Simultaneous First-Price Auctions with Preferences over Combinations: Identification, Estimation and Application∗ Matthew Gentry† Tatiana Komarova‡ Pasquale Schiraldi§ October 2014 (Preliminary and incomplete) Abstract Motivated by the empirical prevalence of simultaneous bidding across a wide range of auction markets, we develop and estimate a structural model of strategic interaction in simultaneous first-price auctions when objects are heterogeneous and bidders have preferences over combinations. We begin by proposing a general theoretical model of bidding in simultaneous first price auctions, exploring properties of best responses and existence of equilibrium within this environment. We then specialize this model to an empirical framework in which bidders have stochastic private valuations for each object and stable incremental preferences over combinations; this immediately reduces to the standard separable model when incremental preferences over combinations are zero. We establish non-parametric identification of the resulting model under standard exclusion restrictions, thereby providing a basis for both testing on and estimation of preferences over combinations. We then apply our model to data on Michigan Department of Transportation highway procurement auctions, we quantify the magnitude of cost synergies and assess possible efficiency losses arising from simultaneous bidding in this market. ∗ We are grateful to Philip Haile, Ken Hendricks, Paul Klemperer, and Balazs Szentes for their comments and insight. We also thank seminar participants at the University of Wisconsin (Madison), the University of Zurich, University of Leuven, Cardiff University, Oxford University, Cornell University, the University of East Anglia, and Universitie Paris 1 for helpful discussion. † London School of Economics, m.l.gentry@lse.ac.uk ‡ London School of Economics, t.komarova@lse.ac.uk § London School of Economics and CEPR, p.schiraldi@lse.ac.uk 1 1 Introduction Simultaneous bidding in multiple first-price auctions is a commonly occurring but rarely discussed design of many real-world auction markets. In environments where values over combinations are non-additive in the set of objects won, bidders must account for possible combination wins at the time of bidding. This in turn substantially alters the strategic bidding problem compared to the standard first price auction with ambiguous welfare implications depending on the importance of synergies (either positive1 or negative2 ) among objects. As a first step toward exploring this issue, we develop a structural model of bidding in simultaneous first-price auctions and study identification and estimation in this framework. We then apply our results to estimate cost synergies arising in Michigan Department of Transportation (MDOT) highway procurement auctions, using the resulting estimates to quantify efficiency losses arising from simultaneous bidding in this application. To underscore the prevalence of simultaneous bidding in applications, note that most widely studied first-price marketplaces in fact exhibit simultaneous bids. Concrete examples include markets for highway procurement in most US states (JofretBonet and Pesendorfer 2003, Krasnokutskaya 2009, Krasnokutskaya and Seim 2004, Somaini 2013, Li and Zheng 2009, Groeger 2014, many others), snow-clearing in Montreal (Flambard and Perrigne 2006), recycling services in Japan (Kawai 2010), cleaning services in Sweden (Lunander and Lundberg 2012), oil and drilling rights in the US Outer Continental Shelf (Hendricks and Porter 1984, Hendricks, Pinkse and Porter 2003), and to a lesser extent US Forest Service timber harvesting (Lu and Perrigne 2008, Li and Zheng 2012, Li and Zhang 2010, Athey, Levin and Siera 2011, many others). Furthermore, in many of these applications we expect bidders to have non-additive preferences over combinations; due, for instance, to capacity effects in highway procurement (Jofret-Bonet and Pesendorfer 2003), distance between contracts in snow clearing and waste collection, or information spillovers in Outer Continental Shelf drilling (Hendricks and Porter 1984). In such cases strategic simul1 These commonly arise from cost savings in procurement auctions. These may arise when bidders have resource and capacity constraints or when winning alternative items offered can meet the same need. 2 2 taneity may substantially influence both bidder behavior and market performance. To illustrate the policy questions arising in simultaneous multi-object auctions, note that given a set of L heterogeneous objects for sale, bidders could in general assign either positive or negative synergies to winning multiple objects. Consequently, bidder i’s preference structure could in principle be as complex as a complete 2L dimensional set of signals describing the valuations i assigns to each of the 2L possible subsets of objects. Meanwhile, the simultaneous first-price mechanism allows bidders to submit (at most) L individual bids on the L objects being sold. Consequently, the simultaneous first-price auction format is necessarily inefficient – the “message space” (standalone bids) permitted is insufficiently rich to allow bidders to express their true preferences (over combinations). On the other hand, while allowing combinatoric bids would alleviate the “message space” problem, due to strategic considerations even this is not guaranteed to produce an efficient allocation (see for example the discussions in Cantillon and Pesendorfer 2006, Crampton at al. 2006). Meanwhile, the combinatorial first-price mechanism may impose substantial practical costs on both bidders (the combinatoric bidding problem) and the seller (in allocating objects; the combinatorial “winner determination problem”). A simultaneous first-price auction sidesteps both concerns at the cost of potential losses in efficiency or revenue resulting from inability to express combinatoric preferences. Hence in evaluating the relative merit of the simultaneous first-price format it is first necessary to assess the magnitude of losses to to simultaneous bidding, a question about which very little is presently known.3 Despite the prevalence of simultaneous bidding across a variety of first-price markets, there presently exists very little work assessing the revenue and efficiency implications of such simulteneity in practice. This dearth of research is not surprising given that there presently exists no known method for estimating preferences over combinations in simultaneous first-price auctions. In turn, without any means to assess the magnitude of such preferences in practice, meaningful statements on the 3 In environments with substitutes it is known that any Bayes-Nash equilibrium of the simultaneous first-price auction achieves at least half of optimal social welfare – see Feldman et al. (2012) discussed in more detail below. Apart from this, however, very little is known about efficiency in practice, and even this (wide) bound becomes meaningless when objects are complements. 3 economic consequences of simultaneous bidding become virtually impossible. Motivated by this gap in the literature, we develop an empirical model of bidding in simultaneous first-price auctions when objects are heterogeneous and bidders have non-additive preferences over combinations, to our knowledge the first such in the literature. This model turns on a novel decomposition of bidder preferences, which we outline briefly here. We represent the total value i assigns to a given combination as the sum of two components: the sum of the standalone valuations i assigns to winning each object in the combination individually, plus a combination-specific complementarity (either positive or negative) capturing the change in value i assigns to winning objects in combination.4 We interpret standalone valuations as private information drawn independently across bidders conditional on observables, but require incremental preferences over combinations to be stable in the sense that complementarities are unknown functions of observables.5 We find this framework natural in a variety of procurement contexts – when, for instance, non-additivity in preferences can be represented as realizations of a “combination shock” realized after a multiple win. Furthermore – and crucially – our framework collapses immediately to the standard separable model when complementarities are zero, supporting formal testing of this hypothesis. We apply this model to data on Michigan Department of Transportation (MDOT) highway procurement auctions and evaluate the efficiency losses due to simultaneous bidding in this market. In so doing, we make three main contributions to the literature on structural analysis of auction markets. First, we propose a structural model of simultaneous first-price auctions permitting identification of non-additive preferences over combinations. Identification in this framework rests on two key assumptions. First, as noted above, we assume that bidders’ incremental preferences over combinations are stable functions of observables. Second, we assume that the marginal distributions of i’s standalone valuations are invariant either to the characteristics of i’s rivals or to the characteristics 4 Note that this decomposition is without loss of generality; the key identifying restriction is the structure we impose on complementarities. 5 Note that this structure does not restrict dependence between i’s standalone valuations for different objects in the market. We view this flexibility as critical, as in practice we expect i’s standalone valuations to be positively correlated. 4 of other objects on which i is bidding.6 We show that optimal behavior in this environment yields an inverse bidding system non-parametrically identified up to the function describing incremental preferences over combinations, with the resulting system collapsing to the standard inverse bidding function of Guerre, Perrigne and Vuong (2000) auction by auction when incremental preferences over combinations are zero. Building on this inverse bidding system, we translate the exclusion restrictions outlined above into a system of identifying restrictions on model primitives, with excludable variation in the characteristics of i’s rivals yielding non-parametric identification and excludable variation in characteristics yielding semiparametric identification of i’s primitives.7 Taken together, these results provide a formal basis for structural analysis of simultaneous first-price auctions with non-additive preferences over combinations, to our knowledge the first such in the literature. Second, building on our identification argument, we develop a three-step procedure yielding empirical estimates of primitives in our structural model. First, in Step 1, we estimate the multi-variate joint distribution of bids as a function of bidderand auction-level characteristics. Due to the high-dimensional nature of this estimation problem, we follow several prior studies (e.g. Cantillon and Pesendorfer 2006 and Athey, Levin and Siera 2011) by employing a parametric approximation to the observed bid density in implementation of this step. Next, in Step 2, we parametrize preferences over combinations as a function of bidder- and combination-specific covariates8 and estimate parameters in this function by minimization of a simulated analog to our semiparametric identification criterion. As in practice we parametrize 6 The first of these exclusion restrictions is widely invoked in the literature; see, e.g. Guerre, Perrigne and Vuong (2009) or Somaini (2012). The second is specific to the combinatoric environment we consider, although we believe it is natural in a variety of applications. 7 As it is difficult to rule out ties a priori in the fully general simultaneous model, we also extend our partial identification results (see Appendix C) to accommodate potential mass points in equilibrium bids. We show that in this case primitives are partially identified, with Monte Carlo analysis suggesting that identified sets are tight in practice. While we do not believe ties are important in the application —they are never observed in the data — we consider, this analysis helps to underscore robustness of our results. 8 In our application, combination-specific covariates might include the sum of engineer’s estimates across projects in a combination, distance between projects in a combination, and indicators for whether projects in a combination are of the same type, among others. 5 preferences over combinations as a linear function of observables, this reduces to a quadratic minimization problem solvable by OLS. Finally, in the third step, we map estimates derived in Step 2 through the inverse bidding system derived in Step 1 to obtain estimates of the distribution of private costs rationalizing observed bidding behavior. We conclude this part by showing the performance of our estimation procedure in a Monte Carlo study. Finally, we apply the framework developed above to analyze simultaneous bidding in Michigan Department of Transportation (MDOT) highway procurement markets. We view this market as prototypical of our target application: large numbers of projects are auctioned simultaneously (an average of 33 per letting round in our 2002-2009 sample period), more than half of bidders bid on at least two projects simultaneously (with an average of 2.65 bids per round across all bidders in the sample), and combination and contingent bidding are explicitly forbidden. Within this marketplace, we show that factors such as size of other projects, number of bidders in other auctions, and the relative distance between projects have substantial reduced-form impacts on i’s bid in auction l. This finding is expected when bidders have non-trivial preferences over combinations, but difficult to rationalize within either the standard separable Independent Private Values model or typical extensions of it (e.g. affiliated values, unobserved heterogeneity, and endogenous entry among others). We then apply the three-step estimation algorithm described above to recover structural estimates of primitives for bidders competing for two-auction combinations, with results suggesting that winning two auctions together leads to cost savings for moderately sized projects but cost increases for large projects: 4.5 percent savings for a two-auction combination of median size, transitioning to 2.3 percent increase for one at the 90th percentile. Finally, we use our estimation results to analyze the implications of the auction design chosen by the MDOT. Specifically, we use our costs estimates to assess the degree of inefficiency in MDOT highway procurement auctions, to estimate the extent of the exposure problem,9 and to determine what share of the expected total surplus is collected by the auctioneer. 9 The exposure problem in auctions of multiple items involves the risk of bidders winning unwanted items, i.e. winning items at prices above bidders’ values for them. 6 Related literature While we are not aware of a detailed structural exploration of bidding in simultaneous first-price auctions, there is a small but growing empirical literature on combinatorial first-price auctions: i.e. first-price auctions in which participants are allowed to submit package bids. The seminal paper in this literature is Cantillon and Pesendorfer (2006), who analyze simultaneous first-price sealed-bid auctions in which bidders can submit bids on combinations. The authors address the problem of non-parametric identification of distributions of bidders valuations when all the bids and all the identities of the bidders are observed. They also suggest an estimation procedure which they apply to data from the London bus routes market, but find little evidence of cost synergies. Allowing bidders to submit combinatorial bids, substantially alters analysis of the bidding problem; in the language of mechanism design, the “message space” (standalone bids) is now sparse relative to the type space (preferences over combinations), and therefore it leads to a fundamentally different identification problem. More recently, Kim, Olivers and Weintraub (2014) extend the methodology of Cantillon and Pesendorfer (2006) to large-scale combinatoric auctions, using additional structure on combinatoric preferences to circumvent the substantial curse of dimensionality involved. They then apply methodology to data on combinatoric auctions used in procurement of Chilean school meals, finding that the combinatoric first-price auction performs well in terms of both efficiency and revenue despite the presence of substantial cost synergies in the marketplace. Paralleling these two structural studies, there is also a small reduced-form literature seeking to quantify the role of preferences over combinations in multi-object auctions. For instance, Ausubel, Cramton, McAfee and McMillan (1997) and Moreton and Spiller (1998) use regression analysis to measure synergy effects in the recent experience in FCC spectrum auctions. Lunander and Lundberg (2012) use data from public procurement auctions of internal regular cleaning services in Sweden to show that firms inflate their standalone bids in combinatorial first-price auctions relative to their corresponding bids in simultaneous first-price auctions. Despite this, they do not find significant differences in the procurer’s cost between these two types of auctions. Lunander and Nilsson (2004) experimentally compare simultaneous, sequential, and combinatorial first-price sealed-bid auctions and show that, despite 7 potential for synergies, revenue comparison between formats produced statistically insignificant differences. From a more theoretical perspective, there exist several studies analyzing strategic interaction in stylized models involving simultaneous first-price auctions. For instance, Szentes and Rosental (1996) study a first-price sealed-bid acution for identical objects with two identical players and complete information, while Ghosh (2012) examines a simultaneous sealed-bid first-price auction for two identical objects with budget-constrained symmetric bidders. While these models confirm that interaction between auctions can have substantial effects on behavior and welfare, the stylizy focus on stylized models which are not well suited to support empirical analysis. There is also a substantial literature analyzing properties of various combinatorial auction mechanisms: Ausbel and Milgrom (2002), Ausbel and Cramton (2004), Cramton (1998, 2002, 2006), Krishna and Rosenthal (1996), Klemperer (2008, 2010), Milgrom (2000a, 2000b), and Rosenthal and Wang (1996), to mention just a few. Detailed surveys of this literature are given in de Vreis and Vorha (2003), and Cramton et al. (2006). While these studies are similar in that they explicitly consider settings where bidders have preferences over combinations, the theoretical and empirical problems encountered in the simultaneous first-price format differ substantially from those encountered in a combinatorial context.10 Finally, approaching the problem from a substantially different angle, there is a growing literature on simultaneous first-price auctions within computer science. This literature is focused almost exclusively on theoretical worst-case efficiency bounds, termed in computer science the “Bayesian price of anarchy.” For instance, working within essentially the same model we consider here, Feldman et al. (2012) show that when preferences are subadditive expected social welfare of any BNE is at least 12 of optimal social welfare. Meanwhile, Syrgkanis (2012) considers a more restrictive class of “fractionally subadditive” valuations, showing that in this case there exists a 10 Though only tangentially related to our problem, there is also a growing literature on multi-unit discriminatory auctions of homogeneous objects. Reny (1999, 2011), Athey (2001), and McAdams (2006) address issues of existence of equilibria and equilibrium properties in such auctions. Meanwhile, Hortacsu and Puller (2008), Hortacsu and McAdams (2010), and Hortacsu (2011) provide more empirical perspectives on multi-unit auctions. 