Lucie Cerna The EU Blue Card: A Bridge Too Far? Lucie Cerna University of Oxford Department of Politics & IR Oxford, OX1 3UQ United Kingdom lucie.cerna@politics.ox.ac.uk Paper prepared for the Fifth Pan-European Conference on EU Politics Porto, Portugal (23-26 June 2010) Please do not cite or quote without the permission of the author. Comments are welcome. Abstract: In May 2009, the European Union approved a Blue Card on the conditions of entry for high-skilled third-country nationals. The directive sought to make the EU internationally more competitive. But member states were reluctant to cede responsibility for labour market access regulation - immigration remains a sensitive area. They have differing demographics and labour markets; thus varying preferences for high-skilled immigration (HSI). Therefore, their HSI policies are distinct, which the constructed HSI index demonstrates. The paper argues that these differences and the national self-interest of member states continue to dominate immigration. The final version of the Blue Card does not make much of a difference since it is mainly a marketing tool. Key words: Blue Card, European Union, EU governance, high-skilled immigration, index, policy change 1 Lucie Cerna I. Introduction While many countries have faced similar challenges associated with high-skilled immigration (HSI thereafter), the policy responses of states have been different. With the increasing competition for the ‘best and brightest’1, policy developments have taken place at the national, regional and global levels. For instance, a number of national governments have implemented ‘high-skilled-immigrant-friendly’ policies in order to compete internationally for high-skilled migrants. At the global level, some movements are visible, with GATS Mode-4 as the prominent one. The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) covers four major groups of services. Mode 4 focuses on the temporary movement of natural persons - services are provided by individuals abroad (e.g. intra-company transfers, business visitors, contract service suppliers and independent professionals) (Martin 2003). However, it would be wrong to characterise high-skilled migration governance as multilateral on this basis. Rather, Mode 4 is limited in scope, implying little constraint on state sovereignty and is largely a reflection of declarations of unilateral liberalisation that might have happened anyway (Betts & Cerna forthcoming). Several regional agreements on labour migration are in place, such as the European Union (EU), North Atlantic Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), Mercado Común del Sur (MERCOSUR) and Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC).2 The EU, however, has the most developed regional scheme concerning the free movement of workers inside the EU (some exceptions apply). Attempts have also been made to appeal to third-country nationals (TCNs) through the EU Blue Card in order to compete mainly with Australia, Canada and the United States (US) in a ‘global war for talent’. The Directive on the admission of high-skilled immigrants seeks to 2 Lucie Cerna establish more attractive entry and residence conditions for third-country nationals to work in EU member states. The paper contributes to a wider debate on EU integration and labour immigration policy, and serves as an empirical contribution through the Blue Card case study. The Blue Card presents a puzzle: while EU member states face similar challenges through labour shortages and ageing populations, their support for a harmonised HSI policy varies. The original proposal sought to manage labour market issues and make the EU more competitive vis-à-vis its international competitors, such as the US and Canada. However, member states have been reluctant to cede responsibility to regulate labour market access to the EU. The Blue Card Directive is a good choice for this analysis because HSI is considered the least controversial among the four migration areas, which were presented in the 2005 Green paper. Nevertheless, there are variations in national HSI policies, demonstrated by the constructed HSI index. These differences have been transferred to the EU level and have made an agreement difficult. The paper argues that these differences and the national self-interest of member states continue to dominate immigration policy in Europe. The final version of the Blue Card does not make much of a difference - it represents a triumph of marketing over substantive policy-making. Its failure, however, highlights underlying weaknesses in European institutions and the limits of further integration. The paper proceeds in the following way: Part II analyses the development of labour immigration policy at the EU level. Part III provides an overview of the theoretical framework of preference formation and bottom-up Europeanisation, whereas Part IV discusses the main points of the EU Blue Card, as well as different 3 Lucie Cerna policies of member states, displayed through the HSI index. Finally, Part V offers some conclusions and suggestions for further research. II. Developments at the EU Level Even though HSI might be considered the least contested immigration area, negotiations on the Blue Card have been lengthy and difficult. According to Lahav, “in the areas of political asylum, cultural policy, VAT, education, agriculture/fishing, unemployment, immigration, workers rights, etc Europeans are either divided or unwilling to cede policy-making authority to the EU” (Lahav 2004: 1174). The Blue Card Directive is not the first try of harmonisation of immigration at the EU level. Earlier attempts date from the 1980s, when the Single European Act introduced a policy toward TCNs, and later the 1990 Dublin and Schengen agreements. This was followed by the Maastricht and the Treaty on European Union. However, immigration policy was limited to asylum and transit visas, all placed in the third pillar of Justice and Home Affairs. While the Treaty of Amsterdam expanded the area of immigration in the first pillar (e.g. external border controls, visas, other rights of TCNs, immigration and asylum), member states ensured that decisions had to be taken unanimously in the European Council, even after the five transitory years. This procedure for immigration has remained until the Treaty of Lisbon. The Tampere Summit of 1999 introduced a five-year mandate to harmonise immigration policies and recognised labour market needs in different sectors, as well as demographic needs (Schain 2009). The Lisbon European Council in March 2000 launched the Lisbon strategy – the EU’s goal was to become the most competitive and dynamic knowledge-based economy in the world, and attracting high-skilled 4 Lucie Cerna immigrants was included in this strategy. At this Council, the European Commission (EC) also proposed the implementation of an open method of co-ordination (OMC) to “encourage countries to advance their levels of national policy experimentation and co-ordination through a non-binding yet common governance mechanism” (Caviedes 2004: 289). The flexible policy was aimed at particular areas, including high-skilled immigrants, who are considered positive for economic growth and a lesser burden on the welfare state. Nonetheless, the Council did not adopt the proposal.3 In a similar vein, the Commission proposed a Directive in 2001 on ‘the conditions of entry and residence of third-country nationals for the purpose of paid employment and self-employed economic activities’. While the text focused on different types of labour immigration, it already mentioned that the Community should attract third-county workers due to a shortage of skilled labour in certain sectors (Zaletel 2006). Even though the other European institutions gave positive opinions, the Council only discussed a first reading of the text, and it was officially withdrawn in 2006 (EC 2007d: 3).4 Building on Tampere and Lisbon, the Hague Programme of 4-5 November 2004 recognised that EU businesses were increasingly dealing with labour shortages, thus legal immigration would help to boost the European knowledge-based economy (EC 2007d). In December 2005, the Commission presented a Green Card according to the Communication, Policy Plan on Legal Migration (COM(2005)669) on the adoption of several legislative proposals for the period from 2007 to 2009. This selective approach was endorsed by the European Council in December 2006, inviting the Commission to present these proposals as part of the comprehensive EU Migration Policy (EC 2007b). The proposals concerned four types of immigration: 5 Lucie Cerna high-skilled immigrants, intra-company transfers, seasonal workers and trainees. This was the first time that a proposal was disaggregated by type of labour immigration. The EU decided to start with high-skilled migrants because consultations by the Commission indicated more support for high-skilled than for low-skilled immigrants (Guild 2007, Luedtke 2009). The small number of high-skilled immigrants is less likely to be linked with a negative feeling of changed cultural identity in the native population than is the case with general immigration (Money & Falstrom 2006). High-skilled immigrants have higher earnings and tax payments, less reliance on social benefits and fluency in the receiving country’s language, which eases their integration into the receiving society. They are distinct from low-skilled immigrants, whose integration is often perceived by the native population to pose greater problems. In addition, high-skilled workers and professionals create much less of a challenge than manual workers because “immigrant scientists, engineers and physicians reinforce the nation’s supply of scarce talent and mix easily with the domestic population by becoming dispersed throughout the country” (Portes & Rumbaut 1996: 293). These immigrants tend to be more dispersed in the receiving country, and thus are likely to create limited geographic concentration and backlash by native population. III. Bottom-Up Immigration Policy While there are incentives for HSI due to common challenges among member states, progress at the EU level has been limited.5 The literature often presents immigration policy as an example of either neo-functionalist or intergovernmental nature.6 On the one hand, EU institutions such as the Commission and the Parliament have been 6 Lucie Cerna pushing for a harmonised migration policy. When referring to the Commission, the DG Justice, Freedom and Security (JLS) is the key actor in driving labour immigration policy, but the DG Employment, Social Affairs and Equal Opportunities is also involved to some extent. The neo-functionalists consider economic cooperation inevitably spilling over into other areas, such as migration policy (Haas 1958, Stone Sweet & Sandholtz 1998). On the other hand, intergovernmental theories consider supranational institutions as means of locking in preferred domestic political arrangements (Moravcsik 1998) and see member states as the primary political actors (Givens & Luedtke 2004 & 2005, Guiraudon 2000). Member states are represented in the Council of the European Union and have been able to veto policy proposals on labour immigration due to the unanimity rule. Therefore, while there has been some progress over the years, migration policy at the EU level has not reached the same degree of harmonisation as other policies.7 Rather than plotting the two theories against each other, the paper proceeds by focusing on bottom-up processes, where member states policies concerning labour immigration of TCNs are transferred upwards to the EU level. In EU integration studies, bottom-up Europeanisation in policy-making has been rather neglected so far (Menz 2009). This is in contrast to top-down Europeanisation, where EU-driven liberalisation leads top-down from the EU to national level in internal labour migration (e.g. free movement of workers inside EU) (Menz 2002: 724). In bottom-up processes, governmental actors have to engage in two-level games (Putnam 1988), where they negotiate policies at the national level and then take their agendas to the EU level. This results in a second level game and bargaining over EU policy. There governments seek to shape policy-making through either proactive suggestions or blockage/delay (Menz 2009). But bottom-up Europeanisation 7 Lucie Cerna in immigration policy is “an extremely arduous game to play, as other governments need to be successfully persuaded, given the de jure unanimity requirement for decision-making in the Council” (Menz 2009: 7). The following sections will identify actors and their preferences in this ‘game’. National Actors The focus of this paper is to analyse differences in member states’ policies, resulting from different actors and their preferences at the national level. It uses the Blue Card as a case study. According to Georg Menz, national responses are influenced by “national interest groups, the political orientation of the government, the process of public debate, media attention and far-right parties” (Menz 2002: 740). Therefore, the emergence of national preferences needs to be examined.8 Some authors propose that temporary labour immigration policy is mainly determined by economic interest groups (Caviedes 2006, Meyers 1995 & 2004, Freeman 2006, Menz 2009). Key actors at the national level hence include labour market associations, such as unions, professional associations and employers’ associations. Their relative strength and potential for building coalitions influences their lobbying capacity with the government. For instance, Eytan Meyers analyses a number of factors that pertain to different labour immigration policies. Gary Freeman seeks to specify particular policy dynamics that can emerge in area of labour migration. For example, temporary labour immigration policies fall under nonimmigrant work visas, governed by interest group policies. HSI has been “successfully sold as a cost-free policy that produces substantial, if diffuse, benefits for the society in a global economy privileging technology and creativity” (Freeman 8 Lucie Cerna 2006: 238). The recruitment of high-skilled workers is beneficial for the receiving country, while costs, if any, are diffuse. Both Meyers and Freeman argue that labour immigration policies (in particular HSI) are converging, although for different reasons. Meyers claims that immigration policies converge mainly due interdependence, economic and ideological cycles, and common migratory pressures. According to Freeman, HSI policies are converging because “several European countries amended their laws to permit easier entry of skilled foreign workers…and the settler societies have shown growing interest in tapping pools of temporary skilled labour in recent years” (Freeman 2006: 237-238). However, in contrast to the presented convergence arguments, this paper argues for continuing divergence among countries’ HSI policies. While governments might display similar policy goals for liberalised policies, their adopted policies and conditions do not always match these goals in reality. Countries’ policies still differ in their depth and pace of openness. Therefore, another argument of preference formation is presented. Three actors are considered important. Native high-skilled labour will have restrictive preferences as high-skilled immigrants constitute labour market competition for them. Native low-skilled labour can support more open HSI as these workers can benefit from increase job opportunities. Capital will be highly in favour of more open HSI in order to fill labour shortages. These actors compete for political influence by building coalitions. Coalition-building between actors with varying HSI preferences, mediated by labour market organisation and political representation, determines cross-national variations in HSI policy outputs (Cerna 2009). 9 Lucie Cerna For instance, institutions such as (high-skilled) unions or professionals associations are interested in the representation of native high-skilled workers and gain influence in the policy-making process in some countries (e.g. Scandinavia), while political parties consider the representation of high-skilled workers important in others (e.g. Germany). Capital, e.g. employers’ associations and businesses, plays a more influential role in some countries (e.g. United States - US), but are more restricted in their power in others (often through tripartite policy-making).9 And lowskilled workers are represented to different degrees as well. These three actors can form different coalitions in order to achieve their desired policy outputs, which then varies across countries. But labour market organisation is not the only way of aggregating preferences of the actors. They can also gain political representation through political parties, districts/states, as well as links between unions or employers’ associations and the government. Since coalitions vary across countries, some are more open towards high-skilled immigrants than others. These differences have been shifted upward to the EU level. Even if member states have agreed on the Blue Card directive, the final outcome is based on a lowest common denominator.10 It has been watered down from the original proposal, and immigration control (in this case of HSI) remains with the sovereign member states. Instead of explaining immigration policy-making at the national level, this paper focuses on analysing the lack of agreement at the EU level. IV. The EU Blue Card Directive Labour migration into Europe boosts our competitiveness and therefore our economic growth. It also helps tackle demographic problems resulting from our ageing population. This is particularly the case for highly skilled labour. With today’s proposal for an EU Blue Card we send a clear signal: highly skilled migrants are welcome in the EU! (EC 2007a) 10 