ECOLE NATIONALE DU GENIE RURAL DES EAUX ET DES FORETS ENGREF TECHNICAL SYNTHESIS QUANTITATIVE MANAGEMENT OF WATER RESOURCES: COMPARISON OF THE EXISTING ASSESSMENTS OF VARIOUS TOOLS LEBOUCHER Bertrand E-mail: leboucher@engref.fr January 2006 ENGREF Centre de Montpellier ENGREF Centre de Montpellier B.P.44494 – B.P.44494 – 34093 MONTPELLIER CEDEX 5 34093 MONTPELLIER CEDEX 5 Tél. (33) 4 67 04 71 00 Tél. (33) 4 67 04 71 00 Fax (33) 4 67 04 71 01 Fax (33) 4 67 04 71 01 Ministère de l’Ecologie et du Développement Durable 20 avenue de Ségur - 75302 Paris 07 SP Tél. (33)1.42.19.20.21 KEY WORDS Water resource, quantitative management, prefectorial management, royalties, river contract, water table contract order, SAGE, Volumetric ABSTRACT Apart from specific agricultural areas, French water resources seem sufficient to handle the average during an average year. However, during specially dry years (e.g. 2003 and 2005), a real imbalance between water resources and their uses forced some very restrictive measures to be applied. These crisis showed the limits of the current tools used in the quantitative management of water resources in France. This work is a short summary of the existing assessments of some tools used to manage water resources. Some management tools try to avoid a crisis either by encouraging people to save water (e.g. royalties), or planning their removal long in advance (e.g. SDAGE, SAGE, PGE, quantitative management of water resources), whereas others try to limit the impact of crisis situations when they have already started (quantitative management of water resources, prefectorial orders). Managing water resources on a local scale (watershed) seems to be a good idea. Gathering frequently the people related to the management of the resources with highly motivated elected officials appears to be a necessity for the project to move forward quickly. Finally, the different tools used in the quantitative management of water resources seem to be more complementary than competitors. In fact, some of them define a regulation framework whereas others put into concrete effect the measures set out in the schedule. 2 INTRODUCTION Within the last few years, the imbalance between water resources and their use has been increasing. The low-water of 2003 is a good illustration of this trend. A low amount of rainfalls and a particularly long heat wave were the causes of severe low-waters. This event showed how committed to the management of water resources the authorities could be (77 districts planned restrictive uses of their water resources) and also the limits of the current tools used in the quantitative management of water resources. Many different tools have been used in France to manage water resources (quantitative management): regulatory tools (e.g. prefectorial order) economic tools (e.g. royalties) tools used for participative water management (e.g. SAGE, contracts) Some management tools try to avoid crisis either encouraging people to save water (e.g. royalties), or planning their removal long in advance (e.g. SDAGE, SAGE, PGE), whereas others try to limit the impact of crisis situations once they have already started (quantitative management of water resources, prefectorial order). This report is a short summary of existing assessments of some tools to manage water resources. It should be helpful to have a better understanding of their limits and to assess and compare their interest and efficiency. Although brief reviews of the contents of these tools may precede their assessments, this work contains no exhaustive presentation. 3 PREFECTORIAL ORDERS This section deals with two tools used in the quantitative management of water resources: prefectorial orders and framework orders. These two statutory tools are greatly interconnected. O SHORT REVIEW OF PREFECTORIAL ORDERS AND FRAMEWORK ORDERS: Prefectorial orders Section 9 of the French Water Act of January 3rd 1992 and its Order in Council of September 24th 1992 allow prefects to temporarily limit or suspend the consumption of water in the event of threats of drought. When it appears to be a necessity, the watershed prefect may write an order to coordinate the actions in all the departments included in the watershed. In this case, all the prefects of the concerned departments have to write prefectorial orders conform to the one of the watershed prefect. A prefectorial order is a widely used statutory tool. The low-water of 2003 is a good illustration of this trend. Among 77 departments concerned by actual limitations of water consumption, more than 800 prefectorial orders were published. Also, in the more recent case of the low-water of 2005, 72 departments had already applied restrictive measures on the consumption of water on August 30th 2005, and more than 600 prefectorial orders had been issued before September 16th 2005. Error! Néant Aucun arrêté Mesures planifiées Mesures de limitation des usages non effectives mais des mesures ont été planifiées à long terme en cas de nécessité (arrêtés cadre) Niveau 1: mesures limitées: toute mesure de limitation des usages inférieures ou égales à 1j/7 ou à 15% du volume sur au moins un bassin Mesures effectives Niveau 1: mesures fortes: mesure de limitation des usages supérieures ou égales à 1j/7 sur au moins un bassin versant mais inférieures à 7j/7 Niveau 3: restrictions totales: restriction totale sur au moins un bassin versant Pic. 1 : Prefectorial orders applied in August 30th 2005 (MEDD, 2005) Prefectorial orders are usually issued after meetings of a group called the “drought cell” gathering all the representatives of the people involved in the management of water resources in the concerned area. To be sure that the prefectorial order is observed, DDE, DDAF and CSP may check with consumers. They also play an important role in communication. Indeed, checking with and 4 meeting consumers gives them an opportunity to explain to people the reasons why such restrictive measures have been taken. (DIREN, 2004) It should be noted that some local communities strenghten the measures taken through prefectorial order by issuing municipal by-laws. The purpose of the latter is usually either