Stock Market Development and Economic Growth in Developing countries: Evidence from Panel VAR framework Boopen Seetanah, V Sannassee, M Lamport aUniversity of Mauritius,Reduit, Mauritius * Corresponding author. Tel.:+230 4541041; E-mail address:b.seetanah@uom.ac.mu (Boopen Seetanah) Introduction ‘World stock markets are booming and stock markets in developing countries account for a disproportionately large share of this boom. Investors are venturing into the world’s newest markets and some are seeing handsome returns. But are developing countries themselves reaping any benefits from their stock markets?’ (Levine 1996) Economists have traditionally concentrated on the role of financial development to the economic growth of countries Overall there exists an overwhelming consensus that well-functioning financial intermediaries have played a significant role in economic growth (King and Levine, 1993 (a, b); Levine and Zervos, 1998; Levine et al, 2000 (a, b); Wachtel, 2003, Seetanah 2008 among others). More recently, the emphasis has been increasingly shifted to stock market indicators and the effect of stock markets on economic development1 and the latter has been the subject of recent theoretical interest (see Demirguc-Kunt and Levine, 1996, Levine and Zervos,1993, 1995, 1998 among others). Although some analysts view stock markets in developing countries as “casinos” that have little positive impact on economic growth, recent evidence suggests that stock markets may give a big boost to economic development. In fact, the focus on stock markets as an engine of economic growth is a new opening in financial literature. Going further, its benefits had been largely ignored in the past, but now there is consensus concerning the positive effects brought about by stock markets (see Pagano 1993, Levine and Zervos, 1998). In principle a well-developed stock market should theoretically increase saving (by enhancing the set of financial instruments available to savers to diversify their portfolios) and efficiently allocate capital to productive investments, which leads to an increase in the rate of economic growth. In doing so they provide an important source of investment capital at relatively low cost (Dailami and Aktin, 1990; Greenwood and Smith, 1992). A more developed equity market also provides liquidity that lowers the cost of the foreign capital that is essential for development. As such the presence of stock markets would mitigate the principal agent problem and reduce assymetryinformation, thus promoting efficient resource allocation and growth (Adjasi and Biekpe 2006). Perotti and van Oijen (1999) stress on the fact that diverse equity ownership creates a constituency for political stability, which, in turn, promotes growth. However it has also been argued that stock markets may be counter productive, for instance more liquid stock markets may put companies at risk of counter-productive takeovers or even with the high level of integration and with the development of technological progress, if left uncontrolled, a stock 1 Stock market development involves the deepening of the stock market by increasing market capitalisation, as compared to banking sector development where monetisation increases financial intermediary development. 2 market can lead to economic collapse. Moreover, the effect of uncertainty on savings rate and economic growth as markets become more liquid is ambiguous. (Bencivenga and Smith 1991). Empirical evidence shows the existence of a strong positive correlation between stock market development and economic growth (Atje and Jovanovich, 1993, Demirgüç-Kunt and Levine, 1996a, b, Korajczyk, 1996, Levine and Zervos, 1996, 1998). However there exists some authors who could not established any significant link between stock market development and growth as well, for instance Bencivenga and Smith (1991), Naceur and Ghazouani (2007) and Adjasi and Biekpe (2006) for developing countries cases. In fact, previous empirical research has suggested a connection between stock market development and economic growth, but is far from definitive. Although the relationship postulated is a causal one, most empirical studies have addressed causality, dynamics and endogeneity obliquely, if at all. Moreover the existing literature tend to focus overwhelmingly on developed countries sample and moreover have failed (Levine and Zervos (1993), Atje and Jovanovic (1993), Levine and Zervos (1998)) to decouple the relative contribution of banking and stock market development on economic growth in a single framework. Our work is believed to depart from and contribute to the existing literature in various ways. In the first instance it focuses on a panel set of developing countries and moreover simultaneously examines banking sector development, stock market development, and economic growth in a unified framework. It deals with issues of unmeasured cross country heterogeneity, causality, dynamics and endogeneity, elements relatively ignored in the literature of growth modelling, by innovatively employing rigorous panel VAR procedures to examine the complex linkages between stock market 3 development, bank development and economic growth. Such a framework will enable us not only to detect any bi causal relationships but also the presence of indirect effects banking and stock market development