Lucie Cerna The quotation illustrates the Commission President José Manuel Barroso’s rationale behind the Blue Card. It seeks to create a single application procedure for non-EU workers to reside and work within the EU, and to establish a common set of rights for workers in member states. The Council of the EU adopted the Directive on 25 May 2009 (Council of European Union 2009). The Blue Card allows high-skilled TCNs to work in an EU country for a maximum of four years. After 18 months, the migrant can move to another EU country. Applicants need to show a recognised diploma and have at least three years of professional experience in order to be eligible. High-killed migrants can bring their families and the application procedure is expected to take less than three months. The directive, however, does not create the right of admission. The scheme is entirely demand-driven, respecting the principle of Community preference and member states’ jurisdiction to decide on the numbers of persons admitted. In particular, member states should take into consideration the Acts of Accession terms and continue to give preferences to workers of the EU-811 and EU-212 over TCNs (EC 2007c). But who are the high-skilled migrants in the first place? There is no universal definition for HSI (Lowell 2008). The three main definitions consider education, occupation and salary level, but overlap to some extent (Chaloff & Lemaitre 2009). Education definitions consider mainly tertiary education, as defined in the International Standard Classification of Education (ISCED). High-skilled occupations rely on statistics based on the International Standard Classification of Occupations (ISCO), and consider managers, professionals and associates, for instance. Salary level definitions represent considerable flexibility. 11 Lucie Cerna An earlier attempt has been the 1995 OECD Canberra Manual, which defines the Measurement of Human Resources in Science and Technology (HRST). But it is limited to occupations in science and technology sectors, whereas high-skilled immigrants can work in a variety of sectors ranging from information technology (IT), engineering, finance and biotechnology to health care and education, to name a few. After many discussions about the definition of high-skilled TCNs, member states agreed to focus on salary level. Main Points and Objectives According to Elspeth Guild, there are three main arguments for the Blue Card: 1) businesses need economic migrants to fulfil their recruitment needs (business argument); 2) the EU is no longer producing sufficient numbers of workers to meet its business needs (demographic argument); and 3) the evidence of the failure of the current high-skilled regime since the high-skilled go to Canada and the US, rather than to the EU (competition argument) (Guild 2007: 3). The Directive’s aim is to provide member states and EU companies with additional means to recruit, retain and better allocate (and re-allocate) workers. The Commission seeks to raise the competitiveness of the EU economy through the contribution by legal immigrants (EC 2007c). The EU, with 1.7 percent third-country high-skilled workers of the total of the employed population, is behind the other main immigration countries, such as Australia (9.9 percent), Canada (7.3 percent), US (3.2 percent) and Switzerland (5.3 percent). It has been difficult for the EU to attract highskilled migrant workers13 (EC 2007c). 12 Lucie Cerna The EU Blue Card provides for a “one-stop-shop” system for TCNs who would like to live in a member state for work purposes. It simplifies, shortens and accelerates the process for employers and immigrants (EC 2007b). The Directive is also meant to give legal TCNs basic socio-economic rights on equal basis to EU’s nationals.14 But, in this paper, only the admission part of the Blue Card will be taken into consideration since it has created the most controversy among member states. Europe needs to speak with one voice if it seeks to attract ‘the best and brightest’. Immigrants will be aware of the conditions to be admitted in any member state. ‘Less attractive’ member states could benefit from EU’s higher visibility and the attention given to the new scheme. The ‘advertising’ value of the EU Blue Card should make it more successful (EC 2007c). A European solution could “offer greater visibility, predictability and transparency than 27 different national systems” (Weizsäcker 2006: 3). In 2007, only about ten member states had special programmes for highskilled TCNs that surpassed categories of scientists, artists, intra-corporate transferees and university professors. Mobility in the EU was hindered through differences in definitions and admission conditions for high-skilled workers (EC 2007d). The new scheme is unlikely to solve the present and future challenges, but should constitute an important contribution (EC 2007d: 2). Common Challenges in Member States Whereas individual member states focus on their needs, the EU institutions (e.g. Commission) consider the global picture - or at least the EU situation on the whole. For example, member states face common problems in various areas, such as falling 13 Lucie Cerna birth rates and an ageing population. Eurostat projections indicate that in the EU, “population growth until 2025 will be mainly due to net migration, since total deaths will outnumber total births from 2010. The effect of net migration will no longer outweigh the natural decrease after 2025” (EC 2005: 4). This will have serious repercussions on the number of employed people in the EU, as “the share of population of working age […] in the total population is expected to decrease strongly, from 67.2 percent in 2004 to 56.7 percent in 2050, a fall of 52 million […]”. The decline in the total population is expected by 2025 and in the working age population by 2011 (EC 2005: 4). Some member states (e.g. Germany, Hungary, Italy and Latvia) have already experienced a decline in the working age population, while it would happen later in others (i.e. Ireland from 2035). These demographic trends, however, will not affect all member states to the same degree. Labour immigration could mean a short to mid-term solution to this trend (EC 2005). Another major challenge is labour shortages, traditionally linked to low-skilled jobs, but unfilled jobs in high-skilled sectors, such as IT, engineering and health care, increasingly pose a challenge. The former European Commission President, Romano Prodi, argued in 2001 that the EU “urgently needs to ease restrictions on labour mobility, particularly in the technology sector, which faces a shortage of up to 1.7 million qualified workers by 2003” (The Economist, 31 March 2001). At the 2007 Blue Card press conference, the European Commission President Manuel Barroso stated that the EU would have future shortages of labour and skills, already the reality in some sectors. He claimed that European economies depended on a skilled and mobile labour force and needed “a European approach to legal immigration if we want to be serious in becoming the most competitive, knowledge-based society in the world” (Barroso, Press Conference, 23 October 2007). According to Commission 14 Lucie Cerna estimates, labour shortages will peak by 2050 when 25 million Europeans are expected to retire from work and one-third of the population will be over 65 years of age (EC 2007d). Labour shortages have prompted the EU to look for high-skilled migrants beyond its borders. But the degree and the composition of labour shortages vary among member states. It is also a challenge to obtain comparative data on labour vacancies, by itself difficult to establish (Mayer 2008). Public Opinion Even if the EU institutions presented a case for delegating immigration policy to the EU level, the need for this action was less clear among citizens of member states. According to Gallya Lahav, “the European public understands the benefits and necessity of dealing with immigration supranationally, but is unwilling to accept the consequences of such an action – the loss of national sovereignty” (Lahav 2004: 1177-1178). Recent surveys demonstrate that European public opinion is most divided about asylum and migration policy among all the Justice, Freedom and Security areas covered in the survey. In Figure 1, a clear majority (63 percent) favour more decision-making at the EU level in this field, while 24 percent believe that there should be less decision-making at the same level. Around one European out of fifteen is content with the present situation or lacks an opinion (6 and 7 percent, respectively). The total EU results have not changed significantly since the question was previously asked in spring 2006 (Eurobarometer 2008: 18) In all member states except Finland, the UK and Ireland, a relative majority of respondents prefers more decision-making at the EU level, whereas in Sweden (43 vs. 38 percent) and Austria (47 vs. 37 percent) public opinion is quite divided. In 15 Lucie Cerna contrast, in 2006, a relative majority of Swedes (43 vs. 40 percent) favoured less decision-making at supranational level, whereas the British clearly favoured more decision-making at the EU level (Eurobarometer 2008: 20). Figure 1: More European level decision-making of asylum and migration policy? Source: Eurobarometer 2008: 20. However, this survey does not distinguish between types of migration. There might be a need and rationale for harmonised policies at the EU level on asylum due to burden-sharing. Border protection might also necessitate cooperation at the EU level. But for labour migration, the need for harmonisation is less clear. It can be the case that member states who require assistance dealing with irregular migrants welcome the opportunity of delegating these policies to the EU level. 