Introduction xiii From time infinitum, development theology in all its incarnations and ramifications has treated Agriculture as the prime mover, a chief energy source to sustain people, create property and power, the launching pad for celeritous development and a foundation on which the whole economic edifice can and does rest. The history of human civilisation is abreast with evidences that agricultural revolution/growth has preceded industrial growth and economic literature is filled with theories treating agriculture as precursor for advanced stage of development. Be it the stage of ‘Feudalism’ in Marxist literature that paves the way for the much advanced phase of capitalism or the antithesis ‘Take-off’ stage in the so called Non-Communist Manifesto of Rostow that zooms the economy into the stage of high mass consumption; it is agriculture that provides the base for the advanced and developed stage of civilisation and economy. The impregnable position occupied by agriculture is because the roles agriculture plays. Kuznets classifies the contributions made by agriculture to economic growth as Product Contribution, Market Contribution, Factor Contribution and Foreign Exchange Contributioni. In simple terms the contributions made by agriculture to economic growth can be mentioned as1. Supplying food stuffs and raw materials to the expanding sectors in the economy, 2. Providing an investible surplus of saving and taxes to support investment in other expanding sectors of the economyii, 3. Selling for cash a ‘marketable surplus’ that raises the demand of the rural population for the products of other expanding sectors, and 4. Relaxing the foreign exchange constraint by earning foreign exchange through exports or by saving foreign exchange through import substitution. As far as India is concerned Agriculture is not just a profession or a source of livelihood here, it is rather a way of life, a tradition, which, for centuries, has shaped the thought, the outlook, the culture and the economic life of the people. Agriculture was and continues to be the chief source of livelihood/employment for millions of Indians living in villages and the only sector that till today is the backbone of the Indian economy and provides a platform to the Indian economy adopting a ‘leap-frog strategy’ of development Agriculture, therefore, is and will continue to be central to all strategies for planned socio-economic development of the country. Rapid growth of agriculture is essential not only to achieve self-reliance at national level but also for household food security and to bring about equity in distribution of income and wealth resulting in rapid reduction in poverty levels.iii. All said and done Indian agriculture from the time of the advent of the British was in a very bad shape. The land system was obstructive, technology was not obsolete; it was primitive, scale of production small, agriculturists illiterate and government Introduction xiv unresponsive. Agriculture was not in a position to supply the essential foodstuff to the growing Indian population and the goal of generating an exportable surplus was a distant dream. Examples of markets being manipulated by organised traders were not hard to find. These manipulations had sometimes heightened the suffering and misery associated with famines.iv The status of Indian agriculture at the time of independence is aptly summarised in a paragraph written by Prof. Dantwala-“For more than half a century prior to independence, the performance of Indian agriculture was quite dismal. The disastrous Bengal famine in 1943 rudely awakened India to dire necessity to rapidly augment food production and streamline the distribution system. The culpability of food prices in causing millions of starvation deaths was grimly demonstrated by the Bengal famine. To add to its woes the partition of the country resulted in a more than proportionate reduction in growth –stimulating assets, particularly irrigation…. About the time the First Five Year Plan was launched the country was experiencing severe food shortage and the consequent upsurge in food prices.”v The development strategy that was adopted in the post-independence era while emphasising rapid industrialisation and realising that a precondition to growth is a structural shift in production from primary to secondary and then to the tertiary sector, also accepted that the sectoral goals are interlinked and no sector of the economy can be expected to achieve uninterrupted progress without reinforcing support of other sectors. The establishment of an agrarian economy which ensures food and nutrition to India’s growing population, raw materials for its expanding industrial base and surpluses for exports, and a fair and equitable reward system for the farming community for the services they provide to the society, became the main target for the Plans for development in general and agriculture in particular. It was the belief in ‘Agriculture Development as Precursor to Overall Development of the Economy’ that encouraged the government to give proper place to agriculture in the post independence era. The policy makers adopted a two-fold strategy for regenerating agriculture immediately after independence. The first element of this strategy was to implement land reforms in order to remove institutional bottlenecks and the second element was to undertake massive investment in irrigation and other infrastructure in order to update the existing agricultural technology. The Green Revolution that followed in the 1970s further pepped up the development process through a revolution in the production technology. The net result of this strategy was the rapid strides that the Indian agriculture took in the first few decades after independence. In taking the annual food grains production from 51 million tonnes of the early fifties to 206 million tonnes at the turn of the century, agriculture contributed significantly in achieving selfsufficiency in food and in avoiding food shortages in our country. All is however not well at the agricultural front. The pattern of growth of agriculture has, brought in its wake, uneven development, across regions and crops as also across different sections of farming community and is characterized by low levels of productivity and degradation of natural resources in some areas. Capital inadequacy, Introduction xv lack of infrastructural support and demand side constraints such as controls on movement, storage and sale of agricultural products, etc., have continued to affect the economic viability of agriculture sector. Consequently, the growth of agriculture has also tended to slacken during the nineties. Agriculture has also become a relatively unrewarding profession due to generally unfavourable price regime and low value addition, causing abandoning of farming and increasing migration from rural areas. The situation is likely to be exacerbated further in the wake of integration of agricultural trade in the global system, unless immediate corrective measures are taken. However, before coming on to discuss the main aspects chosen for analysis in the book, it would be in the fitness of things to first conceptualise public policies for developing agriculture. Public policies would broadly include the Vision of agricultural development, Mission, Objectives, Strategy, Instruments and Organisation and Management. Such an analysis is important for the following reasons1. An overview of public policies is indispensable to understand different aspects related to agriculture and give us a complete picture of Indian agriculture, the place accorded to it in the planning process, the roles expected of it, the targets set for it and the importance given to it vis-à-vis other sectors of the economy. 2. Agricultural Production in India or in any country of the world depends directly on the vision, mission, objectives, strategy, instruments and organisation and management of agriculture chosen by the people and adopted by the government. Any change in the vision, objective, strategy etc. has significant impact on production and productivity. Be it the land reforms policy or introduction of new technology in the pre-reform era or the country signing the WTO agreement and thereby accepting the patent regime and reduction in farm subsidy etc. in the post reform era, the strategy, instruments and management of agriculture has affected and will be affecting agricultural production. 3. A brief analysis of the public policies and the shift therein would be of help in assessing the progress made by agriculture and delineating the growth path that it has taken. 4. Agricultural Price Policy, which the present study attempts to study and analyse, at length forms an important part of the strategy, organisation and management of agriculture followed in the country. I. BRIEF REVIEW OF PUBLIC POLICIES FOR AGRICULTUREvi: Public policies on Agriculture in India like that in any other nation of the world can be analysed under the following six heads- Vision, Mission, Objectives, Strategy, Instruments and Organisation and Management. We may attempt a very brief discussion of these here. Introduction xvi 1. Vision of Agricultural Development: The policy makers since independence have debated on two alternative visions for agricultural development in India. Desai nomenclates these as I. Welfarist & II. Economic Welfarist (i)Welfarist: - As per the welfarist vision agriculture is viewed as a source of food and raw material for the economy and its peoplevii. Such a view however is very narrow and is suitable only when agriculture is subsistence-oriented and static. This was the case with Indian agriculture in the pre-independence era. The situation has however changed completely with agriculture recording commendable performance in the post- independence era. The welfarist vision has gradually lost its importance in the independent India. (ii) Economic Welfarist: - This broader view supported by manyviii, views agriculture as a means to larger goals of employment-led economic growth, poverty alleviation and self-reliance. This larger vision is more consistent with the notion of structural transformation of the economy from a predominantly agricultural one to an advanced industrialised one. Desai extends support to this vision also on the ground that – a. This vision makes the whole process of economic growth people centred. b. While the welfarist vision is narrower and passive and leads to myopic view about allocating and using public resources for agriculture by neglecting this sector as its relative importance declines in course of structural transformation of the economy; the economic welfarist recognises the coexistence of relative decline and the growth of real agricultural gross domestic product in absolute amount as a natural phenomenon. c. The economic welfarist vision recognises farming as an entrepreneurial economic activity rather than just a way of life and mainly an uneconomic activity. The development of the agricultural sector has seen a gradual transition in the Vision of agricultural development with the policy makers increasingly accepting and adopting the broader economic welfarist vision. 