to take more restrictive measures than the ones issued in the prefectorial order, or to take into account local factors. These municipal by-laws are mainly used to report to worries about breaks in the drinkable water supply. Framework orders Framework orders have been created by the decree 92-1041 of September 24th 1992. They are usually set up in catchment areas and define the restrictive measures that are to be applied in the event of droughts. Thanks to their transparancy, framework orders make the management of water resources easier when the crisis has already occured than mere prefectorial orders (« in the action » management). They also help to coordinate the restrictive measures taken by the various concerned departments, i.e. they ensure the coherence of the actions based in particular on the principle of upstream-downstream solidarity. It is important to notice that unlike prefectorial orders framework orders are not limited in time. Nevertheless, they can be modified. O REVIEW OF FEEDBACK AND ASSESSMENTS OF PREFECTORIAL AND FRAMEWORK ORDERS Feedback on the management of the low-water of 2003 showed that even a massive use of prefectorial orders and framework orders didn’t give satisfactory results in terms of the quantitative management of water resources (DIREN, 2004). For example, more rivers dried-up in 2003 than during an average year (e.g. in the department called Doubs more than 300 km of rivers dried-up, and in the Loire, more than 340 km). Therefore, it seems wise to analyse and assess the effectiveness of these tools so as to understand what could be improved. Assessment of the tools General remarks : The “drought cell” appears to have a positive impact on the quantitative management of water resources. Its frequent meetings help the people involved in water resources to better understand each other. It usually gathers representative of farmers, Météo France, EDF, the civil service, drinking water unions, water distribution companies and hydraulic structure managers. Associations involved either in fishing or the preservation of nature are usually welcome. However, the composition of the cell often appears to be unbalanced, which directs the debate on the side of the most represented interest group. Apart from the inside of the drought cell, the feedback on the low-water of 2003 shows a lack of information about the measures taken or to see if the crisis became worse. The implementation of a framework order helps to improve this diffusion of information as the measures to be taken in case of a crisis are pre-established. Controlling users of water resources directly on site is an effective way to check whether or not the restrictive measures are applied but it also helps to broadcast information about the measures and their causes (e.g. among the 2500 controls made in 2005, about 95% showed a good respect of the restrictive measures) (MEDD, 2005). However, the multiplicity of the water resources combined with numerous infringements make on-site controls a really difficult exercise. To make it easier and more efficient some French departments (e.g. la 5 Vienne) draw up a schedule of the on-site controls with the public prosecutor’s department before the crisis occurs. Finally, the lack of coordination between various concerned departments sometimes causes conflict between people using the same water resource but subjected to different rules of consumption. Prefectorial orders : Prefectorial orders usually set up time-slots during which people are allowed to use water resources. These time-slots become shorter as the crisis worsens. It may end with a total ban. Feedback on the 2003 low-water underlined the fact that restrictive measures are usually adopted a little late with regard to the situation. This may well be the consequence of a difficult collection of data (pluviometry, level of groundwater and rivers etc) usually carried out in haste and with little popularity of the measures to be taken by the Prefect. Therefore, an early management of the drought would seem to be more efficient. Framework order : The assessment of the measures effectively applied in the Departments where a framework order was already established in 2003 shows a net tendency to slowness. In particular the decisions of application (translation of measures into action) were usually late with regard to the crisis - especially for the first restrictive measure to be adopted and the measure of total ban - and less tough than planned in the framework order. Assessment of results due to the application of prefectorial orders : It is legitimate for the stakeholders in the quantitative management of water resources to wonder whether or not the adopted restrictive measures are efficient. Nevertheless, the assessment of the impact of the actions scheduled in a prefectorial order appears to be a really tough exercise. For example, when a prefectorial order defines timeslots so that water users (e.g. farmers) are allowed to pump water out only within these timeslots, overequipment can make this measure ineffective as it is then possible for the user to increase the outputs (the discharge rate) and so to free himself from the time constraints. Other phenomena interfere too. During the low-water of 2003, the measures of total ban on water-taking seem to have had a good impact on the flow-rates of several rivers. However, it is difficult to know if this good impact was mainly due to the prefectorial orders or to the “natural” halt to irrigation in August. To conclude, although it is difficult to quantify the efficiency of prefectorial and framework orders, the main factors that may guarantee a positive effect of the taken measures have been identified : anticipation of the measures and a strong upstream-downstream solidarity to contribute to equity between water users. Therefore, it seems essential to promote framework orders since they define in advance the measures to be taken and their thresholds of application. Then these measures are applied through Prefectorial orders when a drought occurs. Moreover, unlike mere Prefectorial orders, framework orders take into account the principle of