DocumentNumber: RL 6/172 Organisation: Hooper Communications Address: 4 Western Road Fortis Green Town: London County: London PostCode: N2 9HX Author: Mr R Hooper Source: Consultative Document Date: 17 July 1994 HOOPER COMMUNICATIONS 17 July 1994 Mr Green RE:- The Future Management of the Radio Spectrum Submission to the Radiocommunications Agency on the Consultative document The future management of the radio spectrum by Richard Hooper Managing Partner, Hooper Communications These are the personal views of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of MAI plc, ABFL Marketing Management and GA Pindar & Son on whose Boards he serves as a non-executive director. Introduction and summary These comments will be very brief for one good reason. Chapter 8 (A possible outcome) would seem to be an eminently sensible basis on which to proceed. It is inventive and flexible and addresses the key issues raised in the body of the Consultative document. I have only one objection in the body of the paper, concerning the auctions ushered in by the Broadcasting Act 1990. It seems unreasonable public policy for broadcasters' spectrum to be auctioned (which is what has happened) when telecommunications operators' spectrum is not. The telecommunications market in the UK is some four times as big as the broadcasting market. Thus broadcasters seem to be unfairly disadvantaged at a time when convergence between media and telecommunications is happening. 4.26 Past performance of RA In recent times the Radiocommunications Agency has become much more open and transparent in its dealings with current and potential users of spectrum. Historically, spectrum discussions and decisions were hidden behind closed doors. Those on the outside feared that dominant spectrum users, eg Post Office Telecommunications/BT and the BBC for example, had an inside track. This view has now changed and the Agency appears to handle current players and new entrants with fairness and common sense. 5.10 Standing independent advisory committee It is doubtful that this could be representative of sufficient interests, and if it were, the conflicts of interest would abound. The Spectrum Review Committees would seem to have been a better way of meeting the same goals. However, if Chapter 8 is adopted, and the RA becomes more of a regulator and less of an executive agency, HMG should consider adopting the Radio Authority/ITC model of regulation rather than the Oftel model. I have doubts as to whether a single individual should be vested with as much power as is the case with Oftel (this in no way reflects on the specific individuals, Carsberg and Cruickshank, who have done and do an excellent job). I would prefer the model of the Radio Authority where a cross-section of seven Members including a strong Chairman, rotating every five years, ensures broadly based and reasonable views. 5.27 Open access to RA's databases With the exception of Defence/Security users of spectrum, I can see no reason for not allowing more open access. Spectrum is in the public domain, licensed out to particular operators for specific terms. Its use should be publicly scrutinised. More open access is likely to "frighten" users into making more efficient use of spectrum and stop any tendencies towards spectrum hoarding. This is highly consistent with the relevant recommendations in this Consultative document. 6.27 Charging for spectrum Charging for spectrum should be introduced (as long as it does not make UK firms uncompetitive with EU firms not paying for spectrum). The recommendation in 6.9 is especially important. Public sector users, including the major spectrum user MOD, should be charged like non-Government users to stop spectrum hoarding and increase spectrum efficiency. Scarce spectrum should not be used for applications which could be accommodated by cable networks under the ground. Charging, using a combination of the methods outlined in Chapter 6, will help to ensure that fixed applications and wireless applications make appropriate choices. Television has historically been a very fixed application whereas radio broadcasting has been usefully mobile, meeting the needs of commuters and car travellers. If, with new technology (flat screens, PDAs eta), mobile applications of television broadcasting do not eventuate, then its very greedy use of spectrum might have to be questioned in the light of genuinely mobile applications seeking spectrum space. 7.13 Changing the legal basis It would seem to be reasonable to permit a secondary market in radio licences during the term of the licence, especially where there had been any use of auctions. Under administrative pricing, the case for a secondary market would appear less strong and could cause political problems if licences started changing hands for prices well in excess of the original administrative price. However, given that spectrum is a scarce resource, radio licences should be for a fixed term, should be revoked if misuse occurs, and should at the end of the fixed term not necessarily be returned to the previous licensee. In this sense, spectrum is not like property. Or rather it can be understood as leasehold rather than freehold. All users of spectrum will therefore remain under pressure to use it efficiently and properly, whilst they have "ownership" of it. Government should not pay much heed to incumbent users of spectrum arguing against new spectrum entrants on the grounds that the market will not stand additional competition. As consolidation continues to happen at the top of the telecommunications, media and computing industries, Government can use spectrum decisions to encourage new entrants "at the bottom". 7.27 Privatising spectrum management There is a strong case for introducing SMOs to improve spectrum management at the assignment level, leaving the RA with the task of spectrum allocation, with the wholesaling and regulatory/policing role. In today's complex information markets, the retailing task includes sophisticated value added services none of this is proper to the role of the RA even if it were staffed to do so. Such a split of wholesaling and retailing would lead to more innovative uses of the spectrum. Retailers/value added resellers can understand the customer far better than the RA. Most would acknowledge that the success of mobile telephony was partly caused by the decision to split retail and wholesale in the first decade. 7.38 Enforcement The RA should remain the policeman of the new structure of spectrum management. I do not think that this role is appropriate to SMOs. If a Microsoft value added reseller's customer is found to be pirating software, that is a problem for Microsoft and its lawyers, not the VAR. 7.58 Auctions I do take strong issue with the statements in para 7.42 that the auctions in the Broadcasting Act 1990 for ITV and national independent radio were for the franchises, not the spectrum. This is disingenuous. The franchises are meaningless without the specified frequencies associated with those frequencies. The Broadcasting Act 1990 ushered in the era of spectrum auctions. The public policy failure concerns fairness. It is surely unfair that Vodafone, for example, should pay very little for its spectrum, yet be allowed to make such handsome profits (margins of 45%), whilst tv and radio stations are paying some £4 billions gross to the Treasury over and above corporation tax during the next decade. Why should the telecommunications industry pay virtually nothing for spectrum whilst the media industry next door is highly taxed? At a time when Government is urging UK media players to become global players, it is curious indeed. Auctions should be tried out, but building on the valuable lessons from the Antipodes. Above all, auctions should be fair to all sectors. If the Government wants broadcasters to pay an extra tax, then why not all commercial users of spectrum. Chapter 8 - A possible outcome This would seem to be eminently sensible. It is a flexible plan which is not dogmatic. It clarifies the core business of the RA (regulatory) and allows the private sector to take over many of the day to day management functions. It uses price to drive efficiency, via a combination of administrative pricing and auctions. It allows a sensible secondary market to emerge. It learns from other countries I do however commend the Radio Authority rather than Oftel model of regulatory structure (see 5.10 above).