RISK AND RISK MANAGEMENT STRATEGIES IN AGRICULTURE: AN OVERVIEW OF THE EVIDENCE FINAL REPORT October 2010 Rural and Environment Analytical Services (REAS) Rural and Environment Research and Analysis Directorate (RERAD) I TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ..................................................................................................................... IV LIST OF FIGURES ................................................................................................................... IV EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ........................................................................................................... V 1. Introduction ....................................................................................................................... 1 2. Risks in agriculture........................................................................................................... 2 2.1 Defining risks in agriculture ............................................................................................. 2 2.2 Sources of risk in Scottish agriculture .............................................................................. 2 2.3 3. 3.1 3.2 4. 2.2.1 Market or price risk ................................................................................................. 2 2.2.2 Production risk ........................................................................................................ 4 2.2.3 Institutional/policy risk ............................................................................................. 5 2.2.4 Other sources of risk ............................................................................................... 5 Interactions between sources of risk and other issues ..................................................... 6 Measuring Risk in Agriculture ......................................................................................... 8 Trends in volatility in agricultural commodities prices ...................................................... 8 3.1.1 Measuring volatility in UK agriculture commodity prices .......................................... 9 3.1.2 Reasons for increased price volatility in agricultural commodities ......................... 13 Income variability........................................................................................................... 16 Effect of Risk on Farm Production and Investment Choices ....................................... 19 4.1 Effects on production ..................................................................................................... 19 4.2 On-farm risk management strategies and efficiency ...................................................... 20 4.3 Impacts on investment................................................................................................... 20 5. Dealing with Risks – Risk Management Tools and Strategies in Agriculture ............. 21 5.1 Rationale for government intervention in agricultural risk management ......................... 22 5.2 Risk management related policies in agriculture ............................................................ 24 5.2.1 Price stabilisation policies ..................................................................................... 24 5.2.2 Supporting “on-farm” actions to reduce risk exposure ........................................... 25 5.2.3 Ex ante measures to assist farmers to mitigate/cope with risk .............................. 26 II 5.3 6. 5.2.4 Ex post measures ................................................................................................. 28 5.2.5 Direct payments .................................................................................................... 29 5.2.6 Summary .............................................................................................................. 31 5.2.7 Measuring public support for risk management tools ............................................ 32 Market-based risk management tools in agriculture ....................................................... 34 5.3.1 Agricultural Insurance systems ............................................................................. 35 5.3.2 Mutual funds ......................................................................................................... 39 5.3.3 Hedging price risk – forward contracts, futures and options .................................. 41 Summary ......................................................................................................................... 47 References ............................................................................................................................. 49 III LIST OF TABLES Table 1 - Coefficient of variation in EU and World prices for various commodities over three periods (from Matthews 2010)................................................................................. 9 Table 2 - Coefficients of variation for UK feed wheat and cattle (liveweight) prices over three periods .................................................................................................................. 10 Table 3 - Frequency of observations substantially outwith trend (2 year moving average), UK feed wheat prices 1988-2010 .................................................................................. 12 Table 4 - Frequency of substantially different from trend (3-year moving average), UK cattle prices 1988-2010 .................................................................................................. 13 Table 5 - Volatility in farm incomes EU-15 (1996-2004) ................................................. 17 Table 6 - Index of income volatility for different farm types by selected EU countries 19962004 (index = 100 equals CV = 31.4) ............................................................................. 17 Table 7 – Summary of risk management tools in agriculture .......................................... 21 Table 8 - Summary of crop insurance types ................................................................... 36 Table 9 - Level of insurance subsidies and ad-hoc/calamity fund payments in selected EU member states ............................................................................................................... 