on growth. The complementarity and subsitutabilty element of bank and stock market development will eventually be assessed. The data set comprises of 27 developing countries studies over a period of 15 years (1991-2007). The rest of the paper is as follows: Section II reviews existing literature on the link between financial development and economic growth; Section III describes the methodology applied in this research as well as sources of data; section IV deals with the empirical analysis and section V concludes the study. II Literature review Financial Development and Economic Growth The theoretical underpinnings of the relationship between financial depth and growth can be traced back to the work of Schumpeter (1912) and, more recently to McKinnon (1973) and King and Levine (1993). These authors claimed that financial development may lead to growth in that a welldeveloped financial system performs several critical functions to enhance the efficiency of intermediation namely by reducing information, transaction, and monitoring costs. Creane, Goyal, Mushfiq, and Sab (2003) argued that a modern and efficient financial system mobilizes savings, promotes investment by identifying and funding good business opportunities, monitors the performance of managers, enables the trading, hedging, and diversification of risk, and facilitates the exchange of goods and services. These functions ultimately result in a more efficient allocation of resources, a more rapid accumulation of human and physical capital, and in faster technological progress, which in turn feed economic growth. Tsuru (2000) also explained the finance-growth link by arguing that financial development can promote economic growth via its positive impact on capital productivity or the 4 efficiency of financial systems in converting financial resources into real investment. However, its effect on the saving rate is ambiguous and could affect the growth rate negatively. ‘In net terms, the impact on welfare is likely to be positive, since increased efficiency of investment in the long term can offset any reduction in the propensity to save’ Tsuru (2000). The relationship between financial development and economic growth was in fact extensively analysed more than two decades ago by Goldsmith (1969), McKinnon (1973), Shaw (1973) and others. They found strong and positive correlations between the degree of financial market development and the rate of economic growth. More comprehensive empirical research was undertaken by King and Levine (1993) who confirmed a very strong relationship between each of their four financial development indicators. Subsequent empirical work by Jayaratne and Strahan (1996), Levine and Zervos (1998) and more recently Roisseau and Sylla (2001) and Seetanah (2008) also confirmed the above. At the micro-economic, Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic (1998) and Rajan and Zingales (1998) reported that financial institutions have been crucial for firm and industrial expansion. However it is worth mentioning that there have been also some studies which could not confirm the beneficial economic effect of financial development, for instance Jappelli and Pagano (1994) and Ram (1999) among others. It should be pointed out that is only recently that scholars have been incorporating the issue of causality and endogeneity in the debate. Among the very few studies is that of Levine et al (2000,a,b) who used dynamic panel estimators to overcome the issue of dynamic in the system. Their results were seen to reconcile with the fact that financial development is a good predictor of economic growth. Similar results were obtained by Beck, Levine and Loayza (1999), Xu (2000). Among the recent few studies focusing exclusively on developing countries feature Christopoulos and Tsionas (2004), Seetanah (2007, 2008) which confirmed earlier work of Luintel and Khan (1999) and that of Demetriades and Hussein (1996). Odedokun (1996) however found mixed results. 5 Stock Market Development and Economic Growth Literature on the topic of economic growth has taken a new stance, given the significance of the effect of stock markets on economic growth. Indeed, past literature considered financial intermediaries as the only causative channel to economic growth, and this new phase of developmental economics has achieved much in helping us understand this unexplored channel of causation since Bagehot (1873). In fact, stock markets and banks provide services that could either be complements or substitutes for each other depending on the industrialisation extent of the economy. Several possible avenues whereby stock market development have been advanced and discussed among them are the following. Stock markets provide an alternative channel for savings mobilisation and better resource allocation (N’Zué 2006). They enable savings mobilisation for financing “immense works” (Bagehot 1906, Hicks (1969), Greenwood and Smith 1996). More efficiently mobilised savings cause capital accumulation, which firms tap to finance large projects via equity issues. This, undoubtedly, spurs economic growth (Levine and Zervos 1998a, 1998b; Adjasi and Biekpe 2006). Focusing on liquidity, Bencivenga, et. al. (1996) and Levine (1991) argue that stock market liquidity plays a key role in economic growth. Without a liquid stock market, many profitable