5/2006 More than a Simple “Crowd-out”: The Case for NEA Grants and US Dance Companies Thomas M. Smith Department of Economics University of Illinois-Chicago 601 S. Morgan (m/c 144) Chicago, IL 60607 (312) 355-3983 TomSmith@uic.edu Abstract This paper tests the crowding-out hypothesis for a balanced panel of nonprofit dance companies in the United States between 1998 and 2003. This research uses a number of model specifications to examine the impact of National Endowment for the Arts (NEA) grants and Non-NEA grants on private donations. The results suggest that NEA grants have a large ‘joint’ crowd-out effect on private donations, and a small positive ‘joint’ crowd-in to non-NEA grants. The end result is that NEA grants have a modest ‘simple’ crowd-out to nonprofit dance companies. Keywords: Crowding-out, Nonprofit Dance Organizations JEL L3 1. Introduction Nonprofit organizations receive income from a number of sources: fees for service, dues, rental of space and/or equipment, government grants, and private donations. Researchers have focused on the relationship between the latter two categories—government grants and private donations. The empirical and theoretical models examining this relationship revolve around the idea that individuals will perceive government dollars as substitutes, and give less (Abrams and Schmidt, 1984). This ‘crowding-out’ between government grants and private donations ultimately results in nonprofit organizations receiving less total donated revenue. This paper examines the relationship between government grants, specifically National Endowment for the Arts grants, and private donated revenue for nonprofit dance organizations in the United States. There has been some research addressing the crowding-out issue for specific arts organizations--Kingma (1989) with public radio, Brooks, (2000b) with symphony orchestra, and Smith (2003) with dance; and some research that has specified types of arts organizations—museums and art galleries— within larger samples (Weisbrod and Dominguez, 1986; Okten and Weisbrod, 2000; Tinkleman, 2004). This paper uses a balanced panel of nonprofit dance companies between 1998 and 2003 from the National Center for Charitable Statistics (NCCS) Digitized Data and the National Endowment for the Arts-Dance Applicant dataset. This paper is organized as follows. A brief discussion of the literature is presented in the second Section. The dataset and empirical models are outlined in Section 3. The results are discussed in Section 4 and Section 5 provides a conclusion and policy implications. 1 2. Crowding-In or Crowding-Out in the Arts The relationship between public and private money to nonprofit organizations has been examined by many researchers (see Steinberg, 1991, for a literature review). The alternative hypotheses that emerge from the body of work are: 1) donors view government funding as a replacement for their gifts, completely crowding-out private donations (Roberts, 1984); 2) government funding is viewed as an imperfect substitute for private donations resulting in incomplete crowding-out of private dollars (Andreoni, 1990; Steingberg, 1991) or; 3) that government funding signals a nonprofit’s worthiness for support, creating a crowding-in effect (e.g. Payne 2001). There does not appear to be a predictable direction of the crowding effect based on industry. Several papers have examined the relationship between government and private contributions specifically in the arts: Kingma (1989), Brooks (1999, 2000a, 2000b, 2003), Okten and Weisbrod (2000), and Smith (2003). Kingma (1989) examines the relationship between public and private funding with respect to nonprofit “public” radio. The results indicate that public funding has a significant crowding-out effect on private donations in the range of $0.14. Brooks (2000b) finds a positive crowding-in between public funding and private funding to symphony orchestras in the amount of approximately $2.50. However, the relationship between public and private funding is non-linear and larger (or continued) grants crowd-out private contributions. Okten and Weisbrod (2000) examine the relationship between public and private grants for a range of nonprofit organizations, including arts exhibits (galleries), and find no significant relationship between public and private donations. Smith (2003) looks specifically at the impact of National Endowment for the Arts funding to nonprofit dance companies and 2 finds a modest crowding-in effect around $3. In another examination of public radio, Brooks (2003) finds a positive and non-linear relationship between public and private funding in public radio. 