16 Lucie Cerna Measuring differences in national HSI policies As the previous section has demonstrated, the preferences for EU immigration policymaking vary among citizens of member states. So does the extent of demographic and labour market needs across member states. States are heterogeneous in terms of labour markets, immigrant inflows, sectoral shortages, data collection and political frameworks (Salt & Almeida 2006). Based on the EU study on the ‘Estimates on annual inflows of work permit holders in 16 EU countries’, the Blue Card could cover at least 74,300 work permit holders for EU-25 (EC 2005: 27). Nonetheless, the number of professional immigrant workers has varied considerably within the EU, ranging from 160 in Lithuania to 15,800 in the UK (2002-2003) (EC 2005: 27). The labour market size and population size of member states fluctuate as well. EU member states have different national interests in the Blue Card, which leads to difficulty of delegating responsibility to the EU level. This variation is demonstrated through national HSI policies. While it is evident that member states’ preferences and thus HSI policies vary, little comparative work has been done to systematically categorise and measure these differences. As a result, it is necessary to examine countries’ HSI in more detail and to disaggregate policies on the terms and conditions attached. This section provides an empirical contribution by constructing a HSI index. The goal of the High-Skilled Immigration Index (HSII) is to analyse the openness of national HSI policies and to rank countries. The degree of HSI competitiveness between countries depends on how liberalised HSI policy and how restrictive admission controls are. The HSII includes twenty countries for 2007. The index has two dimensions: categories for HSI policy and countries. It contains the traditional settlement countries 17 Lucie Cerna (Australia, Canada, New Zealand and the US), West European countries, often with guest-worker or colonial history (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland and the UK), new immigration countries (Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain) and one Asian country (Japan). These advanced industrial countries are chosen to represent different migration histories and experiences, as well as different levels of involvement of interest groups in policy-making. The index includes fourteen EU member states and six other countries (Australia, Canada, Japan, New Zealand, Switzerland and the US), for reasons of comparison in the ‘global war for talent’. Other research on categorising policies exists, such as the Parliament of the Commonwealth of Australia’s Joint Standing Committee on Migration (2004), Christian (2000), Geddes et al. (2004 & 2007), Lowell (2005), McLaughlan & Salt (2002), as well as some SOPEMI reports (mainly 1997 & 1998). In addition, a few authors have analysed temporary foreign worker programmes (for both high- and lowskilled immigrants). Examples include Castles (2006), Martin (2003) and Ruhs & Martin (2008). They present different criteria and sub-categories for a certain number of countries in specific years. Lindsay Lowell (2005) has provided a review of this literature. While these works do not always correspond in categories and years, they offer a cross-section for at least a limited number of countries. However, both an index and a ranking of policies are missing, except for Lowell’s work. Countries do not employ the same legislative mechanism to regulate the employment of temporary labour migrants. The analysis of HSI policies encompasses both primary legislation (e.g. laws, ordinances) and secondary instruments (e.g. regulations, circulars). The ranking concentrates on temporary HSI policies whose common goal is to fill labour market shortages. In addition, this ranking does not go 18 Lucie Cerna as far as evaluating policies in terms of HSI outcomes, i.e. immigrant flows. The HSII looks at the mechanisms (quotas, economically oriented work permit fees and employer-demand) and the rights of high-skilled immigrants (family reunification, duration and renewability of work permit, change from temporary to permanent residence). The HSII ranks twenty countries in July 2007, a few months before the EU Blue Card was proposed. The assigned scores are based on available information about HSI legislation and are primarily compiled through desk research. SOPEMI Annual Reports on Migration and the earlier Continuous Reporting System on Migration have been used to grasp major policy changes. Categories are supplemented by detailed readings of national immigration legislation and policy descriptions on national websites (such as Ministry of Labour, Ministry of Immigration, Work Permit etc). A country’s score is a more important indicator than its rank for the openness of policies towards high-skilled immigrants. A rank can change easily when new countries enter the index or others are taken out. Figure 2 displays the six chosen categories and groups them into two subheadings.15 19 Lucie Cerna Figure 2: Sub-categories of HSII HSII Admission Mechanisms Work Permit Rights Numerical Caps Employer Portability Labour Market Test Spouse’s Work Rights Labour Protection Permanent Residency Rights The HSI index is meant to measure the openness of countries towards highskilled immigrants. It is composed of six categories, and scores are assigned to each of them from 0 to 3. It operates on equal weighting principle, which means that any two policy changes in a particular country that have an equal effect on the openness of policies have an equal effect on the HSI index. For example, one point change in ‘numerical caps’ has the same effect on the overall scores as one point change in ‘spouse’s work rights’. Points are assigned from 3 (=highly restrictive), 2 (=moderately restrictive), 1 (=minimally restrictive) to 0 (=highly open). All policies are ranked on the same criteria. In the end, the individual points for the six categories are added and converted into an index, where the most restrictive country receives a value of 100. The higher the overall score, the more HSI restrictive is the country. 20 Lucie Cerna Figure 3: HSI Index Figure 3 shows that, in 2007, Sweden ranked as the most restrictive country, followed by Austria and then a group including Denmark, Italy, Japan, Spain and Switzerland. The Netherlands, Ireland and the UK ranked as the most open for attracting high-skilled immigrants.16 Most countries occupied the middle field of the ranking. Among them were Canada and the US that, despite not having the most open policies, still exhibited very successful cases for the recruitment of high-skilled immigrants. Even countries like France who liberalised its policy through the ‘carte des compétences et des talents’ only attracted about 590 high-skilled immigrants in 2008, despite a set target of 2,000 per year. This exemplifies that the openness of policies is not always correlated with the policy success in attracting immigrants. Other factors can play a considerable role, including the difference between ‘policies on paper’ and ‘policies in practice’. They can result from the regulation of policies, 21 Lucie Cerna enforcement mechanisms and administrative capacity. Of course, some methodological limitations of the index apply. The findings from the HSI index demonstrate the need to understand national policy variation and their effects on negotiation. Member states’ preferences regarding the Blue Card While the European Commission presented the Blue Card with enthusiasm, this view was not shared by all member states. Nevertheless, in order to avoid the failure of the 2001 directive, the Commission had engaged in consultations with member states and civil society (i.e. unions, employers, NGOs) before proposing the Blue Card directive (Luedtke 2009). As the previous sections have shown, there are differences in labour market needs and demographics, and hence HSI policies in EU member states. Immigration policy at the EU level used to be under unanimity rule until the Treaty of Lisbon entered