long-term investments would not be undertaken because savers would be reluctant to tie up their investments for long periods of time. In contrast, a liquid equity market allows savers to sell their shares easily, thereby permitting firms to raise equity capital on favorable terms. By facilitating longer-term, more profitable investments, a liquid market improves the allocation of capital and enhances prospects for long-term economic growth. A more developed equity market may also provide liquidity that lowers the cost of the foreign capital that is essential for development. Bencivenga et. al. (1996), and Neusser and Kugler (1998)). Liquidity has also 6 been argued to increase investor incentive to acquire information on firms and improve corporate governance (Kyle, 1984; Holmstrom and Tirole, 1993), thereby facilitating growth. Levine further argued that a liquid stock market complements a strong banking system, suggesting that banks and stock markets provide different bundles of financial services to the economy. However Demirguc-Kunt and Levine (1996) point out that increased liquidity can deter growth through at least three channels2. Indeed, for the case of the African subcontinent, liquidity has been a significant factor in hamper stock market development (Adjasi and Biekpe 2006) and consequently retards economic growth. Naceur and Ghazouani (2007) also posits that the beneficial effect of liquidity is only found after a threshold level. Sarkar (2006) also discussed that stock market development may have no effect on fixed capital formation due to the high transaction and information costs in least developed countries. A second link of stock market development on the economy is based on the premise that the presence of stock markets would mitigate the principal agent problem, thus promoting efficient resource allocation and growth (Adjasi and Biekpe 2006). Firstly, given that the stock price at any time is mirror of firm performance, weakening corporate governance would be reflected as a fall in share price. Management would have a disincentive to work in their personal interests if their compensation is tied to stock performance (Jensen and Murphy 1990). Thus the emphasis is on the role of equity markets in providing proper incentives for managers to make investment decisions. Dow and 2 Demirguc-Kunt and Levine (1996) point out that increased liquidity can deter growth through at least three channels. First, by increasing returns to investments, greater stock market liquidity may reduce saving rates through income and substitution effects. If savings rates fall enough and if there is an externality attached to capital accumulation, greater stock market liquidity may slow economic growth. Second, by reducing the uncertainty associated with investment, greater stock market liquidity may reduce saving rates because of the ambiguous effects of uncertainty on savings. Third, stock market liquidity encourages investor myopia, adversely affecting corporate governance and thereby reduces economic growth. 7 Gorton (1997) argued that such investment decisions affect firm value over a longer time period than the managers’ employment horizons through equitybased compensation schemes. Binswanger (1999) and Yartey 2007, Bhide (1999) however argued that the above might not be true in a situation of investor myopia. The role of equity markets in providing portfolio diversification, enabling individual firms to engage in specialized production is bound to result in efficiency gains ( Acemoglu and Zilibotti, 1997, Capasso 2008). Indeed, in the presence of stock markets which provide for various vehicles for transferring risk through which investors can confidently invest. What follows from this is that investors now have the opportunity of switching from low-risk to high risk investments. Obstfeld (1994) shows that international risk-sharing through internationally integrated stock markets improves resource allocation and can accelerate growth. Indeed, stock markets have more information than do financial intermediaries and usually translate in more efficient allocation and better growth (Caporale et al 2004, Adjasi and Biekpe 2006, Atje and Jovanovic 1993). King and Levine (1993b) also stressed on the ability of equity markets to generate information about the innovative activity of entrepreneurs or the aggregate state of technology. Perotti and van Oijen (1999) also argued that that diverse equity ownership creates a constituency for political stability, which, in turn, promotes growth. Empirical review Pioneering work from Spears (1991), Pardy (1992) Atje and Jovanovic (1993), show that stock market development is strongly correlated with growth rates of real GDP per capita. More importantly, they found that stock market liquidity predict the future growth rate of economy. Levine and Zervos (1998), Filer et al. (1999), Rousseau and Wachtel (2000) and Tuncer and Alovsat 8 (2001) examined stock market-growth nexus and exhibited positive casual correlation between stock market development and economic activity. Nevertheless, most of earlier studies suffered from various statistical weaknesses namely with respect to endogeneity and causality issues together with unmeasured cross country heterogeneity. Subsequent research, with larger panel sets and longer time series and attempted to