8 tighter worst-case efficiency bound. Note that these studies analyze bidder behavior only tangentially, with existence of BNE never directly addressed. Furthermore, even these (wide) bounds no longer convey any restrictions when objects are complements; in this case, virtually nothing is known about efficiency of the simultaneous first-price mechanism. 2 A general model of simultaneous first-price auctions Consider a one-shot game in which N risk-neutral bidders compete for L prizes allocated via separate simultaneous first-price auctions. Apart from the possibility of simultaneous bidding, auctions are run according to standard first-price rules: the high bidder in auction l wins object l and pays the amount bid. Bids are binding, bidders may not submit combination bids, bids in one auction may not be made contingent on outcomes in any other, and there is no resale. For the moment, assume ties are broken randomly and independently across auctions. Allocations and outcomes In analyzing this environment, we adopt the following notation and definitions. An allocation a is an L × 1 vector whose lth element gives the identity of the bidder winning object l. An outcome from the perspective of bidder i is an L × 1 indicator vector ω with a 1 in the lth place if object l is allocated to bidder i (al = i) and a 0 in the lth place otherwise. An outcome matrix Ω is a 2L × 1 matrix whose rows contain (transposes of) each possible outcome ω: e.g. if L = 2, " # 0 0 1 1 ΩT = 0 1 0 1 Since in practice we will normalize preferences over the “win nothing” outcome to zero, we could equivalently omit the row corresponding to ω = 0 from Ω. 9 Bidder preferences Bidders have preferences over outcomes but are indifferent to allocations conditional on outcome: i.e. given any set of objects won, i is indifferent to how remaining objects are distributed among rivals. Let Yiω be the combinatoric valuation bidder i assigns to outcome ω, and Yi be the 2L × 1 vector describing the combinatoric valuations i assigns to all possible outcomes (with elements of Yi corresponding to rows in Ω). Yi is known to bidder i at the time of bidding but unknown to rivals or the auctioneer; Yi thus represents bidder i’s private type in the bidding game. We maintain the following two assumptions on private types: Assumption 1 (Independent Private Values). Each bidder i draws private type Yi from an absolutely continuous c.d.f. FY,i with support on a compact, convex set L Yi ⊂ R2 , with Yi private information, FY,i common knowledge, and types drawn independent across bidders: Yi ⊥ Yj for all i, j. Assumption 2 (Values Normalized and Non-decreasing). Yi0 = 0 and Yiω is non0 decreasing in the vector of objects won: ω 0 ≥ ω implies Yiω ≥ Yiω . Actions and strategies Formally, i’s action space is the set of non-negative L × 1 vectors of the form bi ≡ (bi1 , ..., biL ), with bil denoting i’s bid in auction l. Let Bi be the set of feasible (non-negative) bids for bidder i; note that under Assumption 1 we may take Bi to be compact without loss of generality, and under Assumption 2 Bi need not include a null bid (since i always prefers to win any additional object at bid 0). As usual, a pure strategy for bidder i is a function si : Yi → Bi . Following Milgrom and Weber (1985), we define a distributional strategy for bidder i as a probability measure σi on Yi × Bi whose marginal on Yi is Fi . Let s = (s1 , ..., sN ) and σ = (σ1 , ..., σN ) denote pure and distributional strategies respectively. Standalone valuations and complementarities Let Vil denote the valuation i assigns to the outcome “i wins object l alone”: Vil ≡ Yiel , where el (the lth unit vector) is a vector of zeros with a one in the lth place. We call Vil bidder i’s standalone valuation for object l, and let the L × 1 vector Vi ≡ (Vi1 , ..., ViL ) describe i’s standalone valuations over all L objects in the marketplace. We then define the 10 complementarity bidder i associates with outcome ω as the difference between i’s combinatorial valuation for ω and the sum of i’s standalone valuations for objects won in ω: Kiω ≡ Yiω − ω T Vi . Let Ki be the 2L ×1 vector describing i’s complementarities over all possible outcomes ω: Ki ≡ Yi − ΩVi . Note that Ki = 0 if and only if i’s preferences over outcomes are additively separable in the set of objects won. Marginal and combination probabilities Given our distinction between standalone valuations and complementarities, we will frequently wish to distinguish between the marginal and combination win probabilities generated by bid vector b. Toward this end, let P (b; σ−i ) be the 2L × 1 vector describing the probability distribution over outcomes arising when i submits bid b facing rival strategies σ−i , with P ω (b; σ−i ) the element of P (b; σ−i ) describing the probability of outcome ω. Similarly, let Γ(b; σ−i ) be the L × 1 vector describing marginal win probabilities arising when i submits bid vector b facing rival strategies σ−i , with Γl (b; σ−i ) the marginal probability i wins auction l. Note that Γ(b; σ−i ) is related to P (b; σ−i ) by Γ(b; σ−i ) = ΩT P (b; σ−i ). Furthermore, if ties are broken randomly across auctions then Γl (b; σ−i ) depends only on bid bl , and if ties occur with probability zero then Γl (b; σ−i ) is the c.d.f. of the maximum rival bid in auction l. 2.1 Best-response bidding As Milgrom (1999) and others have noted in the context of simultaneous ascending auctions, strategic analysis of bidder behavior in environments with complementarities is complicated enormously by the so-called “exposure problem” – when bids 11 are submitted auction by auction but preferences are defined over combinations, a rational bidder may ultimately regret winning the set of objects allocated to him at the prices he must pay. Put another way, the “message space” (Bi ⊂ RL ) permitted by the simultaneous first-price auction game is insufficient to allow bidders to fully L communicate their preferences (Yi ⊂ R2 ) over outcomes. This turns out to invalidate much classical intuition regarding bidding behavior; for instance, as we show below, a strict increase in type (y 0 > y in all elements) can yield a strict decrease in best-response bid (b0 < b in all elements). In this subsection, we explore what can (and cannot) be said about behavior in the simultaneous first-price auction model. Toward this end, consider the problem of bidder i with type realization yi competing against rivals who bid according to strategy profile σ−i . Conditional on winning outcome ω at bid vector b, i receives net payoff Yiω − ω T b, with the 2L × 1 vector yi − Ωb describing i’s net payoffs over all possible outcomes. Bidder i then chooses b ∈ Bi to maximize πi (b; σ−i ) ≡ (yi − Ωb)T P (b; σ−i ). Let vi be the standalone valuation vector corresponding to i’s type realization yi , and ki ≡ yi − Ωvi be i’s corresponding complementarities. Applying the identity Γ(b; σ−i ) = ΩT P (b; σ−i ), we can then rewrite πi (b; σ−i ) as follows: πi (b; σ−i ) = (yi − Ωb)T P (b; σ−i ) = (Ωvi − Ωb)T P (b; σ−i ) + kiT P (b; σ−i ) = (vi − b)T Γ(b; σ−i ) + kiT P (b; σ−i ). (1) Note that if i’s preferences over combinations are additive, then ki = 0 and (1) reduces to the standard separable form πi (b; σ−i ) = L X (vil − bl )Γl (bl ; σ−i ). l=1 So long as ties are broken independently across auctions, bids in one auction will then have no effect on payoffs in any other, and applying standard auction theory 12 auction-by-auction will characterize equilibrium in the overall bidding game. Robust predictions of best-response bidding As noted above, the “exposure problem” arising when preferences over combinations are not additively separable substantially complicates strategic analysis of the simultaneous first-price auction game. This problem is, if anything, more acute in simultaneous first price auctions than in simultaneous ascending auctions, since in the first-price case bidders cannot update bids as the auction proceeds. This in turn invalidates key predictions of the classical auction model such as monotonicity of best responses in types. Rather, applied to our setting, standard best-response arguments yield only the following (weak) “monotone probability” property: Lemma 1. Consider bidder i competing against rival strategy profile σ−i . Let y 0 and y 00 be any elements of Yi , and let b0 and b00 be any corresponding best responses by i to σ−i . Then (y 00 − y 0 ) · [P (b00 ; σ−i ) − P (b0 ; σ−i )] ≥ 0. In other words, under best-response bidding, P (·; σ−i ) must move in the same dotproduct direction as y. Proof. By definition of best responses, (y 0 − Ωb0 )T · P (b0 ; σ−i ) ≥ (y 0 − Ωb00 )T · P (b00 ; σ−i ) ⇔ y 0 · [P (b0 ; σ−i ) − P (b00 ; σ−i )] ≥ b0 · ΩT P (b0 ; σ−i ) − b00 · ΩT P (b00 ; σ−i ), and analogously y 00 · [P (b00 ; σ−i ) − P (b0 ; σ−i )] ≥ b00 · ΩT P (b00 ; σ−i ) − b0 · ΩT P (b0 ; σ−i ). Combining these last two inequalities yields the desired result. Observe that in contrast to the standard single-auction model, increases in a given element of P (b; σ−i ) could correspond to either increases or decreases in the elements of b. In other words, “monotonicity” of P (b; σ−i ) with respect to y (in the sense 13 defined above) says little about monotonicity of b with respect to y. For instance, suppose that bidder i’s type changes from y 0 to y 00 such that y 00 corresponds to a larger standalone valuation for object l. All else equal, bidder i would then wish to increase probability weight on the outcome “i wins object l alone.” But (in principle) bidder i could increase probability weight on this outcome either by increasing bid in auction l or by reducing bids in other auctions. In extreme cases, this in turn raises the possibility that best responses could be strictly decreasing in type: Example 1: Best responses can be strictly decreasing in type Consider the case of two bidders and two auctions. For bidder 1, 15 5 1 K (1,1) = − v1 − v2 + , 8 16 4 and (v1 , v2 )T ∈ {(0, 0)T , (0, 2)T , (2, 2)T }. That is, bidder 1 has types y 0 = (0, 0, 0, 54 )T , y 00 = (0, 0, 2, 11 )T , and y 000 = (0, 2, 2, 25 )T . 8 8 Suppose that bidder 2’s fixed strategy is to bid either in auction 1 (with probability 12 ) or in auction 2 (with probability 21 ), drawing bids from the uniform U [0; 1] distribution in either case. Bidder 1’s types correspond to the following profit functions: 1 1 1 1 π = −b1 · − · max{min{1, b2 }, 0} − b2 · − · max{min{1, b1 }, 0} 2 2 2 2 max{min{1, b1 }, 0} + max{min{1, b2 }, 0} 5 + ( − b1 − b2 ) · , 4 2 1 1 1 1 00 π = −b1 · − · max{min{1, b2 }, 0} + (2 − b2 ) · − · max{min{1, b1 }, 0} 2 2 2 2 11 max{min{1, b1 }, 0} + max{min{1, b2 }, 0} + ( − b1 − b 2 ) · 8 2 1 1 1 1 000 π = (2 − b1 ) · − · max{min{1, b2 }, 0} + (2 − b2 ) · − · max{min{1, b1 }, 0} 2 2 2 2 25 max{min{1, b1 }, 0} + max{min{1, b2 }, 0} + ( − b1 − b 2 ) · 8 2 0 14 T 3 T 1 1 T , and b000 = 16 , 16 , respecyielding best response bids b0 = 18 , 18 , b00 = 0, 16 tively. Ignoring the first component, which corresponds to the case of winning no auctions, we see that y 000 is strictly greater than y 0 . Thus a strict increase in type (from y 0 to y 000 ) can generate a strict decrease in i’s best response bid (from b0 to b000 ). This is what was to be shown. Monotonicity of bl in vl Obviously, a key feature driving the example above is that while moving from y 0 to y 000 increases the absolute utility i assigns to all outcomes, it also decreases the marginal change in payoff (i.e. complementarity) i assigns to the combination outcome “win 1 and 2 together.” This raises a natural followup question: holding ki and other elements of vi fixed, must an increase in vil (weakly) increase i’s best-response bid for object l? Applying Lemma 1, the answer turns out to be yes: Lemma 2. Let y 0 and y 00 be any elements of Yi such that vl00 > vl0 , vk00 = vk0 for k 6= l, and k 00 = k 0 . For any rival strategy profile σ−i , if b0 is a best response to σ−i at y 0 and b00 is a best response to σ−i at y 00 , then b00l ≥ b0l . Proof. Setting k = k 0 = k 00 , we have y 0 = Ωv 0 + k and y 00 = Ωv 00 + k. Hence applying Lemma 1, (y 00 − y 0 ) · [P (b00 ; σ−i ) − P (b0 ; σ−i ] = (Ωv 00 − Ωv 0 )T [P (b00 ; σ−i ) − P (b0 ; σ−i )] = (vl00 − vl0 ) [Γl (b00l ; σ−i ) − Γl (b0l ; σ−i )] ≥ 0. Thus vl00 > vl0 implies Γl (b00l ; σ−i ) ≥ Γl (b0l ; σ−i ). If Γl (b00l ; σ−i ) > Γl (b0l ; σ−i ), then we must have b00l > b0l since Γl (·; σ−i ) is weakly increasing in bl . Alternatively, if Γl (b00l ; σ−i ) = Γl (b0l ; σ−i ), then either b00l = b0l or b00l < b0l and Γl (·; σ−i ) is flat on an open interval below b0l . But in the latter case bidder i could slightly reduce b0l without changing the probability distribution over objects won, which contradicts the definition of best response. Hence we must have b00l ≥ b0l . Monotone cross-auction effects When does an increase in vl increase bestresponse bids in other auctions? The answer turns out to depend on a strong condi15 tion which we call supermodular complementarities: Definition 1 (Supermodular complementarities). For any Yi ∈ Yi and any outcomes ω1 , ω2 , Yiω1 ∧ω2 + Yiω1 ∨ω2 ≥ Yiω1 + Yiω2 , where ω1 ∧ ω2 denotes the meet of ω1 , ω2 and ω1 ∧ ω2 denotes the join of ω1 , ω2 . Note that this condition is substantially stronger than either of the following plausible but insufficient alternatives: • Positive complementarities: For all Yi ∈ Yi , Yi ≥ ΩVi , where Vi is the standalone valuation vector corresponding to Yi . • Superadditive complementarities: For all Yi ∈ Yi and any outcomes ω1 , ω2 , ω3 such that ω1 = ω2 + ω3 , Yiω1 ≥ Yiω2 + Yiω3 . While these conditions both reflect cases where bidder i wants to win objects “together”, they turn out to be insufficient for cross-auction monotonicity because they fail to provide enough structure on higher-order combinations. Hence it is not hard to construct examples satisfying both positive and superadditive complementarities in which an increase in vl decreases some bk .11 Supermodular complementarities turns out to be exactly the condition required to rule out such problematic cases, leading to the following result: Lemma 3. Suppose that Yi satisfies supermodular complementarities, and let y 0 and y 00 be any elements of Yi such that vl00 > vl0 , vk00 = vk0 for k 6= l, and k 00 = k 0 . For any rival strategy profile σ−i , if b0 is a best response to σ−i at y 0 and b00 is a best response to σ−i at y 00 , then b00 ≥ b0 . Proof. See Appendix. Two further comments are worth noting here. First, we have also explored conditions under which an increase in vl would necessarily lead to a decrease in bk for 11 For instance, a bidder could derive a positive complementarity from winning two objects together but no additional complementarity from winning three. This structure would be consistent with superadditive complementarities, but an increase in (say) v3 could lead bidder i to shift from bidding aggressively in auctions 1 and 2 to bidding aggressively in auctions 2 and 3. 