2. Mission of Agricultural Development: Desai mentions three main missions of agricultural development that the above vision calls for. The Missions are like the broad Plans that the government adopts in order to achieve the vision. These missions have been given credence by the policy makers in India from time to time. The missions area. Concentrating agricultural growth in regions well endowed with irrigation resources and facilities. This mission was adopted by the policy makers under the Intensive Agriculture District Programme (IADP) in 1959. Introduction xvii b. Shifting emphasis away from the areas in (a) above and concentrating on the rain fed and dry farming areas. This mission was adopted under the Draught Prone Area Programme (DPAP), Tribal Area Development Programme (TADP), and Hill Area Development Programme (HADP) in the 1970s and 1980s by the government. c. Making agricultural growth broad based, ensure all pervasive development of agriculture spread all across the country by adopting measures that promote agricultural growth farm size-wise, and farm enterprise-wise. This mission is rather broad and is being adopted in our country since the 7th Five Year Plan. For a vast nation like India where vision no-2 as stated above is always the relevant and suitable one, adoption of mission a & b by any means can be treated only as temporary. Moreover the prolonged adoption of such a mission would cause iniquitous agriculture growth and further aggravate the distortions in agriculture that Bhallaix has pointed as the main curse for the Indian agriculture. Unless the mission is to develop the farm sector of the country spread all across the country with wide variation existing in terms of the size of the farm, technique of production used, crop grown and things like that fostering employment led growth,, achieving self reliance and alleviating poverty will all look a distant dream. The adoption of the Mission-3 would “provide higher sectoral growth, narrow regional differences in agricultural productivity and growth, alleviate poverty more and lead to larger growth linkages of agriculture”x. The adoption of such a mission would make agriculture development mass based and develop the non-farm sector sectors as well. The adoption of this strategy has been supported by many scholars like Mellor and Lele, Desai and Namboodrixi, Gandhixii and others. 3. Objectives of Agricultural Development: The objective of economic growth in general and that of agricultural in particular has been changing with the passage of time and development of new theories of economic growth. Although the list of objective is very long and includes sustainable economic and agricultural growth, sustainable use of natural resources, improvement in human development index that broadly encompasses economic growth, poverty alleviation, income equality and healthy quality of life: It is important that for agricultural growth this list is simplified and prioritised. It is imperative for the policy makers to visualise policy objectives that have roots in the ground rather in an ivory tower. The three prime objectives that policy makers have emphasised in India area. Increment in the per capita output and real net national product. b. Alleviating poverty of especially those who are living below the poverty line by helping agriculture generate employment opportunities and sufficient surplus & c. Improving the quality of life in rural India by fostering growth of education, health facility etc. Introduction xviii These objectives of agricultural growth find support from Johnston and Mellorxiii, Ahluwalia, Rao and others. 5. Strategy of Agricultural Development: The strategy for agricultural development that has been followed so far by the government has been very elaborately and systematically explained by Prof. Dantwalaxiv. Prof. Dantwala has categorised the strategy asa. Extensive Farming- This he believes increases production by bringing the hitherto uncultivated land under the plough. This strategy was useful in the first few years after independence but not in modern times when every single inch of cultivable land is already under plough. b. Intensive Farming- It calls for intensifying cultivation on lands already under cultivation through irrigation, better seed and manure and improved farming practices and grow multiple crops in the plots. c. Bringing Scientific Knowledge based Technical Change – The main demerits of the first two strategies, Dantwala himself admitted, are that they can be applied only for a limited period of time, are agroeconomically non-sustainable and are directly and immediately affected by the law of diminishing returns. The only long-term growth strategy is encouraging the growth of scientific knowledge based technical change in agriculture. Technical change strategy has many advances over the other strategies e.g. –Technical change by increasing total factor productivity reduces the number of people living below the poverty line, ensure complementary of resources and enterprise that is so common in agriculture that results in larger output response, technical change in agriculture being embodied in new biological, chemical, and mechanical innovations and resources ensures their use and ultimately results in a rather rapid growth in farm productivity ( e.g. success of Green Revolution in India). Desai claims that the adoption of the third strategy requires three things-first, promoting adoption of new inputs and resources in which new technology is embodied, second, encouraging use of inputs and resources complementary to these inputs and third, extending knowledge as input on how to use both new and complementary inputs and resources. It is the third objective, which is being adopted and promoted by the government. 6. Instruments for Agricultural Development: The instruments used by government to achieve the objectives can be classified under two broad headsa. Price Factor- This reflects the ratio of composite index of prices received to that of prices paid by agriculture. Price policy since it improves the terms of trade and in turn promotes private investment, technical change and growth in agriculture, has been given a place of Introduction xix prime under the new policy of de-protection and deregulation of trade and industry. The emphasis should have been on pricing of inputs and services such as fertilisers, canal-irrigation water, power and credit. There are people who however oppose this instrument ambiguous and not necessarily delivering the right result. b. Non-Price Factor- Under this head three types of factors are includedTechnological Factor-Agricultural Research and Development and extension, (ii) Economic Factor-Production cum market infrastructure for major farm inputs, resources and services and (iii) Institutional Factor- Agrarian institutions like land tenure, formal credit and poverty alleviating programmes, wage-paid employment and public distribution system. While the importance given to the first two is by no means satisfactory, government has shown sufficient determination and intention to use them in the right earnest in achieving the objectives; it is always the institutional reforms which lag far behind the targets and requirements. It is imperative therefore that the government policy emphasises on the following- (i) Since concealed tenancy is very high it causes disincentives and it must be now legitimised with a provision to protect tenants from eviction. (ii) Consolidation of fragments must be urgently taken to make smaller plots economically more viable. (iii) Poverty alleviation programmes like IRDP and wage-paid employment must be integrated with location specific mainstream sectors like agriculture, allied agriculture, water shed, rural infrastructure and nonfarm activities and (iv) PDS must be targeted which will reduce FCI procurement substantially. 