attend to the earlier criticisms. Beck, and Levine (2003) for instance investigated the impact of stock markets and banks on economic growth using a panel data set dynamic panels (GMM), that stock markets and banks positively influence economic growth. Chen et al (2004) , Paudel (2005) and Love and Zicchino (2006) also acknowledged that stock markets, due to their liquidity, enable firms to attain much needed capital quickly, hence facilitating capital allocation, investment and growth. Alam and Hasan (2003) for the case of the US also found a significant positive impact of stock market development on economic growth. Bahadur and Neupane (2006) concluded that stock markets fluctuations predicted the future growth of an economy and causality is found only in real variables. More recent studies have employed vector models but has been restricted to country case studies mainly and among them features Enisa and Olufisayo (2009), N’Zué (2006) for the case of Ghana , Shahbaz, Ahmed and Ali (2008) for Pakistan and Agrawalla and Tuteja (2007) for the Indian case. There exists however few studies which could not establish any significant link in the stock market-economic growth nexus (refer to theoretical and empirical works of Bencivenga and Smith 1991; Demirguc-Kunt and Levine, 1996; Adjasi and Biekpe 2006; Ghazouani, 2007 and Sarkar 2006 among others). It is noteworthy that Rousseau and Xiao (2007) for the case of China although found that banking sector development was central to the Chinese success, however could not establish any significant relationship for the case of stock market development. 9 In summary, previous empirical research has suggested a connection between stock market development and economic growth, but is far from definitive. Although the relationship postulated is a causal one, most empirical studies, until lately have addressed causality obliquely, and this even more pronounced in the case of panel data analysis. Moreover very few of them have adopted a unified economic mode where both banking and stock development are simultaneously considered in a framework that allows for dynamics, feedbacks and endogeneity issues. To resolve them this paper uses VAR procedures in panel analysis to examine the linkage between stock market development, bank development and economic growth. III Methodology and Data Analysis The model that has been used in this study is based on the principles of some earlier studies (e.g. King and Levine, 1993; Levine and Zervos, 1998; Levine et al., 2000, Wachtel, 1998, 2001, Christopoulos and Tsionas, 2004 and Seetanah, 2008). The model takes the following functional form3: Y f ( IVTGDP, XMGDP, SER, INDEX , PRIGDP ) (1) The dependent variable output, Y was proxied by the real per capita gross domestic product (GDP)4. IVTGDP is the country’s investment divided by its Gross Domestic Product (investment ratio), XMGDP is total of export and an import divided by the GDP of the country and is a measure of openness, EMP is the employment level and SER is the secondary enrolment ratio and proxies for 3 Refer to Seetanah(2008) for a comprehensive justification of the explanatory variables. This measure has been widely used in the literature for instance King and Levine, 1993, Odedokun ,1996; Levine and Zervos, 1998; Ram, 1999 , Seetanah, 2007) 4 10 the quality of human capital. To measure banking development, we follow (Levine et al., 2000) and used PRIGDP, that is the value of credits by financial intermediaries to the private sector divided by GDP and. PRIGDP has been used extensively as an indicator because it improves on other measures of financial development. Higher levels of PRIGDP are interpreted as higher levels of financing services and therefore greater financial intermediary development. This measure of financial development is also more than a simple measure of banking sector size. PRIGDP isolates credit issued to the private sector, as opposed to credit issued to governments, government agencies, and public enterprises. Furthermore, it excludes credits issued by the central bank. Particularly in the context of our study, we consider individual indicators of stock market liquidity. The rationale behind adopting disaggregated indicators is to capture the different effects between stock market development and economic growth more feasibly rather than adopting a single indicator that would be focussed on a single aspect ((Levine and Zervos, 1998). Our indicators of stock market development have been used in previous studies (for example, Pagano 1993 and Demirgiic-Kunt and Levine 1996, Rousseau and Wachtel, 2000, Beck and Levine, 2003). The ratio of stock market capitalization to GDP (INDEX1) is a measure of both the stock market's ability to allocate capital to investment projects and its ability to provide significant opportunities for risk diversification for investors. The ratio of total value of shares traded to GDP (INDEX2) and the ratio of total value of shares traded to market capitalization (INDEX3) are indicators of market liquidity. The former measures the ability to trade economically significant positions on the stock market, and the latter is an indicator of liquidity of assets traded on the market, not adjusted for the size of the market relative to the economy. We also combine the three indicators in an equally weighted index