3. Data and Model This research uses a balanced panel of nonprofit dance companies from the National Center for Charitable Statistics Digitized data 1998-2003 ( NCCS Digitized 9803). The information in the NCCS was collected from the IRS Form 990—the tax form used to report finances of 501(c)(3) organizations with more than $25,000 in annual gross receipts. The nonprofit dance companies in this analysis possess the National Taxonomy of Exempt Entity codes issued by the IRS: A62 for dance. For this analysis, there are dance and ballet companies for each year 1998 to 2003. Similar IRS Form 990 data used by Payne (1998), Okten and Weisbrod (2000), Andreoni and Payne (2003), and Tinkleman (2004) —the IRS’s Statistics of Income (SOI) tapes for 1982,1983, and 1985-1994—only include companies in the upper registry of gross receipts, while the NCCS includes companies that report gross receipts as low as $25,000 and as high as $500 million. The descriptive statistics of these data are listed in table 1. The model examining the effect of public grants on private donations is outlined in Steinberg (1991) and has been presented recently in Khanna, Posnett and Sandler (1995), Payne (1998), Okten and Weisbrod (2000) and summarized in Andreoni (2004): 1) Dit = Priceit + Govtit + Fundit+ PSRit + Xit+it 3 where Dit refers to private monetary donations to the ith company at time t, the Priceit variable is discussed and defined below, Govtit is government grants to the ith company in the current period1, Fundit is fund-raising expenditure for the ith company, PSRit is the program service revenue for the ith company, X is a vector of other co-variants— including dichotomous variables identifying the state where the nonprofit is located, dichotomous variables identifying the year, and the per-capita income2 for the state and period—and ε is a random disturbance. Steinberg (1991) decomposes the government grants into two separate parts: 2) Dit = Priceit + GovtFEDit +GovtSTATEit+ Fundit+ PSRit + Xitφ+it such that government grants reflect both federal and state level payments. Because federal government dollars have an impact on state government dollars and private donations play a role in the decisions of state granting agencies, the correct reduced form equations are 3a) Dit = GovtFEDit + ρ2it Ψ +v1it 3b) GovtSTATEit = GovtFEDit +ρ1it Ψ +v2it The interpretation of and are of ‘joint’ crowd-out (positive or negative). The ‘simple’ crowd-out can be determined by the ratio of the two coefficients 1 2 1 . Much of the research on establishing crowd-out uses a modified version of equation 1), of which the coefficient is interpreted as the ‘simple’ crowd-out. If equation 1) is performed with OLS, the coefficient β2 is bias. However, if the values of government 1 Current private donations have been modeled as a function of current government grants (Posnett and Sandler, 1989 and Payne, 1998) and as a function of lagged government grants (Okten and Weisbrod, 2000). 2 Other measures of economic performance or the political-economic environment have been included (Payne, 1998). 4 grants are approximated using an instrumental variable technique to account for endogeneities, the coefficient is un-bias (Steinberg, 1991; Kingma, 1989). Un-bias estimates of simple crowd-out can also be determined by estimating equations 3a) and 3b). This research will test the relative impact of government grants, including both NEA direct grants and state-level grants, on private donations to determine both ‘joint’ and ‘simple’ crowd-out. Price The Priceit variable is defined by Okten and Wesibrod (2000) 3 as Priceit = (1-T)/ (1 – Fit-1) Where T is the marginal income tax rate facing an individual donor and Fit-1 is the ratio of fundraising expenditure to total donations for the ith firm in the previous period. The numerator of this variable was changed to 1 for Tinkelman (2004) because taxes are constant across all firms. There are several other specifications that with respect to the Price variable. For companies where Donit-1 = Fundit-1, Fit-1 = 1 and Price is undefined by calculation. In these cases, where Donit-1 = Fundit-1 at some positive amount, Price is equal to 148.4, log(Price) = 5, consistent with Weisbrod and Dominquez (1986). However, where Donit-1 = Fundit-1 = 0, then Fit-1 would be undefined. In these cases, Price is equal to 1. In the cases where fundraising is larger than donations, Price is negative. Weisbrod and Dominquez (1986) excluded cases with a negative Price from their analysis. In order to 3 Weisbrod and Dominguez (1986) identified Price = 1(1-F-A), where F is the ratio of fundraising expenditures to donations and A is the ratio of administrative expenditures to donations. The form 990 data used in this analysis does not provide a meaningful measure of A. The price variable without A should not have an adverse impact on the measure of effective firm practice on individual contributions. 