Annex N – Marginal cost based tariffs Introduction 1 In this annex we set out further details our derivation of: (a) our (unscaled) marginal cost based BST and retail tariffs from pure marginal costs, as set out in Section 7; and (b) our calculation of BST and retail base tariffs, the above charges scaled to allow EGAT, MEA and PEA to meet their financial requirements, as set out in Sections 8 and 9. These revised base tariffs reflect 1999 fuel cost levels. Actual tariffs paid by consumers will include an Ft element as described in Section 10 of the main report. Unscaled marginal costs based tariffs Unscaled BST 2 We show the calculation of the unscaled BST in Table N.1. The unscaled BST at each “voltage level”1 is the sum of: (a) the generation cost at each voltage level; and (b) the cumulative transmission capacity charge at that voltage level. 3 In Part A of the Table we show that the cost of peak generation at the entry to the transmission system is 1.38 Baht / kWh, and the cost of off-peak energy is 0.78 Baht/kWh. In Part B we show EGAT’s marginal transmission capacity cost expressed in Baht/kW/month. We have converted this into a Baht/ peak period kWh charge in Part C of the Table. 4 The marginal costs BST is the sum of the cumulative generation and transmission marginal costs, which we show in Part E of the Table. When cumulating energy and transmission marginal costs it is necessary to take appropriate account of transmission losses2- we reproduce the transmission loss factors in Part D. We use the term “voltage level” here for convenience. We note that under the proposed structure of charges, there will be different charges at the exit of the 230:115kV sub-station and at the end of the 115 kV lines, which, strictly speaking, are at the same voltage. 1 2 For example, the peak period marginal cost based BST at exit of 500:230kV substation is the cost of generation at entry to the transmission system, 1.38 Baht/kWh scaled by the loss factor between the entry to the transmission system and the exit of the 500:230kV substation, 3.64%, plus the cost of transmission capacity to the exit of the 500:230kV system, 0.36 Baht/kWh, resulting in a figure of 1.79 Baht/kWh. The cost at the exit of the 230:115/69kV sub-station is the BST at 500:230kV, scaled for incremental losses in the voltage tier, 0.30%, plus the additional capacity cost, 0.28 Baht/kWh. 1 Unscaled retail tariffs 5 We have calculated unscaled retail tariffs using the following high level steps: (a) we calculated the cumulative marginal peak and off-peak generation costs at each voltage level in MEA’s area and each of PEA’s regions; (b) we calculated the cumulative Baht/kW transmission and distribution capacity costs at each voltage level in MEA’s area and each of PEA’s regions (c) we allocated the B/kW capacity charges to Baht/kWh energy charges as appropriate for each tariff category. The allocations reflect: (i) our recommendations to have demand charges for MGS, LGS and Specific business customers only; and (ii) the desire to preserve continuity with existing arrangements; (d) we calculated the sum of generation, transmission and distribution charges at each voltage level in MEA’s area and in each of PEA’s regions; (e) we calculated nationally averaged values for the sum of generation, transmission and distribution charges. The national averages reflects the spread of customers across MEA’s area and each of PEA’s regions specific to each tariff category; (f) we added the customer related charges3 (meter reading billing and collection charges) for each category to create the unscaled marginal cost based tariffs. 6 We discuss these steps in more detail below. 7 We present the marginal generation costs at each voltage level in MEA’s area and each of PEA’s regions in Table N.2. The results are based on: (a) the calculated marginal generation cost of 1.38 Baht/kWh during peak periods and 0.78 Baht/kWh during off-peak periods; and (b) the marginal transmission and distribution losses presented in Table N.3. 3 Customer related costs include meter reading billing and collection, and connection costs. However, connection costs are only applicable to new customers, since existing customers have already paid a contribution through existing connection charges. 2 8 We present the cumulated transmission and distribution marginal costs in Baht/kW in Table N.4. As stated in Annex K, for the purposes of cumulating we have assumed a stylised model in which energy passes from the EGAT system to: (a) MEA at the exit of the 500:230kV sub-station; and (b) PEA at the exit of the 230:115/69kV sub-station. 9 The tariff categories can be divided into two classes: (a) Smaller customer tariff categories, which will generally be charged flat rate energy charges4 and monthly standing charges only5: Residential, SGS, Government, Agricultural pumping and Temporary customers. For these smaller customers more expensive metering is unlikely to be cost effective, so all transmission and distribution capacity costs are allocated to Baht/kWh charges; (b) Larger customer tariff categories: MGS, LGS and Specific business customers6 who be required to migrate to mandatory7 Baht/kW/month demand charges and differential peak and off-peak Baht/kWh charges. For these larger customers, for the purpose of calculating illustrative unscaled charges, we allocated 50% of transmission and distribution capacity costs to Baht/kWh charges. The remaining costs are charged as Baht/kW/month charges. 