upstream-downstream solidarity since they are defined on the whole watershed. So, to optimise framework orders it seems important to improve the anticipation of the measures, to make sure that they are simple and gradual by defining few thresholds but in adapted intervals and ensure the upstream-downstream solidarity on the whole watershed. The first feedback on the low-water of 2005 clearly shows an improvement in the management of drought between 2003 and 2005. In particular, the restrictive measures were taken earlier in 2005 than in 2003 (e.g. there were more framework orders than in 2003, see picture 2) and the restrictions were also more adapted to the situation of crisis (Prefectorial 6 orders were applied faster than in 2003) (MEDD, 2005). Etat des arrêtés de limitation des usages Néant Mesures planifiées Aucun arrêté Mesures de limitation des usages non effectives mais des mesures ont été planifiées à long terme en cas de nécessité (arrêtés cadre) Pic. 2 : French Departments having set up Framework orders in 2005 (MEDD, 2005) 7 TOOLS USED FOR PARTICIPATIVE MANAGEMENT (CONTRACTS, SAGE) This part only deals with river contracts and SAGE. Other tools of participative management have been developed such as PGE (low-water management plan) set up in Adour-Garonne but because of a lack of time they haven’t been tackled in this paper. O SHORT REVIEW OF CONTRACTS AND SAGE SAGE and contracts are tools used for participative management of water resources. They combine meetings, measures planification and regulations on coherent perimeters of interventions (in the case of river contracts, there might be no regulation approach) (ROUSSEAU Cécile, 2005). Since these two tools are complex and look quite similar, they are often little known and even confused by stakeholders. The table below briefly sets out some important characteristics of these tools. Principles SAGE Planification tool with regulatory power (not yet opposable to third party but the current new law project may change that) River contract Intervention tool that schedule makings and their financial plan Mainly management of waterway, water table and enclosure Integrated management on the scale of the watershed Duration of application (approx.) Perimeter Field of intervention management supervision partnership 10 years 5 to 7 years Catchment area, perimeter usually Catchment area defined in the concerned SDAGE and finalized by the prefect Underground and surface water Underground and surface water management (quality and quantity) management (quality and quantity) Management of aquatic ecosystems Management of aquatic ecosystems Preservation of wetlands Preservation of wetlands CLE (Local Commission for Water) Prefect and catchment area committee No financial contract with the partners River committee Prefect and catchment area committee Partnership between 4 entities : State / Region and Department / Water agencies / Inter-communal Syndicates concerned by the project Duration of Very long (2 to 4 years) Long (may be shorter if set up after a elaboration SAGE) The main purpose of a SAGE is to formalise a project on water management by setting common rules, whereas the river contract is a technical and financial agreement without any legal authority. Nowadays, contracts and SAGE are tending to become closer, to complement each other. In fact, it seems that a SAGE is facilitated by the presence of a contract which translates in a concrete way the orientations of the SAGE on part of its application area (ROUSSEAU Cécile, 2005). Therefore, in the Drôme department the implementation of the SAGE – approved by the Prefect in 1997- was made easier by the presence of a first river contract 8 (1990-1997) and a second contract signed in 1999 also helped to put into practice some recommendations of the SAGE. This trend to couple SAGE and contracts has been confirmed by the current concern of the MEDD (Ministry of Ecology and Sustainable Development) to promote operational SAGE (BOURDAT Eva, DESPORTES Geoffroy, PARÉ Sébastien, 2002). In particular, the contracts following upon a SAGE benefit from better financial rates. In the same way, the concrete measures planned in a contract are strengthened by the elaboration of a more general document with legal impact such as a SAGE. O ASSESSMENT OF CONTRACTS AND SAGE Contracts : To illustrate the assessments of contracts related to water management, this part deals more particularly with river contracts. The information below comes mainly from feedback on experiments carried out in the Nord-Pas-de-Calais, Rhône-Alpes and Hérault. The « AScA, ADAGE environnement, 2001» study was in charge of analysing 57 contracts in Rhône-Alpes in 2001. It defined four criteria to assess these contracts: Their relevance (comparison between goals and stakes) Their coherence (comparison between actions undertaken and goals) Their efficiency (comparison between results and goals) Their efficacy (comparison between means and results) Relevance of contracts : According to the « AScA, ADAGE environnement, 2001» study, their is a real adequacy between the goals and the stakes of contracts. However, the level of realisation aimed for the objectives of the contract is usually not so clear. The goals of a contract usually consist of “restoring the river”, “protecting populations from flooding” etc. The lack of accuracy of goals makes an assessment of the contract a particularly challenging task. Furthermore, the balance between the effort put into the achievement of the different goals of a contract is usually not insured. The problems related to the quality of water or the prevention of floods concentrate most of the efforts to the detriment of the fight against pesticides, the quantitative management of water resources or the ecological restoration of the river (ROUSSEAU Cécile, 2005). Coherence of contracts : The coherence of a contract is a subject that is not sufficiently dealt with before signature (DIREN Rhône-Alpes, 2004). This may be due to the fact that most stakeholders have poor knowledge of the various management instruments (BOURDAT Eva, DESPORTES Geoffroy, PARÉ Sébastien, 2002). The quantitative management of