7. Organisation and Management of Agricultural Development: The implementation of strategy and use of instruments depends directly on the organisation and management of different programme. The real controversy or point of debate is between adoption of a Uni-agency model and Multi-agency model. While the former results in concentration of all power in one single organisation and thereby avoid any possibility of confusion and confrontation and clash of interest between the multiplicities of agency that exits in the alternative system; it also suffers from the demerit of creating a monolithic structure that suffers from all the ills of monopoly. The later seems more sound and useful, as implementation of strategy of agricultural development requires specialised knowledge and skills that are highly professional in nature. It results in division of labour and increases efficiency and effectiveness by having six different agencies dealing with the following sub systems or areas of agriculturea. Agriculture Research and Development sub system that includes Indian Council of Agricultural Research and State Agricultural Universities. Introduction xx b. Agri-support infrastructure sub system that consists mainly of government land and agricultural departments, agricultural extension department, irrigation department, rural electricity department etc. c. Agri-input subsystem consisting of institutions that sell fertilisers, seeds, compost manures, plant protection materials, veterinary services etc. d. Agri-services sub-system consisting of rural financial institutions, NGOs and insurance agencies etc. e. Agro- marketing and processing sub-system that consists of regulated markets, cold storages and rural go downs, market intermediaries including FCI etc. f. Agricultural production sub-system, which constitutes landless and farm households who are the clientele of the above mentioned five subsystems. It is these sub-systems that precisely control and manage agricultural development in India. The extent of cooperation and coordination between thee agencies however remain a hotly debated issue. Agricultural development in India can be perceived in the light of the above aspects of the public policies pursued and debated in the country. It is in the light of the above vision, missions, objectives, strategies and instruments that the government has created suitable organisational set up and has tried and is trying to foster agricultural development. All progress in the field of agriculture be it agricultural production, pricing, sustainable development, mechanisation and technological improvement or liberalisation is guided by and can be analysed in the context of these. Attempting even a brief conspectus of the main aspects of agricultural development in India however will prove to be a tall order, a Herculean task, a truly demanding but at the same time very interesting job for any researcher. The present study however does not attempt to do this for two reasons- he feels that such a compendium will be by and large dilettante and will not be able to give deep insight into any important aspect of agricultural development in India and second, attempting such a study is prima-facie not the main objective of the study. The present study aims at studying the characteristic trend in agricultural production and prices in India in the post independence era, comparing the trend in the pre- reform era with the post reform era and then making an overall comparison of such trends with that at the international level. Introduction xxi II. AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION & PRICES IN INDIA: 1. Agricultural Production: Agriculture being the chief source of livelihood for bulk of population and income elasticity of demand for agricultural products remaining very high in this poor country of ours, the importance of agricultural production and prices for other sectors of the economy is self established. Any fluctuation in agriculture production and prices causes fluctuations not only in the purchasing power of the population dependent on it (still around 70%) but at the same time because of the forward and backward linkages causes a change in the cost of living of workers, demand & supply conditions etc. in other sectors of the economy as well, thereby initiating a process of adjustments and readjustments. Instability is the prime feature of any productive activity and as such most industries are subject to short-term fluctuations, agriculture definitely is no exception and as a matter of fact it suffers from instability the mostxv. The very nature of supply, demand and output conditions in agriculture, farmer’s ignorance etc. are such that it creates inherent instabilityxvihere. These changes at times appear irrational or directionless beyond realm of reason to explain and beyond the power to control. Instability is inbred in agriculture in the sense that there are some typical connatural factors, which move the soil cultivation a persistently unstable occupation. Agricultural production is subject to year-to-year fluctuations and also fluctuations within a particular year, owing precisely to the following reasons: Seasonal and weather conditions-With Indian agriculture still remaining a gamble with monsoons and environmental degradation taking place at an alarming rate and thereby making monsoon become very erratic, instability in production has become very common. Farming being a biological process the exogenous variable weather plays an important role in bringing down the agricultural income drought and dust storms, floods and frost are manifestations of the straggle that goes on in farming between man and nature. The chief source of economic disequilibrium in agriculture owes its origin in the vagaries of nature on which agricultural production is so deeply dependent out of these vagaries come to agriculture, many forms of economic risks and uncertainties.xvii Variations due to supplies being in abundance in particular month of the yearThese results from a relative failure of the government policy to regulate the supply of agricultural commodities through adopting proper marketing and buffer stock technique. Deliberate variations attempted by the producer- Indian farmers are largely illiterate and are not aware of the changes taking place in the market and their decisions to vary output and change output composition are not well thought of and depend on whims and fancies rather than any long term objective. Further agricultural production takes place under different situations by people who own small plots and work on a small scale. They are busy in the Introduction xxii production of a few crops and have neither the time nor the ability and they seldom bother for studying the markets to put their product at advantage. The lack of credit facility to the farmer works as on another handicap. This has led to the development of an independent class of middleman which functions as a parasite to the farmers. They collect the small surplus of the individual farmers in the primary market and dispatch them to bigger markets which acts as a reservoir to which produce comes in from all sources, at all season and of wide variations in the quantity and quality. These middlemen play a very destructive role in fluctuating the agricultural production and prices and some times make it like a share market by their acts. Frequently changing policies of the government, which at times promotes agricultural production and at times impedes it. External factors, incentives and disincentives that are beyond the control of the government such as international agreements like WTO, changes in the extent and nature of international demand for agricultural commodities exported by the country. Variations resulting from the conditions of marketing of the agricultural product. Fluctuations in agricultural prices and the agricultural price policy of the government. Fluctuation in agricultural production is harmful not only for the farmers whose income directly depends on the output that they produce, but because of the forward and backward linkages it also negatively affects the demand situation in other sectors, cost of living and income level there. It is of paramount importance for us therefore to study the trends in agricultural production in India in different time period specially in the period before the launching of economic reforms and that after it (so as to have a comparative picture of the two), compare these trends with the same in rest of the world, find the factors responsible for the fluctuation in the agricultural production and then evaluate the policy adopted by the government adopted to promote output and stabilise it. 2. Agricultural Prices: Agricultural production acts as a dominant factor responsible for the wide fluctuations in Agricultural prices. There are three main functions which agricultural prices are supposed to serve: a) It is useful in allocating the sources. This determines the level of production & consumption for producers and consumers respectively. b) It helps in the income distribution. c) It exerts an influence on capital formation. Changes in agricultural prices perform the above three major functions and hence particular movements of agricultural prices may facilitate the achievement of certain Introduction xxiii goals through their operation on one function while those same price movements may operate against other simultaneously held goals through effect on other functions. As a resource allocator, it signals to both producers and consumers to decide about their level of production and consumption. With a change in the relative prices of various agricultural commodities, the resource allocation by the producer and allocation of expenditure on consumption by the consumer to the agricultural commodities is altered. An increase in the price of a particular commodity results in more allocation of resources by the producers for the production of that commodity. The consumers try their level best to substitute these commodities by the cheaper ones. Apart from providing income to the farmers, agricultural prices affect the levels of living of the people involved in the other sector of the economy. This result in the transfer of income between agricultural and non-agricultural sector whenever a change in the agricultural prices take place disturbing the income distribution pattern of the economy. Fluctuations are characteristics of prices. They are the normal features of our competitive system. Fluctuations in the prices agricultural commodities are therefore a natural phenomenon. A special feature of agricultural prices is that they show a far greater degree of fluctuations when compared to industrial prices. This is because of some special characteristics of agriculture that it is the most risky of all industries. While cultivating a land, a great many things may happen to the land between sowing and harvesting. In