16 some k 6= l. Not surprisingly, a sufficient condition for this turns out to be submodular complementarities, defined as above but with Yiω1 ∧ω2 + Yiω1 ∨ω2 ≤ Yiω1 + Yiω2 . Second, when L = 2, complementarities are supermodular or submodular as ki R 0. Hence if L = 2 then cross-auction effects have the same sign as ki : best-response b1 is increasing in v2 if ki > 0 and decreasing in v2 if ki < 0. 2.2 Existence of equilibrium One key message of Lemma 3 is that monotonicity of best responses in the simultaneous first-price auction game depends on strong (and in our view typically implausible) assumptions on the underlying preference space. Insofar as possible, therefore, we seek to analyze equilibrium existence without invoking monotonicity. Toward this end, we here consider two alternative approaches to establishing existence. First, following Milgrom and Weber (1985), we show that an equilibrium in pure strategies exists if the bid space Bi is discrete. Since in practice bids are virtually always specified up to some minimum currency unit, this in turn is sufficient to guarantee existence in virtually all applications. Second, building on Jackson, Simon, Swinkels and Zame (2002), we show that there exists an equilibrium in the “communication extension” of the simultaneous first-price auction game in which bidders send “cheap talk” signals which the auctioneer uses to break ties. If ties occur with probability zero, this in turn corresponds to a full equilibrium in distributional strategies. Existence with discrete bid space First suppose the bid space is discrete; e.g. bids can be specified up to a minimum increment of one cent. Then applying the arguments of Milgrom and Weber (1985) under Assumptions 1 and 2, we establish: Proposition 1 (Equilibrium with discrete bid space). If the bid space B = ×i Bi is discrete, then there exists a pure strategy Bayesian Nash Equilibrium of the simultaneous first-price auction game. If in addition complementarities are stable and supermodular, then there exists a pure strategy Bayesian Nash Equilibrium for any compact convex B. 17 Existence with endogenous tiebreaking Alternatively, consider any bid space L B, and let the outcome correspondence P : B → ∆2 describe the set of allocation rules permissible at bid profile b ∈ B. Following Jackson, Simon, Swinkels and Zame (2002), we define the communication extension of the simultaneous first-price auction game as the game that results when the auctioneer allows each bidder i to submit both a bid b ∈ Bi and a signal s ∈ Si ≡ Yi indicating his private type, where signals s1 , ..., sN may be used to break ties but are otherwise “cheap talk” in that conditional on allocation they have no effect on payoffs. Then applying Theorem 1 in Jackson, Simon, Swinkels and Zame (2002), we obtain the following result: Proposition 2 (Equilibrium with endogenous tiebreaking). There exists an equilibrium with endogenous tiebreaking in the communication extension of the simultaneous ∗ ) first-price auction game: that is, a profile of distributional strategies σ ∗ = (σ1∗ , ..., σN ∗ 2L and a tiebreaking rule p : S × B → ∆ selected from P such that bidders truthfully communicate types and σ ∗ represents an equilibrium given tiebreaking rule p∗ . If in at least one such equilibrium ties occur with probability zero, then there exists an equilibrium in distributional strategies in the original auction game. 3 An empirical framework for simultaneous firstprice auctions Having outlined the key building blocks of our structural model, we turn to the main objective of this paper – development of an empirical framework supporting structural analysis of simultaneous first-price auction markets. Toward this end, we assume the econometrician has access to a “typical” simultaneous first-price auction sample, interpreted as a sample of T auction rounds drawn from some stable underlying data generating process. In each round, the auctioneer offers Lt objects for auction to Nt bidders active in the marketplace (though in general not all bidders need be active in all auctions). Bidders then simultaneously submit sealed bids on the set of auctions in which they are active, with the set of bidders active in each 18 auction common knowledge to all participants.12 For each round t, we assume the econometrician observes data on all bidders i and auctions l present in the market. Asymptotic statements should be interpreted as applying when T → ∞. For each bidder i present at time t, let Sit be the set of auctions in which i bids at time t, with bit the corresponding vector of i’s bids. For each round t, the econometrician observes Sit , bit , and a vector of bidder-specific characteristics Zit for all bidders i active in the round; to simplify notation, we will adopt the convention that Zit includes Sit . For future reference, let Lit denote the cardinality of Sit , and define Zt ≡ (Z1t , ..., ZNt ,t ). Extending our theoretical model, we assume bidders’ private information is drawn independently conditional on Zt and the auction-related observables described below. Meanwhile, on the auction side, we partition the econometrician’s information into two sets of covariates. First, for each object l auctioned at time t, the econometrician observes a vector of covariates Xlt ; for future reference, we define Xt ≡ (X1t , ..., XLt ,t ). The econometrician may also observe a vector of market-level characteristics Wt taken to affect combinatoric valuations but not standalone valuations; we formalize this restriction in Assumption 4 below. In a highway procurement context, Xt would include factors like project size, project location, and type of work in each project, whereas Wt could include distance between projects, interaction between project sizes, and other factors assumed irrelevant for Vil after conditioning on Zit and Xlt . Note that our identification analysis permits Wt to be null. 3.1 Identifying assumptions Even cursory analysis of the simultaneous first-price problem suggests a major empirical obstacle: whereas in general the model could involve up to 2Lit − 1 unknown combinatoric valuations for a given bidder, the data generating process yields only Lit observed bids corresponding to these unobservables. To obtain a viable empirical model for simultaneous first-price auctions, it is therefore imperative to specialize 12 While we do not model entry formally here, our analysis can be readily extended to incorporate endogenous participation along the lines of Levin and Smith (1994) and Athey, Levin and Siera (2011)). We outline this extension in more detail below. 19 the model before taking it to data. Obviously, whether a given specialization is plausible will depend crucially on the problem at hand, and no one assumption is likely to be suitable for all applications. Since our main interest here is procurement, however, we here propose two restrictions on primitives which we find natural in many procurement contexts. As we go on to show, these turn out to be sufficient for non-parametric identification of primitives given data of the form above. We thereby provide a formal basis for empirical analysis of simultaneous bidding in a wide range of applications of practical and policy interest. To our knowledge this is the first such framework proposed in the literature, opening the door for empirical analysis of factors never previously explored. Assumption 3 (Stochastic Vi , stable Ki ). For all i and t, Kit = κi (Zt , Wt , Xt ), with Vit is distributed according to joint c.d.f. Fi (·|Zt , Wt , Xt ). Assumption 4 (Exclusion). Fi (·|Zt , Wt , Xt ) = Fi (·|Zit , Xt ) and κi (Zt , Wt , Xt ) = κi (Zit , Wt , Xt ). Assumption 3 says that complementarities are a stable function of bidder-, auction, and combination-specific observables. This assumption is motivated by our interpretation of Ki as a pure combination effect; i.e. an incremental cost or benefit derived from winning two objects together. We find this structure reasonable for applications such as procurement contracting, where bidders are obligated to perform all projects won. It would be less plausible in a setting like unit demand with resale, where the object ultimately resold would depend on i’s idiosyncratic preferences. Note that κi (·) can also be interpreted as an expectation over a combination-specific utility shock realized after a multiple win. Also, and importantly, Assumption 3 formally nests the hypothesis of additively separable preferences: κi (Zt , Wt , Xt ) = 0. Assumption 4 imposes two exclusion restrictions: own primitives Fi , κi are invariant to rival characteristics Z−it , and standalone valuations Vi are invariant to combination characteristics Wt given Zi , Xt . The former is widely invoked in the non-parametric auction literature (e.g. Haile, Hong and Shum (2003), Guerre, Perrigne and Vuong (2009), Somaini (2014)), while the latter formalizes the exclusion restriction underlying the definition of Wt . Note that the first part of Assumption 20 4 can be justified within a market-wide entry and bidding model along the lines Levin and Smith (1994); where, for instance, auction-level entry decisions depend on auction-specific entry cost draws, with realizations of Vi discovered after entry.13 In addition to the fundamental restrictions on primitives captured in Assumptions 3 and 4, we maintain two regularlity conditions on the underlying auction process: Assumption 5. In each letting t, observed bids are generated by play of an equilibrium with endogenous tiebreaking in the JSSZ communication extension to the simultaneous first-price auction game. Furthermore, for any t, t0 such that (Zt , Wt , Xt ) = (Zt0 , Wt0 , Xt0 ), the equilibrium played at t is the same as the equilibrium played at t0 . Assumption 6. For each (Zt , Wt , Xt ) ∈ Z × W × X and each bidder i active in letting t, the joint distribution of bids submitted by i is absolutely continuous. The assumption that a single equilibrium is played is widely invoked in the literature; see, e.g., Somaini (2014) and references therein. In light of our existence results, Assumption 5 formally interprets this equilibrium to be of the JSSZ type. Assumption 6 is a weak regularity condition on the observed distribution of bids which we expect to hold in any equilibrium such that bidders do not bid atoms. Note that when Ki = 0 any combination of strategies which would represent an equilibrium auction-by-auction will also be an equilibrium in the bidding game, and under standard regularity conditions (e.g. Assumption 1) strategies in any such equilibrium will satisfy the smoothness requirements in Assumption 1. Hence Assumption 6 is without loss of generality when Ki = 0, implying that all results below formally nest this hypothesis as a special case. 3.2 Non-parametric Identification Under Assumptions 3 and 4, model primitives are the distribution of standalone valuations Fi (·|Zit , Xt ) and the complementarity function κi (Zit , Wt , Xt ) for each bidder 13 In practice, we expect more flexible models of auction entry (e.g. Roberts and Sweeting (2013), Gentry and Li (2014)) to better reflect true participation decisions. Under the null hypothesis of zero complementarities, however, these will not help to rationalize the cross-auction bidding patterns noted below. We therefore focus on exogenous participation as a baseline, leaving detailed analysis of cross-auction entry for future research. 21 i. Taking i as given, the identification problem is thus to recover Fi (·|Zit , Xt ) and κi (Zit , Xt ) from observed bidding behavior. Let Gi (·|Zt , Wt , Xt ) be the c.d.f. of the joint distribution of the Lit × 1 bid vector bi submitted by bidder i at observables (Zt , Wt , Xt ); note that under Assumption 5 Gi (·|Zt , Wt , Xt ) is identified directly from observables for all i and t. Consistent with Assumption 1, we permit arbitrary correlation between elements of Vi , but assume vectors Vi , Vj are drawn independently across bidders; we relax this structure to accommodate auction-level unobserved heterogeneity below. Independence of Vi , Vj implies independence of bi , bj , so knowledge of G1 , ..., GNt is sufficient to characterize the joint distribution of all bids submitted by all bidders at time t. L Inverse Bid Function Let P−i (·|Zt , Wt , Xt ) : Bi → ∆2it be the probability distribution over outcomes facing bidder i at observables (Zt , Wt , Xt ) taking rival strategies as given, and Γ−i (·|Zt , Wt , Xt ) ≡ ΩT P−i (·|Zt , Wt , Xt ) be the Lit × 1 vector of marginal win probabilities corresponding to P−i (·|Zt , Wt , Xt ). Note that identification of G1 , ..., GNt implies identification of P−i , Γ−i for all i and (Zt , Wt , Xt ). Given any realization vi of Vi and any vector of complementarities Ki , we can therefore write the problem facing bidder i at observables (Zt , Wt , Xt ) in terms of directly identified objects as follows: max{(vi − b) · Γ−i (b|Zt , Wt , Xt ) + P−i (b|Wt , Zt , Xt )T Ki }. b∈Bi Temporarily suppose that i’s objective is differentiable at b∗ ∈ int(Bi ); we show below that under Assumption 6 this holds almost surely with respect to the measure on Bi induced by Gi . Then by hypothesis of equilibrium play, b∗ must satisfy necessary first-order conditions for an interior optimum: ∇b Γ−i (b∗ |Zt , Wt , Xt )(vi − b∗ ) = Γ−i (b∗ |Zt , Wt , Xt ) − ∇b P−i (b∗ |Wt , Zt , Xt )T Ki . (2) Note that these first order conditions do not require an equilibrium in pure strategies; they depend only on continuity of G1 , ..., GNt . Assumption 6 formally guarantees this 22 condition holds, but recall this is without loss of generality when Ki = 0. L Let Kit denote the following (2Lit − Lit − 1)-dimensional subspace of R2 it : Lit Kit = {k ∈ R2 : k1 = k2 = . . . = kLit +1 = 0}. That is, Kit contains 2Lit -dimensional vectors whose first Lit + 1 components are equal to zero. These zero components correspond to the cases of bidder i winning at most one object (ω = (0, . . . , 0) or ω 0 ω = 1). Taking Ki ∈ Kit as given, the first order conditions (2) generate for each b∗ ∈ int(Bi ) an Lit × 1 system of equations in the Lit × 1 vector of unknown standalone valuations vi . We now establish that this system may be inverted for vi at almost every bi submitted by i. Recall that Γ−i (b|Zt , Wt , Xt ) is an Lit × 1 vector whose lth element describes the probability that bid vector b wins auction l, and under Assumption 6 this is simply the probability that the maximum rival bid in auction l is below bl . Hence ∇b Γ−i (b|Zt , Wt , Xt ) will be a diagonal matrix with (l, l)th element given by the p.d.f. of the maximum rival bid in auction l. In equilibrium this p.d.f. must be positive at (almost) every b∗ ∈ int(Bi ), and again invoking Assumption 6 this will be (almost) every bid submitted. We therefore conclude: Proposition 3 (Inverse Bidding Function). Let K be any vector in Kit , (Z, W, X) be any realization in Z × W × X , and maintain Assumptions 1-6. Then for almost every bi drawn from Gi (·|Z, W, X), there exists a unique vector ṽ ∈ RLit satisfying the first-order system (2) at bi given (K; Z, W, X). This ṽ can be expressed in terms of bi via the inverse bidding function ṽ = ξi (bi |K; Z, W, X), where ξi (·|·; Z, W, X) : Bit × Kit → RLit is defined by ξi (b|K; Z, W, X) ≡ b + [∇b Γ−i (b|Z, W, X)]−1 × Γ−i (b|Z, W, X) − ∇b P−i (b|Z, W, X)T K , 23 (3) and the right-hand expression is identified up to K. Interpreted as a function of bi , ξi (bi |K; Z, W, B) describes the unique vector of candidate standalone valuations at which bi could be a best response under the hypothesis K = κi (Z, W, X). If in fact K = κi (Z, W, X), then under Assumptions 5 and 6 the first-order system (2) describes the true equilibrium bidding relationship and hence we must have vi = ξi (bi |K; Z, W, B) almost surely. Otherwise, there may or may not exist v rationalizing bi at K, but regardless ξi (bi |K; Zt , Wt , Bt ) will represent the unique candidate for vi at which bi satisfies first order necessary conditions for a best response.14 Note that at K = 0 the lth element of ξi (·) reduces to ξil (b|0; Zt , Wt , Xt ) = bil + Γ−i,l (bil |Zt , Wt , Xt ) ; dΓ−i,l (bil |Zt , Wt , Xt )/dbl i.e. the standard inverse bidding function of Guerre, Perrigne and Vuong (2000) defined auction by auction. Identifying restrictions We next apply Assumptions 3 and 4 to translate the inverse bidding relationship (3) into a system of identifying restrictions on model primitives κ and F . For ease of exposition, we suppress the subscript t in notation. First enforce Assumption 3: Ki = κi (Z, W, X) for all i. By Proposition 3, we then must have for almost every bi drawn from Gi (·|Z, W, X), vi = ξi (bi |κi (Z, W, X); Z, W, X). In practice, of course, κi (Z, W, X) is unknown. But for any vector K ∈ Kit , ξi (·|K; Z, W, X) becomes an identified map from bi to the unique vi consistent with bi under the hypothesis κi (Z, W, X) = K: vi = ξi (bi |K; Z, W, X) if κi (Z, W, X) = K. 14 (4) Obviously, imposing sufficient conditions for bi to be a best response – by, for instance, requiring second-order conditions to hold at ξ(bi |K; Zt , Wt , Bt ) – can only improve identification. 