38 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1 - UK feed wheat and cattle (liveweight) prices, 1985-2010*.............................. 10 Figure 2 - UK feed wheat prices two-year moving average with ±10% and ±20% bands 11 Figure 3 - UK cattle (liveweight) prices two year moving average with ±10% and ±20% bands ............................................................................................................................. 13 Figure 4 - Share of MPS, variable and fixed rate payments in the PSE in total farm receipts for selected OECD countries, 1992-97 and 2002-07 ......................................... 33 Figure 5 - Ratio of trading in wheat futures contracts relative to physical production in the UK, USA and South Africa, 1989-2003 .......................................................................... 44 IV EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This paper reviews the literature on risks in agriculture and the tools available to manage them. It is one of several papers produced by the Scottish Government Rural and Environment Analytical Services to contribute to the evidence base for the Brian Pack Inquiry into the Future of Support for Agriculture in Scotland. It identifies (in Section 2) the main risks in agriculture to include the following: ▬ Market or price risk: risk of unpredictable changes in prices of both inputs and outputs due to shocks, trade policy, new markets, etc; ▬ Production or yield risk: disruptions to production arising from weather related factors (e.g. hail, frost, floods, and droughts), crops and livestock diseases and pests, and changes in technology. ▬ Institutional and regulatory risks: unexpected changes in regional or national policy, environmental law, agricultural payments (e.g. Single Farm Payment), etc. ▬ Financial risk: changes in interest rates, access to credit and value of financial assets disrupting the financial flows in a business. ▬ Personnel risk: personnel hazards such as injury, illness, or death. These risks affect farm businesses through fluctuations in income, which can affect investment on the farm – especially when credit markets are imperfect. Depending on the risk attitude of farmers, they also affect farmers’ production choices. In particular, as farmers tend to be risk averse, they may opt for lower return more certain outcomes at the expense of higher returns but less certain ones. An analysis of United Kingdom (UK) feed wheat and cattle prices in Section 3 presents some evidence to suggest that volatility in the prices of these commodities has increased in recent decades. Together with evidence elsewhere in the literature, the analysis shows that with successive Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) reforms, UK and European Union (EU) prices have become more closely related to world prices due to reduced levels of market price support and liberalisation of trade with third countries. Additional causes of increased volatility are also cited in the literature to include growing linkages between energy and agricultural markets and volatility in crude oil prices; biofuels mandates, which create artificial demand for feedstocks and make demand for agricultural produce less responsive to price changes; relatively low global public stocks; and the speculative activity of investors in futures markets. The review of the literature suggests that there is some rationale for government to intervene in managing risks in agriculture due to a range of factors hindering the perfect functioning of markets for some of the risk management tools and on distributional grounds. However, as government interventions can incur significant costs and reduce the incentives for farmers to take private actions to reduce or manage risks, governments’ efforts should focus on creating an enabling environment for farmers to manage their own risks – especially as the risks and V attitudes towards them tend to be farm specific. Further, considerations for risk management should take into account the full range of instruments available for managing risks and the effect of current policies on farmers’ risk environments and responses to risk. The review of risk management related agricultural policies across the OECD identifies intervention purchasing, import tariffs and export subsidies to be the main tools used to stabilise prices, although there is evidence that some countries are probably moving away from these approaches. The paper also finds that policies in other countries have intervened in risk management in agriculture through subsidies on insurance premiums (e.g. Spain, Portugal, United States of America (USA), Canada, Greece) and ad hoc payments to farmers in the event of adverse events affecting agriculture. The paper also finds that although direct payments (such as those in the USA and EU) are not primarily focused on risk management, they do have some impact on risk as they contribute to stabilising farm income and reduce farmers’ aversion to risks. Finally, the paper identifies from the literature that farmers also have available to them a number of market-based instruments for managing risks. Forward and futures contracts and options allow price risk to be shared between buyers and sellers of agricultural produce, which can offer a more efficient means of mitigating price related risks. Farmers can also implement a number of on-farm measures to reduce and mitigate risks, such as diversification within and outwith agriculture, and invest in appropriate technologies to reduce environment related risks. They are also opportunities for farmers to pool risk amongst themselves via mutual funds. VI 1. Introduction 1. Agricultural activity is subject to a wide range of risks due to the variable economic and biophysical environment in which farming operates. While some of these sources of risk are faced in common with other industries, many are specific to agriculture. Their presence affects production choices - with implications for the overall economic efficiency of agricultural production. Further, where the realisation of the risks leads to falls in farm incomes, they can adversely affect the economic welfare of those working in agriculture, with the potential to constrain future investment and growth of farm businesses. It is important, therefore, to understand how the presence of risks in agricultural production affects farming and how the different risks can be mitigated. 