a country like ours, agriculture is a gamble on monsoon and a delay in the monsoons adversely affect the crops. Apart from the risks of natural forces, there are other risks arising from human agencies. An agriculturist may saw the seed expecting a good profit, but owing to some human interference he may find that he will incur a loss. But he cannot switch over another crop in such a contingency, because he stands committed to one crop already for the season. The difficulties faced by an agriculturist in partly social and partly economic in character. In India agricultural prices fluctuate widely, and some times erratically. The percentage of this fluctuation and its intensity vary from season to season, region-toregion and commodity-to-commodity. Further, the rise or fall in agricultural prices is not uniform but selective and owning to the disparity between the prices of competing crops, the crop pattern is disturbed with disastrous consequences and the result is an imbalance in the price structure. The agriculturist does not grow the crop that is required by the nation. As a result, interest of the community suffers. Also, a rise of fall in the price of agricultural commodities is not accompanied by rise or fall in prices of manufactured goods in the same proportion. A rise in price is harmful to consumers, while a fall in price is harmful to agriculturists. Moreover, all fluctuations create uncertainty instability in the national economy because our country is predominantly agricultural in character Introduction xxiv These fluctuations in the price of agricultural products are the greatest hurdle in the way of agricultural development, as they ruin many. It was for this reason that agricultural countries suffered during the depression of 1929. The explanation for agricultural prices being relatively unstable lies in the fact that in agriculture the relation between price, cost and production levels takes place differently from that in industry. Unlike the manufacturing industries, where prices move under free play of forces of demand and supply, to correspond in the long run to cost of production, hardly any relation exists between cost of production and prices in agriculture. This is because of the fact that manufacturing sector is organised on capitalist principles and hence doesn't permit workers in, unless they contribute to production more than the wages they receive and leave behind something as profit consequently, the entire residual population is thrown on agriculture which by its nature and tradition, employs or accommodates whatever population is thrown on it without reference to how much it may a to the total production. So, in agriculture sector, we find that, due to inertia, lag and absence of any other alternative, production is carried whether the prices and cost of production are remunerative or not. If the prices of some manufactured products fall far below the cost of production of industrial manufacturers, the latter would be driven out of business very quickly, thus decreasing supply and tending to raise prices.xviii But the case is different for agricultural sector especially in a developing nation like India where the marginal productivity of more than 20% of the work force is zero; production is being carried on uninterrupted. Further most farmers cannot easily adjust, in response to changes in the price level, the quantity and quality of their output. There is basic difference in instability in the agricultural sector and that in any other sector of the economy. This fact is explained by many actors Agriculture is a biological industry and once investment is sunk, the resources cannot be withdrawn; farmers do not stop their production even if the prices are going down. This results in a rather steady supply of agricultural products. In contrast, the producers in other sectors of the economy sometimes run and at other times simply standstill, farmers mainly stay in full production, irrespective of the impact of business fluctuations upon the demand for farm products. This behaviour of the farmers assures consumers a large and steady supply of food and other farm products, but it means great instability in farm prices and income.xix Further primary producers are not well organised and are thus not in a position of pushing their interest in the marketxx. Thus, when the prices fall, the total agricultural production fails to adjust itself and so in times of adversity, the experiences of agriculture are more embarrassing and the problem more acute than commonly confront other industries.xxi Hence while the producers in other sectors influence market prices by controlling supply, farmers look pathetically at market prices for favour in the observe control on supply. Agricultural prices typically tend to respond more rapidly than do the prices of industrial products to changes in the balance between supply and demand.xxii Introduction xxv Agricultural products cannot be stored for a long period of time and some products not even for few days. Also, they are always in need of cash and having no proper storing facilities. The farmers in under-developed countries having some other problems like efficient acreage allocation, which acts as a hindrance in shifting their resources in response to change in relative prices of crops. Every farmer plans in his own way guided by his own traditional instinct and many a time the whole host of them come to grief owing to an unexpected change in the conditions of the market. Agricultural prices in a developing economy are highly influenced by the interaction between producer, consumer and trader groups. Agricultural marketing is crucial in this regard as the function of modern marketing are enormously increased and complicated which, inter-alia, include moving products from the producer and bringing it to the consumer at the right time, in the right form at a reasonable cost and price. In the absence of any direct contact with the consumer, the farmer doesn't realise the fact that the consumers play such an important role in determining the volume and nature of production. As the supply is not adjusted to adjust with a change in nature and volume of demand prices fluctuate widely. Agriculture in India is in private sector and due to a large number of producer, no single producer have any knowledge regarding the total product and hence can't exert an influence on market price. An in-depth study of the trends in agricultural production and prices is required for a country like India in order to get an idea about the peculiarities of this sector and understand the precise reasons for fluctuation in production and prices of not just specific commodities but for all the commodities taken together. This would help us not only in understanding the phenomenon of fluctuation in production and prices, but also to judge against the same with the happenings on this issue in other nations. III. REVIEW OF LITERATURE: Due to its very inherent nature of showing wide fluctuations, may studies have been conducted to work out the problems of behaviour of agricultural prices and production over a period of time. The studies are mainly concentrated to investigate into the following four types of problems: a) The major field of interest has been to find out the long term & short-term trends. b) Fluctuations in agricultural prices and production. c) Factors influencing behaviour of prices. d) Impact of liberalisation & WTO on Indian agriculture. A number of studies have been made in this area. A review of some of these studies will be very useful. Introduction xxvi K.Krishnamurthyxxiii on the basis of the data for five centers located in four states, found that the seasonal fluctuations were relatively higher in the primary markets than in the secondary markets and seasonal fluctuations were wider in northern states like U.P., Bihar and West Bengal then those in Andhra Pradesh, Madras or Madhya Pradesh. The further observed that in Madras and Andhra Pradesh there were two seasonal peaks where as in other states there was seasonal peak. P. Kamaladevixxiv studied the behaviour of seasonality of price in jowar in southern zones in 1950 and 1960. The districts, one each from Madras, Mysore and Andhra Pradesh were chosen and found that the Inter-regional disparities have tended to narrow down over a period. This was applicable not only to the trend but also to the seasonal variations. V.S. Vyas and A.K. Parikh-xxv have made a study of the trend and fluctuations in food prices for the years from 1948 to 1957. In a systematic analysis they fitted regression to find the trend. Their study shows that, during the preplanning period 1948 to 1951, there was an upward movement in prices except in the case of wheat and bajra. Between 1951 and 1957 all prices showed an upward trend with larger random variations during the planning period a wider seasonal variation around the trend after 1951. It was also observed that upward of strides of prices were more rapid compared to the downward swing since 1951. On the whole wheat, Jowar and bajra, prices were highly correlated. P.V. Johnxxvi investigated into the seasonality in farm prices in Madhya Pradesh. He confined his study to rice, Jowar, Wheat, gram, groundnut, seasum, linseed and gur (raw sugar). He observed that the ranges of variations for different varieties of the same crop are almost identical. With a few exceptions the ranges in seasonal variations for different crops were comparable in magnitude. Nilakantha Rath and V.S. Satyapriyaxxvii investigated into the seasonality of Jowar Prices. Their results show no identifiable seasonal pattern in the movements of jowar prices. They further found that the seasonal rise in prices in excess of storage cost was as frequent as prices equal to or less than the storage cost. Reserve Bank of Indiaxxviii has also conducted a study regarding fluctuations in farm prices for the period 1951-52 to 1964-65. The study found that there were regular cycles of length varying between 