10 The allocation of transmission and distribution capacity costs to peak and off-peak Baht/kWh in each area/region is shown in Table N.5. We then summed the generation, transmission, and distribution charges for each category and calculated the flat rate charges for the smaller tariff categories. We present the aggregated charges for all categories in Table N.6, and the “flat rate” charge for smaller tariff category in Table N.7. 11 We calculated the flat rate charges using estimates of the percentage of total energy consumed during peak hours, calculated from the 1996 TLFS load profile research data. We show the percentage of total energy that each category consumes during peak hours in Part A of Table N.7, and the resulting flat rate charges in Part B. 4 Flat rate energy charges = Baht/kWh charges that are not time of day/week dependent 5 Customers in these tariff categories may opt for Time of Use tariffs, which have differential peak and off-peak energy rates, provided that they install the appropriate metering. 6 Standby and interruptible customers will also fall into this category, but these tariffs are derived from the tariffs for other larger customers and we have discussed only the major tariff categories. 7 Whilst we propose that all such customers should be required to migrate to time of Use tariffs with differential peak and off-peak energy rates, we recognise that not all such customers currently have appropriate metering, and that it is impractical to require them all install such metering immediately. Therefore a transition tariff, with a single rate B/kWh will also be necessary. 3 12 We then calculated nationally averaged generation, transmission and distribution charges in the following way: (a) smaller customers tariff categories: we weighted the charges in MEA’s area and each of PEA’s regions using data specific to each category8. The calculation and the resulting weighted averages for each of the smaller tariff categories are shown in Table N.8. (b) larger customer tariff categories: we calculated nationally averaged aggregated charge by weighting together the charges presented in Table N.6 by the weights for the aggregate of all three classes. We considered weighting the charges to reflect the spread of customers in each separate tariff category, but this would result in slightly different charges for neighbouring MGS/LGS/Specific business customers9, which would be hard to justify on equity grounds and might result in perverse incentives. The weights and the resulting nationally averaged charges are shown in Table N.9. 13 The only customer related costs to be reflected in tariff for existing customers are marginal meter reading, billing and collection (MRBC) costs, which we have shown in Table N.10. 14 Finally we summed the generation, transmission and distribution and the marginal MRBC cost to derive the unscaled marginal cost based tariffs, which we present in Table N.11. Scaled tariffs 15 In Sections 8 and 9 we presented revised BST and retail base tariffs scaled to allow EGAT, MEA and PEA to meet their combined financial requirements. We show the calculation of these numbers in more detail below. 16 We calculated the scaled tariffs using the following high level steps: (a) we unbundled the accounts for EGAT’s generation and transmission businesses, and both MEA’s and PEA’s distribution and retail supply businesses; (b) we calculated financial requirements for each of the separate businesses, and a combined financial requirement for: (i) the aggregate of MEA’s and PEA’s distribution businesses; (ii) the aggregate of MEA’s and PEA’s retail supply businesses; 8 We used forecast annual consumption for FY 1999 from the TLFS September 1998 forecasts to generate the weights 9 See Part B of the Table, where we also show the impact of weighting by each separate tariff category 4 (c) we scaled the generation, transmission, distribution and retail supply costs separately so that the NPV earned from the scaled charges would equal the NPV10 of the financial requirement of EGAT’s generation, EGAT’s transmission, the aggregate of MEA’s and PEA’s distribution businesses and the aggregate of MEA’s and PEA’s retail supply businesses respectively11. The financial requirements are shown in nominal terms in Table N.12. These financial requirements were generated by the first iteration of the financial model. The Base Allowed Revenues presented in Section 5 and Annex G have the same NPV as the financial requirements in Table N.12, but reflect the actual tariff revenue profile (i.e. the results of the scaling exercise) rather than the financial requirement used to generate the scaled tariffs; (d) we summed: (i) the scaled generation and transmission charges at each voltage level to calculate the scaled BST; and (ii) the scaled generation, transmission, distribution and retail supply charges to calculate scaled “target” retail tariffs, and adjusted them in the light of agreed policy constraints in order to calculate recommended retail tariffs. 