water resources in more a question of setting rules to share the resource between users than just a question of building. Therefore, a contract may need a statutory support such as a SAGE to reach its goals. For example when the main goal is to support a minimum flow for a given river, it is usual to define rules to share the water resources between consumers. It may then be a necessity to set up a statutory management tool as a SAGE. The cases of the Orb river and the Astienne aquifer are good illustrations of this. Both the legal representatives in charge of the Orb river and the Astienne aquifer have decided to set up a SAGE to complement the existing contracts so as to improve the management of the minimum flows of the Orb river and to control the amount of water pumped in the Aspienne aquifer (ROUSSEAU Cécile, 2005). Efficiency of contracts : The lack of accuracy in the definition of the goals and the absence of indicators to follow up the undertaken actions make it almost impossible to assess the efficiency of contracts in term of quantitative management of the water resources. 9 Efficacy of contracts : Contracts are particularly adapted to hydraulic operations and river-work. Indeed, as they make the stakeholders of a given watershed to act in concert, they lead to economies of scale. Nevertheless, one of their weakest points is the absence of optional scenarios, even sometimes the absence of debate on the priorities in term of action. This does not allow one to ensure that the taken actions are the best in terms of efficacy. Pic. 3 :Progress status of the river contracts in France in December 1st 2005 (Office International de l'Eau, 2005) Although river contracts always seem to be interesting in terms of quantitative management of water resources (AScA, ADAGE environnement, 2001), they may not be the most efficient tool of management. In particular, river contracts have no statutory reach. Therefore, they do not seem able to ensure a real commitment of local populations in the project of management of their water resources (DIREN Rhône-Alpes, 2004). In the case of quantitative management of water resources, contracts are mainly used to build structures to support the minimum flow of a river (e.g. contract for the river Doux where a dam has been built). However, the results are often disappointing. For example, a SAGE is being set up for the river Doux as the contract has not given significant results. This is strengthened by a problem of perenniality of contracts. In fact, a contract lasts 5 to 7 years and is not renewable. Therefore, it only has this short period of time to ensure a good perennial state for the river. If this difficult task is not achieved by the end of the contract, then - as there is no more financial support - the upkeep of the river is interrupted (BOURDAT Eva, DESPORTES Geoffroy, PARÉ Sébastien, 2002). The establishment of 10 statutory tools to manage the consumption of water resources (e.g. SAGE) is a necessity (DIREN Rhône-Alpes, 2004). To conclude, the assessment of contracts is made difficult by the lack of indicators of followup and the lack of data on the initial condition of the water resources. From a financial point of view contracts are a very attractive tool to local communities as the Department, the Region, the State and the Water Agencies fund the main part of the project. However, contracts seem to reach their limits when the matters are mainly due to conflicts of use or regional development. Then a statutory tool seems necessary and it may also be interesting to couple it with a contract. If it is decided that a contract is the best solution to solve the current problems in the quantitative management of a given water resource, the success of the implementation of this tool mainly depends on four factors (DIREN Rhône-Alpes, 2004) : A formalisation of the goals and the actions to be taken with their definitions as accurate as possible and a hierarchical organisation of the actions A river committee that works properly (regular meetings with people with are representative of the economic and social tissue of the concerned area, real debates during meetings) A good co-ordination of the actions during the whole duration of the contract A follow-up of the contract to assess it and modify it if necessary. A check-up of the balance between the efforts put into different themes (quality, quantity of water, ecological status of the area etc). Now the question is : will the State be able to follow this trend either from a financial, technical or personnel point of view ? SAGE : SAGE were created by the French Water Act of January 3rd 1992. “In a hydrogeographic unit or a water-bearing system, a SAGE ( Plan of Organisation and Management of Waters) plans the general objectives of use, development and quantitative and qualitative protection of superficial and subterranean water resources, aquatic ecosystems and wetlands.” (section 5 of the French Water Act of January 3rd 1992). At the beginning, SAGE was presented as the “miracle” tool to manage water at a relevant scale (catchment area, aquifer) and solve all the problems related to water resources (ALLAIN Sophie, 2003). The picture showing the furtherance of the SAGE thirteen years after their creation puts this infatuation in a more sober context. Indeed, so far only 26 have been set up. 11 Pic.4: Progress status of the SAGE in France in December 1st 2005 ( Office International de l'Eau, 2005) It is thus sensible to ask why so few SAGE have been set up. Assessing this tool of water management is quite challenging. First of all, the adopted measures vary greatly from one SAGE to another, which makes it difficult to conclude on the efficiency of this tool to solve problems related to water resources. Besides, assessments and feedback on existing SAGE are limited. Indeed, the assessment of the first implemented SAGE in France – the Drôme SAGE, approved by the Prefect in 1997- hasn’t started yet. The community of municipalities of Val de Drôme just published the specifications of the study in October 2005 (Communauté de Communes du Val de Drôme, 2005). The drawing office in charge of this study