into force in December 2009. The Treaty extends qualified majority voting to other areas, including immigration policy. This could allow the EU to play a more significant role in labour immigration, especially since the next planned directives deal with intra-company transfers and seasonal workers (EC 2010). But so far, all member states had to agree on the Blue Card directive, the European Parliament issued an opinion and the European Economic and Social Committee, as well as the Committee of the Regions were consulted.17 The role of the EU and of the European Commission is considered weak regarding areas such as labour immigration (Carrera & Guild 2008). The support varied according to the self-interest of member states, i.e. whether they perceived benefits in increased EU delegation. Member states backing the 22 Lucie Cerna directive did not have a specific HSI policy (or had a restrictive policy) and/or were unsuccessful in attracting high-skilled immigrants. Some member states considered the Blue Card as an opportunity to shift the balance between its migration types. Southern European countries, as well as Sweden, currently accept more asylumseekers (or low-skilled workers) than high-skilled workers. These countries would like to attract ‘productive’ and politically less contested type of migrants. For instance, “Swedish politicians now think the Blue Card system for potential migrants with marketable skills proposed by the EU may offer them an honourable way out of their dilemma” [to shift from humanitarian/refugee immigration to HSI and make sure it gets newcomers it wants and not migrants it gets] (Engel 2008: 21).18 France, Spain and Italy also supported the European Commission’s directive for an EU-wide Blue Card (Work Permit 2007). Officials at the French Ministry of Immigration considered the EU Card better than their new skills and talent visa, which had come into effect in 2007 (Author’s interview, Ministry of Immigration, 11 February 2010). It was the EU’s duty to attract the best and brightest (MEP JeanMarie Cavada, ALDE, France). Italy welcomed the directive, but “believed that final text should be braver. Besides the legal channels of immigration, there should be true and effective free movement of workers of all on the European territory” (Italian Socialist MEP Claudio Fava) (European Parliament 2008a). Member states with open and/or successful HSI policies were less interested in the Blue Card and did not want to let the EU dictate who they could and could not admit (e.g. the Netherlands and the UK). Several politicians in the Netherlands were hostile to the directive and the Austrian government condemned the plan as “a centralisation too far” (BBC 2007). The UK has already engaged in a reorientation toward high-skilled policy and has developed an Australian-style points system” 23 Lucie Cerna (BBC 2007). It implemented a new tier system from 2008 and thus was less interested in an EU-wide Blue Card. Other member states protected their native high-skilled workers and pointed to high national unemployment rates, despite labour market shortages in some sectors (e.g. Germany).19 This made HSI liberalisation more debated – member states had to sell the Blue Card to their citizens and were worried about training opportunities: “The new rules must not put additional pressure on the millions of unemployed in the EU member states” (German Conservative MEP Manfred Weber) (European Parliament 2008b). Germany has had experience with a large number of (low-skilled) guest workers in the 1950s/1960s and the resulting problems of integration. It also sought to attract foreign IT professionals with the German Green Card, but the scheme was not generous to immigrants and thus unsuccessful. In addition, Germany had implemented a new immigration law in 2005, which included a focus on HSI. These experiences influenced their preference towards the EU Blue Card. Many member states also remained sceptical of a pan-European solution to the problem. In September 2007, the idea drew fire from former German Economy Minister Michael Glos, who said: “Germany could not take in large numbers of foreign workers just because it needs them at one particular moment.” The Labour Minister at that time, Franz Müntefering, commented that such significant questions could not be resolved like that by Interior Ministers or the responsible EU Commissioner (Der Spiegel 2007b). A number of member states disputed the Blue Card on principle. Especially ministers from new member states (e.g. the Czech Republic) felt that a common migration system for the high-skilled was inappropriate when transitional arrangements limiting the labour mobility of EU citizens from the new member states 24 Lucie Cerna were still in place (Collett 2008).20 But this objection can be interpreted as a selfinterest argument. New member states wanted to push for free movement of their workers. Until they saw benefits of the Blue Card, they did not support the Directive for TCNs. As we would expect, member states wanted to keep labour immigration policy in their own hands and only agreed on conditions from which they would benefit. Their positions reflected national HSI preferences. The 2007 proposal, greatly debated in national governments and ministries, was endorsed by the European Justice and Home Affairs Ministers during a meeting on 25-26 September 2008 (Goldirova 2008). On 4 November 2008, Members of European Parliament (MEPs) in the Civil Liberties Committee gave their vote on the Klamt report on the Blue Card (European Parliament 2008b). The vote was postponed from 13 October 2008 at the last minute for procedural reasons. On 21 November 2008, the full EU Parliament supported the agreement (EurActiv 2008b).21 The Council of the European Union approved the Directive 2009/50/EC on 25 May 2009. It entered into force on 19 June 2009. Member states had until 19 June 2011 for the transposition of the directive. In addition, the Directive included provisions for monitoring of Blue Card holder flows. From 2013, the Commission would annually collect statistics from member states on the number of cards issues, renewed, withdrawn or refused, on nationalities and occupations and their families. From 2014, the Commission had to report on the application to the European Parliament and the Council every three years and recommend any changes (Europa 2009). The final agreement differed significantly from the original proposal and led to a directive based on a lowest common denominator. One of the problems was the 25 Lucie Cerna definition of high-skilled labour. In the end, consensus was reached on using salary level as the sole criterion (EurActiv 2008a). Some EU countries had proposed a ratio of twice the average salary, while others that were more open to immigration were proposing 1.1 or 1.2. A compromise figure of 1.5 was agreed, with derogations to lower the pay to 1.2 times the national average for sectors with acute labour shortages (EurActiv 2008a). Other member states, such as the UK, Finland and Germany, where legislation did not provide for fixed minimum salaries, were reluctant to agree to the concept. They received assurances that the average salary was strictly statistical and that the Blue Card would not require changes to national labour legislation (EurActiv 2008a). Another compromise was reached on the duration of the Blue Card. The 2007 proposal envisioned the possibility for the migrant moving to another member state after two years and working in the EU for a total of five years. Some countries were determined to maintain national sovereignty over the labour market (e.g. Germany). Therefore, the final directive included provisions that allowed high-skilled migrants to move with their families to another EU state after 18 months, but then they would need to apply for a new Blue Card. The total duration of the visa would not exceed four years, in contrast to the five years listed in the earlier proposal (Melander 2008a). But governments could refuse to issue Blue Cards citing labour market problems or if national quotas were exceeded (Melander 2008a). Labour shortages in the EU intensified during recent years. However, when member states finally agreed on the Directive, most EU member states were severely affected by the economic crisis. The success of the scheme has been debatable. Analysts estimated that the Blue Card would not be enough to attract high-skilled staff and compete with the US 26 Lucie Cerna Green Card because it only offered access to one EU state at a time, not free mobility within the European single market (Melander 2008b). “The fact that a Blue Card is not automatically valid for the whole of the EU takes away most of the advantage of having an EU-wide scheme because it gives access to a much smaller market and fewer opportunities”, said Jakob von Weizsäcker (Melander 2008b). The final version of the Blue Card will not add much value since there are