17 The high level steps are explained in more detail below. Calculation of scaled generation and transmission charges, and BST 18 In Table N.13 we show the calculation of the scaled generation charges at each transmission voltage level12. In Part A of the Table we show the unscaled generation charges. The charges are calculated by applying the loss factors presented in Table N.1 to the cost of generation at entry to the transmission system, 1.38 Baht/kWh during peak periods and 0.78 Baht/kWh during off-peak periods, and therefore represent the marginal cost of generation at each voltage level. 19 In Part B we show our forecast of EGAT sales by voltage level used to calculate the required level of scaling. The forecast is consistent with the TLFS September 1998 load forecasts. However, we have: 10 We equated the NPVs using a nominal discount rates of 12.35% (5% inflation and 7% real discount rate. This is equal to a 12.35% nominal discount rate since 1.05 X 1.07 = 1.1235). 11 Given forecast volumes over the period 2000-03 as per the TLFS September 1998 load forecasts. We also calculated forecast peak period and off-peak, and peak MW demand for each tariff category using the TLFS load foreacst and TLFS load profiles from the 1996 TLFS load profile research. 12 Shown only for those voltage levels at which bulk supply is taken 5 (a) split sales at 115/69kV into those at the exit of the 230:115/69kV substation and those at the end of 115kV lines13, based upon the split provided by EGAT in its demand balance; (b) disaggregated into peak period and off-peak period sales, based upon the TLFS 1996 load profile research data. 20 In Part C of the Table we show the scaling factor that is required to uplift the unscaled charges to ensure that generation charges covers EGAT’s generation financial requirements. In Part D we show the resulting scaled charges, and in Part E we show the calculation of the resulting revenue from scaled generation charges and the reconciliation between revenues from scaled charges and the financial requirement. The NPVs in the Table and all other tables in this Annex are presented in FY1998 values. 21 In Table N.14 we show the scaling calculation for transmission capacity charges (calculated using the same methodology). The data is presented in the same format as the calculation for generation. In Table N.15 we show how we calculate the BST by summing generation and transmission charges. Calculation of scaled distribution, retail supply charges and retail tariffs 22 In this annex we explain the calculation of the recommended tariffs. calculated the recommended tariffs by calculating: We “Target tariffs”. Tariffs, fully rebalanced to reflect marginal costs, after scaling to meet EGAT, MEA and PEA’s financial requirements; and then “Recommended tariffs”. The recommended tariffs have been calculated by rebalancing existing 1999 total tariffs (1999 base tariffs plus 1999 Ft) towards target tariffs subject to the policy constraints on tariff rebalancing agreed with NEPO. The key constraint is the requirement that the average base tariffs for any customer category14 should not exceed the average total tariff in FY1999; 23 In any year of the tariff period FY2000 to FY2003, the total tariffs will comprise recommended base tariffs plus Ft (which has been rebased and set to zero in FY1999). 24 In the main report we also presented two alternative sets of base retail tariffs 13 “Unrebalanced tariffs”. Existing tariffs uniformly scaled to the new financial requirements; There are no sales at the end of 69kV lines We have defined “customer category” differently from tariff category. See later in the section for explanation 14 6 “Alternative re-balanced tariffs”. Existing tariffs rebalanced towards target tariffs but with a different set policy constraints from the recommended base tariffs. The key difference is that tariff rebalancing can increase tariffs for any tariff category by up to 10% in real terms pa. 25 These in Annex R. Target retail tariffs 26 In calculating scaled target retail tariffs we have reflected: (a) Generation: the weighted average of scaled generation costs reflected in the BST, scaled by nationally averaged distribution losses to each distribution voltage level; (b) Transmission: the weighted average of scaled transmission costs reflected in the BST, scaled by nationally averaged distribution losses to each distribution voltage level; (c) Distribution: (d) (i) nationally averaged scaled distribution capacity costs; (ii) nationally averaged marginal distribution losses Retail supply related costs: scaled marginal meter reading, billing and collection costs only, since the other component of customer related costs, connection costs are to be charged to new customers only, and are excluded from both revenues and costs in the calculation of financial requirements and tariffs. 