16 and 25 months for prices of creature crops. It also found that seasonal fluctuations were wider for food grains that for non-food grains. For the entire period there was a tendency for seasonal fluctuations to gradually narrow down. L.C. Guptaxxix studied the behaviour of maize price in Madhya Pradesh and observed that major production districts had relatively narrower seasonal fluctuations compared to those districts where maize was an important crop. However for the period, which covered 1952 to 1965, he didn't find either a Introduction xxvii trend for convergence or divergence. The year-to-year variations in harvest prices of maize tended to increase. The result of the wholesales prices in three selected markets was found to be uneven. Fluctuations tended to widen in one market, but narrow down in the other two markets. P.V. Georgexxx in his analysis into the behaviour of agricultural and nonagricultural covered the period from 1952 onwards. His results show that agricultural prices in money terms are flexible both ways. In contrast, price of manufactured goods are found to be flexible only upward but they are inflexible downward. Divatia and Panixxxi in a set of five-equation model to study the behaviour of agricultural prices for the period 1951-52 to 1966-67 took the variables such as equilibrium stocks, realised prices, expected stock, actual stock and intended prices. The model included the variables based on current observations as sell as expected values. Out of eleven equations fitted, seven were linear in log and the rest four simple linear equations. The elasticity of prices with respect to supply was found to be negative (-2.29) and equal in magnitude to that obtained with respect to real income in the non-agricultural sector (2.82). The elasticity with respect to liquid resources was, however, much lower. Shortterm elasticities were almost half of the long-term elasticities in all the three cases, i.e. supply, real income in non-agricultural sector and monetary resources. Values of R2 were above 0.94. The elasticity with respect to liquid resources was however, much lower. J.R. Rao and K.S. Murthyxxxii tried to explain the movement in food prices at three different levels (the farm level, the wholesale level and the retail level) taking the help of production, availability and real income of consumers. They set up a model of three equations in which three variables were simultaneously explained. The current farm harvest prices were explained in terms of the previous year’s retail prices and production. The wholesale prices were explained by retail prices ad availability of food grains. The retail prices were explained in terms of wholesale prices and real income of consumers. R2 was medium to high. The results suggest little influence of production on prices. However, prices at the three levels were closely inter-liked and the influence of previous year's retails prices on current year's farm harvest prices was significant. M.V. Nadkarnixxxiii has analyzed the agricultural prices for the period 1951 to 1968. An exponential equation to the data was fitted in order to know the trend. He calculated the adjusted index number. His findings show no regularity in the fluctuations of food grains prices. The prices, which were above the trend in the beginning of the first plan period, are seen to have moved below the trend by the end of period. During the second plan period the degree of fluctuation around the trend are seen to be lower than during the first and third plans. Introduction xxviii Lal Singhxxxiv studied the trend and seasonality in agricultural prices for the period 1951-52 and 1977-78. He fitted a linear equation to the data to know the trend. The R2 values for all the equations are very high, which suggest that trend component of the wholesale price index series is very important one. As for seasonality of prices in concerned, he found, that the extant of seasonality is very high in case of rice and the extant of seasonality in the wholesale price index of wheat is much less than rice. Thingalayaxxxv analysed the relative stability of agricultural and nonagricultural prices. He found the former unstable than the latter. N.A. Khanxxxvi has studied the problem of stability in more comprehensive way. For the period 1918 to 1938, he found high correlation among price of current year with that of the previous year in case of cash crops and between prices of current year and those of the preceding three years for cereals. His findings further shows that instability in cash crop prices is higher equal that in production. In case of cercal prices, instability is less than that of cash crops, and production instability is still lower. A study at the national level by Prasadxxxvii revealed that annual rate of increase in agricultural prices decelerated during 1969-70 to 1972-73 as compared to the annual average rates of increase during the period 1962-63 to 1968-69.By and large there was a marked decline in the rate of increase in food grain prices including of rice, wheat and pulses. A study by George and Singhxxxviii also revealed a declining trend in prices of different crops from 1967-68 to 197071. Singhxxxix examined the relative variability in harvest prices during ten years period (1953-54 to 1961-62) by working out the co-efficient of variation. The Co-efficient of variation in prices was 12.5, 17.8, 17.1, 11.6 and 20.3 for rice, Jowar, Gur, Cotton and Groundnut respectively. Jowar prices didn't reveal wide fluctuations within a market, not did the degree of variation differ greatly from market to market. Antanixl estimated the linear trend in annual wholesale prices for cereals and pulse crop of Rajasthan during 1961 to 1975 and found that the wholesale prices of all the six-food grain increased significantly during the study period. On an average, the wholesale price index of wheat, barely, bajra, cereals, gram and pulses increased by about 17.61, 91.45, 18.74, 19.09, 33.87 and 26.26 points per year respectively. Antani's study also revealed that the rate of linear increase in prices was more than twice during 1970-75 (40.2 to 82.0 points per year) compared to period 1961-69 (16.3 to 30.1 points). Among all food grains, rate of increase in prices was the highest for gram and lowest for wheat in seventies. The difference in the rate of increase between sixties and seventies was more pronounced for bajra and least for wheat. Mandavawallaxli in his analysis of seasonal price variations between 1970-71 to 1977-78 showed that the difference between the highest or lowest levels of normal seasonally adjusted price index number was 9.6 percent for rice and wheat and 7.7 percent for all food grains, while the cost of storage was around Introduction xxix 5 to 6 percent of the economic cost of purchases by the FCI. On the basis of unadjusted price index, the lowest level of rice price index has shifted from December to March since 1975-76. In the case of wheat it is generally located in March-June. No such uniformity is noticed in respect of highest level for rice while for wheat it was mostly noted in January. Shukla and Mishraxlii based on the analysis of growth trend of wholesale prices for food and non-food crops during the plan periods in Uttar Pradesh concluded that price decreased for all crops during the first plan period but was significant only for rice (8.6%), maize (4.1%) arhar (7%), castor seed (1.5%) and grant nut (8.6%). There was further decrease during the second plan for crops like wheat, barley and Jowar among the cereals and for mustard, sugar cane and potato among the non-food crop. After this period there was a rising trend and price rose by more than 12 percent per annum up to 1973-74. Auloker and Kahlonxliii studied the impact of zonal policy of food grains on the seasonal price behaviour of selected food grains by taking three types of markets (producing, consuming and terminal) in Punjab. The study concluded that the extent of seasonal price variation in the case of wheat diminished during the zonal restriction period. In the free trade period seasonal price fluctuation was more. However, in the case of gram and maize no such trend was observed. Gill and Johlxliv examined the price structure of gram in Punjab. Linear trend for gram prices during 1952 to 1966 was worked out. The prices of gram tended to move continuously upward due to the general shortage of food grains and the general inflationary trend of the economy for the period under study. Violent seasonal price fluctuations reduced producer’s income as the major portion of the produce was sold during post-harvest period (April to July) when the prices were generally the lowest. The price index moves up when sowing of gram starts in September. Lelexlv based on her study for Jowar, rice and wheat in the states of Punjab, Maharashtra, West Bengal and Tamilnadu come to the conclusion that the offseasonal price rise doesn’t always cover storage. Kamla Devixlvi studied the regional, cyclical and seasonal variations in the prices of Jowar in the markets of Andhra Pradesh, Madras and Mysore during 1950s an 1960s. She reported that regional variations are getting reduced over the period both within the southern zone and between southern zone and the rest of the country. Cummingsxlvii examined the spatial price relationships between Khanna (Punjab) and Delhi markets for wheat during 1958-59 to 1963-64. The average price difference between the two markets during the period was Rs.0.88. 