of market development, INDEX. For the sake of discussion in this study we will focus on 11 the result using the composite proxy INDEX and only report the results of the other three indices. The specification used in this study is of a log linear one. Recall model from above and taking logs on the right hand side of the equation results in the following: yit 0 1ivtgdpit 2 xmgdpit 3 serit 4 index 5 prigdp it it (2) where i denotes the different countries in the sample and t denotes the time dimension. The small letters denotes the natural logarithm of the variables. The main sources of our independent variables are from the World Bank’s ‘World Development Indicators’ CD RPM and the IMF’s ‘International Financial Statistics’ (IFS) CD ROM except for the case of SER, where the World Development Reports and individuals country’s Central Statistical Office’s has been consulted. Using the Im, Pesaran, and Shin (1995) panel unit root tests, the test was applied on the dependent and independent variables. Im, Pesaran, and Shin (1995) developed a panel unit root test for the joint null hypothesis that every time series in the panel is non-stationary. This approach is based on the average of individual series ADF test and has a standard normal distribution once adjusted in a particular manner. Results of this test applied on our time series in levels reject a unit root in favor of stationarity (the results were also confirmed by the Fisher-ADF and Fisher-PP panel unit root tests, refer to appendix) at the 5 percent significance level for each variable. It was judged safe to continue with the panel data estimates of the above econometric specifications. 12 Analysis and discussion Endogeniety issues and the Panel Vector Autoregressive Model There might still be the possibility of the loss of dynamic information even in panel data framework as the dependent variable may have something to do in explaining itself as well (Levine et al, 2000). It is likely that there exists dynamic feedbacks and indirect effects among the variables in a growth function, particularly with respect to our financial development variables. Including these feedbacks are essential to the modeling of our hypotheses since as Pereira and De Fructos (1999) argued ‘if feedback exists, an elasticity of zero with respect to some determinants in a static framework would have been neither necessary nor sufficient for public capital to have no effect on output.’ Indeed both banking and stock market development can directly affect output directly but they may also have indirect positive impacts5 on a country’s output as they may affect private capital and other inputs in the growth functions. Furthermore one should realise that the output level of a country may also translate into the more development in the financial system, that this resulting in reverse causation (see Seetanah 2008 among others). Given the possibility of endogeneity and causality issues we use vector autoregressions (VAR) on panel data to enable us to consider the complex relationship that might exist between banking and stock market development economic growth6. This framework also allows us to test the substitutability and complementarity issue between banking and stock market development rigourously. Moreover, Panel VAR also allows for a firm-specific unobserved 5 It has also been argued though that higher availability of the public input could also reduce the demand for private inputs and crowding out effects (Lighthart, 2000). 6 Powell, Ratha, and Mohapatra (2002) and Love and Zicchino, (2006) used similar approach in their respective study. The former studied the interrelationships between inflows and outflows of capital and other macro variables and the later that of financial development and dynamic investment behaviour. 13 heterogeneity in the levels of the variables. Panel-data vector autoregression combines the traditional VAR approach, which treats all the variables in the system as endogenous, with the panel-data approach, which allows for unobserved individual heterogeneity. We specify a first order VAR model as follows: it 0 1 it 1 i t (3) where zt is a six-variable vector (gdp, ivtgdp, xmgdp, ser,index, prigdp) and the variables are as defined previously. We use i to index countries and t to index time, are the parameters and is the error term. For the econometric analysis, the system of equations as above is expressed as a log-linear regression for ease of interpretation. The lowercase variables are the natural log of the respective uppercase variables In applying the VAR procedure to panel data, we need to impose the restriction that the underlying structure is the same for each cross-sectional unit. Since this constraint is likely to be violated in practice, one way to overcome the restriction on parameters is to allow for “individual heterogeneity” in the levels of the variables by introducing fixed effects, denoted by i in the model (Love and Zicchino, 2006). Since the fixed effects are correlated with the regressors due to lags of the dependent variables, the mean-differencing procedure commonly used to eliminate fixed effects would create biased coefficients. To avoid this problem we use forward meandifferencing, also referred to as the ‘Helmert procedure’ (see Arellano and Bover, 1995). This procedure removes only the forward mean, i.e. the