24 But recall that this relationship must hold for almost every bi in the support of Gi (·|Z, W, X). Under the hypothesis κi (Z, W, X) = K, Equation 4 thus implies a unique identified candidate F̃i (·|K; Z, W, X) for the unknown c.d.f. Fi (·|Z, W, X): Z 1[ξi (Bi |K; Z, W, X) ≤ v] Gi (dBi |Z, W, X). F̃i (v|K; Z, W, X) = (5) Bi Now enforce Assumption 4: κi (Z, W, X) = κi (Zi , W, X), Fi (·|Z, W, X) = Fi (·|Zi , X). Letting κ0 ≡ κi (Zi , W, X), we then must have for any (Z−i , W ): F̃i (·|κ0 ; Zi , Z−i , W, X) = Fi (·|Z, W, X) = Fi (·|Zi , X). (6) The right-hand side of this final expression is invariant to (Z−i , W ), with κ0 also invariant to Z−i . Holding (Zi , X) fixed, we thereby obtain two classes of identifying restrictions on the unknown function κi (·): the first induced by variation in Z−i and leading to the possibility of non-parametric identification, the second induced by W and leading to the possibility of semiparametric identification. We develop each of these in turn. Non-parametric identification of κi based on variation in Z−i To understand how variation in Z−i identifies κi (·), consider a simple two-auction example. Holding (Zi , W, X) fixed, define κ0 ≡ κi (Zi , W, X) as above. Starting from some initial 0 competition structure Z−i , let Z−i be the competition structure derived from Zi by adding one additional bidder to Auction 2. Then the marginal probability that i 0 wins Auction 1 will be similar at Z−i and Z−i , but the probability of the combination outcome “i wins both 1 and 2” will differ. Furthermore, under Assumption 4, this change in combination win probabilities is the only way changing Z−i matters for i’s strategy in Auction 1. Therefore to the extent that moving from competition 0 structure Z−i to competition structure Z−i matters for i’s behavior in Auction 1, 0 it can be only through κ0 ; if moving from Z−i to Z−i has no effect, then we must have κ0 = 0. The number of feasible “experiments” is limited only by the support of Z−i , with each experiment inducing a continuum of non-linear equations in the 25 finite vector κ0 . Under weak regularity conditions this system will have the unique (overdetermined) solution κ0 = κi (Zi , W, X). Noting that (Zi , W, X) is arbitrary, iteration of the argument then yields identification of κi (·) for any (Zi , W, X). We now formalize this intuition. By linearity of ξi (Bi |K; Z, W, X) in K, note that for any K ∈ Kit and any (Z, W, X) we can write EBi [ξi (Bi |K; Z, W, X)|Z, W, X] = Υi (Z, W, X) − Ψi (Z, W, X) · K, (7) where Υi (Z, W, X) is an identified Lit × 1 vector defined by Z Bi + ∇b Γ−i (Bi |Z, W, X)−1 Γ−i (Bi |Z, W, X) Gi (dBi |Z, W, X) Υi (Z, W, X) = Bi and Ψi (Z, W, X) is an identified Lit × 2Lit matrix defined by Z Ψi (Z, W, X) = ∇b Γ−i (Bi |Z, W, X)−1 ∇b P−i (Bi |Z, W, X)T Gi (dBi |Z, W, X). Bi Furthermore, by Equation (6) and invariance of Fi (·|Zi , X) in Z−i we must have for 0 : any Z−i , Z−i 0 EBi [ξ(Bi |κ0 ; Zi , Z−i , W, X)|Z, W, X] = EBi [ξ(Bi |κ0 ; Zi , Z−i , W, X)|Z 0 , W, X]. (8) Substituting (7) into (8), we thereby obtain an Li × 1 system of linear restrictions in the 2Li × 1 vector κ0 = κ(Zi , W, X): (Υi (Z, W, X) − Υi (Z 0 , W, X)) − (Ψi (Z, W, X) − Ψi (Z 0 , W, X)) · κ0 = 0. (9) 0 For a single Z−i , Z−i pair, this system will typically be rank-deficient and thus will not uniquely determine κ0 . But the underlying equality restriction must hold for 0 every Z−i , Z−i ∈ Z−i . Pooling these restrictions, we therefore conclude: Proposition 4. For any (Zi , W, X) ∈ Zi × W × X , suppose there exist vectors 26 Z−i,0 , Z−i,1 , ..., Z−i,J in the support of Z−i |Zi , W, X such that the JLi × 2Li matrix Ψi (Zi , Z−i,1 , W, X) − Ψi (Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X) .. MΨ ≡ . Ψi (Zi , Z−i,J , W, X) − Ψi (Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X) has full column rank when projected onto Kit . Then κi (Zi , W, X) is identified. Recall that the expectations criterion (8) exploits only equality of first moments of Fi (·|Zi , X) across Z−i , whereas the underlying invariance restriction (6) requires equality (and, under Assumption 1, finiteness) of all moments. The system of equations in Proposition 4 merely provides a simple and directly verifiable sufficient condition guaranteeing that the underlying system of functional identities has a unique solution. Note further that variation in, e.g., number of rivals in other auctions will produce exactly the kind of variation in Ψi needed for full column rank of MΨ : intuitively, changes in combination win probabilities relevant for cross-auction bidding only through κ0 . We thus view full column rank of MΨ as a weak regularity condition guaranteeing identification of model primitives. Parametric identification of κi based on variation in (Z−i , W ) While nonparametric identification is useful as an ideal, in applications we will typically wish to impose some parametric structure on κi (·). Toward this end, suppose that to the assumptions maintained above we add the hypothesis that κi (·) is of the form κi (Zi , W, X) = C̃i (Zi , W, X, θ0i ), (10) where C̃i (Zi , W, X, θ0i ) is a known transformation of (Zi , W, X, θ0i ), and θ0i ∈ Θi ⊂ Rpi . For simplicity, we consider the case when κi (Zi , W, X) is linear in parameters – that is, κi (Zi , W, X) = Ci (Zi , W, X)θ0i . Then Assumption 4 gives us that for any (Z, W, X), (Z 0 , W 0 , X) with Zi = Zi0 , Equation (8) reduces to the linear-in-parameters form (Υi − Υ0i ) − (Ψi Ci − Ψ0i C0i ) · θ0i = 0, 27 where Υi , Ψi , Ci are identified functions of (Z, W, X) and Υ0i , Ψ0i , C0i are identified functions of (Z 0 , W 0 , X). Given an appropriate collection of 0 , Wj0 , Xj )}Jj=1 , {(Zi,j , Z−i,j , Wj , Xj ), (Zi,j , Z−i,j we can then express θ0i as the solution to the following L2 -minimization problem min θ∈Θi J X Υij − Υ0ij − (Ψij Cij − Ψ0ij C0ij ) · θ T Υij − Υ0ij − (Ψij Cij − Ψ0ij C0ij ) · θ , j=1 (11) with identification of θ0i implied by a standard rank condition on the difference (Ψij Cij − Ψ0ij C0ij ) across j. Note that given {Υij , Υ0ij , Ψij , Ψ0ij }Jj=1 , the problem of finding θ0i reduces to intercept-free least squares of differences (Υij − Υ0ij ) on differences (Ψij Cij − Ψ0ij C0ij ) across j. The L2 -minimization problem described above can be written in an analogous 0 integral form if we consider all possible (Zi,j , Z−i,j , Wj , Xj ), (Zi,j , Z−i,j , Wj0 , Xj ) . Namely, the L2 criterion would have the form Z Z Z T (Υi − Υ0i − (Ψi Ci − Ψ0i C0i ) · θ) (Υi − Υ0i − (Ψi Ci − Ψ0i C0i ) · θ) 0 ,W 0 ) (Zi ,X) (Z−i ,W ) (Z−i 0 dFZ−i W (Z−i , W 0 |Zi , X) dFZ−i W (Z−i , W |Zi , X)dFZi X (Zi , X) This latter criterion will typically induce a richer set of restrictions on θ0i than will the discrete version above. Identification of Fi To complete the argument, it only remains to note that under Assumptions 3-6, identification of κi (Zi , W, X) for any (Zi , W, X) implies nonparametric identification of Fi (·|Zi , X) at (Zi , X): Fi (v|Zi , X) ≡ F̃i (v|κi (Zi , W, X); Z, W, X) for all (Zi , W, X), with F̃i (·|·; Z, W, X) a directly identified function of observables. The conditions above yield identification of κi (Zi , W, X) for arbitrary (Zi , W, X), from which we 28 conclude that Fi (·|Zi , X) is identified. 4 Application: Simultaneous Bidding in Michigan Highway Procurement As noted in the Introduction, simultaneous bidding arises in a wide variety of frequently studied procurement markets: for highway construction, snow clearing, recycling, cleaning, and offshore drilling among others. Our goal in the last section was to develop an empirical framework suitable for structural analysis across many such markets. As one illustration of the novel empirical insights made possible by this framework, we now turn to consider a particular application: the marketplace for Michigan Department of Transportation (MDOT) highway construction and maintenance contracts. As common in similar procurement contexts, MDOT allocates contracts for a wide range of highway construction and maintenance services via lowprice sealed-bid auctions. Contracts are auctioned across 15 to 20 “letting dates” per year, with multiple contracts auctioned on each letting date: an average of 33 per letting date across our sample period (2002-2009), with a maximum of 83 on a single date. More than half (56 percent) of bidders submit bids on multiple contracts within any given letting date, with a median of 3 and a mean of 3.96 contracts bid among bidders in this subset. Bids are submitted to MDOT auction by auction, with combination and contingent bidding explicitly forbidden by MDOT auction rules. Bidders may amend bids up to the letting date, but once announced letting results are legally binding, with winning bidders held liable for failure to complete contracts won (though they may subcontract up to 60 percent of contract work). The instutional framework of the MDOT auction marketplace thus closely parallels our simultaneous first-price structure, with factors like capacity constraints, subcontracting costs, project location, and project type inducing potential non-additivity in project payoffs. 29 4.1 Data and descriptive statistics MDOT provides detailed records on contracts auctioned, bids received, and letting outcomes on its letting website (http://www.michigan.gov/mdot). Building on these records, we observe data on (almost) all contracts auctioned by MDOT over the sample period October 2002 to March 2009.15 Our sample includes a total of 5532 auctions over X letting dates, where for each auction the following information is observed: project description, project location, prequalification requirements, the internal MDOT engineer’s estimate of the total cost of the project, and the list of participating firms and their bids. Based on this information, we classify projects into several project types, leading to a final distribution of projects across types summarized in Table 1. As evident from Table 1, roughly 60 percent of contracts are for road and bridge construction and maintenance broadly defined, with the remainder mainly for safety and other miscellaneous construction. The data contains information on a total of 629 unique bidders active in the MDOT marketplace over our sample period, which we subclassify by size and scope of activity as follows. We define “regular” bidders to be those who have submitted more than 100 bids in the sample period. This yields a total of 35 regular bidders in the sample, with all remaining bidders classified as “fringe”. For the subsample of regular bidders, we also collect data on number and location of plants by firm. This data is derived from a variety of sources: OneSource North America Business Browser, Dun and Bradstreet, Hoover’s, Yellowpages.com and firms’ websites. Based on this information, we further subclassify regular bidders as “large” or “small” by number of plants in Michigan, with “large” regular bidders defined as those with at least 6 plants. We thus obtain a final classification of 9 large regular bidders, 26 small regular bidders, and 594 fringe bidders in the MDOT marketplace. 4.1.1 Summary statistics Tables 2 and 3 summarize several key measures of market structure and bidder behavior. Table 2 surveys the auction side of the marketplace. The first key feature 15 For a small number of contracts MDOT records are incomplete. 30 Table 1: Summary of Projects by Type Contract Type New Construction Preventive Maintenance Resurfacing Road Reconstruction Road Rehabilitation Roadside Facilities Safety Traffic Operations Bridge Construction Bridge Reconstruction Bridge Rehabilitation Miscellaneous Frequency 0.46 12.00 14.99 9.07 7.70 6.42 11.28 6.12 0.36 11.37 3.58 16.65 emerging from this table is, not surprisingly, the large number of contracts auctioned simultaneously in the market: a mean of 33 per letting date across the whole letting date, with a maximum of 83 on a single letting date (note that smaller “supplements” lettings are occasionally held two or three weeks after the main letting in a given month). The number of bidders submitting bids on any given contract is small relative to the total number of bidders active in the marketplace, with about five bids per contract received on average across the sample (approximately 2.5 of these on average by regular bidders). For each contract, MDOT prepares an internal “Engineer’s Estimate” of expected procurement cost released to bidders before bidding; the log of this estimate is summarized in Table 2, with the dispersion in this measure indicating the substantial variation in size and complexity of projects in the marketplace (from tens of thousands to hundreds of millions of dollars if measured in levels rather than logs). The statistic “Money Left on the Table” measures the percent difference between lowest and second-lowest bids; on average this is 7.4 percent or roughly $112,000 per contract, suggesting the presence of substantial uncertainty in the marketplace. Finally, to provide a more complete picture of bidder activity, we also report data on project subcontracting. As evident from the last two rows of Table 2, this represents an important component of the MDOT auction 31 Table 2: Auction Level Summary Statistics Auctions per Round Bidders per Auction Large Bidders per Auction Medium Bidders per Auction Fringe Bidders per Auction Log Engineer’s Estimate Money Left on the Table Project Duration (in days) Fraction Sub-Contracted Sub-Contractors per Project Mean 33.279 4.893 0.900 1.563 2.520 14.296 0.074 119.808 0.153 2.985 St. Dev. 21.776 3.109 0.961 1.709 2.476 1.543 0.084 147.801 0.198 4.079 Min 1.000 1.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 9.482 0.000 6.000 0.000 0.000 Max 83.000 19.000 5.000 8.000 16.000 18.923 0.931 910.000 0.917 49.000 Table 3: Bidder Level Summary Statistics Bids by Round Bids by Round if Large Bids by Round if Small Participation Rate Participation Rate if Large Participation Rate if Small Mean 2.65 4.873 3.161 0.010 0.060 0.060 St. Dev. 2.45 1.283 0.583 0.023 0.068 0.034 Min 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.000 0.024 0.006 Max 26.000 26.000 17.000 0.242 0.242 0.127 marketplace, with approximately three subcontractors and 15 percent of contract value subcontracted on average. Table 3 reframes the auction-level participation variables in Table 2 to provide a clearer picture of bidder behavior in the MDOT auction marketplace. Again, the key pattern emerging from Table 3 is the prevalence of simultaneous bidding in MDOT procurement auctions, with the average bidder competing in roughly 2.5 auctions per round and regular bidders competing in substantially more (3.16 for small regular and 4.87 for large regular bidders respectively). Again note that number of bids submitted in any given auction is small relative to the number of bidders in the marketplace, with regular bidders competing in about six percent of total auctions on average. 32 Figure 1: Distribution of Simultaneous Bids Submitted 0.45 0.4 Fraction of Bidders in Sample 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 5 10 15 Number of Simultaneous Bids 20 25 As a graphical perspective on the scope of simultaneous bidding in the MDOT marketplace, Figure 1 plots the distribution of the number of bids by round submitted by all bidders in the sample. As evident from Figure 1, more than 55 percent of bidders in our sample submit multiple bids in the same round, with the median bidder in this subsample bidding on 3 contracts simultaneously. Despite this, it is uncommon for a representative bidder to compete in a large number of auctions; almost 90 percent of bidders in our sample bid in 5 or fewer auctions and only 2 percent bid in more than 10. Not surprisingly, the outliers in this respect are almost exclusively large regular bidders, although even these bid in fewer than 5 auctions on average. 