a number of shortfalls that are not addressed. First, each member state will maintain the right to determine the number of immigrant workers that can be admitted into the domestic labour market through the Blue Card. So “this is not an open doors policy” because “if a given member-state needs engineers or doctors, it has to decide how many, and then it will provide a state with a common procedure” (BBC 2007). This is not harmonisation per se (Collett 2008). Second, the Blue Card also does not deal with the problem of qualification and skills recognition for TCNs (Collett 2008). Third, the rate of success of the Blue Card is unclear. Surveys of high-skilled immigrants showed that immigration policies were not their main concern. Instead, other pull factors played an important role (Collett 2008). A greater number of immigrants might come to the UK, Ireland or Germany, rather than to Italy or Spain, for reasons such as language, higher wages and greater working opportunities. In the end, the Blue Card took many years of negotiations to reach a compromise. Member states pursued their self-interest and retained the right to determine the number and conditions of high-skilled TCNs. The UK, Ireland and Denmark wanted their immigration policies left to their own jurisdiction - not the EU’s – and opted out. In addition, they had their own HSI policies in place and could attract enough high-skilled immigrants. But at least they were not in the way of 27 Lucie Cerna adopting the Directive. Therefore, the success of the Blue Card is likely to be modest. As such, the Blue Card presents mainly a procedural simplification. V. Conclusion The ‘global war for talent’ has intensified in recent years. Not only were developments visible at the national level, but reforms were also underway at the global and regional levels, most notably in the EU. One proposed reform by the European Commission was the EU Blue Card. The Directive was passed by the Council of European Union in May 2009. The EU Blue Card has been a welcomed initiative at the EU level - its objectives were to streamline processes, create a centralised decision-making arena and offer one simple application procedure and flexibility for high-skilled immigrants. These steps were to improve the EU’s position in the global competition for ‘the best and brightest’. It has been difficult to obtain the support of all member states as some consider the Blue Card to be more beneficial than others. Member states have varying needs in terms of demographics and labour markets. Therefore, as the constructed HSI index demonstrated, HSI legislation and policies differed considerably among member states. Actors with varying interests already existed at the national level and these preferences were shifted upwards to the EU level. It has led to an agreement with the lowest common denominator, with an opt-out of some member states.22 The application of the Blue Card is likely to be limited. Even though it was publicised to mirror the US Green Card, there are some significant differences. The Blue Card does not “offer the security of residence and access to the labour market, and does not create a right of entry for a migrant worker” (Guild 2007: 4). When the 28 Lucie Cerna EU first proposed the then-Green Card in 2007, the US (in particular pro-business groups) was concerned that it would lose the competition for ‘the best and the brightest’ to Europe. At that time, H-1B visas for the high-skilled were exhausted on the first day of the financial year and employers’ associations, as well as multinational corporations, had been lobbying for an increase in the cap for many years. With the global economic crisis, the situation has changed. The Blue Card directive was passed in May 2009, but the need for high-skilled immigrants had decreased since the Blue Card was discussed in 2005. The US has not exhausted its H-1B cap almost five months after the start of the financial year; Australia decreased the number of high-skilled immigrants for 2009, while Canada and New Zealand were among the few that have not restricted its quota/targets so far. However, labour shortages in certain high-skilled sectors (e.g. engineering and health care) in the EU continue and thus member states still need to recruit high-skilled migrants. Many of them have restricted their national policies towards TCNs since they are limited in their actions towards EU workers (e.g. Ireland and the UK) (Migration News 2009). The final version of the Blue Card will not make much of a difference - it represents a triumph of marketing over substantive policy-making.23 Many member states already have national policies towards TCNs in place. With the Blue Card, member states retain the right to decide the number and conditions for high-skilled migrants. The Blue Card signals to other countries that 1) the EU welcomes highskilled migrants and 2) it is an important player in the ‘war for talent’. But the Blue Card also demonstrates that member states are not willing to delegate decisions on the needs of their labour markets to the EU institutions. Therefore, its failure highlights underlying weaknesses in European institutions and the limits of further integration. 29 Lucie Cerna Some member states will continue to be more successful in attracting highskilled migrants than others, with or without a Blue Card. Factors, such as wage levels, advancement opportunities and language issues play an important role (Chaloff& Lemaitre 2009). The Blue Card might be a first step, but different preferences and sovereignty concerns precluded member states to agree on more than a lowest common denominator. Even though HSI is supposed to be the most ‘rational’ type of immigration, it cannot escape the fear of citizens and national policy-makers to delegate the decision on the entry of high-skilled immigrants to EU institutions. The politicisation of immigration should be examined by future scholars. This paper has presented an analysis of the benefits and challenges of the Blue Card. Further research should also provide an examination of these issues once the Directive is transposed into national legislation. The EU Blue Card offers a number of areas for consideration, such as the shifting governance from national to EU level, the increasing competition for high-skilled immigrants, migration policy-making and EU integration. The paper has only touched the surface of these important, but complex, topics. NOTES 1 ‘The best and brightest’ refer to high-skilled immigrants, meant to promote innovation and international competitiveness. While many definitions of high-skilled immigrants exist, the image that often comes to mind is that of a “relatively small elite, covering perhaps persons with doctorates, researchers, high-level engineers” (Chaloff & Lemaitre 2009: 10). Definitional issues are discussed in later sections. 2 They are analysed in Lavenex (2006). 3 See Caviedes 2004 and Menz 2002 for a detailed overview of EU developments in immigration. 4 For an analysis of the failed 2001 directive and the successful 2007 directive, see Luedtke 2009. 5 Some authors argue that the harmonisation of immigration policies is necessary due to efficiency arguments (e.g. Straubhaar 2000). National policies should be made similar to prevent “certain countries from opening the borders of all fellow member states as well as to establish a common system for managing migration flows” (Caviedes 2004: 292). 30 Lucie Cerna 6 For a mixture of both approaches, see Geddes 2003 and Messina 2007. There are several other hypotheses found in the literature, such as path-dependency (Hansen 2002), the role of elites (Guiraudon 2000) and the rights-based explanation (Hollifield 1992). Due to space constraints in this paper, I cannot address these hypotheses. 8 “They emerge through domestic political conflict as societal groups compete for political influence, national and transnational coalitions form, and new policy alternatives are recognised by governments” (Moravcsik 1993: 481). 9 Tripartite policy-making refers to government, unions and employers’ associations. 10 “A lowest common denominator outcome does not mean that final agreements perfectly reflect the preferences of the least forthcoming government - since it is generally in its interest to compromise somewhat rather than veto an agreement- but only that the range of possible agreements is decisively constrained by its preferences” (Moravcsik 1993: 501). 11 Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia. 12 Bulgaria and Romania. 13 The EU is witnessing employment growth of three percent per year in higheducation sectors (1 percent in other sectors), a change in the occupational structure in favour of high-skilled non-manual workers and, for these workers, high employment rates are coupled with low unemployment rates (83.2 against 4.8 percent) (EC 2007c). 