mean of all the future observations available for each firm-year. This transformation 14 preserves the orthogonality between transformed variables and lagged regressors, so we can use lagged regressors as instruments and estimate the coefficients by system GMM7. Estimation and Analysis We estimate the coefficients of the system given in (3) after the fixed effects have been removed and Table 1 report the results of the model. Table 1:Results from the VAR model (1991-2007) Response to Respons Constant gdp t-1 e of ivtgdpt- xmgdpt- sert-1 index- prigdpt-1 1 1 1 Gdp ivtgdp xmgdp ser -0.43 0.25 0.44 0.38 0.21 0.13 (1.64) (2.34)* (2.15)* (2.19)* (1.99)* (1.87) (1.98)* 0.36 0.26 0.64 0.15 0.17 (1.87)* (2.15*) (2.21)* (2.14*) (1.81)* (2.22) (1.82) 0.88 0.21 0.17 0.57 0.09 0.11 (1.75)* (2.21)* (2.13)* (1.97)* (1.58) (1.51) (1.02) 0.11 0.26 0.07 0.08 0.54 0.03 (1.44) (2.24)* (1.33) (1.65)* (1.98)* (0.45) (1.52) 0.12 0.17 0.19 0.05 0.08 7 In our case the model is “just identified”, i.e. the number of regressors equals the number of instruments, therefore system GMM is numerically equivalent to equation-by-equation 2SLS. 15 index prigdp 0.43 0.12 0.11 0.19 0.19 (1.34) (1.88)* (1.72)* (1.87)* (2.11)* (1.96) (1.77) 0.32 0.16 0.12 0.05 0.15 (2.23)** (1.96)* (1.44) (1.95)* (1.22) (2.22)*** 405 405 405 405 405 405 25 25 25 25 25 25 (1.54) No. of 0.57 0.13 0.15 0.56 obs No of countries The VAR model is estimated by GMM and fixed effects are removed prior to estimation. Reported numbers show the coefficients of regressing the row variables on lags of the column variables. Heteroskedasticity adjusted tstatistics are in parentheses. *** indicates significance at 1% level, ** at 5% and *** at 10% respectively. The small letters denotes variables in natural logarithmic and t values are in parentheses Table 1 is a composite table where each column can be viewed and analysed as an independent function. For instance, of interest to us primaririly is column 1 which is in fact our output equation. It is observed that the coefficient of index is positive and significant (+0.13) and this suggest that stock market development has had a positive and significant effect on economic growth for our sample of developing countries over the year of studies. In fact, the coefficient of 0.17, a measure of output elasticity, denotes that a one percent increase in stock market development contributed to 0.17 percent increase in 16 the GDP of our selected economies and this is the direct effect. These positive elasticities results takes into account the often ignored issues of panel stationarity, dynamics, and endogeinty. The results are consistent to those of Levine and Zervos (1998) and Rousseau and Wachtel (2000) but do not validate those of Adjasi and Biekpe (2006). It is noteworthy that the three indices of stock market development namely index1, index2 and index3 all also yielded positive and significant coefficients of 0.15, 0.09 and 0.11 respectively. Interestingly the banking development proxy also exhibits positive and significant effects on growth and suggest that banks and stock markets play somewhat different roles in economic progress (similar to Levine and Zervos 1998) and that put together financial development is confirmed to be an ingredient of growth. Interestingly the higher coefficient of PRIGDP tends to show that in, developing countries at least, the banking sector’s contribution to economic performance is relatively higher than stock market development. This can be explained by the fact that developing countries’ stock markets have not yet reached those maturity levels (from both investors and firms perspectives) as the case of developed or newly industrialised countries. Moreover financial intermediaries remain till now the major source of investment credits in most of the economies under study. It should be stressed that our results oppose those found by Atje and Jovanovic (1993) and Caporale, Howells and Soliman (2004). The rest of the growth explanatory variables turned out to be also significant and have the expected signs. It should be however noted that the magnitude of the stock market development (and even the banking development) coefficient remains relatively smaller than for instance private investment and 17 openness which remains the major growth drivers in developing according to this study. The VAR framework, as discussed before, enables us to gauge more interesting insights on endogeneity issues and indirect effects as well. While it has been shown that stock market development induces growth (stock market led growth), referring to the ‘index’ equation, it is observed that a reverse causation exists as well as output appears to be also a determinant of stock market development thus supporting a bi-causal and reinforcing relationship. In other words, output level which proxies economic well being and level of development, may play an important role in the development of stock markets as well. These results are consistent with those obtained from Rousseau and Wachtel (2000) and Seetanah (2008). The ‘index’ equation can also be viewed as a stock market development equation with, in addition to income level, education attainment investment level and banking development being other determinants. The latter is particularly interesting as it reveals some sort of complementarity