4.1.2 Reduced-form regressions To assess the potential implications of simultaneous bidding on bidder behavior and auction outcomes, we first explore several simple reduced-form regressions. The 33 unit of analysis in these regressions is a bidder-auction-round combination, with the dependent variable log of bid submitted by bidder i in auction l in letting t. We regress log bids on a vector of regressors indended to capture effects of own-auction and cross-auction characteristics on i’s bid in auction l at time t. We describe these regressors in detail below. Note that for bidders competing in many auctions simultaneously there are a very large number of ways to measure potential crossauction effects, with effects potentially non-linear across combinations. To preserve transparency of the empirical specification, therefore, we focus on bidders competing in two or three auctions. Regression specification Based on prior work on highway contracting markets, we expect three auction-level characteristics to be of primary importance in determining i’s bid in auction l: the size of auction l, as proxied by the MDOT engineer’s estimate of expected project cost, the level of competition i faces in auction l, and the distance between project l and i’s base of operations. To control for the first two effects, we include log of engineer’s estimate and number of rivals in all regression specifications. Meanwhile, as a proxy for the third, we construct for each bidderproject pair the minimum straight-line distance (in miles) between any of i’s plants and the centroid of the county in which project l is located. We then control for the log of this distance in our baseline specifications. As elsewhere in the literature, we expect project costs to be increasing almost one-to-one in project size, aggressiveness to be increasing in competition, and project costs (to i) to be increasing in distance. We therefore expect a positive cost on log of distance to project, a negative coefficient on number of rivals, and a coefficient on log engineer’s estimate of close to one. To explore potential cross-auction interaction in the MDOT marketplace, we seek a set of covariates relevant for bidding in auction l only through κ: i.e. factors shifting combination payoffs but irrelevant for standalone valuations after conditioning on characteristics of auction l. We expect (at least) the following factors to be relevant in this respect: combination size (due to potential capacity effects), number of rivals in other auctions (shifts combination win probabilities), distance to alternative projects (as a proxy for substitution between auctions), and whether projects are of the same 34 type. We construct measures of each of these as follows. As one measure of bid effects due to cross-auction competition, we consider the average number of rivals across all auctions except l played by bidder i. The effects of cross-auction competition on strategies in auction l are theoretically ambiguous, depending both on the sign of κ and on strategic responses by bidders in both auctions. A priori, however, if κ is negative, we expect greater competition in auction j to increase marginal returns to winning auction l. To proxy for effects of combination size, we consider the log of the average engineer’s estimate across all auctions but l in which i is competing. Insofar as marginal costs to be increasing in capacity utilization (e.g. Jofret-Bonet and Pesendorfer (2003)), we expect the coefficients on this variable to be positive. In principle, complementarities arising between similar projects may differ from those arising between different projects. To allow for this possibility, we also consider log of average engineer’s estimates in other probjects of the same type, defined similarly to ln aeng other but only averaging across other projects of the same type as l. In principle, the sign of this effect could be either positive or negative, with a negative sign interpreted as a relative complementarity between projects of the same type. Finally, as an additional proxy for substitutability between projects, we define log of distance to the neareast other projects, measured as the log of the minimum distance (in miles) between bidder i and the nearest project other than l. Insofar as two projects close to i are more substitutable than two projects further away from i, we expect this variable to have a negative sign. Regression results Table 4 reports OLS estimates for our baseline regression specifications: logs bids by bidder, round, and auction on the own- and cross-auction characteristics defined above. All regression specifications include a full set of bidder type, project type, and letting date indicators, with standard errors clustered at the bidder-round level to allow for correlation within bidder i’s bids. Columns in Table 4 report results of this procedure for bidders competing in two auctions, three auctions, and either two or three auctions respectively. 35 Estimated effects of own-auction characteristics correspond closely both to our priors and to findings elsewhere in the literature. As expected, bids are increasing almost one for one in project size, with the coefficient on log engineer’s estimate exceeding 0.98 in all specifications. Similarly, the negative coefficient on number of rivals suggests that competition increases bidder aggressiveness, with one additional competitor associated with a 0.5 percent decrease in average bids. Finally, the coefficient on log distance to project suggests that a one percent increase in i’s distance from the project leads to about a 0.8 percent increase in i’s bid on average. More importantly, estimated cross-auction effects are also highly significant, with magnitudes stable across specifications and signs broadly consistent with our prior expectations. In particular, the positive coefficient on log of average engineer’s estimates in other auctions suggests that competing in a larger auction k leads to a substantial decrease in aggressiveness by bidder i in auction l, with the negative (though absolutely small) coefficient on log of average engineer’s estimates in other same-type projects suggesting that this effect is ameliorated slightly when the two projects are of the same type. Similarly, the coefficient on average number of rivals in other auctions suggests that facing more competition in auction k leads bidder i to bid less aggressively in auction l; while slightly surprising in light of our priors, this effect runs strongly counter to the standard separable model. Finally, the negative sign on log minimum distance to other projects indicates that increasing distance to project k makes project k less substitutable with auction l. While the latter effect is only significant at the 10 percent level, it corroborates the hypothesis that simultaneous bidding induces strategic spillovers. 4.2 Structural estimation Building on the identification results in Section 3.2, we now turn to consider structural estimation of the complementarity vector κ(·). In principle, the results in Section 3.2 support fully non-parametric estimation. In practice, of course, the dimensionality of the problem renders this infeasible. We therefore implement estimation of κ(·) in two steps. First, following Athey, Levin and Siera (2011) and Cantillon 36 Table 4: OLS Estimates of Cross-Auction Effects y = ln(bid) log of engineer’s estimate number of rivals in the auction log of minimum distance to the county centroid average number of rivals across all other auctions played log of average engineer’s estimate in all other auctions played log of average engineer’s estimate in all other same type auctions played L=2 L=2 L = {2, 3} L≥2 0.983*** (0.00364) -0.00577*** (0.00113) 0.983*** (0.00363) -0.00574*** (0.00113) 0.986*** (0.00253) -0.00582*** (0.000777) 0.980*** (0.00156) -0.00591*** (0.000488) 0.00959** (0.00373) 0.00960** (0.00373) 0.0127*** (0.00254) 0.0167*** (0.00168) 0.00229** (0.00109) 0.00224** (0.00109) 0.00294*** (0.000823) 0.00236*** (0.000621) 0.0156*** (0.00267) 0.0192* (0.0104) 0.0152*** (0.00234) 0.0162*** (0.00173) -0.00373*** (0.00109) -0.00373*** (0.00109) -0.00372*** (0.000844) -0.00312*** (0.000427) (log of average engineer’s estimate in all other auctions played)2 log of minimum distance to the nearest other project Constant Observations R-squared -0.000310 (0.000804) -0.00894** (0.00367) 0.0407 (0.0398) -0.00906** (0.00369) 0.0302 (0.0501) -0.0106*** (0.00301) 0.0226 (0.0294) -0.00702*** (0.00164) 0.0511** (0.0242) 4,193 0.974 4,193 0.974 7,946 0.972 22,359 0.973 Unit of analysis is bidder-auction-round, with standard errors clustered by bidder within each round. Variables log of engineer’s estimate, number of rivals in the auction and log of minimum distance to the county centroid measure size, strength of competition, and distance to project l respectively. Remaining variables proxy for cross-auction characteristics: average number of rivals, average engineer’s estimate, and distance to auctions other than l in which i is competing. 37 and Pesendorfer (2006) among others, we estimate a parametric approximation to the equilibrium distribution Gi of bids submitted by each bidder i appearing in bidder i’s problem. Second, we translate these estimates through the first-order condition (2) to obtain a minimum-distance criterion paralleling Equation (8). Under the auxiliary assumption that κ(·) is linear in parameters, the solution to this minimum-distance problem has a simple OLS closed form, with the resulting parameters yielding a minimum-distance estimator of the unknown function κ. As a first take on the problem of estimating κ, we focus on bidders competing in two simultaneous auctions. Our motivation for this is twofold. First, for the two-auction problem, the list of primitive-relevant characteristics is relatively clear, and the dimensionality of these is such that most can be explicitly conditioned on. Second, larger auction sets will require approximating a higher-dimensional joint distribution of bids, with cross-auction effects potentially non-monotone. This will require substantially more challenging tradeoffs between parsimony and flexibility, with (at present) little guidance on an appropriate technical balance. The twoauction case allows us to abstract somewhat from these challenging technical issues, thereby substantially increasing both transparency and credibility of the resulting estimates. Specification for Gi Building on our reduced-form analysis, we model i’s bid in auction l as depending on the following observables: i’s type, characteristics Xilt influencing i’s standalone valuation for contract l, characteristics Wilt relevant for i’s preferences over combinations involving auction l, competition in auction l, and competition in other auctions for which i is competing. As above, we use (log) number of rivals as a proxy for strength of competition in auction l, and (log) average number of rivals in other auctions where i bids as a proxy for strength of cross-auction competition. We describe construction of Xilt and Wilt in detail below. We follow Cantillon and Pesendorfer (2006) in specifying a joint log-normal approximation to the bid vector bi submitted by each bidder i. In particular, for bidder 38 i facing market structure (Zt , Wt , Xt ), we estimate the following first-step model: ln(bit ) ∼ MVN(·|µ(Zt , Wt , Xt ), Σ(Zt , Wt , Xt )). As typical in applications, we take µ(·) to be a linear function of observables: µ µilt = βDilt , µ is a subset of (Zt , Wt , Xt ) which includes the following elements: log engiwhere Dilt neer’s estimate for project l, log number of rivals in auction l, log sum of engineer’s estimates across other projects in which i bids, log number of rivals in i’s other auctions, an indicator for submitting multiple bids, and a constant term. We break our specification for Σ(Zt , Wt , Xt ) into two parts: one for the marginal variance σl2 (Zt , Wt , Xt ) of bilt , the other for correlations ρkl (Zt , Wt , Xt ) between bikt and bilt . In particular, for variance terms σl2 (Zt , Wt , Xt ) we specify σ σl2 (Zt , Wt , Xt ) = exp(αDilt ), and for correlation terms ρkl (Zt , Wt , Xt ) we specify ρkl (Zt , Wt , Xt ) = exp(γDitρkl − 1) exp(γDitρkl + 1) σ where Dilt and Ditρkl are known transformations of (Zt , Wt , Xt ). In our baseline specσ ification, Dilt includes log engineer’s estimate in auction l, log number of rivals in auction l, log sum of engineer’s estimate across other auctions, and log number of rivals across other auctions. Meanwhile, Ditρkl includes the product of log engineer’s estimates for pair kl, the product of number of rivals in pair kl, and indicators for projects of the same type and projects in the same county. 39 Specification for κ For the moment, we adopt the following simple linear specification for κ(·): for each outcome ω involving at least two projects, κω (Z, W, X) = θ01 + θ02 · ln sum eng ω , (12) where ln sum eng ω denotes the log sum of engineer’s estimates across projects won at ω. Note that in the L = 2 case (our main focus here) this reduces to a log sum of engineer’s estimates in auctions played by bidder i. Estimation algorithm Having specified κ to be linear in parameters θ0 , we implement estimation of θ0 based on L2 -type criterion (11) derived in Section 3.2. If all Γj , Γ0j , Ψj , Ψ0j , Cj , C0j in the criterion (11) were known or their consistent estimators were available, we could immediately obtain a θ̂ for θ0 by conducting least squares based on (11). To construct a criterion of the form (11), however, we must first resolve several practical issues: choosing a set of counterfactual quadruples 0 {(Zi,j , Z−i,j , Wj , Xj ), (Zi,j , Z−i,j , Wj0 , Xj )}Jj=1 at which to evaluate (11), accounting (1,1) in choice of these for the deterministic link between X1,j , X2,j and ln sum engj counterfactual quadruples, and simulation of the functions Υj , Υ0j , Ψj , Ψ0j at the counterfactual quadruples chosen. We address these implementation issues as follows. 0 , Wj0 , Xj )}Jj=1 First consider choice of the set of counterfactuals {(Zi,j , Z−i,j , Wj , Xj ), (Zi,j , Z−i,j at which to evaluate the criterion (11). In principle, any choice of such that “regressors” Ψj Cj − Ψ0j C0j in (11) satisfy a standard rank condition will be sufficient to construct an estimator for θ0 . In practice, however, we expect selections approximating the empirical distribution of (Z, W, X) to improve estimation performance. For the set of baseline points {(Zj , Wj , Xj )}Jj=1 in the criterion (11), we thus employ all realizations of (Z, W, X) in the subset of bidders with L = 2. For each (Zj , Wj , Xj ) in this collection, we then construct a counterfactual pair (Zj0 , Wj0 , Xj0 ) as follows. First, we randomly draw one auction within the pair; label this Auction 2 WLOG. For this auction, we then draw counterfactual realizations of the number of rivals and log engineer’s estimate from their empirical distributions among projects of the same type as Auction 2, holding all other characteristics fixed. We thereby 40 obtain a counterfactual point (Zj0 , Wj0 , Xj0 ) for comparison with (Zj , Wj , Xj ) in the criterion (11). Second, observe that in this construction drawing a new realization of Wj (size of combination) necessarily involves drawing a new realization of X2,j (size of project 2). We therefore consider estimation under the following slight strengthening of Assumption 4: Assumption 7. For all bidders i, auctions l, and rounds t, the marginal distribution of Vilt depends on Xt only through Xlt : Fl (·|Zi , X) = Fl (·|Zi , Xl ). In other words, standalone valuations in auction l depend only on characteristics 0 in auction l. Hence shifting from (Zj , Wj , Xj ) to (Zj0 , Wj0 , Xj0 ), where X1,j = X1,j but 0 X2,j and X2,j can be different, will give us the following equation: (Υ1,j − Υ01,j ) − (Ψ1,j Cj − Ψ01,j C0j ) · θ0 = 0, where Υ1,j denotes the first element of the L × 1 vector Υj , and Ψ1,j denotes the first row of the L × 2L matrix Ψj , and as above C(Z, W, X) denotes the transformation of observables entering linearly in κ.16 Applying the logic behind our system criterion (11), we thus obtain a final estimation criterion based on invariance of standalone valuations in Auction 1 only: θ0 = arg min θ Mj J X X 2 (m ) (m ) (m ) Υ1,j − Υ1,j j − Ψ1,j Cj − Ψ1,j j Cj j · θ . (13) j=1 mj =1 In general, when L is greater than 2, shifting from (Zj , Wj , Xj ) to (Zj0 , Wj0 , Xj0 ), where for some 0 l0 we have Xl,j = Xl,j for l 6= l0 but Xl0 ,j and Xl00 ,j can be different, gives us the following system of (L − 1) equations: 16 (Υ−l0 ,j − Υ0−l0 ,j ) − (Ψ−l0 ,j Cj − Ψ0−l0 ,j C0j ) · θ0 = 0, where Υ−l0 ,j denotes the (L − 1) × 1 vector obtained from the L × 1 vector Υj by eliminating the l0 -th component Υl0 ,j , and Ψ−l0 ,j denotes the (L − 1) × 2L matrix obtained from the L × 2L matrix Ψj by eliminating the l0 -th row. 41 (m ) (m ) (m ) we consider Mj counterfactual points Zj j , Wj j , Xj j the properties described above for (Zj0 , Wj0 , Xj0 ). The sim- Here, for each (Zj , Wj , Xj ) , mj = 1, . . . , Mj , that have plest case is when Mj = 1, j = 1, . . . , J. Finally, given the L2 -type criterion of the form (13), we need to simulate (Υj , Ψj ) (m ) (m ) (m ) (m ) (m ) and (Υj j , Ψj j ) for each (Zj , Wj , Xj ) and Zj j , Wj j , Xj j , mj = 1, . . . , Mj , compared. For a given realization (Z, W, X), we accomplish this in three steps. First, we draw a size-R random sample of bid vectors {bri }R r=1 from the joint distribution Ĝi (·|Z, W, X) implied by our first-step estimates for Gi . Next, for each realization bri of Bi , we compute corresponding realizations for Γi (bri |Z, W, X), ∇Γi (bri |Z, W, X), and ∇Pi (bri |Z, W, X) based on our first-step estimates for the bid distributions Ĝ1 (·|Z, W, X), . . . , ĜNt (·|Z, W, X) played by i’s rivals (with ∇Pi (bri |Z, W, X) approximated via finite differences). Finally, we approximate Ψ and Υ by averaging appropriate products of these functions across draws {bri }R r=1 : R 1X r Υ̂ = bi + ∇Γi (bri |Z, W, X)−1 Γi (bri |Z, W, X); R r=1 R 1X Ψ̂ = ∇Γi (bri |Z, W, X)−1 ∇Pi (bri |Z, W, X)T . R r=1 (m ) (m ) (m ) Repeating this procedure for each set of pairs (Zj , Wj , Xj ) and Zj j , Wj j , Xj j , mj = 1, . . . , Mj , appearing in (13), we ultimately obtain the simulated L2 -type criterion Mj J X 2 X (mj ) (mj ) (mj ) Υ̂1,j − Υ̂1,j − Ψ̂1,j Cj − Ψ̂1,j Cj ·θ . j=1 mj =1 The minimization of this criterion with respect to θ will yield a closed-form estimate θ̂ for θ0 expressed by the formula for the OLS estimator. Practically, however, firststep approximation error in Gi typically produces a small number of substantial outliers in estimated pseudo-values (typically two or three draws at each estimation iteration).17 To avoid undue influence of these obvious outliers on estimates of θ, we 17 More precisely, first-step approximation error in Gi leads to a small number of bid draws at 42 therefore implement estimation using Stata robust regression in place of simple OLS. 4.3 Estimation results We now report results from applying this structural estimation procedure in Section 4.2 to the sample of bidders competing in two simultaneous MDOT auctions. We first report results from our first-step estimation of bid distributions Gi for all bidders, then discuss estimates of κ(·) for the two-bidder sample derived from these through the algorithm outlined above. Estimates of Gi Table 5 reports results from first-step maximum likelihood estimation of i’s bid distribution Gi based on the log-normal approximation described in Section 4.2. As above, we subclassify these into effects on mean parameters µ(Z, W, X) and effects on variance parameters Σ(Z, W, X), with point estimates interpreted as follows. The first panel of Table 5 reports estimates β̂ for parameters β affecting mean parameters µ(·). Not surprisingly, these are qualitatively similar to those in our reduced-form specifications 4, with number of rivals increasing aggressiveness, size of other contracts decreasing aggressiveness, and a coefficient on log engineer’s estimate