5 retain the balanced panel, these observations will not be dropped. Instead, where Fundit-1 > Donit-1 , Price = (Price)2 up to a maximum of 148.4. A True Panel? One of the critiques of using the SOI tapes is that the returns for a particular year include organizational information from different fiscal years. That is, the 1999 SOI tapes may include information for organization “A” from fiscal year 1998 and information for organization “B” from fiscal year 1999. As such, using observations from sequential SOI tapes may not represent a true panel. It can also be the case that information from two sequential SOI tapes may not represent consecutive fiscal years for a specific organization (Tinkleman, 2004). The NCCS however, is organized by fiscal year. As such, the 1998 NCCS includes financial data for an organization’s 1998 fiscal year. This analysis only includes nonprofit arts organizations that have complete information (nonmissing IRS Form 990) for each year 1998 through 2003. Likewise, the information in the NEA-DA is organized by fiscal year of the company and grant year—the year the NEA granted money (or didn’t grant money) to the organization. As such, the information from the NEA-DA can be merged with the NCCS data for a consistent fiscal year. 4.1 Estimates of ‘Simple’ Crowd-out Using Total Grants OLS and TOBIT The analysis of equation 1 was estimated using OLS. The results of the OLS model suggest that current government grants (column 1) crowd-out $0.65 in private contributions. This estimate is statistically significant. This indicates that the average nonprofit dance company has a net gain of $35 for every for every $100 received from 6 government sources : a gain of $100 from government sources is accompanies by a loss of $65 from private sources. Other results from the OLS estimates indicate that every dollar of fundraising increases private donations by more than $6.65. Companies that receive more from ticket sales and other program service revenue also receive more in private donations in the range of 60%. Higher state-level per-capita income has a positive but insignificant impact on private donations. The price of donating has a negative but insignificant impact on private donations. The estimates using the Tobit technique are reported in column 2. The Tobit results indicate that every dollar in current government grants crowds-out $0.47 in private support for the average nonprofit performing arts organization. The Tobit estimates for fundraising and program service revenue—$6.73 and $0.593—are also very similar to the OLS estimates. The similarity between the Tobit and OLS estimates are consistent with the fact that only 25 percent of the observations in this sample have a zero value for the dependent variable (McDonald and Moffitt, 1980). With the Tobit estimates, the impact of per-capita income is negative (although not significantly different than zero). The price variable for both Tobit estimates is also negative but insignificant. Both the OLS and Tobit estimates suggest t a crowding-out effect of government grants on private donations. Instrumental Variable: 2SLS As indicated, some researchers have suggested that there may be an endogeneity issue between government grants and private donations—e.g. omitted variables effecting both government and private dollars (Payne, 1998; Okten and Weisbrod, 2001; Andreoni and Payne, 2003). In order to correct for this, this paper employs an instrumental 7 variable technique. In the first stage, current government grants are estimated using state-level legislative appropriations to state arts agencies and state arts councils in the state where the nonprofit organization is located. Although some researchers have used state level government transfer payments or total state level government expenditures to approximate the “size of the pie (Andreoni and Payne, 2003, p. 805)” that nonprofit organizations are fighting for, this research uses the appropriations to the agencies responsible for determining grants. In effect, this research is approximating the size of the serving fork used to distribute the pie. Because government grants can come from both the state and federal level, using a state level proxy does not simply replace the actual government grants. The F-statistic for the first stage (22.67) indicates that the choice of state-level appropriations is a good instrument. The IV estimates for government grants indicates that every $1 received by a company from the public sources crowds-out $1.56 in private contributions. This estimate is twice the size of both the OLS and Tobit estimates. Fixed-Effects One of the advantages of this dataset is that it includes information on the same arts organizations across periods. These data represent a true panel of organizations by fiscal year4. As such, equation 1 can be estimated under a firm fixed-effects model. The results of the firm fixed-effects estimation are listed in column 4 of table 1. The null hypothesis of no fixed effects is rejected with an F value of 8.62. The coefficient for the government grants indicates that one dollar of government funding crowds-out $1.03 in private funding. The magnitude of the government coefficient for the fixed-effects 4 For this research, companies were only used if there were returns for each of the four fiscal years, 19982003. 