesting insights, we will demonstrate how network methodologies can be used to deepen our understanding of the convergence process, and provide metrics for the same. Examining only aggregate transactions does not allow us to distinguish, for instance, between convergence among the SIC codes which make up a sub-group, or across SIC codes which are unrelated to photography, and hence imaging. Using the data on number of M&A and alliances between SIC codes, valued adjacency matrices were constructed for each year between 1984 and 1998. Figures 11 & 12 offer a pictorial representation of M&A and alliances over time, allowing one to visualize the increasing density and changes in patterns of inter-industry linkages. For ease in analysis, we break down the “digital group” into the four subgroups mentioned earlier (Pg 17) –computing, electronics, photography and miscellaneous. Apart from providing a visual representation of linkages between industries, network methodologies provide several algorithms for measuring connectivity. In particular, we used four network parameters to describe the relationship between industries in the digital group over time. We use these parameters to describe two phenomena – the overall convergence within this group of industries, as well as the specific pattern of interlinkages between the major sub-groups (i.e. computing, electronics and photography). While using network parameters, one must keep in mind the important caveat that unlike in social network analysis, industries are non-sentient actors and the linkages studied here are not of the nature of long chains of communication flows- we merely borrow some existing algorithms to analyze the patterns of linkages between nodes in a graph. The four parameters for uncovering the digital convergence process are as follows: Clique membership: a clique is a sub-graph, which is fully interconnected. Thus a set of industries which are reciprocally tied to each other through alliance or acquisitions links represents a clique. For each year, we first detect all cliques with membership greater than 3. Then, we calculate the percentage of these cliques, which are composed of members from different sub-groups. Finally, we calculate the percentage of across sub-group cliques, which included firms from the photography sub-group. This measure of across sub-group clique formation, studied over time, gives an estimate of the extent and rate of convergence. Component membership: Two vertices x and y are in the same strong component if there is a path connecting x to y and a path connecting y to x. Thus membership in a component implies reciprocal paths between all the members. By calculating the percentage of industries in the “digital group” which belong to the same component, and observing this measure over time, we are able to provide an estimate of how much (and how fast) convergence within this group of industries is taking place. Degree Centrality: The number of vertices adjacent to a given vertex in a symmetric graph is the degree of that vertex. For a given binary network with vertices v1.... vn and maximum centrality Cmax, the network centralization measure is (Cmax - C (vi)) divided by the maximum value possible, where C (vi) is the centrality of vertex vi. This measure is used to estimate the extent to which individual industries are connected to the digital group, as well as the overall interconnectivity of the network. Density: The density of a binary network is the total number of ties divided by the total number of possible ties. For a valued network it is the total of all values divided by the number of possible ties. We partition the adjacency matrix based on sub-group membership, and then study the trends in density within, and across sub-groups. This allows us to understand the specific patterns of inter-linkages within the “digital group” which cause convergence. It should be noted that we are implicitly using the notion of cohesion (ties) to measure the strength of linkages between industries. In social network analysis, two network methodologies (cohesion and structural equivalence) compete for legitimacy in displaying the patterns of contact among actors (Burt, 1992; Strang and Tuma, 1993). Structural equivalence shows the relative similarity of each pair of industries in being linked with the remaining members of the industry set. Cohesion reveals the actual direct (and indirect) “contacts between each and every industry. Intuitively, cohesion is the most compelling method for our problem, as one would be hard pressed to view industries as competing for partnering with other industries. Rather, it seems more appropriate to search for growing proximity between the various industries through the incidence of alliances or acquisitions among its constitutive firms. We should identify cohesive blocks of industries, rather than structurally equivalent blocks. In other words, changes in adjacency rather than competition underpin the notion of