of approximately 0.98. The most notable differences is that number of rivals in other auctions now increases aggressiveness in auction l; while the model is theoretically ambiguous, this was our prior when auctions are substitutes. In the next two panels of Table 5, we present estimates for parameters in the variance-covariance matrix Σ(Z, W, X). Variance parameters (Panel 2) suggest that bidders facing more competition and competing in larger auctions submit less dispersed bids; while we have no strong priors on these effects, the direction seems natural. More interestingly, covariance parameters suggest several broad patterns in bidding across auctions. First, not surprisingly, bidder i bids relatively more similarly in similar auctions: i.e. in the same county and of the same type. Second, competing very large quantiles of the maximum rival bid. Since the equilibrium inverse bid function involves division by g−i (·), these in turn produce artificially large pseudo-values for virtually all choices of θ. 43 Table 5: First-Step MLE Estimates of Gi Mean µl β̂ MLE SEs 95% CI 0.00894 0.00101 0.00231 0.00161 0.00220 0.02155 0.18527 0.22030 0.97881 0.98277 -0.03268 -0.02364 0.00826 0.01458 -0.00938 -0.00075 -0.19198 -0.10749 α̂ MLE SEs 95% CI -1.03484 -0.19618 -0.26642 -0.02824 -0.10595 0.05439 0.00619 0.01848 0.00305 0.01309 γ̂ MLE SEs 95% CI 0.08874 0.03110 0.02260 0.53391 0.01542 0.50991 0.85777 0.24466 0.36658 0.14784 0.23643 -2.42973 -0.33682 -0.09286 -0.03241 Constant 0.20278 Log engineer’s estimate 0.98079 Log rivals in auction -0.02816 Log sum engineer’s (across l) 0.01142 Log sum rivals (across l) -0.00506 Multiple auction -0.14973 Variance σl Constant Log engineer’s estimate Log rivals in auction Log sum engineer’s (across l) Log sum rivals (across l) Covariance ρkl Constant 0.68384 Same county 0.30562 Same type 0.19214 Product of log engineer’s -1.38328 Product of log rivals -0.06264 -1.14144 -0.20831 -0.30265 -0.03422 -0.13160 -0.92823 -0.18404 -0.23020 -0.02225 -0.08029 in larger projects tends to decrease correlation in i’s bids. In other words, bidders competing in two large projects tend to compete in one relatively more aggressively than the other. We interpret this as consistent with the presence of increasing costs to multiple wins. Finally, stronger competition within the pair tends to decrease correlation in bids. Since more competition obliges bidder i to compete more aggressively, and thereby decrease markups conditional on winning, we again interpret this as consistent with substitution between projects. Estimates of κ Building on the first-step estimates in Table 5, we now apply the two-step algorithm outlined in Section 4.2 to obtain estimates of the structural pa44 rameters θ0 appearing in κ(·). As above, we focus on the sample of bidders competing in two auctions, with results interpreted as applying to this subsample. Expectations in the criterion (13) are simulated based on 30 draws from Gi (·|Z, W, X), where to reduce simulation noise we use the same latent random draws for both (Zj , Wj , Xj ) and (Zj0 , Wj0 , Xj0 ). Table 6 reports estimates θ̂ derived from this procedure. Results suggest that κ(W ) is characterized by a positive intercept (point estimate 110.29), with projects of the same type and projects with sum engineer’s estimates below 1000 having larger intercepts on average. As sum of engineer’s estimates increases, however, projects become more and more substitutable (point estimate -0.0503), with the small estimated quadratic effect failing to reverse this sign. The mean of sum engineer’s estimates in our two-auction sample is 2300, with a median of 1200 and a 90-10 range of [364, 5000] (units in all cases in thousands of dollars). Evaluating the coefficients in 6 at these values yields point estimates of κ(W ) = 0.42 at the mean and κ(W ) = 51.51 at the median of product sizes, with a range [108.66, −113.71] corresponding to the 90-10 range of sum engineer’s estimates. To interpret these numbers, first recall that in the MDOT marketplace bidder i is solving a low-price sealed bidding problem: max(b − vi )Γi (b|Z, W, X) + Pi (b|Z, W, X)T κ(Z, W, X), b The key source of private information in this problem is cost of contract completion, so a positive point estimate for κ(·) here implies lower cost, i.e. complementarity in the language of our model. The estimates in Table 6 thus suggest that bidders view small projects as complements but large projects as substitutes. While combination effects are approximately zero on average, they are substantially positive (approximately $51,000) at the median and substantially negative (approximately $-113,000) at the 90th percentile of project sizes. Our estimates thus suggest that a joint win leads to cost savings are roughly 4.25 percent of combination size at the median ($51,000 / $1,200,000), transitioning to cost increases of approximately 2.27 percent of combination size (-$113,000 / $5,000,000) at the 90th percentile. 45 Table 6: Estimates of θ0 , Two-Auction Subsample θ̂ SE Constant 110.29 90.14 Sum of EE -0.0503 0.0040 (Sum of EE)2 / 1000 0.0011 0.0003 (Sum of EE) ≤ 1000 16.34 6.03 Projects of same type 215.16 91.73 Units are in thousands of dollars, positive κ means higher cost. “Sum of EE” is sum of engineer’s estimates. Mean sum of EE is 2300, mean bid is 1180. Standard errors are not yet corrected for first-step and simulation error, hence are underestimated. Taken together, these numbers highlight both the potential importance of combinatorial preferences and the fact that these may differ qualitatively across both auctions and bidders. While declining complementarities between larger projects is natural and consistent with prior findings in the literature (e.g. Jofre-Bonet and Pesendorder (2003)), the changing sign of κ(·) is both novel and of considerable economic interest. We view this pattern as consistent with an underlying U-shaped cost curve, with average completion costs falling until firm resources are fully employed and rising substantially thereafter. 5 Conclusion Motivated by an institutional framework common in procurement applications, we develop and estimate a structural model of bidding in simultaneous first-price auctions, to our knowledge the first such in the literature. We first explore a general theoretical model of the simultaneous first-price problem, showing that sparsity of the “message space” relative to the preference space can substantially alter behavior in the bidding problem. We then specialize this theoretical model to an empirical 46 framework in which standalone valuations are stochastic but incremental preferences over combinations are stable functions of observables, establishing non-parametric identification of the resulting model under standard exclusion restrictions. Finally, we apply this framework to data on Michigan Department of Transportation highway construction and maintenance auctions, with preliminary results suggesting substantial complementarities between small projects and substantial substitution between large projects in this market. As our primary interest in this paper is simultaneity per se, we do not explicitly address dynamics in our structural bidding model. Under some simplifying assumptions, however, our results have a formal dynamic interpretation. In particular, suppose that dynamic aspects of bidder behavior are well-approximated by the Oblivious Equilibrium (OE) solution concept of Weintraub, Benkard, and Van Roy (2008): bidders forecast evolution of their own states in detail but form expectations over rival behavior based only on a long-run market average. Then estimates of κ(·) as we derive them above will formally capture both within- and across-period complementarities associated with winning each combination of auctions. In principle, we could then further decompose κ(·) into dynamic and static elements, but for purposes of our analysis here this is inessential; we primarily seek to assess implications of preferences over combinations on bidding behavior and auction outcomes, and at least within round t these are likely to be similar regardless of how such preferences arise.18 Note that the large number of projects auctioned in the MDOT market, the large number of bidders competing for these auctions, and the relatively low participation rates by even large bidders together suggest that market evolution will in fact be well-approximated by a long-run average. Thus while OE may not perfectly capture all aspects of strategic interaction over time, we find it a plausible representation in the application considered here. 18 Obviously, for predicting evolution of behavior across rounds a precise decomposition of κ(·) would be of first importance. 47 Appendix A: Complementarities depending on V In this appendix, we explore prospects for generalizing the conclusions in Sections 2 and 3 above to the case where complementarities are additively separable and/or affine functions of standalone valuations. Such a case could arise if, for instance, winning two auctions together increases i’s valuation for one or both objects by a fixed percentage. Notation and definitions Let el denote the L-dimensional lth unit vector. We say complementarities are additively separable in v if for each ω that contains at least two non-zero components (that is, ω T ω ≥ 2), the complementarity function is a function of the vector of standalone valuations v = (v1 , v2 , . . . , vL )T such that X K ω (v) = φl (vl ) + K̄ ω (14) l: ω T el =1 for some functions φl , l = 1, . . . , L. If each function φl (·) is linear in its argument vl , then we obtain the special case of complementarities affine in v: X K ω (v) = δ l vl + K̄ ω , if ω T ω ≥ 2. (15) l: ω T el =1 As usual, if ω contains at most one component equal to one (that is, ω T ω ≤ 1), then we set K ω (v) ≡ 0. An important special case of (15) is when all δ l are identical and K̄ ω = 0 for any ω. This case describes the situation of a constant relative complementarity – that is, when K ω (v) is a constant ratio of the additive valuation. Now assume that complementarities are affine in v, and define an L × 1 vector δ and an L × L matrix D(δ) as follows: δ ≡ (δ 1 , δ 2 , . . . , δ L )T D(δ) ≡ diag(δ 1 , δ 2 , . . . , δ L ). Let A denote the 2L × 2L matrix such that its (2L − L − 1) × (2L − L − 1) submatrix (aij )i,j=L+2,...,2L coincides with the identity matrix of size 2L − L − 1, with all the other elements of A are 0. We then have K(v) = AΩD(δ)v + K̄, where K̄ denotes the 2L × 1 vector of constant components K̄ ω in the functions of complementarities. Clearly, the first L + 1 elements in K̄ are zero since they correspond to the cases of ω such that ω T ω ≤ 1. 48 Monotonicity of best responses Analysis of own- and cross-auction monotonicity becomes much more complex when we try to extend the results of Lemma 2 to more general forms of complementarities. Consider the case of affine complementarities. Suppose that v 00 and v 0 differ only in the l’s component, and that the collection {K̄ ω } is fixed. Then, using techniques similar to the ones in the proof of Lemma 2 we can show that for any rival strategy profile σ−i , if b0 is a best response to σ−i at v 0 and b00 is a best response to σ−i at v 00 , then (1 + δ l )(vl00 − vl0 ) Γl (b00l ; σ−i ) − Γl (b0l ; σ−i ) ≥ δ l (vl00 − vl0 ) P el (b00 ; σ−i ) − P el (b0 ; σ−i ) . The right-hand side of this inequality contains the probability of winning auction l only and, thus, depends on the whole vectors of best responses b0 and b00 rather than just their l’s components. Not much can be inferred from this inequality, even though some results can still be obtained. Suppose that vl00 > vl0 . If −1 < δ l < 0 and if the best response in auction l decreases – that is, b00l < b0l , – then at least for one other component m 6= l the best response decreases too – that is, b00m < b0m . The inequality can be rewritten as X P ω (b00 ; σ−i ) − P ω (b0 ; σ−i ) . Γl (b00l ; σ−i ) − Γl (b0l ; σ−i ) ≥ −δ l ω: ω T el =1, ω T ω≥2 Alternatively, suppose that δ l > 0. Then b00l < b0l implies that at least for one other component m 6= l it holds that b00m > b0m . Example 2 below illustrates that with affine complementarities it is possible to have situations when a strict increase in vl with other standalone valuations unchanged can produce a strict decrease in bl . Example 2. Consider the case of two bidders and two auctions. For bidder 1, 1 7 11 K (1,1) = − v1 − v2 + , 8 6 4 T 00 and (v1 , v2 )T ∈ {(0, 0)T , (0, 2)T }. That is, bidder 1 has types y 0 = (0, 0, 0, 11 4 ) and y = 29 T (0, 0, 2, 12 ) . Suppose that bidder 2’s fixed strategy is to bid either in auction 1 (with probability 12 ) or in auction 2 (with probability 12 ), drawing bids from the uniform U [0; 1] distribution in either case. 49 Bidder 1’s types correspond to the following profit functions: 1 1 1 1 0 π = −b1 · − · max{min{1, b2 }, 0} − b2 · − · max{min{1, b1 }, 0} 2 2 2 2 max{min{1, b1 }, 0} + max{min{1, b2 }, 0} 11 + − b1 − b2 · , 4 2 1 1 1 1 00 − · max{min{1, b2 }, 0} + (2 − b2 ) · − · max{min{1, b1 }, 0} π = −b1 · 2 2 2 2 max{min{1, b1 }, 0} + max{min{1, b2 }, 0} 29 + − b1 − b2 · 12 2 T 17 T yielding best response bids b0 = 78 , 78 and b00 = 0, 24 . Thus, even though v2 increases and v1 remains fixed, the best response in auction 2 decreases. Notice that y 00 is not greater than y 0 (in the component-wise sense) as the last component in y 00 is strictly smaller than that in y 0 . Such a situation was impossible in the case of constant complementarities because there an increase in one standalone valuation vl weakly increased the 2L -vector of valuations y and, moreover, for the components of y that increased strictly the changes were identical and equal to (vl00 − vl0 ). Now the change is equal to (vl00 − vl0 ) for ω = el and is equal to (1 + δ l )(vl00 − vl0 ) for any ω such that ω T el = 1 and ω T ω ≥ 2. These changes will even be of different signs if δ l < −1, as was illustrated in this example. The lemma below considers additively separable complementarities in the form of (14) and shows that the supermodularity condition for these complementarities is satisfied if and only if it is satisfied for their constant components K̄ ω . Lemma 4. Let complementarities be defined as in (14). Then for any outcomes ω1 , ω2 , Yiω1 ∧ω2 + Yiω1 ∨ω2 − Yiω1 − Yiω2 = K̄ ω1 ∧ω2 + K̄ ω1 ∨ω2 − K̄ ω1 − K̄ ω2 . (16) Hence, complementarities are supermodular if and only if K̄ ω1 ∧ω2 + K̄ ω1 ∨ω2 ≥ K̄ ω1 + K̄ ω2 . Proof. See Appendix B. Equation (16) and the fact that its the right-hand side does not depend on standalone valuations allows us to generalize the result of Lemma 3 to the case of additively separable complementarity functions. Lemma 5. Suppose complementarities are defined as in (14) and are supermodular. Suppose that the vectors v 00 and v 0 of standalone valuations are such that vl00 > vl0 , vk00 = vk0 for k 6= l. For any rival strategy profile σ−i , if b0 is a best response to σ−i at the corresponding y 0 and b00 is a best response to σ−i at the corresponding y 00 , then b00 ≥ b0 . 50 Non-parametric identification Our next step is to generalize the non-parametric identification result above to the case when complementarities are affine functions of standalone valuations. Namely, for a given subset ω containing at least two elements, X δ l (Zi , W, X)vi,l + K̄ ω (Zi , W, X). K ω = K ω (vi , Zi , W, X) = l: ω T el =1 When ω T ω ≤ 1, the complementarity is set to 0. As can be seen, the functional form of complementarities does not depend on Z−i . As we show below, under weak conditions there is enough variation in Z−i | Zi , W, X to determine the linear (in vi,l ) part of complementarities as well as the constant part. Define the Li × 1 vector δ(Zi , W, X) as δ(Zi , W, X) = (δ 1 (Zi , W, X), δ 2 (Zi , W, X), . . . , δ Li (Zi , W, X))T , and the D(δ(Zi , W, X)) as the Li × Li matrix D(δ(Zi , W, X)) = diag(δ 1 (Zi , W, X), δ 2 (Zi , W, X), . . . , δ Li (Zi , W, X)). Then K(vi , Zi , X) = Ai Ωi D(δ(Zi , W, X))vi + K̄(Zi , W, X), where K̄(Zi , W, X) denotes the 2Li × 1 vector of constant components in the complementarities (obviously, K̄(Zi , W, X) ∈ Ki ). Matrix Ai denotes the 2Li × 2Li matrix such that its (2Li − Li − 1) × (2Li − Li − 1) submatrix (aij )i,j=Li +2,...,2Li coincides with the identity matrix of size 2Li − Li − 1, and all the other elements of Ai are 0. Clearly, the rank of matrix Ai Ωi is equal to Li . Using the first-order condition and taking into account the form of K(vi , Zi , W, X), obtain vi = bi + [∇b Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X)]−1 Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X) − [∇b Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X)]−1 ∇b P−i (bi |Z, W, X)T Ai Ωi D(δ(Zi , W, X))vi + K̄(Zi , W, X) , where, as before, Z = (Zi , Z−i ). Denote Π(bi , δ, Z, W, X) = ILi + [∇b Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X)]−1 ∇b P−i (bi |Z, W, X)T Ai Ωi D(δ). For given Zi , Z−i , W and X, define ∆(Zi , Z−i , W, X) as the set of δ ∈ <Li such that Π(bi , δ, Z, W, X) is non-singular for almost all bi . 