should hand in the results by the end of 2006. Finally, it is important to notice that a new bill on water plans to modify the definition of the SAGE tool (it was adopted in a first reading by the Senate on April 14th 2005). In particular, it would allow SAGE to be opposable to third persons if certain conditions are reached (ROUSSEAU Cécile, 2005). Therefore, when adopted this bill will oblige the existing SAGE and those being set up to be updated. These potential evolutions of the tool SAGE may nuance the conclusions of this part. Before analysing the positive and negative points of SAGE, it is important to specify the range of application of this tool. It seems justified to set up a SAGE when there are complex problems in the management of water resources, especially when conflicts of use between several people appear. In the case of simpler problems, which for example concern only two 12 categories of people, simpler tools such as bilateral agreements or river contracts may be more effective, faster and cheaper to implement (SHF, 2003). According to Mr Yves CORTES ( FRANCOIS-PONCET Jean, OUDIN Jacques, 2001), after a rapid development during the years following their creation, SAGE procedures have slowed down. The complexity of the procedure of elaboration may explain this slow down. It is difficult to keep stakeholders involved in the set up of a SAGE motivated when the delays of implementation of this management tool exceed six years (three years on average for the emergence of the SAGE, i.e. demarcation of the area of application, creation of the CLE, and at least three more years for the elaboration. This depends on the initial level of knowledge on the water resources in the area of the SAGE and the complexity of the problems to be solved) (ALLAIN Sophie, 2003). The complexity of the procedure or a lack of political involvement may either explain the fact that the procedure to set up a SAGE is really slow. For example, it is the absence of motivated elected members that made the procedure of elaboration of the Marne aval SAGE to slow down (MATE, 1998). This slowness of procedure introduces a problem of perenniality of the SAGE. Indeed, an election during the time of the procedure could delay the set-up of the SAGE as the elected members might change and the new ones may not feel motivated by setting up a SAGE. Besides, this slowness is coupled with a lack of flexibility of the process. According to Mr Yves CORTES, president of the CLE of the Mayenne SAGE, “the quorum [...] with its 2/3 rule, is often difficult to attain” (FRANCOISPONCET Jean, OUDIN Jacques, 2001). Other problems also occur frequently as a lack of financial support (there is nothing planned in the current French Water Act about financial support for SAGE) and the fact that the measures taken through current SAGE can not be opposed to third parties. Financial problems : As a regional councillor in Alsace, Mr Hugues GEIGER said (FRANCOIS-PONCET ; OUDIN, 2001) “I have noticed that SAGE are really long and hard to set up. Besides, there are only little financial means to achieve this procedure. Therefore, I think that the necessity to create new financial supports has become stronger and stronger. This might be the only way for the French government to properly apply the European Directive”. The CLE of the SAGE Nappes profondes de Gironde has found a solution to ensure a sustainable financial support for the animation of the implementation of the SAGE. It sets up a principle of “solidarity between users of the water resources” by making people having an interest or being involved in the causes of the implementation of the SAGE pay for it. This of course includes all the water consumers of the Gironde water table. According to the CLE, these fees also make water consumers realise that water resources are rare and precious (EPTB, 2004). Problems due to the non-opposability to third parties: The fact that the measures taken by a SAGE are not opposable to third parties may interfere with the efficiency of this tool. For example, this is a problem for the Petite Camargue Guardoise SAGE as it has no means to fight against people damming up to make sure they have enough water. However, the new bill on water should allow SAGE to be opposable to third parties in certain conditions. Beyond the general remarks made above on the complexity of setting up a SAGE as well as on its “badly defined” technical, financial and legal framework (CORTES Yves, 2001), assessing the SAGE tool is really hard as it gratly depends on its geographical area of application, the problems to solve and the people involved in them. Nevertheless, experiences of various SAGE and their procedures have revealed several conditions that facilitate their success. The will for dialogue between stakeholders : 13 Since it is not compulsory to set up a SAGE to manage water resources, communication and dialogue between all those involved in the management of this natural resource appear to be essential. Crisis situations such as droughts, floods and conflicts between consumers turn out to be an essential -even indispensable- engine of dialogue and help water users to be fully aware of the situation in terms of water resources (France Nature Environnement, 2003). On the contrary, a lack of conflict may lead to a lack of motivation from the elected members to achieve the procedure of the relevant SAGE. This is what happened in the case of the Canche and Authie SAGE. Moreover, it is a prime necessity not to avoid the reasons of the conflicts. Some CLE do that to dodge “explosive” situations, though one of the main parts of a SAGE is to help people to move from conflict to dialogue and co-operation. Thus it is essential for a SAGE to approach problems by considering all possible opinions and solutions. For example, in the case of the Nappes profondes de Gironde SAGE the absence of a priori on the way to solve problems and conflicts happened to have greatly facilitated dialogue between those concerned (SHF, 2003). However, it seems that the SAGE tool reaches its limits in terms of dialogue in situations of aggravated conflicts, in particular when they concern