82% of the monthly differences were less than Rs.2.99 and in six months only the price differences exceeded Rs.4.00. Lele'sxlviii study brings out that regional price differences are not greater than what the costs of shipment would warrant them to be. This study covered three Introduction xxx major food grains namely, Jowar, rice and wheat in the states of Punjab, Maharashtra & West Bengal and Tamilnadu. Shahxlix studied the variation in prices for gram in four secondary markets of Uttar Pradesh, during the period 1963-64 to 1969-70 and found that there is no significant difference in prices between regions. Subramanianl assessed the impact of trade liberalisation through a multimarket approach. The results of Subramanian are largely in accordance with that of Parikh et al. Subramanian found that about two-third of the impact of liberalization in agriculture comes from liberalization of manufacturing sector. Therefore, liberalizing agriculture sector alone is not advisable. Liberalisation in agriculture sector, if preceded by that in manufacturing sector, leads to acceleration of growth in agriculture. Subramanian also opined that liberalizing agriculture would lead to rise in poverty, specially when agricultural commodity price rises without commensurate increase in production. The reduction of tariff in manufacturing sector would, however, help in reducing poverty. This is another reason for preceding liberalization in manufacturing sector over the agricultural sector. Likely implications of liberalisation on different sectors and sections of the Indian economy have been assessed by various other researchers. The studies done by Parikh et alli (1996) and Subramanian (1993,1994), involving Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) modeling, are worth mentioning. Parikh et al indicate that liberalization triggers growth in agriculture, the impact is more when this is combined with the liberalization in manufacturing sector. In the short run, trade liberalization in agriculture, however, increases poverty. This further stresses the need for strong safety nets for the poor. Nayyar and Senlii (1994) point out that larger participation by India in a number of crops like rice and cotton would worsen its terms of trade and unless the volumes are adjusted quickly their would-be a decline in the balance of trade. They also point out that the real export potential from agriculture does not lie in the major crops but it is in the development of horticulture and food processing. According to them, for these commodities, improved marketing, quality control and logistics are the real drivers are not trade policy restrictions. Vyasliii (1994) also argued for the careful approach towards agricultural exports. He pointed out that India should continue with its policy of selfsufficiency in food grains. According to him, trade in food grains should be of secondary importance over domestic requirements and the sector should be protected from the international competition for the time being. However, for commercial crops, export orientation is justified, if these satisfy three conditions,viz., (a) there is a genuine and growing surplus after meeting domestic requirements,(b) ratio of export to domestic prices is favorable and (c) there is a growing international demand. He also advocates prioritisation of crops where India has comparative advantage. In his view Cotton, tea and tobacco export should be emphasised, whereas exports of sugar should be de- Introduction xxxi emphasized. Vyas also agreed with Nayyar and Sen (1994) that fruits, vege tables, flowers, herbs, etc., could-be important export product for India. The impact of trade liberalisation will, however, be different for different crops, agro-climatic regions and farms of different sizes. Sharma, Gulati and Pursellliv (1996) have assessed the impact of agricultural trade liberalisation on major crops of India. The study, using a multi-market model, indicates that liberalising of wheat by 6.4 per cent, of cotton by 6.4% and sugar cane by about 4.5% from their current levels. Prices of cereals will, however, fall by about 10 per cent, of pulses by about 9% and of oilseeds and edible oils by about 38 per cent. These changes in prices will influence allocation of land under crops. They showed reasonable gains in income, employment, wage rate and tax revenue following liberalisation; the combined index of all these gains called efficiency index went up by about 4% over the base period. Ramesh Chandlv (1999) has studied the effect of trade liberalisation on selected crops like rice, maize, chickpea, rapeseed & mustard. Estimating the impact on the wholesale and farm level prices studied the effect at National level by estimating the consumer and producer surpluses. The study showed a sharp positive impact on net return following free trade from production of exportable such as maize and rice. The impact was negative for importable such as rapeseed-mustard. Thus, impact of trade liberalisation would vary from commodity to commodity. Raolvi(2001) worth of the view that trade liberalisation would not affect India's food security. “ In the prices of foodgrains at the moment are out of reach of the poor, it is not due to the rise in exports but to the steep rise in procurement and issue prices”. A study by Sekharlvii(2003) has eluded a longer period: 1970-2001 for international prices and 1980-2001 for domestic prices. The comparision revealed that inter-year variability is generally lower in the domestic markets than in international markets. The regression analyses on the determinants of price volatility found international prices to be significant in some cases while output fluctuations where observed to be insignificant. A brief review of the literature on agriculture production and prices in India prompts one to profusely praise the researchers for their commendable job. Some finer aspects related to the variables chosen have been brought to the fore by them and some neglected aspects have been given their due. However, there is always a scope for improvement. The present study finds the following gaps in the studies conducted so far: 1. Most of the studies conducted so far are grain specific studies whereby the researchers have endeavoured to analyse the fluctuations in prices and production of the grains under study. There is a dearth of study that takes into account agricultural prices and production as a whole i.e. for all food and nonfood items taken together. Introduction xxxii 2. The studies have investigated the seasonality of farm prices and very little effort has been done to make comparison between fluctuation in production and prices in time periods spanning more than half decades. The impact of the shift in policy paradigm or agricultural growth strategy has not been explored sufficiently. 3. Most of the studies have taken price and production trends in the pre-reform period. Very few works have been carried over recently to study the trends in the post-reform period and compare the trends in the pre-reform period with that of the same in the post reform period. 4. The impact of the Structural Adjustment Programme and India joining the W.T.O. wand wagon is another aspect that has not been sufficiently dealt with so far. This is a very interesting and at the same time debatable area with economists owing allegiance to different ideology bitterly criticising or openly supporting the liberalisation policy and trade policy reforms and the W.T.O. provisions for India. Issues like reduction in farm subsidy, patenting etc. have scarcely been taken for in-depth study. 5. There is exiguity of work that takes into account the agricultural development of India in the international perspective and compares the trend in production and prices in India with that of it at the international level. IV.THE PRESENT STUDY: This book makes a modest attempt to bridge this gap and come up with findings that are of help not only to the students of economics or those interested on the issue but also to the future researchers in the field and the policy makers. The study aims at analysing the long–term behaviour of agricultural prices and production in India. It takes the entire period after independence for discussion, as this has been the period in which the nation shrugging-off the age-old subjugation and exploitation launched economic planning for rapid economic growth. Agriculture was accorded a prominent place in the development strategy that followed henceforth. Since the introduction of Structural Adjustment Programme in India in 1991 that introduced reforms at the fiscal level, exchange rate, trade and capital market without making explicit reference to agriculture. But it has made a significant difference to it and it stands clear as dividing line for any study of Indian agriculture in the post independence era. 1.Hypotheses: - The study attempts to test the following hypotheses – 1. Prices and Production levels of Indian agriculture in both Pre and Post reforms era have been much below the International Standard. 2. Agricultural Price Policy of Government of India has been thoroughly confusing for a competitive global environment under WTO regime. 3. The policy of subsidy to agriculture in India has been a point of concern. 