51 E.g., ∆(Zi , Z−i , W, X) 3 0. If δ = δ(Zi , W, X) ∈ ∆(Zi , Z−i , W, X), then vi = Π(bi , δ(Zi , W, X), Z, W, X)−1 bi + Π(bi , δ(Zi , W, X), Z, W, X)−1 [∇b Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X)]−1 Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X) − Π(bi , δ(Zi , W, X), Z, W, X)−1 [∇b Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X)]−1 ∇b P−i (bi |Z, W, X)T K̄(Zi , W, X). Assuming that δ =∈ ∆(Zi , Z−i , W, X), let us denote D1 (δ, Zi , Z−i , W, X) = EBi Π(Bi , δ, Z, W, X)−1 Bi Z, W, X h i + EBi Π(Bi , δ, Z, W, X)−1 [∇b Γ−i (Bi |Z, W, X)]−1 Γ−i (Bi |Z, W, X)Z, W, X , h i D2 (δ, Zi , Z−i , W, X) = EBi Π(Bi , δ, Z, W, X)−1 [∇b Γ−i (Bi |Z, W, X)]−1 ∇b P−i (Bi |Z, W, X)T Z, W, X , 0 from the support of Z |Z , W, X, Keeping Zi , W, X fixed, let us draw another value Z−i −i i 0 ). Due to the assumptions made on the distribution of the and denote Z 0 = (Zi , Z−i standalone valuations, E[Vi |Z, W, X] = E[Vi |Z 0 , W, X]. Therefore, for δ = δ(Zi , W, X) ∈ 0 , W, X), ∆(Zi , Z−i , W, X) ∩ ∆(Zi , Z−i 0 D1 (δ(Zi , W, X), Zi , Z−i , W, X) − D1 (δ(Zi , W, X), Zi , Z−i , W, X) = 0 D2 (δ(Zi , W, X), Zi , Z−i , W, X) − D2 (δ(Zi , W, X), Zi , Z−i , W, X) K̄(Zi , W, X). For fixed Zi , W, X, this system has 2Li − 1 unknowns (Li in δ(Zi , W, X) and 2Li − Li − 1 in K̄(Zi , W, X)) and Li equations. This gives us the following result. Proposition 5. Suppose that for (Zi , W, X) ∈ Zi × W × X , there exist J + 1 ≥ (2Li − 1)/Li + 1 vectors Z−i,0 , Z−i,1 , ..., Z−i,J in the support of Z−i |Zi , W, X such that there is a T unique δ ∈ Jj=0 ∆(Zi , Z−i,j , W, X) and a unique κ ∈ Ki that solve the system of J · Li equations D1 (δ, Zi , Z−i,j , W, X) − D1 (δ, Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X) = (D2 (δ, Zi , Z−i,j , W, X) − D2 (δ, Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X)) κ, j = 1, . . . , J. (17) Then the values of δ(Zi , W, X) and K̄(Zi , W, X) are identified, and thus, the complementarity function is identified for these values of Zi , W , X. T System (17) is non-linear in δ. However, for each fixed δ ∈ Jj=0 ∆(Zi , Z−i,j , W, X), this system is linear in κ. Proposition 5 implies that in the case of identification it is not possible TJ to have a situation when for different δ1 and δ2 , where δ1 , δ2 ∈ j=0 ∆(Zi , Z−i,j , W, X), system (17) has solutions κ1 ∈ Ki and κ2 ∈ Ki , respectively. Thus, in this sense the question of identification of δ(Zi , W, X) and K̄(Zi , W, X) comes down to the question of existence of solutions to systems of linear equations: (17) can have a solution κ for one 52 δ only, and for that δ it has to be unique. Using the Kronecker-Capelli theorem, which gives the necessary and sufficient conditions for the existence of a solution to a system of linear equations, and also the necessary and sufficient conditions for the uniqueness of such a solution, we formulate the identification result in the Proposition 6 below. Before we proceed to Proposition 6, let Ei denote the 2Li × (2Li − Li − 1) matrix such that its (2Li − Li − 1) × (2Li − Li − 1) submatrix (ẽij )i=Li +2,...,2Li , j=1,...,2Li −li −1 coincides with the identity matrix of size 2Li − Li − 1, and all its other elements (that is, all the elements in the first Li + 1 rows) are equal to zero. For every κ ∈ Ki there is a unique L κ̌ ∈ R2 i −Li −1 such that κ = Ei κ̌. Obviously, this κ̌ is formed by the last 2Li − Li − 1 values in κ. System (17) can be equivalently written as D1 (δ, Zi , Z−i,j , W, X) − D1 (δ, Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X) = ((D2 (δ, Zi , Z−i,j , W, X) − D2 (δ, Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X)) Ei ) κ̌, j = 1, . . . , J, (18) L with κ̌ ∈ R2 i −Li −1 . For a fixed δ, system (17) is linear in κ, has the J · Li × 2Li matrix of coefficients, and imposes restrictions on the solution κ by requiring that κ ∈ Ki . Its equivalent representation (18) is linear in κ̌ for a fixed δ, has the J · Li × (2Li − Li − 1) L matrix of coefficients, and does not impose any restrictions on the solution κ̌ ∈ R2 i −Li −1 . This allows us to apply the Kronecker-Capelli theorem to system (18) in a straightforward way. Proposition 6. Suppose that for (Zi , W, X) ∈ Zi × W × X , there exist J + 1 ≥ (2Li − 1)/Li + 1 vectors Z−i,0 , Z−i,1 , ..., Z−i,J in the support of Z−i |Zi , W, X such that there is a T unique δ ∈ Jj=0 ∆(Zi , Z−i,j , W, X) that satisfies the following two conditions: 1. First, rank ([M1 (δ, Zi , W, X) | M2 (δ, Zi , W, X)]) = rank (M2 (δ, Zi , W, X)) , where M2 (δ, Zi , W, X) denotes the J · Li × (2Li − Li − 1) matrix (D2 (δ, Zi , Z−i,1 , W, X) − D2 (δ, Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X)) Ei .. M2 (δ, Zi , W, X) ≡ , . (D2 (δ, Zi , Z−i,J , W, X) − D2 (δ, Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X)) Ei 53 (19) and M1 (δ, Zi , W, X) denotes the J · Li × 1 vector D1 (δ, Zi , Z−i,1 , W, X) − D1 (δ, Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X) .. M1 (δ, Zi , W, X) ≡ . . D1 (δ, Zi , Z−i,J , W, X) − D1 (δ, Zi , Z−i,0 , W, X) 2. Moreover, this δ is such that M2 (δ, Zi , W, X) has full column rank: rank (M2 (δ, Zi , W, X)) = 2Li − Li − 1. (20) Then the values of δ(Zi , W, X) and K̄(Zi , W, X) are identified, and thus, the complementarity function is identified for these values of Zi , W , X. Condition (19) requires that in system (18), the rank of the matrix of coefficients M2 (δ, Zi , W, X) is equal to the rank of the augmented matrix [M1 (δ, Zi , W, X) | M2 (δ, Zi , W, X)] for one δ only. The Kronecker-Capelli theorem guarantees then that (18) has a solution κ̌ for that δ only. Condition (20) then guarantees this κ̌ is determined uniquely, and, thus, κ = Ei κ̌ is determined uniquely. Note that all the identification conditions in Proposition 6 are formulated in terms of δ. The closed form for δ(Zi , W, X) cannot be found but in practice one can find δ(Zi , W, X) and K̄(Zi , W, X) by solving, e.g., the following optimization problem: min T 2Li −Li −1 δ∈ J j=0 ∆(Zi ,Z−i,j ,W,X), κ̌∈R Q(δ, κ̌, Zi , W, X), where Q(δ, κ̌, Zi , W, X) ≡ (M1 (δ, Zi , W, X) − M2 (δ, Zi , W, X)κ̌)T (M1 (δ, Zi , W, X) − M2 (δ, Zi , W, X)κ̌) . Appendix B: Proofs Proof of Lemma 3. Suppose that K satisfies supermodular complementarities, and let b0 ,b00 l be the (N − 1) × 1 vector of rival bids in auction l, be any two feasible bids. LetPB−i l 10 L0 0 B−i = (B−i , ..., B−i ) be the ( Nl − l) × 1 vector of all rival bids across all auctions, and G−i (B−i ; s−i ) be the joint distribution of B−i given strategies σ−i . Let k(b; B−i ) be player i’s expected complementarity given own bid vector b and the complete rival bid vector B−i : k(b; B−i ) = Eω [K ω |b, B−i ]. The expectation here is over ties; otherwise, bidder i will win each auction in which his bid is the highest, ω = ω(b, B−i ) will be deterministic, and k(b; B−i ) = K ω(b,B−i ) . Note that 54 K T P (b) is the expectation of k(b; B−i ) with respect to G−i (·): K T P (b) = Eω [K ω |b] = EB−i [Eω [K ω |b, B−i ]] Z = k(b; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ). We next show that K T P (b) is supermodular in b. By definition, K T P (b) is supermodular in b if for all b0 , b00 we have K T P (b00 ∨ b0 ) + K T p(b00 ∧ b0 ) ≥ K T p(b00 ) + K T p(b0 ), where b00 ∨ b0 and b00 ∧ b0 denote the meet and join of (b0 , b00 ) respectively. Obviously, if b00 ≥ b0 , then b00 ∨ b0 = b00 and b00 ∧ b0 = b0 , so the inequality holds trivially (and likewise if b0 ≥ b00 ). Thus suppose that the vectors are not ordered: i.e. that b00 b0 and b0 b00 . Now rewrite the supermodularity condition in terms of the integrals above: Z 00 0 Z k(b ∨ b ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ) + k(b00 ∧ b0 ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ) Z Z 00 ≥ k(b ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ) + k(b00 ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ). Rearranging terms yields the equivalent integral expression Z 00 k(b ∨ b0 ; B−i ) + k(b00 ∧ b0 ; B−i ) − k(b00 ; B−i ) − k(b0 ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ) ≥ 0. (21) In the case of no ties for (b00 ∨ b0 ; B−i ), (b00 ∧ b0 ; B−i ), (b00 ; B−i ) and (b0 ; B−i ), we have ω(b00 ∨ b0 ; B−i ) = ω(b0 ; B−i ) ∨ ω(b00 ; B−i ), ω(b00 ∧ b0 ; B−i ) = ω(b0 ; B−i ) ∧ ω(b00 ; B−i ), and thus, by the supermodularity of K, k(b00 ∨ b0 ; B−i ) − k(b00 ; B−i ) − k(b0 ; B−i ) − k(b00 ∧ b0 ; B−i ) ≥ 0. If for b00 ∨ b0 , b00 ∧ b0 , b00 and b0 , ties occur with probability zero (with respect to the distribution G−i (·) of B−i ), then the last inequality implies (21). Thus, supermodular K implies supermodularity of K T P (b) in b. To complete the argument, note that supermodularity of K T P (b) implies that an increase in any element of b will weakly increase marginal returns to other elements of b. We know from Lemma 2 that an increase in vl will weakly increase bl , and by supermodularity 55 of K T p(b) this will also increase bids in other auctions. This establishes the claim. Proof of Lemma 4. Note that X Yiω1 ∧ω2 + Yiω1 ∨ω2 = X (vl + φl (vl )) + K̄ ω1 ∧ω2 + l: (ω1 ∨ω2 )T el =1 l: (ω1 ∧ω2 )T el =1 X = l: ω1T el =1, (vl + φl (vl )) + K̄ ω1 ∨ω2 X (vl + φl (vl )) + ω2T el =0 l: ω2T el =1, X (vl + φl (vl )) + 2 (vl + φl (vl )) l: (ω1 ∧ω2 )T el =1 ω2T el =0 + K̄ ω1 ∧ω2 + K̄ ω1 ∨ω2 . Also, Yiω1 + Yiω2 = X l: ω1T el =1 X + X (vl + φl (vl )) + K̄ ω1 + l: ω2T el =1 X (vl + φl (vl )) + 2 l: ω2T el =1, ω1T el =0 X (vl + φl (vl )) + K̄ ω2 = (vl + φl (vl ))+ l: ω1T el =1, ω2T el =0 (vl + φl (vl )) + K̄ ω1 + K̄ ω2 . l: (ω1 ∧ω2 )T el =1 The result follows. Proof of Lemma 5. Analogously to the proof of Lemma 3, for player i’s given vector of standalone valuations v, own bid vector b and the complete rival bid vector B−i , consider the expected complementarity k(v, b; B−i ) = Eω [K ω (v)|v, b, B−i ]. As in the proof of Lemma 3, the expectation here is over ties. Note that K(v)T P (b) is the expectation of k(v, b; B−i ) with respect to G−i (·): Z K(v)T P (b) = Eω [K ω (v)|v, b] = EB−i [Eω [K ω (v)|v, b, B−i ]] = k(v, b; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ). Let b0 and b00 be any two feasible bid vectors. Let us establish that K(v)T P (b) is supermodular in b, that is, for a given v, K(v)T P (b00 ∨ b0 ) + K(v)T p(b00 ∧ b0 ) ≥ K(v)T p(b00 ) + K(v)T p(b0 ). 56 This supermodularity condition van be rewritten as Z Z k(v, b00 ∨ b0 ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ) + k(v, b00 ∧ b0 ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ) Z Z ≥ k(v, b00 ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ) + k(v, b00 ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ), or equivalently, as Z k(v, b00 ∨ b0 ; B−i ) + k(v, b00 ∧ b0 ; B−i ) − k(v, b00 ; B−i ) − k(v, b0 ; B−i ) dG−i (B−i ) ≥ 0. In the case of no ties for 4 we have that (b00 ∨b0 ; B−i ), (b00 ∧b0 ; B −i ), (b00 ; B −i ) and (b0 ; B (22) −i ), from Lemma k(v, b00 ∨ b0 ; B−i ) + k(v, b00 ∧ b0 ; B−i ) − k(v, b00 ; B−i ) − k(v, b0 ; B−i ) = K̄ ω(b 0 00 ∨b0 ;B ) −i = K̄ ω(b ;B−i )∨ω(b + K̄ ω(b 00 ;B ) −i 00 ∧b0 ;B −i ) 0 0 00 ;B ) −i − K̄ ω(b ;B−i ) − K̄ ω(b + K̄ ω(b ;B−i )∧ω(b 00 ;B ) −i 0 − K̄ ω(b ;B−i ) − K̄ ω(b 00 ;B ) −i ≥ 0. If for b00 ∨ b0 , b00 ∧ b0 , b00 and b0 , ties occur with probability zero (with respect to the distribution G−i (·) of B−i , then the last inequality implies (22). Proof of Proposition 3. The proof of Proposition 3 rests on two key claims. First, the first-order system (2) must be well-defined for almost every bi submitted by i, i.e. almost everywhere with respect to the measure induced by Gi (·|Z, W, X). Second, at almost every bi at which first order conditions hold, the first-order system (2) must be invertible. We establish each claim in turn. First show that the first order system (2) is well-defined for almost every bi submitted by i. Recall that we can write bidder i’s objective as π(vi , b|K; Z, W, X) = (Ωvi + K − Ωb)T P−i (b|Z, W, X). where vi and K are given at the time of maximization. Note that the system (2) necessarily holds at any best respose where π(vi , ·|K; Z, W, X) is differentiable and that Assumption 5 implies that each observed bi is a best response. Hence the system (2) will be well defined for almost every bi submitted by i if and only if π(vi , ·|K; Z, W, X) is differentiable almost everywhere with respect to the measure on Bi induced by Gi (·|Z, W, X). But under Assumption 6 Gi (·|Z, W, X) is absolutely continuous. To establish the claim, it is thus sufficient to prove differentiability of π(vi , ·|K; Z, W, X) a.e. with respect to the Lebesgue measure on Bi . Clearly (Ωvi + K − Ωb) is differentiable in b for any vi , K ∈ RLit × K. Thus differentiability of π(vi , ·|K; Z, W, X) at b is equivalent to differentiability of P−i (·|Z, W, X) at b. Let 57 B−i be the Li × 1 random vector describing maximum rival bids in the set of auctions in which i participates. Again applying Assumption 6 to rule out ties, the probability i wins combination ω at bid b is P ω (b|Z, W, X) = Pr({∩{l:ωl =1} 0 ≤ B−i,l ≤ bi,l } ∩ {∩{l:ωl =0} bi,l ≤ B−i,l < ∞}). P For each ω ∈ ΩiP , let bω be the ( ω) × 1 sub-vector of b describing i’s bids for objects in ω be the ( ω, B−i ω) × 1 sub-vector of B−i describing maximum rival bids for objects in ω at (Z, W, X). Applying the ω, and Gω−i (bω |Z, W, X) be the equilibrium joint c.d.f. of B−i formula for a rectangular probability and simplifying, we can then represent P−i (·|Z, W, X) in the form X 0 0 ω P−i (b|Z, W, X) = aωω0 Gω−i (bω |Z, W, X), ω 0 ∈Ω where each aωω0 is a known scalar (determined by ω, ω 0 ) taking values in {−1, 0, 1}. But by absolute continuity each c.d.f. Gω−i (·|Z, W, X) is differentiable a.e. (Lebesgue) in its 0 support, and interpreted as a function from Bi to RLi , each bω is continuously differentiable 0 0 in b. Thus interpreted as a function from Bi to R, each Gω−i (bω |Z, W, X) is differentiable on 0 0 a set of full Lebesgue measure in B−i . The set of points in Bi at which all Gω−i (bω |Z, W, X) 0 0 are differentiable is the intersection of points in Bi at which each Gω−i (bω |Z, W, X) is differentiable, i.e. the intersection of a finite collection of sets of full Lebesgue measure in 0 Bi . But from above differentiability of Gω−i (b|Z, W, X) for all ω 0 implies differentiability of ω (b|Z, W, X). Hence P ω (·|Z, W, X) is differentiable on a set of full Lebesgue measure P−i −i in Bi . This in turn implies differentiability of π(vi , ·|K; Z, W, X) a.e. with respect to the measure on Bi induced by Gi (·|Z, W, X), as was to be shown. We next establish that the first-order system (2) must yield a unique solution ṽ for almost every bi submitted by i. Let B̃i be the set of points in Bi at which π(·, ·|K; W, Z, X) is differentiable in b; from above, B̃i is a subset of full Lebesgue measure in Bi . Choosing any b ∈ B̃i and rearranging (2) yields ∇b Γ−i (b|Z, W, X)ṽ = ∇b Γ−i (b|Z, W, X)b + Γ−i (b|Z, W, X) − ∇b P−i (b|W, Z, X)T Ki . Hence uniqueness of ṽ is equivalent to invertibility of the Li ×Li matrix ∇b Γ−i (b|Z, W, X). Recall that Γ−i (b|Z, W, X) is an Li × 1 vector whose lth element describes the probability that bid vector b wins auction l. Note that b ∈ B̃i rules out ties at b. Thus for b ∈ B̃i the lth element of Γ−i (b|Z, W, X) is the marginal c.d.f. Gl−i (b|Z, W, X) of B−i,l , from which it follows that ∇b Γ−i (b|Z, W, X) is a diagonal matrix whose l, lth element is the marginal l (b|Z, W, X) of B p.d.f. g−i −i,l . Hence ∇b Γ−i (b|Z, W, X) will be invertible at b if and only if l g−i (b|Z, W, X) > 0 for all l. But by hypothesis each submitted bid bi is a best response to rival play at (Z, W, X) l (·|Z, W, X) = 0 on for some (v, K). Suppose that there exists an > 0 such that g−i 58 (bil − , bi ]. Then player i could infintesimally reduce bil without affecting either Γ−i l (·|Z, W, X) > 0 or P−i , a profitable deviation for any (v, K). Hence we must have g−i almost everywhere (Lebesgue) in the support of Bi . By Assumption 6, this in turn implies l (·|Z, W, X) > 0 for almost every b submitted by i. Since l was arbitrary, we must have g−i i ∇b Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X) invertible for almost every bid bi submitted by i. Hence for almost every bi submitted by i there will exist a unique ṽ satisfying (2) at bi , given by ṽ = bi + ∇b Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X)−1 Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X) + ∇b Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X)−1 ∇b P−i (bi |W, Z, X)T K. The RHS of this expression is identified up to K, establishing the claim. Appendix C: Partial identification with general Gi The point identification result for the complementarity function κi (Zi , W, X) and the conditional distribution of Vi |Zi , W, X relied on the equations in the first order conditions obtained from bidder’s optimization of the payoff function. To derive those equations we employed the absolute continuity of bid distribution functions Gi . That, in particular, eliminated the possibility of bidders playing atoms in the equilibrium. In this appendix, we want to illustrate an approach to the identification question when no continuity restrictions are imposed on Gi . Our identification method is based on using inequalities for bidder’s best responses and employing the exclusion restrictions in Assumption 4 to obtain bounds on the complementarity function and the distributions of standalone valuations. Throughout our analysis here we continue to impose Assumptions 1-5. Let us fix (Zi , W, X) ∈ Zi × W × X . As before, Fi (·|Zi , W, X) denotes the L-variate distribution of the vector of standalone valuations Vi of the bidder conditional on Zi , W, X. As Fac (Rp ) we denote the set of all absolutely continuous cumulative distribution functions on Rp . Observable are the distribution functions Gi (b|Z, W, X), where Z = (Zi , Z−i ), of the bids in the equilibrium played by the bidders for any Z−i ∈ Z−i |Z, W, X, i = 1, . . . , N . The identification set is defined as the set Hi (Zi , W, X) = {(Fi (·|Zi , W, X), κi (Zi , W, X)) : Conditions (C1), (C2), (C3) satisfied} . When writing the identification set in this form, we already make us of the exclusion restrictions in Assumption 4. The conditions in the definition of Hi (Zi , W, X) are the following: (C1) Fi (·|Zi , W, X) ∈ Fac (RLi ), and the support of Fi (·|Zi , W, X) is a compact, convex set in RLi (consistent with Assumption 1). 