convergence. Figures 3-10 present the various network parameters that we calculated on the adjacency matrices. Figures 3 and 4 depict three measures of the network of digital group firms over time. The first is component membership. Nodes in a graph belong to the same component if there are reciprocal paths between them. The metric in Figures 3 and 4 captures the percentage of industries in the digital group, which belong to the same component, over time. Density captures the extent of interconnections in the network. Centrality indicates the average number of connections that a node in the network has. As can be seen there is a clear increasing trend in the acquisitions network for all three, indicating that the industries in the group are becoming more closely interconnected over time, and also that each individual industry is more tightly linked to the network as a whole. The alliance network shows some cyclicality and after peaking in 1995, all three measures show a decline. This is consistent with our findings from the analysis of alliances to within group and outside the group industries. We interpret these findings in line with our earlier remarks about exploration and exploitation. The next four graphs continue to show network trends signaling digital convergence, but we have singled out the traditional imaging industries, i.e., photography, as providing a distinct benchmark. Using M&A and alliances, we ask how well the photography industries are connected with the digital group as a whole. We also ask how likely these photography industries are included in cliques, thus shedding light on their relative marginality or centrality, against a backdrop of the digital group as a whole. Figures 5 & 6 are density measures, disaggregated by sub group. Thus, after partitioning the adjacency matrix by sub group, we calculated the density within and across groups. For both acquisitions and alliances, the computer sub-group showed the higher internal density across all years. Further, for both acquisitions and alliances, the density of ties between the computer and photography group are higher than the density of ties between the photography and electronics group. Thus, we conclude that the photography industry is converging towards the computing industry more than it is towards the consumer and other electronics industries. Finally, for acquisitions only, the convergence between computers and photography is stronger than that between computers and electronics, whereas the converse is true for alliances. This might be in part because the relationship between the computing and electronics industries is a vertical one, and the observed alliances might have been motivated by supply requirements. Figures 7 and 8 represent the average degree centrality of members in the photography sub group, compared to the centrality of the entire group, on average. As the adjacency matrices for acquisitions are not symmetric, we calculated separate in centrality (acquiring) and out centrality (acquired by) measures. Findings from these measures show that while the photography industries might be involved in the convergence of the industries in the digital group, they do not form most central industries. The computing industries occupy that positions, and are clearly the most important contributors to the convergence in this group. Figures 9 & 10 represent the percentage of cliques in the group, which are composed of members from different subgroups (cross cliques), and also the percentage of cross cliques, which have a member from the photography industry. Consistent with previous results, the alliances network is almost completely dominated by cross cliques, whereas the acquisitions network shows a gradual increase of cross cliques over time. For acquisitions, the proportion of these cross cliques which have an industry from the photography subgroup reaches its peak of bout 50% in 1989 and then levels off. For alliances, this proportion starts at very high levels, and after fluctuating between 1985 and 1990, grows steadily till 1993, and then levels off. One explanation for the high initial values might be that prior to the first release of a digital camera in 1984, there might already have been a gradual buildup in cross industry alliancing activity, which we could not observe because of data limitations. (Our data on alliances is left censored beyond 1984). Finally, our results are suggestive of the sub groups that figure more prominently in the convergence process. Cumulatively, the network measures make it possible to measure the extent, as well as the rates of convergence across industries. In particular, they help us to understand which sub-groups within the digital group are more tightly connected than others, and also the sub-groups which are most active in the convergence process. Discussion At the onset of this paper we suggested that the convergence phenomenon could be uncovered through inter-firm activities, including myriad forms of strategic