14 It concerns working conditions (including pay and dismissal), health and safety at the workplace, education, vocational training, recognition of qualifications, social security (including health care), export of pensions once they are paid, access to goods and services (including procedures for housing) and tax benefits (EC 2007b). 15 More information is presented in Appendix A. The justification for the category selection is not included due to the usual constraints. But it is available from the author. 16 But policies change over time. For instance, the UK has implemented a new Points Based System from January 2008, and Sweden has liberalised its labour immigration policy in December 2008. These changes would have moved the countries’ rankings. 17 The procedure on legal migration remains subject to Council unanimity with Parliament only consulted. But: EU laws on illegal migration, internal and external border controls, and burden-sharing of refugees fall under EU co-decision procedure. 18 Sweden’s new liberal labour immigration policy came into force in 2008. 19 Business leaders in Germany complained that shortages in skilled workers such as engineers and computer specialists could start to have a negative effect on the economy (Der Spiegel 2007a). 20 Currently, Austria, Belgium, Germany and Denmark continue to protect their markets from new EU member states’ workers. “Our citizens cannot be in a worse situation than non-EU states”, Czech minister Ivan Langer said (Goldirova 2008). 21 The report had a clear majority of 388 to 56, due to a pact between the European Parliament’s two major parties (European Socialist Party and center-right European People’s Party). However, the large number of abstentions (124), led by the European Liberals and Green Party, indicated important disagreements (EurActiv 2008b). 22 This outcome was not much different from the directive on ‘posting of workers for the provision of services’, which, after long negotiations, resulted in a lowest common denominator regulation. It did not intrude into member state arrangements and the practical effect was minimal (Menz 2002: 738). 7 31 Lucie Cerna 23 The German Green Card also had a marketing element as it was aimed at the US Green Card. REFERENCES Barroso, J. M. (2007), ‘Opening remarks of President Barroso - Legal immigration’, European Commission Speech 07/650, 23 October 2007. BBC (2007), ‘EU ‘Blue Card’ to target skilled’, BBC News, 23 October 2007. Betts, A. and Cerna, L. “Global governance of high-skilled labour migration”, in A. Betts (ed), Global Migration Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Carrera, S. and Guild, E. (2008), ‘The French presidency’s European Pact on Immigration and Asylum: Intergovernmentalism vs. Europeanisation? Security vs. Rights?’, CEPS Policy brief, September. Castles, S. (2006), ‘Back to the future? Can Europe meet its labour needs through temporary migration?’, IMI Working Paper 1: 1-38. Caviedes, A. (2004), ‘The open method of co-ordination in immigration policy: a tool for prying open Fortress Europe?’, Journal of European Public Policy 11(2): 289310. Caviedes, A. (2006), Cracks in the Fortress Europe? How Sectoral Needs Shape Labour Migration Policy, Department of Political Science, University of WisconsinMadison. Cerna, L. (2009), ‘The varieties of high-skilled immigration policies: coalitions and policy outputs in advanced industrial countries’, Journal of European Public Policy 16(1): 144-161. Chaloff, J. and Lemaitre, G. (2009), ‘Managing highly-skilled labour migration: a comparative analysis of migration policies and challenges in OECD countries’, OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper 79, 18 March 2009. Christian, B. P. (2000), Facilitating high-skilled migration to advanced industrial countries: comparative policies, Working Paper of the Institute for the Study of International Migration, Georgetown University. http://www.georgetown.edu/sfs/programs/isim Collett, E. (2008), ‘The proposed European Blue Card system: arming for the global war on talent?’, Migration Policy Institute, 7 January 2008. Council of European Union (2009), ‘Council adopts the “EU Blue Card”: more advantages for highly skilled foreign workers’, Press release 10266/09, 25 May 2009. www.consilium.europa.eu/ueDocs/cms_Data/docs/pressdata/en/misc/107989.pdf 32 Lucie Cerna Der Spiegel (2007a), ‘European Commission launches new push for ‘Blue Card’, Der Spiegel, 7 November 2007. Der Spiegel (2007b), ‘Müntefering weist Zuwanderungs-Pläne der EU scharf zurück’, Der Spiegel, 14 September 2007. Engel, M. (2008), ‘The new face of Sweden’, Financial Times Magazine, 19/20 January 2008. EurActiv (2008a), ‘EU eyes higher pay for skilled immigrants’, EurActiv.com, 26 September 2008. EurActiv (2008b), ‘Divided Parliament approves EU Blue Card system’, EurActiv.com, 21 November 2008. http://www.euractiv.com/en/socialeurope/divided-parliament-approves-eu-blue-cardsystem/article-177380 Eurobarometer (2008), ‘The role of the European Union in Justice, Freedom and Security areas’, Eurobarometer Special Report 290, Wave 68.2, European Commission. Europa (2009), ‘Entry and residence of highly qualified workers (EU Blue Card)’, European Legislation, 18 August. http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/justice_freedom_security/free_movement_of_ persons_asylum_immigration/l14573_en.htm European Commission (2005), ‘Policy plan on legal migration’, 21 December 2005, {SEC(2005)1680}. European Commission (2007a), ‘Making Europe more attractive to highly skilled migrants and increasing the protection of lawfully residing and working migrants’, 23 October 2007. IP/07/1575. European Commission (2007b), ‘Simplified admission procedures and common set of rights for third-country workers’, European Commission Memo 07/422, 23 October 2007. European Commission (2007c), ‘Attractive conditions for the admission and residence of highly qualified immigrants’, European Commission Memo 07/423, 23 October 2007. European Commission (2007d), ‘Proposal for a Council Directive on the conditions for entry and residence of third-country nationals for the purposes of highly qualified employment: Summary of the impact assessment’, European Commission SEC(2007) 1382, 23 October 2007. European Commission (2010), ‘Delivering an area of freedom, security and justice for European’s citizens: Action plan implementing the Stockholm Programme’, Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the 33 Lucie Cerna European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions, COM(2010) 171 final, 20 April. European Parliament (2008a), ‘Vote on EU Blue Card’, European Parliament Press Release, 16 October 2008. European Parliament (2008b), ‘Blue Card scheme backed by MEPs’, European Parliament Press Release, 5 November 2008. Freeman, G. (2006), ‘National models, policy types and the politics of immigration in liberal democracies’, West European Politics 29(2): 227-247. Geddes, A. (2003), The Politics of Migration and Immigration in Europe, London: SAGE. Geddes, A. et al. (2004), The European Civic Citizenship and Inclusion Index, Brussels: British Council. http://www.britishcouncil.org/brussels-european-civic-citizenship-and-inclusionindex.pdf Geddes, A. et al. (2007), Migrant Integration Policy Index (2nd edn), Brussels: British Council. http://www.integrationindex.eu/ Givens, T. and Luedtke, A. (2004), ‘The politics of European Union immigration policy: institutions, salience and harmonisation’, The Policy Studies Journal 32(1): 145-165. Givens, T. and Luedtke, A. (2005), ‘European immigration policies in comparative perspective: issue salience, partisanship and immigrant rights’, Comparative European Politics 25(3): 1-22. Goldirova, R. (2008), ‘EU ministers flesh out foreign worker “Bleu Card” plan’, EUobserver.com, 25 September. Guild, E. (2007), ‘EU policy on labour migration: a first look at the Commission’s Blue Card initiative’, CEPS Policy Brief 145, CEPS, Brussels. Guiraudon, V. (2000), ‘European integration and migration policy: vertical policymaking as venue shopping’, Journal of Common Market Studies 38(2): 251-271. Haas, E. (1958), The Uniting of Europe: Political, Social and Economical Forces: 1950-1957, London: Stevens & Sons. Hansen, R. (2002), ‘Globalization, embedded realism and path dependence: the other immigrants to Europe’, Comparative Political Studies 35(3): 259–283. Hollifield, J. (1992), Immigrants, Markets and States: The Political Economy of Postwar Europe, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. 