significant economic stakes. This is what happened in the case of the Basse Vallée de l’Ain SAGE. The measures to take involved hydroelectric structures of EDF upstream of the SAGE area of application. After a meeting, EDF and the State decided not to implement these measures (Agence de l'Eau RMC, 2002). A report written by France Nature Environnement with the help of MEDD entitled “SAGE et Participation du Public” concludes with: “the elaboration of a SAGE depends mainly on the political will of local actors -especially elected members- and on the distribution of the established political power. Therefore, a SAGE may not be a good solution to solve problems in cases of exacerbated conflicts.” (SAGE et Participation du Public, 2003). Finally, a mistake is to set up a SAGE to make people adopt a project. In this case there is no real dialogue and it may lead to an impasse. That is what happened to the Mayenne SAGE. In fact, the latter was mainly set up to make people agree to a project: to build the Saint Calais du Désert dam. Unfortunately, the preliminary studies showed that building this dam may not be relevant which led to an endless SAGE procedure (France Nature Environnement, 2003). The ability to involve all stakeholders: The ability to locally involve all the people directly concerned by the SAGE as soon as the procedure starts is essential to obtain a united schedule of actions. The sooner the meetings between the representatives start the easier it is to make people –especially elected members of the CLE- understand the real problems they will have to solve in terms of quantitative management of water resources. Setting up a river contract may be a good opportunity to think over problems. This is what was done in the Drôme. A first river contract started in July 1990, i.e. seven years before the SAGE. It scheduled actions in parallel to the elaboration of the SAGE. It introduced a sort of dynamic among people and elected members which was extended by the SAGE and a second river contract that was meant to put into concrete action the scheduled measures. The existence of a perennial, legitimate and financially strong carrier-organization also greatly helps to make a SAGE succeed in solving the problems it has been designed for (La SAGE, une chance pour la politique de l’eau, 2003). According to the inquiry “ SAGE et Participation du Public » (2003) carried out by France Nature et Environnement, the more dynamic the carrier-organization, the shorter the setting up of the corresponding SAGE. In particular, if the president of the CLE is also the president of the carrier-organization, this may help to quickly finish the elaboration of the SAGE (if of course the president is committed to this task). Therefore, the commitment of all those involved in the elaboration of a SAGE –especially the elected members- is essential for its success. It helps to not avoid critical problems so that stakeholders may design a better, more efficient plan of action. Avoiding problems related to 14 water resources that may bring conflicts during meetings would only lead to a hollow SAGE unable to solve the main problems. Actions not properly defined may also have a bad effect on the efficiency of a SAGE. To the question “is the SAGE tool relevant for the quantitative management of water resources?” posted on the forum of the website www.sitesage.org Bruno de GRISSAC answered “SAGE is an efficient tool to manage water resources if its goals are clear and its measures are precisely defined”. According to the associations involved in SAGE, the contents of the latter are often disappointing. They are not ambitious from a legal point of view and they often give vague recommendations with no details about their modalities of application (France Nature Environnement, 2003). Finally, to stimulate the creation and application of SAGE it seems important to more involve both the State and the Water Agencies. They could play an important part and not only as financial supports but also by providing civil servants, technical means etc (Le SAGE, une chance pour la politique de l’eau, 2003). A global consideration of the problems including local concerns and interactions with bordering territories, in particular when they share the same water resources : The choice of the area on which the SAGE is set up plays an important part in its success. SAGE set up on small areas are known to be easier to manage and more efficient to solve problems when elected members are really committed to the project (SHF, 2003). However, the case of the Basse Vallée de l’Ain SAGE shows that links between upstream and downstream may be strong and are to be taken into account when setting up the SAGE. The area of this SAGE does not cover the EDF dams built upstream and to which the management of the flows of the Basse Vallée is strongly linked. Therefore, the actions taken by the CLE depends mainly on decisions made upstream by EDF (Agence de l'Eau RMC, 2002). Although already voted by the CLE, the chapter of the SAGE related to the management of the flows of Basse Vallée has been removed by the State during the approval of the SAGE. This is apparently a consequence of a “bilateral negotiation between the State and EDF” (France Nature Environnement, 2003). Therefore, we could think that it is better to set up SAGE on wide areas that cover the most upstream-downstream processes related to water resources. Nevertheless, the case of the Vilaine SAGE set up on a large area (about 11000 km2 covering almost 6 Departments) set a new problem: how could people consider the whole area and try to solve local problems? A solution would be to set up several SAGE on small areas and to manage their connection (SHF, 2003). But still, meetings and dialogues with the concerned people the farthest upstream during the implementation would play a significant part in the success of this project. To conclude, tools used for participative management such as contracts and SAGE appear to be able to solve some problems related to water resources. In particular, their local scale of application seems sensible as it helps the tool to adapt itself to the local