alliances as well as mergers and acquisitions. Through these activities firms are able to escape their path dependence which derives from their quest to accumulate a coherent set of distinct competencies (Teece et al., 1994) such that they can extend their boundaries into unrelated areas (Kogut and Zander, 1992). We sought to complement the question of what is convergence, with the questions regarding the how (e.g., firm strategy) and the why (i.e., drivers) of convergence. The phenomenon requires us to consider the firm, its industry and a set of potentially complementary and overlapping industries. There is a profound tension between the firm, and its need to be coherent with its industry that might increasingly blend with other industries and therefore call the coherence imperative into question. We have stressed that convergence can be decomposed into different classes, most notably supply (technology and firms) versus demand (needs and customers). Furthermore, we imply these classes of convergence evoke different types of corporate strategic responses with the supply convergence inviting more enduring and irreversible commitments such as joint ventures, corporate ventures and internal developments (or if too delayed swifter efforts, but with a cost such as acquisitions). If the convergence is demand driven, strategic responses might be more flexible and reversible, for example collaborative marketing and distribution agreements. Three drivers were spelled out: (de) regulation, socio-economic developments and technological innovations that destroy current competencies or create new ones. To illustrate our arguments convergence was mapped in the digital imaging arena. Taking information on alliances and mergers and acquisitions (M&A), network methods were employed to uncover the growing overlap in a number of relevant imaging industries during the period 1984-1999. We showed how strategic alliances, and acquisitions contribute to the blurring of pre-existing boundaries and the rise of new blocks of industries, and also how their incidence can be used to measure the extent and rate of the convergence process. Firm versus Industry The convergence process on the supply side, uncovered in this empirical study, does not inform us about heterogenity of responses by firms in an industry. We have assumed that technological innovations constitute the drivers of the “digital convergence”(Yoffie, 1997), but we have remained agnostic about the motivation of firms to participate in this process Neither have we shed any light on the relative prominence of firms in triggering or shaping convergence as a technological trajectory. For example, how do firms acquire absorptive capacity in surviving the onslaught that is associated with technological convergence? Will internal ventures endow them with the capacity to adapt on the emerging landscape that we call digital imaging. Is convergence endogenous to the set of industries that undergo convergence? If so, should we attribute crucial disequilibrating effects to the conduct of some firms? Indeed, what role do we attribute to firms in choreographing the convergence process, or alternatively, which firms are central in mediating the observed convergence? From our empirical analysis it should not be surprising that firms with social capital should be viewed as pivotal in triggering or shaping convergence. Extending firm boundaries by linking up with other firms and their competencies as opposed to building new competencies internally, and by branching out to firms with distant technologies requires a substantial stock of “relational competencies” (Kale 1997, Khanna 1998). A track record of forging strategic alliances or succesful acquisitions is testimony to such competencies. We would therefore surmise that the cumulative level of alliance activity or acquisition activity predicts a firm’s prominence in the convergence process. While we constructed networks of industries based on their firms’ inter-firm activities and observe changing patterns of density, we should also recognize compelmentary data and methods for mapping the process. Alternative methods for tracking convergence include the creation of networks, based on patent citation patterns within and across disciplines. The convergence thus construed is more basic and need not culminate in market overlap or shifting boundaries (e.g. Almeida, 1997). Unlike patent citations, interfirm alliances and acquisitions entail commitment of (intangible and tangible) assets and reveal a rearrangement of the corporate landscape. Thus, convergence derived from corporate development actions might be a lagging convergence indicator. Patent citations reveal growing overlap in technological fields, might be a leading convergence indicator. In any event, attempot to use patent citations might render our exploration more robust, and should, at a minimum, further help us in traingulating the measurement of convergence. Similarly, we should obtain insights