34 Lucie Cerna Lahav, G. (2004), ‘Public opinion toward immigration in the European Union: Does it matter?’, Comparative Political Studies 37: 1151-1183. Lavenex, S. (2006), ‘The competition state’, in M. P. Smith and A. Favell (eds), The Human Face of Global Mobility: International Highly Skilled Migration in Europe, North America and the Asia-Pacific, New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers. Lowell, L. (2005), ‘Policies and regulations for managing skilled international migration for work’, United Nations, Mortality and Migration Section of the Population Division/DESA, New York. Lowell, L. (2008), ‘Chapter 2: Highly skilled migration’, in IOM, World Migration Report, Geneva. Luedtke, A. (2009), ‘Uncovering European Union immigration legislation: policy dynamics and outcomes’, International Migration, early view: 1-27. Martin, P. (2003), Managing labour migration: temporary worker programs for the 21st century, Geneva: International Institute for Labour Studies. Mayer, M. (2008), ‘The formation of Germany’s preferences on the economic migration directive: institutions, structural factors and domestic actors’, Paper prepared for the UACES Conference Exchanging Ideas on Europe 2008: Rethinking the European Union, Edinburgh, 1-3 September 2008. McLaughlan, G. and Salt, J. (2002), Migration policies towards highly skilled foreign workers, Report to the United Kingdom Home Office, London. Melander, I. (2008a), ‘Blue Card will struggle to lure immigrant talent’, Reuters, 26 September. Melander, I. (2008b), ‘EU agrees “Blue Card” to lure high-skilled migrants’, Reuters, 22 October. Menz, G. (2002), ‘Patterns in EU labour immigration policy: national initiatives an European responses’, Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies 28(4): 723-742. Menz, G. (2009), The Political Economy of Managed Migration: Nonstate Actors, Europeanization, and the Politics of Designing Migration Policies, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Messina, A. (2007), The Logics and Politics of Post-WWII Migration to Western Europe, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Meyers, E. (1995), The Political Economy of International Immigration Policy: A Comparative and Quantitative Study, PhD Dissertation, Department of Political Science, University of Chicago. Meyers, E. (2004), International Immigration Policy: A Theoretical and Comparative 35 Lucie Cerna Analysis, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Migration News (2009), ‘Obama, Congress’, July 16(3). http://migration.ucdavis.edu Money, J. and Falstrom, D. Z. (2006), ‘Interests and institutions in skilled migration: comparing flows in the IT and nursing sectors in the US’, in M.P. Smith and A. Favell (eds) (2006) The Human Face of Global Mobility: International Highly Skilled Migration in Europe, North-America and the Asia-Pacific, New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers, pp. 131-56. Moravcsik, A. (1993), ‘Preferences and power in the European Community: a liberal intergovernmentalist approach’, Journal of Common Market Studies 31(4): 473-524. Moravcsik, A. (1998), The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. OECD (1995), ‘The measurement of scientific and technological activities manual on the measurement of human resources devoted to S&T: Canberra manual’, Paris: OECD. OECD (1998), SOPEMI 1997 Annual Report (Trends in International Migration), Paris: OECD. OECD (1999), SOPEMI 1998 Annual Report (Trends in International Migration), Paris: OECD. Official Journal of the European Union (2009). ‘Council Directive 2009/50/EC of 25 May 2009 on the conditions of entry and residence of third-country nationals for the purposes of highly qualified employment’. European Council, 18 June. Parliament of the Commonwealth of Australia (2004), To make a contribution: review of skilled labour migration programs 2004, Canberra: House of Representatives Publishing Unit. Portes, A. and Rumbaut, R. (1996), Immigrant America: a Portrait (2nd edn), Berkeley: University of California Press. Putnam, R. (1988), ‘Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of two-level games’, International Organization 42(3): 427–460. Ruhs, M. and Martin, P. (2008), ‘Numbers vs rights: trade-offs and guest worker programs’, International Migration Review 42(1): 249-265. Salt, J. and Almeida, J. (2006), ‘International migration in Europe: patterns and trends since the mid-1990s’, International Migration Review 22(2): 155-175. Schain, M. (2009), ‘The state strikes back: immigration policy in the European Union‘, European Journal of International Law 20(1): 93-109. 36 Lucie Cerna Stone Sweet, A. and Sandholtz, W. (1998), European Integration and Supranational Governance, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Straubhaar, T. (2000), ‘New migration needs a NEMP’, HWWA Discussion Paper 95, Hamburg: Hamburgisches Welt-Wirtschafts-Archiv. The Economist (2001), ‘Bridging Europe’s skills gap’, The Economist, 31 March. Weizsäcker, J. von (2006), ‘A European Blue Card Proposal’, Horizons Stratégiques du Centre d’Analyse Atratégique, Number 1, July 2006. Work Permit (2007), ‘France wants immigration harmonised across EU’, Work Permit UK, 19 November 2007. Zaletel, P. (2006), ‘Competing for the highly skilled migrants: implications for the EU common approach on temporary economic migration’, European Law Journal 12(5): 613-635. Appendix A: Definitions of Sub-Categories 1) Numerical caps: a high score (3 points) is given if admission numbers are fixed and small numbers permitted; declining points are given if numbers are fixed but generous; or there is an ability to periodically adjust numbers, or there are no caps at all. a) 3 pts: admission numbers are fixed (quota), small numbers permitted b) 2 pts: admission numbers fixed, but generous numbers c) 1 pts: admission numbers fixed, but periodically adjusted, or planned numbers announced d) 0 pts: no numerical caps at all 2) Labour market test: a high ranking score is given if there is a strong test of the labour market, i.e. a lack of available workers; declining points are given if employers need only assert good faith, or the government awards points for skills, or applicants are streamlined through pre-determined shortage occupations, or there is no test at all. a) 3 pts: strong labour market test (i.e. lack of available native workers), certification procedure b) 2 pts: employers need to assert good faith or government awards points for skills (i.e. points system), attestation procedure c) 1 pts: applicants streamlined through pre-determined shortage occupations (or tier system/ equivalent), no advertising necessary d) 0 pts: no labour market test at all 3) Labour protection: a high score is given if there are stringent requirements on wage setting and other protections such as no lay-off provisions etc; declining points are given if there are fewer protections or no immigrant-specific legal protection other than existing labour law. 37 Lucie Cerna a) 3 pts: stringent requirements on wage setting and other protections (dismissal provisions, high minimum salary level, health/ safety provisions, working hours etc) b) 2 pts: fewer requirements on wage setting and other protections (e.g. smaller number of conditions than for the above category) c) 1 pts: minimal requirements on wage setting and other protections (e.g. no minimum remuneration) d) 0 pts: no immigrant-specific legal protection other than existing labour law 4) Employer portability: a high score is given if the foreign worker can work only for the original employer and in one place; declining points are given for the degree to which work authorisation is ‘portable’ between employers. a) 3 pts: work authorisation is tied to employer, occupation/ sector and place of work b) 2 pts: work authorisation is tied to employer (for certain time period), but worker has to apply for a new work permit to change c) 1 pts: work authorisation is portable between employers in a given occupation/ sector or region d) 0 pts: no restrictions on employer portability (employment anywhere) 5) Spouse’s work rights: a high score is given if the spouse is not permitted to either accompany the worker (or other dependents) or to work; declining points are given if the spouse is permitted to obtain independent working rights, or the spouse has unlimited working rights. a) 3 pts: spouse is not permitted to accompany worker or to work b) 2 pts: spouse is permitted to apply for independent working rights c) 1 pts: spouse has unlimited working rights after a certain time period or expedited procedure/ no labour market needs test in case spouse has to apply for independent working rights d) 0 pts: spouse has unlimited working rights from the start 6) Permanent residency rights: a high score is given if the temporary migrant is prohibited from transitioning to any permanent status; declining points are given if transitions are relatively possible, or there is an additional transition to naturalised citizenship. a) 3 pts: transition to permanent from temporary status is prohibited b) 2 pts: no automatic transition envisioned (i.e. need to switch programmes) or possibility to apply for permanent status exists (more than 5 years) c) 1 pts: transition to permanent residency is relatively possible after some years (3-5 years) d) 0 pts: additional transition to naturalised citizenship (or very short time period to permanent residence: less than 3 years) 38