specificities of the considered watershed and its water users. The efficiency of such tools depends greatly on the commitment of those involved in the management of water resources. Thus it is of prime priority for elected members of the concerned areas to carry out the project with motivation and dynamism. Contracts and SAGE are two different tools. A SAGE sets a statutory framework whereas a contract is more an operational tool. Therefore it is essential that the choice of the tool comes from a real dialogue between all the people concerned by the water resources. Nevertheless, more than two “rival” tools, SAGE and contracts are complementary; the SAGE sets a statutory framework and defines the measures to be taken and the contract puts them into concrete action. Besides, feedback on SAGE and contracts have shown that setting up one tool is easier when the other has already been set up. They have also revealed some of their gaps: the complexity and time needed to implement these tools, the difficulties of setting up a perennial tool of management of the water resources etc. In particular, it is essential for contracts and SAGE to be able to anticipate the major events of the areas where they are set up (e.g. demographic increase, new big buildings, the evolution of agricultural areas etc.). 15 ROYALTIES: Water royalties as well as Water Agencies were created by Act n° 64-1245 of December 16th 1964. The initial role of water royalties was to collect money to ensure financial support to some selected projects and not to modify the behaviour of water users. Although royalties related to the “deterioration of water quality” have been defined with accuracy in the Acts – especially that of December 16th 1964- the definition of other water royalties has been blurred since their creation. Article 18 of Ordinance n°66-700 of September 14th 1966 states that “payment of royalties may be claimed from people or institutions that make interventions of Water Agencies useful or a necessity because: - either they contribute to a loss of quality of water - or they pump water - or they modify water flow in part of the watershed Royalties may also be claimed from people who benefit from buildings made with the contribution of Water Agencies.” Quality and quantity royalties are computed using the following formula (Agence de l'eau RMC, 2005): R=A x C x T Where R = royalties A = basis of taxation (quantity of pollution, volume of water taken, etc.) C = coefficients (geographical position, coefficient of flow for the shunt, etc.) T = rate (€/ unit of basis of taxation) However there is no official way to compute the basis of taxation in the case of “quantitative royalties”. Nowadays, royalties collected by the Water Agencies are computed by their board of directors. Watershed committees - comprising of 40% of local elected members, 40% of representatives of water users and 20% of representatives of the State - give their approval about the rates of royalties. Therefore, royalties may be different from one of the six main watersheds in France to another (Table 1). watershed Adour-Garonne Artois-Picardie Loire-Bretagne Rhin-Meuse Rhône-Méd.-Corse Seine-Normandie France métropol. « quality royalties » (1) Total(2) €/hab. 104 96 184 122 296 551 1353 16 20,8 15,9 30,4 21 31,7 23,2 Total(2) Total royalties(1) €/hab 138 117 236 139 346 646 1622 21,2 25,5 20,3 34,8 24,5 37,1 27,9 (1) Average (2) In over 2000-2002 millions of euros Table 1: rate of royalties in the six French watersheds (FLORY Jean-Claude, 2003) This geographical disparity may make the analysis of the thirty year long data on royalties difficult. Nevertheless, a report on the assessment of Water Agencies issued by the Commissariat général au Plan in 1997 raised several criticisms about the efficiency of royalties. In particular, rates are too low to make royalties play an incentivising role: “royalties 16 are not high enough to be incentive (...) Rather than the principle “polluters pay”, it is the principle “I pay but it is an investment” that governs this tool. In a way water users gather in groups that intend to “make a profit” out of royalties on a long time-scale.” The new bill on water resources will harmonise the maximum rates of royalties on the whole French territory (till now these maximum rates have been set at 0. 2 €/m3 in areas where water resources are sufficient to cover the needs of users and 0.03 €/m3 in areas where they are not) (OLIN Nelly, 2005). The rate of royalties also depends on water users (Table 2). The following table contains rounded values as they have been averaged over 1997-2002. However it clearly shows that contributions of local communities (approximately 80%) are much higher than those of farmers (approximately 1 to 2 %). This result is not as stunning as it may first appear as local communities also get about 80% of state aid (FLORY Jean- Claude, 2003). Nevertheless, the “state aid/royalties” ratio is greater than six for farmers (and greater than three if we only consider quantitative royalties). Even if a total rebalancing is not possible, all water users (even farmers) think that a partial one would be a good idea (FLORY Jean- Claude, 2003). Local communities Pollution Resource S/Total Industries Pollution Resource S/Total Agriculture Pollution Resource S/Total global Pollution Resource S/Total Royalties in M€ (averaged over 19972002) Distribution of royalties in % (averaged over 19972002) State aid (averaged over 19972002) Distribution of state aid in % (averaged over 19972002) 932 189 1121 70 14,2 84,2 642 123 765 65,1 12,4 77,5 138 57 195 10,4 4,2 14,6 110 18 128 11,2 1,8 13 2 13 15 0,2 1 1,2 59 35 94 5,9 3,6 9,5 1072 259 1331 80,6 19,4 100 811 176 987 82,2 17,8 100 Table 2: royalties and state aids for local communities, industries and farmers (FLORY Jean-Claude, 2003) Another point of imbalance exists. 