between these the apparently competing source of bank based and market based finance. This is yet another rejoiner to Levine and Zervos (1998) argument that banks and stock markets play different roles in economic progress. One could also argue that banking development levels acts as some signalling effect on the financial system stability, lead to optimistic outlook and thus encouraging financial investment and stock development8. In general, thus, stock market development is bound to have better growth effects in the presence of the above three variables. Referring to the ‘investment equation’, positive indirect effects of stock market development on private investment are noted. This confirms the view that stock market development encourages private investment (including foreign investment). An elasticity value of 0.12 denotes that a percentage 8 Referring to the banking development equation, there is not significant evidence that stock market development encourages banking sector development directly 18 increase in index would lead to 0.12 increase in private investment. Given that the direct effect of investment is to the order of 0.44 percent increase in the GDP for a 1 percentage increase in private investment, put together this leads to a 0.12 x 0.44 percentage increase in the output after two years. This is an estimate of the indirect effect of stock market development on output via the private capital channel. Similar findings can be found for banking sector development. Finally, the presence of bi-causality between private investment, education and income level is found. Orthogonalised impulse-response functions analysis9 and variance decompositions10 overall produced equivalent results. Details are available from the corresponding author upon request. Conclusion and policy implications This paper focused on a panel set of developing countries to simultaneously examined banking sector development, stock market development, and economic growth in a unified framework. It employed rigorous panel VAR procedures to examine the complex linkages between stock market development, bank development and economic growth for the case of 27 developing countries studies over a period of 15 years (1991-2007). Results from the analysis showed that stock market development is an important ingredient of growth, but with a relative lower magnitude as compared to the other determinants of growth, particularly with banking development. Interesting stock market development and banking development are seen to 9 The impulse-response functions describe the reaction of one variable to the innovations in another variable in the system, while holding all other shocks equal to zero. Impulse response are orthogonalised since the actual variance–covariance matrix of the errors is unlikely to be diagonal. 10 This shows the percent of the variation in one variable that is explained by the shock to another variable, accumulated over time. The variance decompositions show the magnitude of the total effect 19 be complement to each other and moreover there are important indirect effects through ‘investment channel’ to growth. It is noteworthy to emphasise on the dynamic process of the stock market development and growth nexus. Given the above findings, the policy implications for government are numerous. They should attempt to develop the financial sector even more and one of the first steps is to have less state involvement in the system. This includes cutting back on public ownership of financial institutions and minimising monetary financing of budget deficits. Government should ensure clear and concise rules for investment, and to attract capital on equity markets from the international monetary system.The deregulation and liberalization process should continue in a cautious way and more competition within the financial sector should be encouraged. This may mean a more opened approach to multinational banks and other institutions which would also benefit the industry in terms of financial innovation. As such stronger, more transparent institutional and legal framework should be present to consolidate the sector. Investment in human resources remains also a major factor to accompany the sector’s development process. Moreover, governments should promote stock market liquidity by for instance propagating knowledge to the public of the benefits of investing in stock markets (N’Zué 2006) and moreover, create state-run mutual funds so as to ensure higher liquidity on stock markets11. These incentives would promote both domestic and foreign investments to penetrate the domestic economies, and thus help draw immense benefits from these sources of capital. 11 An example is the case of Argentina where the state runs its mutual fund to favour its stock market. 