8 model is larger than that found in the non-fixed effect model (OLS and TOBIT), but is smaller than the estimate using 2SLS. This result is consistent with other estimates using fixed-effects find that government grants that find positive ‘reputation effects’ (Payne, 1998). 4.2 Estimates of ‘Joint’ and ‘Simple’ Crowd-out Using NEA Grants The analysis of equation 1 using OLS estimates the ‘simple’ crowd-out—the relationship between government grants and private donations. The estimate of the relationship between government grants and private donations are bias if there are endogeneities. Un-bias ‘simple’ crowd-out can be established by analyzing the reduced form of the crowd-out equation, equations 3a) and 3b). These estimates reveal that NEA grants crowd-out $2.10 in private donations and that NEA grants crowd-in $0.42 in statelevel government grants. The ‘simple’ crowd-out of government grants are $1.47. The fixed-effects estimates of ‘joint’ crowd-out reveal that NEA grants crowd-out $4.07 in private contributions and crowd-in $0.78 in state-level grants. The ‘simple’ crowd-out of government grants are $2.28. The estimates of simple crowd-out using both OLS and Fixed-Effects are very similar to the estimates of simple crowd-out using instrumental techniques. 5. Conclusion This research uses a panel of nonprofit dance organizations from 1998 to 2003 to examine the impact of government grants on private donations. Theory suggests that individuals will substitute public money—in whole or partially—for their own donations. This substitution will lead to crowding-out (complete or partial) between government 9 grants and private funding. Using several estimating techniques, this research has provided evidence that, on average, government grants crowd-out private donations to nonprofit performing arts organizations in the range of $1.50-$2.00. 10 REFERENCES Abrams, B and Schmitz, M (1984),”The Crowding-out effect of governmental transfers on private charitable contributions: cross-section evidence,” National Tax Journal 37: 563-568. Andreoni, J (2004)” Philanthropy,” in Gerard-Varet, L.A. and S.C. Kolm and J. Ythier (eds), Handbook of Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism, Holland: Elsevier. Andreoni, J (2000), “Impure Altruism and Donations to Public Goods: A Theory of Warm Glow Giving,” Economic Journal, 100: 464-477. Andreoni, J and A. Payne (2003), “Do Government Grants Crowd Out Giving or Fundraising?” The American Economic Review, 93(3): 792-812. Association of Cultural Economics International. (2004). “The State of The Arts: A Panel on the Economics of Performing and Visual Arts,” University of Illinois at Chicago, Chicago. Bergstrom, T, L. Blume and H. Varian (1986), “On the Private Provision of Public Goods,” Journal of Public Economics, 29: 25-49. Brooks, A. (1999) “Do Public Subsidies Leverage Private Philanthropy for the Arts? Empirical Evidence on Symphony Orchestras,” Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 28(1): 32-45. Brooks, A. (2000a) “Is There a Dark Side to Government Support for Nonprofits?” Public Administration Review 60(3): 211-218. Brooks, A. (2000b) ”Public Subsidies and Charitable Giving: Crowing Out, Crowding in, or Both?” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 19(3): 451-464. Brooks, A. (2003) ”Taxes, Subsidies, and Listeners Like You: Public Policy and Contributions to Public Radio,” Public Administration Review, 63(5): 554-561. Illinois Economic Association. (2001). “The State of The Arts: A Panel on the Economics and Finances of Performing Arts in Illinois,” University of Illinois at Chicago, Chicago. Khanna, J, J. Posnett and T. Sadler (1995), “Charity donations in the UK: New Evidence Based on Panel Data,” Journal of Public Economics, 56 (2): 257-272. Kingma, B. (1989) ”An Accurate Measure of the Crowd-out Effect, Income Effect, and Price Effect for Charitable Contributions,” Journal of Political Economy 97:1197 -1207. 