80% of state aids and royalties are devoted to the fight against pollution, whereas less than 20% are devoted to the quantitative management of water resources (Table 2). Though the “state aid/royalties” ratio is approximately equal to one, the imbalance between problems related to the amount of water resources and their pollution could be worrying. This trend should be carefully monitored to be sure that Water Agencies do not exclusively focus on pollution problems, thereby dropping problems related to the quantitative management of water resources. Finally, royalties are really complex to compute, which makes them hard to understand for lay people (FLORY Jean-Claude, 2003). This lack of simplicity may make people wonder if this tool is fair for all water users. It also makes it difficult for people to translate the rate of royalties into the state of the concerned water resources, i.e. to understand when an alert about the water resources becoming rare is “broadcast” through the rate of royalties. 17 For royalties to have an incentivising effect, the water demand (e.g. for irrigation) must depend on the price of water (MONTGINOUL Marielle, 1997). If this is not the case then royalties will have no incentive effect. An alternative may then be to set up a system of quotas, or to combine both tools (quotae and royalties). It is important to notice that when water shortages occur, crops are often already established and farmers will irrigate at any water cost to save their harvest (MONTGINOUL Marielle, 1997). Then water demand for irrigation does not depend on the price of water so royalties cannot have an incentivising effect on farmers. It may then be far more efficient to set up quotas. 18 BIBLIOGRAPHY Agence de l'Eau RMC, 2002. SAGE MODE D’EMPLOI N°2. Bassin Rhône Méditerranée Corse, Premiers retours d’expérience en complément du SAGE MODE D’EMPLOI édité en mars 1997. Lyon, Agence de l'Eau RMC. 82 p. Agence de l'Eau RMC, [mise à jour 2005]. Les redevances. [en ligne]. Disponible sur Internet : http://www.eaurmc.fr/nos-metiers/redevances.php. (Consulté le 10 janvier 2006) ALLAIN Sophie, 2003. La Procédure de SAGE : chance ou chimère ? IN : Le SAGE une chance pour la politique de l’eau. Colloque SHF-Cercle Français de l'Eau, Paris, 19 mai 2003. AScA, ADAGE environnement, 2001. Etude du fonctionnement des procédures de contrats de rivière, lac et milieu en région Rhône-Alpes, synthèse et propositions, 35 p. Disponible sur Internet : http://www.gesteau.eaufrance.fr/contrats/situation.php. (consulté le 9 janvier 2006) BOURDAT Eva, DESPORTES Geoffroy, PARE Sébastien, 2002. Bilan de la gestion de l’eau dans le Nord-Pas-de-Calais. Rapport de TGE. Paris, ENGREF, 46 p Communauté des communes du Val de Drôme, 2005. Cahier des charges. Etude bilan, évaluation et prospectives du contrat de rivière Drôme Haut Roubion n°2 et du SAGE Drôme, 27p. CORTES Yves, 2001. Pour une relance de la politique des SAGE. IN : FRANCOIS-PONCET Jean, OUDIN Jacques, 2001. La réforme de la loi sur l'eau. Rapport d'information n° 146 (2000-2001) du 14 décembre 2000, fait au nom de la commission des Affaires économiques et du Plan. Paris, Le Sénat, p.53-58. Disponible sur : http://www.senat.fr/rap/r00-146/r00146.html. (Consulté le 10 janvier 2006) Direction de l’eau, 2005. Sécheresse 2005, Premier bilan provisoire de l’étiage 2005 au 16 septembre 2005. Paris, MEDD, 10 p. DIREN, 2004. Bilan national de l'étiage 2003. Paris, Ministère de l'Ecologie et du Développement Durable, 33 p. Disponible sur Internet : http://www1.environnement.gouv.fr/IMG/eau/GB291_Bilan_national_secheresse2003.pdf. (Consulté le 9 janvier 2006) DIREN Rhône-Alpes, 2004. 20 ans d’expérience sur les contrats de rivière en Rhône-Alpes, 11 p EPTB (Etablissements Publics Territoriaux de Bassin), 2004. La gestion équilibrée de la ressource en eau à l'échelle des bassins versants. Actes des Rencontres Techniques Nationales, 6 octobre 2004, Clermont-Ferrand. 117 p. Disponible sur Internet : http://www.eptb.asso.fr/dyn/eptb-asso/fichiers/actesclermont.pdf. (Consulté le 10 janvier 2006). FLORY Jean-Claude, 2003. Les redevances des agences de l’eau. Paris, Ministère de l'Ecologie et du Développement Durable, 182 p. Disponible sur Internet : http://www2.environnement.gouv.fr/dossiers/eau/pages/politique/gouvernance/loi_eau/Rappo rt-flory.pdf (consulté le 10 janvier 2006) France Nature Environnement, 2003. SAGE et Participation du Public, Analyse de l’élaboration concertée et de la mise en œuvre des Schémas d’Aménagement et de Gestion des Eaux. Paris, Fédération Française des Associations de Protection de la Nature et de l’Environnement. 22 p. 19 FRANCOIS-PONCET Jean, OUDIN Jacques, 2001. La réforme de la loi sur l'eau Rapport d'information n° 146 (2000-2001) du 14 décembre 2000, fait au nom de la commission des Affaires économiques et du Plan. Paris, Le Sénat, 82 p. Disponible sur : http://www.senat.fr/rap/r00-146/r00-146.html. (Consulté le 10 janvier 2006) MATE (Ministère de l’Aménagement du Territoire et de l’Environnement), Agences de l’eau, Conseil Supérieur de la Pêche, 1998. Schémas d’Aménagement et de Gestion des Eaux. Premiers retours d’expériences. Actes du séminaire national des 4 et 5 novembre 1997, Saint-Ouen. MONTGINOUL Marielle, 1997. Une approche économique de la gestion de l’eau d’irrigation : des tools, de l’information et des acteurs. Thèse en sciences économiques : Université de Montpellier I, 262 p. Office International de l'Eau, 2005. Etat d'avancement des contrats de rivière au 01/12/2005. [En Ligne]. Disponible sur Internet : http://www.gesteau.eaufrance.fr/contrats/situation.php. (Consulté le 9 janvier 2006). Office International de l'Eau, 2005. Etat d'avancement des SAGE au 01/12/2005. [En Ligne]. Disponible sur Internet : http://www.gesteau.eaufrance.fr/sage/situation.php . (Consulté le 9 janvier 2006.) OLIN Nelly, 2005. Les actions du gouvernement pour la gestion quantitative de l’eau. Communiqué de la Ministre de l’Ecologie et du Développement durable le mardi 9 août 2005. [En Ligne]. Disponible sur http://www.ecologie.gouv.fr/article.php3?id_article=4517. (Consulté le 12 décembre 2006). ROUSSEAU Cécile, 2005. Etat des lieux des structures de gestion des milieux aquatiques dans l’Hérault, Propositions d’amélioration. Mémoire de Stage de Fin d'Etude. Montpellier, ENGREF, 87 p SHF, 2003. Le Sage, Une chance pour la politique de l’eau. Colloque Société Hydrotechnique Française-Cercle Français de l'Eau, Paris, 19 mai 2003. 39 p. 20