about a firm’s technological know–how in shaping digital convergence. Digital imaging is a unique area as it embodies the combinative skills of hardware, software and photography capabilities. We would surmise here that absorptive capacity matters; the firms which have been able to reach out to digital imaging relevant partners, or who have been active in expanding their home grown bundles of expertise should be better positioned in shaping the technological trajectory that embeds their expertise. A possible way for evaluating a firm’s stock of relevant technological skills is an inventory of its patents in digitally oriented products or technologies. We did not track the firms’ range of intellectual proprieties in this study but it seems plausible that these bundles should define a firm’s readiness to participate in the center rather than in the periphery of the convergence process. Finally, we believe there is value to studying the tension imposed by convergence on the coherence of firms. Firms are motivated to, and often advised to stay “close to the knitting” and to forego unrelated diversification. We believe that a major impetus to future research and theory is the abandonment of a simplistic inquiry into the relatedness problem of strategic diversification and instead a proposal to identify a balance between firm specialization and despecialization. The concern with competency traps, real options, and organizational learning are testimony to the need to search for an optimal tradeoff among various firms strategies. References Almeida, Paul (1996) Knowledge sourcing by foreign multinationals: Patent citation analysis in the U.S. semiconductor industry. Strategic Management Journal. 17: 155-165. 1996 Winter Barkema, Harry G. Bell, John H J. Pennings, Johannes M (1996) Foreign entry, cultural barriers, and learning. Strategic Management Journal. 17(2): 151-166. 1996 Burt, Ronald S (1997) The contingent value of social capital. Administrative Science Quarterly. 42(2): 339-365. 1997 Jun. Chesbrough HW and Teece DJ (1996) When is virtual virtuous? Organizing for Innovation. , Harvard Business Review, Jan-Feb Cyert R.& March JG (1963) A Behavioral Theory of the Firm, Publisher :Prentice Hall, Khanna, Tarun (1998) The scope of alliances Organization Science. 9(3): 340-355. 1998 May/Jun. Kogut, B., and U. Zander,(1992) "Knowledge of the Firm, Combinative Capabilities and the Replication of Technology," Organization Science, 3, 1992, pp. 383-397 Kogut, Bruce. Kulatilaka, Nalin (1994) Options thinking and platform investments: Investing in opportunity. California Management Review. 36(2): 52-71. 1994 Winter Levitt T (1983) The globalization of markets, Harvard Business Review, May-June 1983 March J.G., Sproull L.S. & Tamuz M, (1991). Learning from samples of one or fewer. Organization Science, 2(1): 1-13. Monteverde K (1995) Technical dialog as an incentive for vertical integration in the semiconductor industry , Management Science/Vol 41, No 10, Oct0ber 1995 Nagarajan A and Mitchell W (1998) Evolutionary Diffusion: Internal and External Methods used to acquire encompassing, complementary and incremental technological changes in the lithotripsy industry., Stratgeic Management Journal 19: 1063-1077. Nelson, R. & Winter, S. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Pennings J and Kim HO (2000) Technology evolution at the producer consumer interface, Working Paper, The Wharton School. Penrose, Edith. (1959) The Theory of the Growth of the Firm Pindyck RS & Rubenfeld DL (1998) Microeconomics, Prentice Hall, New Jersey Pisano G. (1996) In search of dynamic capabilities :The origins of R&D competence in Biopharmaceuticals. ,Working Paper 1996. Puranam P.(1999) Grafting innovation: a case study of technology procurement through acquisition, Working Paper, The Wharton School. Schmookler J (1966) Invention and economic growth, Cambridge, Mass. Harvard University Press. Teece D.J.,Rumelt R,Dosi G, Winter SG, (1994) Understanding corporate coherence: theory and evidence, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization1994 Teece, David J (1996) Firm organization, industrial structure, and technological innovation.(1996) Journal of Economic Behavior &Organization. 31(2): 193-224. 