11 Kotler, P and J Scheff. (1997) Standing Room Only: Strategies for Marketing the Performing Arts, Boston, MA: Harvard University Press. McCarthy, K, A. Brooks, J. Lowell and L. Zakaras, The Performing Arts in a New Era, Santa Monica, CA: Rand. McDonald, J and Moffit, R (1980),“The Uses of Tobit Analysis,“ The Review of Economics and Statistics, 62(2): 318-321. Okten, C and B Weisbrod. (2000) “Determinants of Donations in Private Nonprofit Markets,” Journal of Public Economics, 75: 255-272. Payne, A. (1998) “Does the government crowd-out private donations? New evidence from a sample of non-profit firms,” Journal of Public Economics, 69: 323-345. Payne, A. (2001) “Measuring the Effect of Federal Research Funding on Private Donations at Research Universities: Is Federal Research Funding More than a Substitute for Private Donations,” International Tax and Public Finance 8: 731 -751. Posnett, J and T. Sandler (1989), “ Demand for Charity Donations in Private Non-Profit Markets: The Case of the U.K,” Journal of Public Economics, 40: 187-200. Roberts, R (1984),”A positive model of private charity and public transfers,” Journal of Political Economy, 92: 136-148. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1986) “Do Government Grants to Charity Reduce Private Donations?’ in S. Rose-Ackerman, ed. The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy, New York, Oxford Press: 313-332. Smith, T. M (2003) “The Effect of NEA Grants on the Contributions to Nonprofit Dance Companies,” Journal of Arts Management, Law and Society, 33(2): 98-114. Steinberg, R (1990) “Taxes and Giving: New Findings,” Voluntas, 1(1): 61-79. Steinberg, R (1991), “Does Government Spending Crowd Out Donations? Interpreting the Evidence, “ Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 62: 519-617. Tinkleman, D (2004),”Using nonprofit organization-level financial data to infer managers’ fund-raising strategies,” Journal of Public Economics, 88: 2181-2192. Warr, P (1983), “The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income,” Economic Letters, 13: 207-2111. Weisbrod, B and N. D. Dominguez (1986), “Demand for collective goods in private 12 nonprofit markets: can fundraising expenditures help overcome free-rider behavior?” Journal of Public Economics, 30: 83-95. 13 Table 1. Descriptive Statistics Variable Independent Privatet Dependent Govt NEAgrantt STATEgrantt PSRt (ALL) FundExpt Pricet Mean Std Dev Private dollars donated to dance organizations in current period 1,362 229,959 1,019,263 Total Government support to all dance organizations Government Support to all dance organizations in current period Non-NEA grant dollars to dance organizations Program Service Revenue Fundraising Expenditure 1,362 46,068 113,197 1,362 13,204 26,125 1,362 1,362 1,362 32,864 50,124 24,692 8,1324 1 Where Ft is the ratio of fundraising 1 Ft 1,362 1.39 4.92 Description expenditure to total contributions 14 Table 3. Impact of Government Funding on Private Donations Dependent variable: Dollars of private donations Estimating Technique One-Way Variable Intercept Pricet Governmentt FundRaiset PSREVt Year 1999b Year 2000 Year 2001 Year 2002 Year 2003 PerCapYjt State Effects N R2 LogL Fa 1. OLS S.E.) -51,108 34,556 -708.62 1,638.71 -0.652 0.1492 6.645 0.2911 0.5954 0.028 23,49 47,866 -4,079 47,847 -19,662 47,933 45,525 47,907 16331 47918 10.205 11.015 YES 1362 0.7499 2.Tobit S.E.) -124,600 40,177 -710.94 1802 -0.4688 0.1648 6.7385 0.3194 0.5938 0.0315 -10,094 55,644 -15,930 55,600 -30,947 55,724 36,629 55,452 8,179 55,382 15.26 11.201 YES 1362 3 I.V. 7. Fixed Effects S.E.) S.E.) -45241 23,395 37852 35754 -654.21 -623.30 1780 1,681 -1.58 -1.031 0.215 0.1804 6.542 7.142 0.3554 0.3655 0.6841 0.7280 0.0312 0.0362 -9,514 -49,885 -10,014 -49,080 -21,015 -49,125 28,014 -49,225 5,414 -49,001 11.02 -8.05 YES NO 1362 1362 0.2147 -15322 8.62 BOLD: Significant at 0.10 or greater a: H0 is no fixed effects b: Benchmark Year is 1998 15 Table 4. Impact of NEA Funding Estimating Technique: 1. OLS Dependent variable: Variable Intercept Pricet-1 NEAt FundRaiset PSREVt Year 1999 Year 2000 Year 2001 Year 2002 Year 2003 PerCapYjt STATE N R2 OLS One-Way Fixed Effects One-Way Fixed Effects DON STATE DON STATE S.E.) -68,593 34,579 -521.29 1,649.46 -2.102 3.118 6.087 0.2639 0.6013 0.0287 5073 48206 -7821 48171 -23625 48255 46782 48242 18582 48292 10.28 9.025 YES 1362 0.7485 S.E.) 26,396 6,244 -238.82 297.87 0.4277 0.5630 0.8517 0.0476 -0.0083 0.0052 -3526 8705 5489 8699 5982 8714 -1516 8712 -2257 8721 5.021 3.212 S.E.) 27404 36255 -554.00 1704.5 -4.07 2.883 6.603 0.3570 0.714 0.0370 -- S.E.) -5080 5871 -65.70 276.05 0.7816 0.4669 0.5420 0.0578 0.0117 0.0059 -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- -- 6.245 4.451 4.215 3.211 1362 0.3255 1362 0.8019 1362 0.2772 BOLD: Significant at 0.10 or greater a: H0 is no fixed effects b: Benchmark Year is 1998 . 16