4. There would be a net gain to Indian agriculture under WTO. Introduction xxxiii 2.Methodology: Methodology is the skeleton, the base on which the whole edifice of any work is built. It is often said that if hypothesis is the pole star always guiding a person in the desired direction and helping him to keep himself focussed; methodology is the tool kit, the apparatus, the instrument which helps to successfully complete the journey, solving the intricate problems and tackling the obstacles on the way. The present study relies on both historical and comparative research methods. In order to know the existing view on agriculture production and specially prices, it uses historical method and takes a journey down the history lane, briefly reviewing the works done relating to production and prices in India in the post independence era. Such an exercise has given the present study a deeper insight in the problem under study, idea about the gaps in the works done so far and strategy to fill the gaps. Comparative method has been used to make a comparison between – (i) Production and price levels in the pre-reforms and post reforms period. (ii) Production and prices in India with that of the rest of the world. The data collected from various sources such as Planning Commission, Ministry of Agriculture, Various issues of Economic survey, RBI Bulletin, World Development Report, WTO & UNCTAD websites and different international agencies both for the period before and after reforms have been analysed using various statistical tools such as average, variation, fitting of exponential trends etc. In order to get the average values for prices and production, the sum total has been divided by the number of years under study. For knowing the instability of prices we have calculated the coefficient of variation by using the following formula; Coefficient of Variation = Standard deviation = Standard Deviation X 100 Arithmetic Mean ----------------------------------------------------------Sum of the squares of deviations around Mean Number of observations Since the agricultural prices and production have not behaved in a consistent way and have fluctuated considerably over the period, fitting of linear trend will not give satisfactory results. So, we have fitted the following growth/exponential equations to the price and production data of different periods as sub classified in our study to discern the trend. Though, to make a comparison linear trend has also been fitted and results mentioned. As the datas for the entire period (1951-52 to 2006-07) are available with different Bases, all the datas for price and production have been shifted to a common base 1993-94 and 1981-82 respectively in order to bring uniformity in Introduction xxxiv the comparison. For this we have used the formula for base shifting of index number and splicing of data. The estimated exponential equation is given by: Y = b0 e b1t The estimated equation in the log form can be written as-ln Y = ln b0 + b1t The estimated growth equation is given by: Y= e b0 +b1 t The estimated equation in the log form can be written as-ln Y = b0 + b1t The estimated linear equation is given by: Y = b0 + b 1 t Where, Y is variable in equation. t is time variable. b0 is intercept. b1 is coefficient. For base shifting of index number we used the following formula: New base year Index = Old Index number for current year X 100 Old Index number for new Base year For Splicing the data, we used the following formula: Spliced Index = Current year index X old Index No. of new Base year 100 3. Scheme of Work: The present work is arranged in the following manner: INTRODUCTION: This briefly introduces the work, outlining the main aspects of public policy on agriculture, the role and importance of agricultural production and price, review of literature and hypotheses, methodology and scheme of work thus giving an indication of the shape of things to come in the work. Introduction xxxv CHAPTER-1: INDIAN AGRICULTURE IN THE PRE-REFORMS ERA: The first chapter of the present work studies the Price and Production trends in the Indian agriculture in the period between introduction of economic planning and economic reforms in the country. The entire period spanning about four decades (1951-52 to 1990-91) has been divided into three sub periods for analytical convenience and to facilitate comparison- (i). 1951-52 to 1966-67, (ii) 1967-68 to 1979-80 and (iii) 1980-81to 1990-91. CHAPTER-2: INDIAN AGRICULTURE IN THE POST-REFORMS ERA: The introduction of Economic Reforms in India in 1990-91 has brought in significant changes in almost all spheres and agriculture definitely is no exception. A number of changes affecting the agricultural sector have taken place after 1990-91 and the second chapter makes an effort to study the impact of these changes on agricultural production and prices in India. It also makes a modest attempt to compare the trends in production and prices in the pre and post reforms period. In order to understand where the Indian economy stands vis-à-vis other economies, efforts are made to compare the trends in production and prices in India with that in rest of the world. CHAPTER-3: AGRICULTURAL PRICE POLICY IN INDIA Agricultural Prices play important roles in allocating resources, distributing income and inducing capital formation. Government control over agricultural prices is therefore necessary to have control over these and as such in India the government declares agricultural price policy and has a system to regulate the prices. The third chapter of the present work studies in detail the agricultural price policy of the government since independence and examines the claim that it has been misdirected, confusing and inappropriate. CHAPTER-4: ISSUE OF AGRICULTURAL SUBSIDY The fourth chapter of the present work attempts to study one of the most contentious issues in contemporary Indian agriculture- the issue of farm subsidy. For generations farm subsidy had been a regular and essential feature of the Indian agriculture, regarded as essential support to the poor Indian farmers enabling them to carry agricultural work as means of livelihood. The situation has changed dramatically after the introduction of economic reforms and India signing WTO agreement. India is under tremendous pressure to do away with farm subsidy by the West and critics are debating the implications of such a policy on Indian agriculture in general and the conditions of the farmers in general. An attempt has attempted to analyse these interesting issues in this chapter. CHAPTER-5: IMPACT OF WTO ON INDIAN AGRICULTURE The penultimate chapter of the present work sees Indian agriculture in the global perspective – under WTO regime to be more precise. It analyses the impact of different WTO provisions/ agreements such as Market Access, Export Subsidy, Introduction xxxvi Domestic Support, Sanitary & Phyto-sanitary Measures, TRIPS and reduction in tariffs on the Indian agriculture. CHAPTER-6: CONCLUSION AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS: The final chapter as common to most studies concerns itself with the main findings of the work. It also attempts to prescribe some policy recommendations for the government. There is a sincere feeling that after adopting these recommendations the position of agriculture can be improved in India to a considerable extent. Notes & References Kuznets Simon (1965), “Economic Growth and Structure”, New York. As per Kuznets agriculture makes four types of contribution to economic growth-Product Contribution, Market Contribution, Factor Contribution and Foreign Exchange Contribution. Product Contribution is made by agriculture by supplying food grains to the non- agricultural sector for the sustenance of the latter’s labour force and making available important raw materials for the agro-based industries of these sectors. ‘Market Contribution’ to economic growth is made when agriculture sector purchases some products from other sectors at home or abroad and sells some of its product to dispose of its surplus product, get some items needed for continuing production and buy consumer goods from other sectors. Similarly as the relative importance of agriculture in the economy declines with economic growth and development, agriculture becomes a principal source of supply of capital and surplus labour to other sectors of the economy. This has been called Factor Contribution. Finally agriculture contributes to the foreign exchange kitty of the economy either by contributing to the exports earning of the economy or by producing agriculture import substitutes. This has been termed as the foreign exchange contribution of agriculture. For a detailed and scientific treatment of these contributions one should refer to Ghatak, Subrata & Ken Ingersent, “ Agriculture and Economic Development’ Select book Service SYNDICATE, New Delhi i Agriculture as a matter of fact provides four broad types of growth linkages to the non-a-agricultural sectors. These are –(i) Production Linkage- This occurs when agriculture provides its outputs as inputs to the non-agricultural sectors e.g. agriculture providing raw materials to a number of agro-based industries like cotton, food-processing, sugarcane etc. (ii) Demand Linkage- This arises when agriculture Introduction xxxvii makes available market for consumer non-durables and durables produced by non-agricultural sector e.g. in India as for a very considerable period of time when agriculture was contributing more than 50% of country’s GDP , agriculture was the main source of demand for products in the non-agricultural sector. (iii) Saving Linkage- This occurs when agriculture provides financial savings and demand for insurance services. In India where the household saving constitutes more than 70% of the gross domestic savings and agriculture is the main source of occupation saving linkage is automatically very strong. (iv)Investment Linkage- This emerges because agriculture provides demand for the intermediate inputs and capital goods produced by the non- agricultural sectors. Mellor John W( 1973), “Accelerated Growth in Agricultural Production and Inter-sectoral Transfer of Resources” in Economic Development and Cultural Change, October 1973,p-5, writes , “ ----- both in concept and in practice it is possible to make large net transfers of resources to other sectors. If these transfers are used productively, the rate of economic growth can be accelerated.” ii iii Quoted from the New Agricultural Policy of Government of India. Sen, Amartya and Dreze, Jean, “ India Economic Development and Social Opportunity” ,Oxford University Press, New Delhi, 1995. iv Dantwala, M.L., “Strategy of Agricultural Development Since Independence.” In M.L.Dantwala and Others (EdS) Indian Agricultural Development Since Independence, Oxford and IBH Publishing Co. Pvt. Ltd. 1986 v This section draws heavily from Bhupat M Desai’s , “ Policy Framework for Reorienting Agricultural Development” Presidential Address delivered at the 61st Annual Conference of The Indian Society of Agricultural Economics, held at the Gulbarga University, Gulbarga-585106 (Karnataka), December 27,2001 vi See for example Government of India (1959), Report on India’s Food Crisis ad Steps to Meet it’ Report prepared by the Agricultural Production Team sponsored by the Ford Foundation , New Delhi and also Pinstrup- Anderson, Per and Rajaul Pandya- Lorch (1994), Alleviating Poverty, Intensifying Agriculture vii Most of the modern researchers in the field of Indian agriculture support the Economic Welfarist view. Vocal support has come from Johnston, Bruce F and John W Mellor {(1975), The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development’ American Economic Review Vol-51, No-4 September}, Dantwala {The Two Worlds of Food and Agriculture’ The Economic Weekly, Vol-14,No.43, October 27 & ‘Incentives and Disincentives in Indian Agriculture’ Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol-22, No.2, AprilJune},Raj, K.N. {1969,Some Questions Concerning Growth, Transformation and Planning of Agriculture and Effectively Managing Natural Resources, Discussion Paper _, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington D.C. U.S.A. August}, Dandekar, V.M {1970, Agriculture Growth with Social Justice in Over Populated Countries’ Economic and Political Weekly, Vol-5, No—29,30 &31, Special Number July},Mellor, John W {1966, The Economics of Agricultural Development, Cornell University Pres, Ithaca, N.Y., USA, & 1976, ‘ The New Economics of Growth’ Cornell University Pres, Ithaca, N.Y., USA,}Asian Development Bank,{1976, Rural Asia: Challenges and Opportunities, Manila}, Rangarajan, C{ Agricultural Growth and Industrial Performance in India, Research Report No.