1996 Nov. Teece D.J., Pisano G. & Shuen A. (1997). Dynamic capabilities of and strategic management, Strategic Management Journal, 18(7): 509-533. Yoffie D (1997) Competing in the age of digital convergence , HBS Press, Mass. Harvard University Firm Strategies and Market Convergence Demand Side Supply Side Substitution Complementarity Different technological capabilities become similar in the sense that they can satisfy the same set of needs. Different technologies are brought together to create new kinds of technology Speed: Depends on tech.opportunity and appropriability Speed: Depends on tech.opportunity and appropriability Eg.Computing, communication, and imaging, biotechnology & pharmacology Eg.Optoelectronics, bioinstrumentation The needs of different consumer sets becomes similar. Different (but related) needs are met by bundling products together. Speed:Gradual Speed:Rapid if led by de-regulation Globalization of markets,homogenization Eg. Commercial, consumer and of demographic segments. investment banking, hardware & software Diagram 2 Table 1 List of primary SIC codes of all firms which have launched a digital camera SIC 2835 3555 3571 3572 3577 3579 3651 3674 3827 3841 3861 3942 5043 5045 5064 5065 6719 7372 7373 7383 Group MISC MISC COMP COMP COMP ELEC ELEC ELEC PHOTO MISC PHOTO MISC PHOTO COMP ELEC ELEC MISC COMP COMP MISC Industry IN VITRO, IN VIVO DIAGNOSTICS PRINTING TRADES MACHY, EQUIP ELECTRONIC COMPUTERS COMPUTER STORAGE DEVICES COMPUTER PERIPHERAL EQ, NEC OFFICE MACHINES, NEC HOUSEHOLD AUDIO & VIDEO EQ SEMICONDUCTOR, RELATED DEVICE OPTICAL INSTRUMENTS & LENSES SURGICAL, MED INSTR, APPARATUS PHOTOGRAPHIC EQUIP & SUPPL DOLLS AND STUFFED TOYS PHOTOGRAPHIC EQUIPMENT AND SUPPLIES-WHLSL COMPUTERS, PERIPHERALS, AND SOFTWARE-WHLSL ELECTRICAL APPLIANCES TV AND RADIO-WHLSL ELECTRONIC PARTS & EQUIPMENT-WHLSL OFFICES OF HOLDING COMPANIES PREPACKAGED SOFTWARE COMPUTERS INTEGRATED SYSTEM DESIGN NEWS SYNDICATES Table 2 Entry of firms into digital camera market Number of entries as of Jan 1, 1999 Of which startups (founded after Jan 1, 1985) From home industries COMP PHOTO ELEC MISC Unknown Computers, Software and peripherals Photographic equipment & supplies Consumer & other electronics Miscellaneous 76 26 28 17 12 10 9 Code 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Figure 1 Trends in M&A activities by firms in the "Digital Group" 600 Series1 500 Ttransactions Series2 400 Series3 300 200 100 0 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 Y ear 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 Series 1 Number of acquisitions outside the “digital group” by firms in the “digital group” Series 2 Number of acquisitions within the digital group (but not within the same SIC code) by firms in the “digital group. Series 3 Number of acquisitions within the same SIC code by firms in the “digital group. Figure 2 Trends in Alliance/JV activities by firms in the "Digital Group" 0.25 Series1 0.2 Series2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 1984 Series 1 Series 2 1986 1988 1990 Year 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 Number of alliances within the digital group (but not within the same SIC code) normalized by total number of alliances made by firms in the “digital group”. Number of alliances within the same SIC code by firms in the digital group normalized by total number of alliances made by firms in the “digital group”. Figure 3 %age M&A activity:Network parameters 80 60 40 20 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000CompMemb Density Centrality Years Figure 4 %age 200 JV/Alliance activity :Network parameters 150 100 CompMemb Density Centrality 50 0 1980 CompMemb Density Centrality 1985 1990 1995 Year 2000 Percentage of industries (in the digital group), which are members of a single strong component The average density of the network. (Scaled) The degree centrality of the network. Figure 5 Density within and across subgroups misc Acquisitions 2.5 comp elec 2 1.5 1 0.5 photo comp-photo elec-photo comp-elec Density 0 1980 -0.5 1985 1990 1995 2000 Figure 6 Density within and across sub-groups Alliances 5 comp 4 elec photo 3 comp-photo 2 elec-photo comp-elec 1 Density 0 1980 Key Misc Comp Electronics Photo Comp-photo Elec-Photo Comp-Elec Density 1985 1990 1995 Miscellaneous sub group Computing sub group Electronics sub- group Photography sub group A sub group composed of computing and photography A sub groiup composed of electronics and photogrpahy A sub group compsed of computing and electronics Density of the entire digital group 2000 Figure 7 Degree Centrality of Photo Subgroup Acquisitions 12 10 Out 8 In 6 Mean 4 2 0 1980 -2 1985 1990 1995 2000 Figure 8 Degree centrality of Photo Subgroup Alliances 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1980 PhotoCentrality Centrality (mean) 1985 1990 1995 2000 Key Out In Mean PhotoCentrality Out-centrality of the photography sub group In centrality of the photography sub group Mean centrality of the entire digital group Centrality of the photography sub-group Note: because the acquisitions adjacency matrix is not symmetric, both in and out centrality are calculated for them. The adjacency matrices for alliances are symmetric. Figure 9 %crosscliques 120.00 Cliques within Digital Group Acquisitions 100.00%photocrosscliqu es 80.00 60.00 40.00 20.00 0.00 1980 -20.00 1985 1990 1995 2000 Figure 10 %crosscliquesCliques within digital group 120%photocrosscliq Alliances 100ues 80 60 40 20 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Key %crosscliqes The percentage of the total number of cliques which involved members from different sub-groups. %photocrosscliques The percentage of %crosscliques which involved a memebr from the photography sub-group.