27 We show the weighted average generation and transmission costs in Table N.16 and the nationally averaged distribution losses in Table N.17. 28 We propose that scaled distribution capacity costs be reflected in tariffs in the following manner: (a) smaller customers tariff categories: all costs be allocated to Baht/kWh charges; (b) larger customer tariff categories: 100% of scaled distribution charges for MGS, LGS and Specific business customers be reflected as Baht/kW/month demand charges. The reason for this proposal is that the allocation of all scaled transmission costs to Baht/kWh charges and all scaled distribution costs to Baht/kW/month charges results in Baht/kW/month charges that are similar in magnitude to current charges. 7 29 To calculate standardised national distribution charges we have included the cost of MEA’s 230kV system in with its 115/69kV system, and it is this cost which is reflected in the nationally averaged charge for the 115/69kV system. 30 We show the calculation of the scaled, nationally averaged distribution charge and reconcile the revenue received from the scaled charges with the financial requirement for distribution in Table N.18. The cumulated distribution charges are calculated based on the distribution losses in Table N.17, and the reconciliation is calculated using forecast retail sales volumes presented in Table N.1915. 31 We then calculated “flat rate” Baht/kWh generation, transmission and distribution charges for smaller customers from the peak and off-peak charges. The calculation is shown in Table N.20. In Part A of the Table we show the unbundled peak and offpeak charges. In Part B we show, for each tariff category, the percentage of total consumption consumed during the peak. We used the national average figure for the category. We calculated the national average by weighting together the percentages for each tariff category in MEA’s area and each of PEA’s regions 16, using forecast consumption in FY 2000. In Part C of the Table we show the resulting unbundled “flat rate” charges. 32 In Table N.21 we show the aggregation of generation, transmission and distribution charges for MGS, LGS and Specific business customers. 33 In Table N.22 we show the scaling calculation for retail supply related costs, and in Table N.23 we add together the charges for generation, transmission, distribution and retail supply related costs and present a summary of the target retail base tariffs. 34 In Table N.24 we show the forecast revenue resulting from the target retail tariffs17 for FY2000. Recommended base retail tariffs 35 The target base tariffs do not take account of policy constraints on tariff rebalancing. We calculated recommended base tariffs based upon the following key policy constraints. (a) the need to maintain a progressive block for residential customers which ensures that larger residential customers continue to crosssubsidise smaller residential customers (less than 150kWh/month). Cross-subsidy will remain greatest for very small consumers, those with consumption less than 35 kWh/month; 15 The MW demand, and peak and off-peak volume forecasts for each tariff category were calculated from the TLFS September 1998 forecasts using data on load profiles from the TLFS 1996 load research project 16 As estimated by the TLFS 1996 load research project 17 Calculated by multiplying target tariffs by forecast consumption in Table N.19 8 (b) the average unit base tariff for each customer category in FY2000 should be no more than the average total tariff in FY 1999. For this purpose we have defined customer category to mean tariff category, the following exceptions: (i) given the need to cross-subsidise smaller residential customers we have viewed residential customers as three customer categories, very small (less than 35kWh/month), small (35-150kWh/month) and large (150+ kWh/month); (ii) we have viewed MGS, LGS and Specific Business customers, as single group, since we recommend a unified Baht/kW and Baht/kWh tariff for them; and (iii) we did not apply this constraint to streetlighting, for which a tariff is being introduced for the first time18; 36 In Table N.25 we show that target tariffs exceed current tariffs for residential customers, agricultural customers and government customers. Therefore we have to calculate revised tariffs for these customers which are consistent with the policy constraints. 