-33, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington D.C. , October}, Jakhade, V.M. & T.,R.,Sundharam, ‘ Role of viii Introduction xxxviii Agriculture in the National Economy’ in M.L. Dantwala and Others (Ed) Indian Agricultural Development Since Independence} etc. Bhalla, G.S. “The Nature of Agricultural Development in India” Article downloaded from the internet. Bhalla has mentioned three main distortions of Indian agriculture -1. Inter-Personal inequality-Very large inequalities in the distribution of both income and assets exist in rural India. Among the cultivator households income inequalities are generally highly correlated with land ownership/land holding. 2. Inter-regional inequality- India demonstrates vast regional inequalities. For example it is the north western states of Punjab, Haryana and Uttar Pradesh which have recorded consistently high growth rates since mid-sixties. On the other hand the Eastern region comprising of Orissa, Bihar and West Bengal has had a dismal performance. Except for Andhra Pradesh the recent performance of the southern region has not been very satisfactory. Being primarily dependent on rains the central region has demonstrated a high degree of instability in its growth performance. & 3. Rural Poverty- Rural Poverty in India is inversely correlated with agricultural growth and is of alarming magnitude. The present study strongly supports the view that the adoption of the Mission a & b mentioned above would further complicate these distortions and would lead to increased Inter-personal & Inter-regional Inequality and make the problem of rural poverty even worse in the length and width of the country. ix x Desai Bhupat M ibid. xiDesai Bhupat M & N.V. Namboodri, “ Strategy and Sources of Growth in Crop Agriculture” in Bhupat M Desai (Ed) Agricultural Growth paradigm for the Ninth Plan Under New Economic Environment” and also “ Policy Strategy and Instruments for Alleviating Poverty” Economic and Political Weekly,Vol-33, No-41, October 10,1998(1998) Gandhi Vasan P, “ The Role of Agriculture in India’s Economic Development: A Survey” in Bhupat M Desai (Ed) Agricultural Growth paradigm for the Ninth Plan Under New Economic Environment” xii Johnston Bruce F & John F Mellor, “ The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development” The American Economic Review, Vol-51, No.-4, September 1961 xiii ibid xiv Coren, R. L. ‘The Economics of Agriculture’, London. James Jams Visbet & Co. Ltd., Cambridge University Press. 1955. pp 142 xv Ezaciel,M "The Cobweb Theories" Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol. 52 1938 pp.256 xvi Schultz, T.W. "Economic Effects of Agricultural Programme", The American Economic Review, Vol XXX No.5, February 1941, pp. 135 xvii xviii F.L. Thomson, " Agricultural Prices", McGraw Hill, London, 1936, pp 78-80 Schultz T.W., " The Economic Organization of Agriculture, McGraw Hill Book Company, Inc. 1953 pp. 323 xix xx Sinha, S.P., "Indian Agriculture ....................... pp 40 Introduction xxxix xxi Kirk, John A, Agriculture and Trade Cycle, Reprint, Kelley Publication London, 1933, pp.3 Maynard, Geoffrey, "Economic Development and the price level" Macmillan and company Ltd., London, 1962, pp. 277 xxii Krisnamurthy, K, “ Seasonality in Wholesale Prices of Rice, “ Artha Vijana, 2 (2), June 1960,pp-97109 xxiii Kamladevi,P, “ Prices of Jowar in the Southern Zone between 1950 and 1960” Agricultural Situation in India, 16 (11), February 1962,pp-112-1118 xxiv Vyas,V.S. and A.K.Parikh, “ An Analysis of Food Prices in India (during 1948-57)”, Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 16 (30, July-September 1961,pp-25-32 xxv John,P.V., “ Seasonal Variation of Wholesale Prices of Selected Agricultural Commodities in Madhya Pradesh,1953-57” Agro-Economic Research Centre, Gwalior, 1962 xxvi Rath Nilankar and V.S. SatyaPriya, “Seasonal Movement of Prices of Jowar in Maharashtra and Mysore.” Artha Vijana, 7 (1), March 1965, pp-54-56 xxvii Reserve Bank of India, “Seasonal Variations and Secular Trends in Wholesale Prices1951-52 to 1964-65.”R.B.I. Bulletin, 19(6), June 1965,pp-867-892 xxviii Gupta, L.C., “ Price Behaviour of Maize in Some markets of Madhya Pradesh,1952-53 to 1964-65” Agro-Economic Research Centre, Jabalpur,1967 xxix xxx George,P.V., “ Price Behaviour in India” Economic Series, Bombay University Press, Bombay 1968 xxxiDivitia,V.V. and P.K.Pani, “ Variations in Cereal Prices,1951-52 to 1966-67: An Explanatory Model” Economic and Political Weekly, 3(26-28), July 1968 Rao, J.R. and K.S. Murthy, “ An Econometric Study of Rice Prices in India, 1948-60” Indian Journal of Economics, 45 (4), April 1965 xxxii Nadkarni, M.V., “ Agricultural Prices and Development with Stability” National Publishing House, Delhi, 1973 xxxiii Singh, Lal. S, “ Agricultural Price Policy and Stabilisation Measures in India” Capital Publishing House, New Delhi,1983 xxxiv Thingalaya, N.K, “Agriculture and Its Terms of Trade’ Ph.D. Thesis, Department of Economics, University of Bombay, 1961 xxxv Khan, N.A., “ Problems of Growth of An Underdeveloped Economy” Asia Publishing House, Bombay, 1961 xxxvi Introduction xl xxxvii Prasad, K, “ Recent Trends in Agricultural Prices” Yojna, XVII (9), June 1,1973 George, M.V.,and R.P.Singh, “ Recent Trends in Input-Output Prices and Their Impact on farm Income” Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Bombay, XXVI(1), Jan-Mar,1971 xxxviii Singh, H.S., “ Price Movements and Degree of Market Integration-A Study of Groundnut and Jowar Markets” Seminar Series V, Marketing of Agricultural Commodities, Indian Society of Agricultural Economics, Bombay, 1965 xxxix Antani,K.L. , “ Price Behavior of Major Food Grains in Rajasthan” Unpublished M.Sc. Agricultural Economics Thesis, University of Udaipur, Jobner Campus, 1978 xl Mandawalla, K.M., “ Seasonal Variations in Prices of Food grains with Special Reference to Wheat and Rice- 1970-71 to 1977-78” Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Bombay, XXXIV (4), Oct-Dec, 1979 xli Shukla,P.C. and B, K. Mishra, “ Agricultural Price Behaviour in U.P. Since 1950-51 to 1973-79” Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Bombay, XXXIV (4), Oct-Dec, 1979 xlii Aulakh, H.S. and A.S. Khalon, “The Role of Zonal Policy in Creating an Imperfect Market Structure in Punjab.” Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Bombay, XXIII (1), Jan-Mar, 1978 xliii xliv (7) Gill, K.S. and S.S. Johl, “ Price Structure in Punjab” Agricultural Situation in Punjab, New Delhi, XXV Lele, Uma J, “ Working of grain Markets in India” Department of Agricultural Economics, Cornell University Press, Ithaca xlv Kamla Devi P, “ Prices of Jowar in the Southern Zone Between 1950-60” Agricultural Situation in India, New Delhi, XVI (11), Feb,1962 xlvi Cummings, Ralph. W (Jr.), “ Price Efficiency In The Indian Wheat Market” Implex India, New Delhi, 1967, pp-186-90 xlvii xlviii ibid. Shah,S.L. and Others, “ Temporal and Spatial Fluctuations in Prices of Some Agricultural Commodities and factors Affecting Them” Conference Paper at Jabalpur on June 8-9, 1970. xlix Subramanian s. (1993). Agricultural trade liberalisation and India. OECD, Development Centre Studies, Paris. liParikh, K.S., N.S.S. Narayana, Manoj Panda and A. Ganesh Kumar (1996). “Strategies for economic liberalisation: Consequences for Growth, Welfare and Distribution”. Economic and political Economy, Vol. 30, No.39. lii Nayyar, Deepak and Abhijit Sen (1994). “ International Trade and the Agricultural Sector in India”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.29, No. 20, May 14, pp. 1187-1203. l Introduction xli Vyas (1994). “Agriculture Price Policy: Need for Reformulation” in G.S.Bhalla(ED.1994), Economic Liberalisation and Indian Agriculture, Institute for Studies in Industrial Development, New Delhi. liii Sharma A., A.Gulati and G. Pursell (1998). Agricultural Trade Liberalisation and Efficient Gains—An Analysis of Major Indian Crops. Economics Progress Report NO. 128, ICRISAT, Patancheru, Hyderabad. liv Chand Ramesh(1999) Effect of Trade Liberalisation on Agriculture in India: Commodity Aspects. Working paper no. 45, The CGPRT Centre, Jalan Merdeka 145, Bogor 16111,Indonesia. lv lviRao, C.H. Hanumantha(2001), “WTO and Viability of Indian Agriculture”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 36, No. 36, September 8-15. Sekhar, C.S.C. (2003), Volatility of Agricultutal Prices—An Analysis of Major International and Domestic Prices. Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations, New Delhi. lvii