59 (C2) κi (Zi , W, X) ∈ Ki . (C3) For each Z−i ∈ Z−i |Zi , W, X, bidder’s behavior is consistent with the maximization of the payoff function π(vi , b; Z, W, X) = viT Γ−i (b|Z, W, X)−bT Γ−i (b|Z, W, X)+P−i (b|Z, W, X)T κi (Zi , W, X) with respect to b ∈ Bi . That is, for each Z−i ∈ Z−i |Zi , X, W , every bidder i’s bid vector bi observed in the equilibrium satisfies the inequality viT Γ−i (bi |Z−i ) − bTi Γ−i (bi |Z−i ) + P−i (bi |Z−i )T κ(Zi , W, X) ≥ viT Γ−i (b|Z−i ) − bT Γ−i (b|Z−i ) + P−i (b|Z−i )T κ(Zi , W, X) ∀ b ∈ Bi , (23) where for notational simplicity we wrote Γ−i (·|Z−i ) and P−i (bi |Z−i ) instead of Γ−i (bi |Z, W, X) and P−i (bi |Z, W, X) respectively, thus omitting fixed (Zi , W, X) from the notation. Let Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) stand for the projection of the identification set onto the second component – on the set of κi (Zi , W, X). Let Hi,F (Zi , W, X) stand for the projection of the identification set onto the first component – on the set of Fi (·|Zi , W, X); and let Hi,Fl (Zi , W, X) stand for the projection of Hi,F (Zi , W, X) onto the marginal distribution of Vil conditional on Zi , W, X – that is, on the set of univariate distribution functions Fil (·|Zi , W, X). Even though it is very difficult to obtain a closed form description of the sets Hi,F (Zi , W, X) and Hi,κ (Zi , W, X), it is possible to give closed form characterizations of their supersets. These supersets are given in Proposition 7 below. − First, we introduce some notations. Let ∆+ ,l [f (u)] and ∆,l [f (u)] denote differences in the values of f (·) associated with adding and − to the lthe component of u respectively: ∆+ ,l [f (u)] = f (u + el ) − f (u), ∆− ,l [f (u)] = f (u − el ) − f (u), where el denotes the Li -dimensional lth unit vector. Suppose there exist known scalars v ≥ 0 and v̄ < ∞ such that v ≤ vil ≤ v̄ for any l; note that these could be strictly outside the support of Vil . For each bi ∈ Bi , define − + I,l (bi |Z−i ), I,l (bi |Z−i ) as follows: ( − I,l (bi |Z−i ) = v if ∆− ,l [Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] = 0, ( + I,l (bi |Z−i ) = v̄ if ∆+ ,l [Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] 60 = 0, T ∆− ,l [bi Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] ∆− ,l [Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i )] T ∆+ ,l [bi Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] ∆+ ,l [Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i )] ) else ; ) else . − + Also, for each bi ∈ Bi , define the following S,l (bi |Z−i ) and S,l (bi |Z−i ): ( − S,l (bi |Z−i ) = 0 if ∆− ,l [Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] = 0, ( + S,l (bi |Z−i ) = 0 if ∆+ ,l [Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] = 0, ∆− ,l [P−i (bi |Z−i )] ∆− ,l [Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i )] ∆+ ,l [P−i (bi |Z−i )] ∆+ ,l [Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i )] ) else ; ) else . For any K ∈ Ki , let F̃il− (·|K; Z−i ) denote the c.d.f. of − − sup I,l (bi |Z−i ) − S,l (bi |Z−i )T K , >0 and let F̃il+ (·|K; Z−i ) denote the c.d.f. of + + (bi |Z−i )T K (bi |Z−i ) − S,l inf I,l >0 . Hereafter we assume that ties are broken independently across auctions. Proposition 7. a) A superset of Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) can be found in the following way: (1) Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) = L \ K̃i,l , l=1 where K̃i,l is defined as 0 K̃i,l = {K ∈ Ki F̃il+ (·|K; Z−i ) ≤ F̃il− (·|K; Z−i ) 0 ∀ Z−i , Z−i ∈ Z−i |Zi , W, X}. b) A superset of Hi,Fl (Zi , W, X) can be found as the set of univariate functions Fil (·) ∈ Fac (R) such that for any η ∈ R, \ \ 0 )]}. Fil (η) ∈ [F̃il+ (η|κ0 ; Z−i ), F̃il− (η|κ0 ; Z−i 0 κ0 ∈Hi,κ (Zi ,W,X)Z−i ,Z−i ∈Z−i |Zi ,W,X (1) (1) Let us denote this superset as Hi,Fl (Zi , W, X). c) A superset of Hi,F (Zi , W, X) can be found as the set of Li -variate functions Fi (·) ∈ Fac (RLi ) such that each lth marginal distribution function generated by Fi (·) belongs to (1) Hi,Fl (Zi , W, X), l = 1, . . . , Li . 61 Moreover, for any η = (η1 , . . . , ηLi ), Fi (η) ≤ min inf inf l=1,...,Li κ ∈H(1) (Z ,W,X) Z−i ∈Z−i |Zi ,W,X 0 i i,κ Fi (η) ≥ max Li X l=1 F̃il+ (ηl |κ0 ; Z−i ), sup sup (1) κ0 ∈Hi,κ (Zi ,W,X) Z−i ∈Z−i |Zi ,W,X F̃il− (ηl |κ0 ; Z−i ) − Li + 1, 0 . Proof. Let ∆δ [f (u)] = (f (u + δ) − f (u)) denote changes in f (u) induced by adding the vector δ to the vector u. For notational simplicity, let κi (Zi , W, X) = κ0 . Then we can equivalently restate (23) as follows: viT ∆δ [Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] − ∆δ [bTi Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] + ∆δ [P−i (bi |Z−i )T ]κ0 ≤ 0 ∀ δ ∈ Bi − bi , (24) where the difference Bi − bi is understood as the Minkowski difference. System (24) is linear in vi and κ0 . The set of solutions of (vi , κ0 ) to this system can be shown to be convex. Its intersection with [v, v]L × Ki is convex as well. In a special case when Bi consists of a finite number of points, the set of solutions is a convex (closed) L polyhedron in <2 −1 . Any subsystem of a finite number of inequalities from system (24) can easily be resolved to give an upper bound (a lower bound) on the lth component vil in terms of the minimum (maximum) of some linear functions with of κ0 with known coefficients. That could be used to get bounds on the distribution functions of standalone valuations in terms of κ0 . However, the formulas for the bounds on each component obtained from a finite system of linear inequalities are quite complicated. An easier way to obtain bounds on each vil is to consider only those alternative bids b that differ from bi in the lth coordinate. Since the ties are broken independently across auctions at bi , then a change in the lth component of bi affects only the lth component of Γ−i . Noting that Γ−i,l is monotone in bil and rearranging, we thus must have for any such that bi − el ∈ Bi and bi + el ∈ Bi T ∆− ,l [bi Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] ∆− ,l [Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i )] − T ∆− ,l [P−i (bi |Z−i ) ] ∆− ,l [Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i )] ≤ κ0 ≤ vil T ∆+ ,l [bi Γ−i (bi |Z−i )] ∆+ ,l [Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i )] − T ∆+ ,l [P−i (bi |Z−i ) ] ∆+ ,l [Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i )] κ0 . (25) If for a given , we have that bi − el ∈ / Bi or bi + el ∈ / Bi , then at least one of + ∆− [Γ (b |Z )] and ∆ [Γ (b |Z )] is equal to 0, and then in order to bound vil we ,l −i,l i −i ,l −i,l i −i can use our prior knowledge that vil ∈ [v, v]. 62 Using our notations above, we can say that for any bi in the support of Gi : − − + + I,l (bi |Z−i ) − S,l (bi |Z−i )T κ0 ≤ vil ≤ I,l (bi |Z−i ) − S,l (bi |Z−i )T κ0 , and hence, − − + + sup I,l (bi |Z−i ) − S,l (bi |Z−i )T κ0 ≤ vil ≤ inf I,l (bi |Z−i ) − S,l (bi |Z−i )T κ0 . >0 >0 (26) Then by the inequalities in (26), we must have for any Z−i ∈ Z−i |Zi , W, X: F̃il+ (·|κ0 ; Z−i ) ≤ Fil (·) ≤ F̃il− (·|κ0 ; Z−i ). (27) Pooling information across Z−i , it follows that we can have K = κ0 only if 0 0 ) ∀ Z−i , Z−i ∈ Z−i |Zi , W, X. F̃il+ (·|K; Z−i ) ≤ F̃il− (·|K; Z−i (28) This gives part a) of this theorem. Part b) immediately follows from (27). Part c) follows from (27) and the well known result on sharp Frechet-Hoeffding bounds for joint distributions. The next proposition provides an expectations version of the partial identification argument. Even though the supersets it gives are larger than those in Proposition 7, computationally they are easier to obtain. Before formulating this proposition, let us define + Li matrices χ− (Z ), χ+ (Z ) as follows: Li × 1 vectors Ψ− −i −i (Z−i ), Ψ (Z−i ) and Li × 2 Li − Ψ− (Z−i ) ≡ E[I,l (Bi |Z−i )|Z−i ] l=1 Li + Ψ+ (Z−i ) ≡ E[I,l (Bi |Z−i )|Z−i ] l=1 − T Li χ− (Z−i ) ≡ E[S,l (Bi |Z−i )|Z−i ] l=1 + T Li χ+ (Z−i ) ≡ E[S,l (Bi |Z−i )|Z−i ] l=1 . Proposition 8. A superset of Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) can be found in the following way: (2) Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) = \ K̂i , >0 where K̂i is defined as n + 0 K̂i ≡ K ∈ Ki Ψ− (Z−i ) − Ψ (Z−i ) o + 0 0 − χ− (Z−i ) − χ (Z−i ) K ≤ 0 for all Z−i , Z−i ∈ Z−i |Zi , W, X . 63 (2) Results analogous to parts b) and c) in Proposition 8 hold as well with Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) (1) replacing Hi,κ (Zi , W, X). Proof. Taking expectations of (26) across bil , we obtain − − E[I,l (Bi |Z−i )|Z−i ] − E[S,l (Bi |Z−i )|Z−i ]κ0 ≤ E[Vil |Z−i ] + + ≡ E[Vil ] ≤ E[I,l (Bi |Z−i )|Z−i ] − E[S,l (Bi |Z−i )|Z−i ]κ0 . (29) 0 and l, we obtain Then pooling restrictions of the form (29) across Z−i , Z−i − + 0 + 0 Ψ− (Z−i ) − χ (Z−i )κ0 ≤ Ψ (Z−i ) − χ (Z−i )κ0 (2) 0 ∀ Z−i , Z−i ∈ Z−i |Zi , W, X. (30) (1) Set Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) is larger than Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) because first-order stochastic dominance implies inequalities for expectations. (2) Note two features of Hi,κ (Zi , W, X). First, it can be represented as the intersection of a set of half-spaces in Ki , where half-spaces are bounded by hyperplanes involving slope + − + 0 0 vectors (χ− ,l (Z−i ) − χ,l (Z−i )) and intercepts (Ψ,l (Z−i ) − Ψ,l (Z−i )), and the intersection 0 is taken over collections of (Z−i , Z−i , , l). (2) Second, if Gi is absolutely continuous, then Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) is a singleton, and as we (2) show below, the analysis of Hi,κ (Zi , W, X) essentially becomes our identification strategy in the case of point identification. Indeed, bidder i’s objective function is differentiable at almost every observed bi . Hence as → 0 we will have for all l lim ∆− ,l bi Γ−i (bi |Z−i ) →0 ∆− Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i ) ,l = lim ∆− ,l bi Γ−i (bi |Z−i )/ →0 ∆− Γ−i,l (bi |Z−i )/ ,l = ∂(bi Γ−i (bi |Z−i ))/∂bil , dΓ−i,l (bi |Z−i ))/dbil + and therefore Ψ− (·) → Ψ(·). Analogously, it is straightforward to show that Ψ (·) → Ψ(·), + χ− → χ(·), and χ → χ(·). Hence the restriction (30) implies 0 0 Ψ(Z−i ) − χ(Z−i )κ0 ≤ Ψ(Z−i ) − χ(Z−i )κ0 0 ∀ Z−i , Z−i ∈ Z−i |Zi , W, X. 0 are interchangeable, we thus have for any Z , Z 0 ∈ Z |Z , W, X: Noting that Z−i , Z−i −i i −i −i 0 0 Ψ(Z−i ) − χ(Z−i )κ0 ≤ Ψ(Z−i ) − χ(Z−i )κ0 0 0 Ψ(Z−i ) − χ(Z−i )κ0 ≤ Ψ(Z−i ) − χ(Z−i )κ0 , or equivalently 0 0 Ψ(Z−i ) − χ(Z−i )κ0 = Ψ(Z−i ) − χ(Z−i )κ0 64 0 ∀ Z−i , Z−i ∈ Z−i |Zi , W, X. But this is exactly the identification restriction invoked in Proposition 3 in the current paper. Thus we can strictly generalize our existing identification results (which depend on differentiability a.e.) to partial identification for arbitrary Gi . 65 References ATHEY, S. (2001), “Single Crossing Properties and the Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria in Games of Incomplete Information”, Econometrica, 69, 861–889. ATHEY, S., LEVIN, J., and SEIRA, E. (2011), “Comparing Open and Sealed Bid Auctions: Evidence from Timber Auctions”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126, 207–257. AUSEBEL, L.M., and CRAMTON, P. (2004), “Auctioning Many Divisible Goods”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 480–493, April-May. BIKHCHANDANI, S. (1999), “Auctions of Heterogeneous Objects”, Games and Economic Behavior, 26(2), 193–220. CANTILLON, E. and PESENDORFER, M. (2006), “Combination Bidding in Multi-Unit Auctions”, (Mimeo). CRAMTON, P. (2006), “Simultaneous Ascending Auction”, Ch. 4 in Cramton, P., Shoham, Y., and Steinberg, R. (eds) Combinatorial Auctions (Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 2006), 99–114. CRAMTON, P., SHOHAM, Y., and STEINBERG, R. (eds) (2006), Combinatorial Auctions (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press). DE VREIS, S., and VORHA, R.V. (2003), “Combinatorial Auctions: A Survey”, INFORMS Journal of Computing, 13(3), 284–309. FELDMAN, M., FU, H., GRAVIN, N., and LUCIER, B. (2012), “Simultaneous Auctions are (Almost) Efficient”, (Working Paper, http://arxiv.org/abs/1209.4703 ). FLAMBARD, V., and PERRIGNE, I. (2006), “Asymmetry in Procurement Auctions: Evidence from Snow Removal Contracts”, The Economic Journal, (116), Issue 514, 1014– 1036. GHOSH, G. (2012), “Simultaneous First-Price Auctions with Budget-Constrained Bidders”, (Working Paper). GROEGER, J.R. (2012), “A Study of Participation in Dynamic Auctions”, (Forthcoming at International Economic Review ). GUERRE, E., PERRIGNE, I., and VUONG, Q. (2000), “Optimal Nonparametric Estimation of First-Price Auctions”, Econometrica, 68(3), 525–574. HASSIDIM, A., KAPLAN, H., MANSOUR, Y., and NISAN, N. (2011), “Non-price Equilibria in Markets of Discrete Goods” (Working Paper, http://arxiv.org/abs/1103.3950 ). HENDRICKS, K., PINKSE, J., and PORTER, R. H. (2003), “Empirical Implications 66 of Equilibrium Bidding in First-Price, Symmetric, Common Value Auctions”, Review of Economic Studies, 70, 115–145. HENDRICKS, K., and PORTER, R. H. (1988), “An Empirical Study of an Auction with Asymmetric Information”, American Economic Review, 78(5), 865–883. HORTACSU, A. (2011), “Recent Progress in the Empirical Analysis of Multi-Unit Auctions”, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29(3), 345–349. HORTACSU, A. and McADAMS (2010), “Mechanism Choice and Strategic Bidding in Divisible Good Auctions: An Empirical Analysis of the Turkish Treasury Auction Market”, Journal of Political Economy , 188(5), 833–865. HORTACSU, A., and PULLER, S. L. (2008), “Understanding Strategic Bidding in MultiUnit Auctions: A Case Study of the Texas Electricity Spot Market”, RAND Journal of Economics, 39(1), 86–114. JACKSON, M. O., SIMON, L. K., SWINKELS, J. M., and ZAME, W. R. (2002), “Communication and Equilibrium in Discontinuous Games of Incomplete Information”, Econometrica, 70(5), 1711–1740. JOFRE-BONET, M., and PESENDORFER, M. (2003), “Estimation of a Dynamic Auction Game”, Econometrica, 71(5), 1443–1489. KLEMPERER, P. (2008), “A New Auction for Substitutes: Central Bank Liquidity Auctions, the U.S. TARP, and Variable Product-Mix Auctions. Bayesian Games and the Smoothness Framework”, (Working Paper, Oxford University). KLEMPERER, P. (2010), “The Product-Mix Auction: A new auction design for differentiated goods”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(2-3), 526–536. KRASNOKUTSKAYA, E. (2011), “Identification and Estimation in Procurement Auctions under Unobserved Auction Heterogeneity”, Review of Economic Studies, 78(1), 293–327. KRASNOKUTSKAYA, E., and SEIM, K. (2011), “Bid Preference Programs and Participation in Procurement”, American Economic Review, 101(6), 2653–2686. KRISHNA, V., and ROSENTHAL, R.W. (1996), “Simultaneous Auctions with Synergies”, Games and Economic Behavior, 17, 1–31. LI, T., and ZHANG, B. (2010), “Testing For Affiliation In First-Price Auctions Using Entry Behavior”, International Economic Review, 51(3), 837–850. LI, T., and ZHENG, X. (2009), “Entry and Competition Effects in First-Price Auctions: Theory and Evidence from Procurement Auctions”, Review of Economic Studies, 76(4), 1397–1429. 67 LI, T., and ZHENG, X. (2012), “Information Acquisition and/or Bid Preparation: A Structural Analysis of Entry and Bidding in Timber Sale Auctions ”, Journal of Econometrics, 168(1), 29–46. LU, J. and PERRIGNE, I. (2008), “Estimating Risk Aversion Using Ascending and Sealed Bid Auctions: Application to Timber Data”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 23, 871– 896. LUNANDER, A., and LUNDBERG, S. (2013), “Bids and Costs in Combinatorial and Noncombinatorial Procurement Auctions – Evidence from Procurement of Public Cleaning Contracts”, Contemporary Economic Policy, 31(4), 733–745. LUNANDER, A., and NILSSON, J. (2004), “Taking the Lab to the Field: Experimental Tests of Alternative Mechanisms to Procure Multiple Contracts”, Journal of Regulatory Economics, 25(1), 39–58. McADAMS, D. (2006), “Monotone Equilibrium in Multi-Unit Auctions”, Review of Economic Studies, 73, 1039–1056. MILGROM, P. (1999). “Combination Bidding in Spectrum Auctions,” in Competition, Regulation and Convergence: Current Trends in Telecommunications Research, Sharon Gillett and Ingo Vogelsang (Eds), Mahwah, New Jersey: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Publishers, pp 19-26. MILGROM, P. (2000a), “Putting Auction Theory to Work: The Simultaneous Ascending Auction”, Journal of Political Economy, 108(2), 245–272. MILGROM, P. (2000b), “Putting Auction Theory to Work: Ascending Auctions with Package Bidding”, (Unpublished Working Paper). MILGROM, P., and WEBER, R. (1985), “Distributional Strategies for Games with Incomplete Information”, Mathematics of Operations Research, 10(4), 619–632. RENY, P. J. (1999), “On the Existence of Pure and Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibria in Discontinuous Games”, Econometrica, 67, 1029–1056. RENY, P. J. (2011), “On the Existence of Monotone Pure Strategy Equilibria in Bayesian Games”, Econometrica, 79, 499-553. ROSENTHAL, R.W., and WANG, R. (1996), “Simultaneous Auctions with Synergies and Common Values”, Games and Economic Behavior, 17, 32–55. SIMON, L.K., and ZAME, W.R. (1990), “Discontinuous Games and Endogenous Sharing Rules”, Econometrica, 58(4), 861–872. SOMAINI, P. (2011), “Competition and Interdependent Costs in Highway Procurement”, (Working Paper, Stanford University). 68 SYRGKANIS, V. (2012), “Bayesian Games and the Smoothness Framework”, (Working Paper, http://arxiv.org/abs/1203.5155 ). SZENTES, B., and ROSENTHAL, R.W. (2003), “Three-object Two-bidder Simultaneous Auctions: Chopsticks and Tetrahedra”, Games and Economic Behavior, 44, 114–133. 69