20 REFERENCES Akinlo A. E ,and Akinlo O. 2009, Stock market development and economic growth: Evidence from seven sub-Sahara African countries, Journal of Economics and Business Volume 61, Issue 2, March-April 2009, Pages 162-171 Arestis, Phillip, Panicos Demetriades, and Kul Luintel, 2001. Financial Development and Economic Growth: The Role of Stock Markets," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 2001, pp. 16-41. Atje, Raymond and Boyan Jovanovic, 1993. Stock Markets and Development, European Economic Review, 1993, pp. 632-640. Beck T and Levine T. 2004. Stock markets, banks, and growth: Panel evidenceJournal of Banking & Finance Volume 28, Issue 3, March 2004, Pages 423-442 Bencivenga, Valerie and Bruce Smith, 1991. Financial Intermediation and Endogenous Growth," Review of Economic Studies, 1991, pp. 195{209. Christopoulos, D.K. and Tsionas E. G., 2004. Financial development and economic growth: Evidence from panel unit root and cointegration tests. Journal of Development Economics, 73, 55-74. Creane S., Goyal, A. Mushfiq M., and Sab R. 2003. Financial development and growth in the Middle East and North Africa, IMF Working Paper, Washington, DC. Demetriades, Panicos and Khaled Hussein, 1996. Does Financial Development Cause Economic Growth? Time-series Evidence From 16 Countries., Journal of Development Economics, 1996, 51, 387-411. 21 Demirgüç-Kunt A. and Maksimovic V. 1998. Law, finance, and firm growth, Journal of Finance, 53, 2107-2139. Goldsmith, R., 1969. Financial structure and development, New Haven, Yale University Press. Imam Alam M, Hasan T 2003. The causality between stock market development and economic growth : evidence from the United States, Studies in Economics and Finance, 21 (1), 93-104 Jappeli T. and M. Pagano., 1994. Saving, growth and liquidity constraints, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(1), 83-109. Jayaratne J. and Strahan P.,1996. The Finance-Growth Nexus: Evidence from Bank Branch Deregulation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(3), pp. 639-70. Kennedy, P 2003, A guide to econometrics, 5th edition, Oxford, Blackwell King, R. and Levine R., 1993b. Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), pp. 717-37. King, Robert E. and Levine, Ross 1993a. “Financial Intermediation and Economic Development.” in Financial Intermediation in the Construction of Europe. Editors: Colin Mayer and Xavier Vives. London: Centre for Economic Policy and Research, pp. 156-89. Kirwan, F. and D. Holden, 1986, Emigrants’ Remittances, Non-Traded Goods andEconomic Source in the Source Country, Journal of Economic Studies, Vol. 13,No. 2, pp. 52-58. Levine R. and Zervos A., 1998. Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth. American Economic Review, 88(3), pp. 537-58. Levine R., Loayza N., and Beck T., 2000. Financial intermediation and growth: Causality and causes. Journal of Monetary Economics, 46, 31-77. 22 Levine R., Loayza N., and Beck T., 2000b. Finance and the sources of growth. Journal of Financial Economics, 58, 261-300. Levine, Ross, and Sarah Zervos, 1998. Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth," American Economic Review, June 1998. pp. 688-726 Love I and Zicchino L. 2006, Financial development and dynamic investment behavior: Evidence from panel VAR. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 46, 190-210 Luintel B., and Khan M. 1999. A Quantitative Reassessment of the FinanceGrowth Nexus: Evidence from a Multivariate VAR. Journal of Development Economics; V.60, pp. 381-405. Mc Kinnon R., 1973. Money and capital in economic development, Washington DC: Brookings Institution Odedokun, M., 1996. Alternative Econometric Approaches for Analysing the Role of the Financial Sector in Economic Growth: Time Series Evidence from LDCs. Journal of Development Economics; V.50-#1, pp.119-146. Odedokun M.O. 1998, Financial Intermediation and Economic Growth in Developing Countries, Journal of Economic Studies, Vol. 25 No.3, pp.203-224 Pereira, A.M. and R.F. De Frutos 1999. Public capital accumulation and private sector performance, Journal of Urban economics, Vol.46, pp300-322 Pereira, A. M. and O Roca-Sagales. 2003, Spillover effects of public capital formation: evidence from the Spanish Regions, Journal of Urban economics, Vol. 53 pp 238-256 Rajan R. and Zingales L., 2000. The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial Development in the 20th century, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No 265, OECD publishing 23 Ram R., 1999. Financial Development and Economic Growth: Additional evidence, The Journal of Development Studies, 35, No. 4, 1999, 164-174. Rousseau, Peter and Paul Wachtel, 2000. Financial Intermediation and Economic Performance: Historical Evidence from Five Industrialized Countries, Journal of Banking and Finance, 2000, pp. 1933-1957. Rousseau P and Sheng X, 2007. Banks, stock markets, and China's ‘great leap forward’ Emerging Markets Review Volume 8, Issue 3, September 2007, Pages 206-217 Schumpeter J., 1912. The Theory of Economic Development. Oxford University Press, Oxford Seetanah B. 2008. ‘Financial development and economic growth in an ARDL approach. Applied Economics Letter, 4(43), pp 43-50 Shaw E., 1973. Financial deepening in economic development, New York, Oxford University Press. Tsuru K., 2000. Finance and Growth: Some theoretical considerations, and a review of the empirical literature, Economics Department Working papers no 228. Wachtel, Paul. 2003. How much do we really know about growth and finance? Federal Xu Z., 2000. Financial development, investment and growth. Economic Inquiry, 38, 331-344 Appendix: List of developing countries Algeria, Angola, Brazil, Cameroon, China, Ghana, Egypt, Ethopia, India, Indonesia, Israel, Kenya, Mauritius, Malaysia, Malawi, Morroco, Mexico, Nigeria, Pakistan, South Africa, South Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, Tunisia, Uganda 24