37 In Table N.26 we show how we calculated our recommended progressive block structure for residential customers. In order to calculate such a progressive block structure we: (a) calculated the average tariff paid by three representative consumers: a very small customer consuming 35kWh per month; a small customer consuming 150kWh per month, and a large customer consuming 450kWh per month (the average consumption for customer consuming in excess of 150kWh per month); (b) calculated new base tariffs, which equated the charges paid by three representative consumers with the 1999 average tariff. We have simplified the progressive block structure by reducing the number of blocks from eight to three. We proposed that very small customers should not face a monthly charge, accordingly we have set the Baht/kWh charge for the first 35kWh in FY2000 so that the representative very small customer faces no increase (or decrease) in average tariff. We propose small customers should pay half the target monthly charge, and have set the Baht/kWh charge for the 35th to 150th Baht/kWh in FY2000 so that the representative small customer faces no increase (or decrease) in tariffs. We propose that large residential customers should pay the full target monthly charge, and have set the Baht/kWh charge so that the representative large residential customer faces no increase (or decrease) in charges in FY2000; 18 We understand that under some abnormal circumstances, a very small percentage of streetlighting is currently charged for 9 38 In order to forecast the impact of these recommended tariffs on revenues received by MEA and PEA we forecast: (i) the number of customers whose monthly consumption was in each of the bands 0-35 kWh (very small customers), 35150kWh (small customers) and more than 150kWh (large customers); (ii) the volume of consumption in each band (i.e the first 35 kWh per month, the 35th-150th kWh per month, more than 150kWh) 39 The forecasts were based upon the TLFS aggregate load forecasts for residential volumes and customer numbers and sample data provided by MEA and PEA. Our forecasts are presented in Table N.27. 40 In Table N.28 we show the calculation of recommended tariffs for agricultural pumping. We calculated the recommended Baht/kWh and Baht/month charges by setting the Baht/month charges at the target rate, and adjusting the Baht/kWh charges appropriately to achieve an average tariff equal to the 1999 average tariff. 41 In Table N.29 we show the calculation of the recommended government tariffs. Again, we have adjusted the Baht/kWh charges to meet the constraint, and reflected the full Baht/month target tariff in the recommended tariff19. 42 .These policy constraints mean that it is not possible to fully rebalance tariffs, i.e. it is necessary to have cross-subsidy between customer categories. Agricultural pumping, residential and government tariffs are cross-subsidised by charges in excess of target tariffs levied on other categories. 43 We have levied an additional charge of 25% of target tariffs on temporary tariffs as measure to incentivise temporary tariff customers to move on to permanent tariff category, and have levied additional charge of just over 3% on SGS, MGS, LGS, Specific business and streetlighting tariffs, which is the amount necessary to recover the cross-subsidy in favour of agricultural, residential and government customers. 44 We show the calculation of the recommended charges for temporary, SGS, MGS, LGS, Specific Business and streetlighting in Table N.30. 45 In Table N.31, we summarise the resulting recommended retail tariffs for each year. In Table N.32 we show the revenues received by MEA and PEA, based upon the load forecasts and the recommended tariff revenues, and in Table N.33 we show the reconciliation of these revenues with the aggregate sector financial requirement (the sum of generation, transmission, distribution and retailing revenues). 19 We have taken this approach because, we have offset these reductions in tariffs against the monopoly distribution and transmission charges for agriculutral and government customers, which are Baht/kWh charges. 10 46 In Tables N.34 and N.35 we show the recommended tariffs for FY2000, unbundled into the generation, transmission, distribution and retail components. The unbundled tariffs reflect the scaled generation, transmission, distribution and retail charges and the allocations of the cross subsidy (necessary in the light of policy constraints). 47 We have made in a manner which does not distort competition. The key principle is that TUOS and DUOS charges payable by independent suppliers in respect of free customers (MGS, LGS and Specific Business customers) should be the same as the transmission and distribution components of the published retail tariff for those categories. Therefore we have allocated the additional charges necessary to cover the cross-subsidy to distribution charges, and set the DUOS charges equal to the distribution charges, inclusive of the cross-subsidy element. 48 The tariff categories which are receiving the cross-subsidy, residential, agricultural pumping and government are all captive customers20, so the allocation of cross-subsidy has no implications for competition. We have allocated the reductions in charges to distribution. However, where the reduction in charges exceeds the distribution charge, we have allocated the charges to transmission and then to retailing (monthly) charges. 20 i.e. not free customers 11