2. In recent years, interest in the risks faced by farm businesses – particularly from price volatility – has grown as the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) has reoriented from price support in favour of direct farm payments.1 Concerns are also raised that further trade liberalisation would leave Scottish and, more widely, EU farmers further exposed to the vagaries of world price shocks. The 2007/8 agricultural commodity price spike, in particular, has heightened concerns around volatility in agricultural markets. 3. A number of tools are available to manage risks in agriculture and these range from those that can be provided as part of government policy to those provided privately through the market or the individual actions of farmers. Given this background, this paper reviews studies on risks in agriculture and tools available to manage them. It is one of several papers produced by the Scottish Government Rural and Environment Analytical Services to contribute to the evidence base for the Brian Pack Inquiry into the Future of Support for Agriculture in Scotland. 4. The paper largely draws on the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)2 framework for a holistic approach to understanding risk and risk management in agriculture. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows: Chapter 2 reviews the sources of risk in agriculture, including market or price, production or yield, institutional or regulatory, financial and personnel risks. Chapter 3 reviews studies on trends in volatility in agricultural commodity prices, assesses volatility in UK prices for two key agricultural commodities – wheat and beef, and examines volatility in farm incomes. Chapter 4 assesses the effects of risk and uncertainty on farm production and investment. Chapter 5 assesses the rationale for government intervention to manage risks in agriculture, reviews agricultural risk management strategies and current policy approaches in the EU and other OECD countries, agricultural insurance mechanisms and mutual funds, and a range of market-based risk management tools. Chapter 6 provides some concluding discussion. 1 For example through the Single Farm Payment 2 OECD project on Risk Management in Agriculture, Trade and Agricultural Directorate: http://www.oecd.org/agriculture/policies/risk 1 2. Risks in agriculture 2.1 Defining risks in agriculture 5. Although definitions of risk vary within the literature, in agriculture risks arise due to uncertainty over factors determining returns to agricultural production (OECD 2008). Uncertainty in agriculture reflects the nature of most farm production systems, which is influenced by ever-changing economic and biophysical conditions. The natural lag between when production decisions are made and when returns to farming can be realised exposes agricultural enterprises to the variability, in the intervening period, of a range of factors that determine the value of production. These include weather, animal and plant health, changes in agricultural markets and a range of macroeconomic factors. Variability in these factors results in uncertainty over key determinants of farm income like output price, yield, and input costs - with implications for farmers’ economic welfare and effects on the economic (allocative) and technical efficiency of farm production. 6. Broadly, the variability in these factors affecting production can be separated into two – anticipated variations occurring seasonally or cyclically, and those that are unpredictable in nature. Generally, the assessment of risks in agriculture tends to focus on those factors that tend to vary unpredictably (i.e. where variability is uncertain), since anticipated variations can be incorporated into production decisions or provided for. 2.2 7. Sources of risk in Scottish agriculture While there are several ways to classify risks, the specific typology is not considered important as long as all risk factors are accounted for. In the context of agriculture this paper identifies the following categories of risks (OECD 2008): market or price risk – uncertainty about future changes in prices of both inputs and outputs due to shocks, trade policy, new markets, etc; production or yield risk – uncertainty about the quantity from agricultural production arising from weather related factors (e.g. hail, frost, floods, droughts), crop and livestock diseases and pests, and changes in technology, etc; institutional or regulatory risk – uncertainty regarding the regional or national policy and legal environmental for agriculture; financial – uncertainty about financial flows within a business due to variability in interest rates, access to credit and value of financial assets; and, personnel risks – uncertainty due to personnel hazards, such as injury, illness, or death. 2.2.1 Market or price risk Output price risk 8. The length of most agricultural production cycles (ranging from a few weeks to several years) result in a lag between when a farmer makes production decision and the product is sold, which means that output prices are often unknown at the start of the production cycle. This is particularly important because farm 2 businesses are price-takers, as the output of any one farm tends to be too small relative to the total market supply and thus an individual farm cannot to influence prices. 9. The causes of fluctuations in output price are often linked to other sources of risk within and outwith agriculture, and can be split broadly into effects on market demand and supply. Thus, it is important when assessing output price risk to focus not only on output price variability, but also on the variability of the underlying drivers. For example, unforeseen changes in consumer demand due to food health scares caused by an animal disease (e.g. BSE, Foot and Mouth Disease), can have a significant effect on output prices. Similarly, macroeconomic factors, such as movements in exchange rates and changes in economic conditions, can alter the relative competitiveness of farm businesses internationally, which can affect demand for agricultural produce. 10. On the supply-side, impacts on yield that are widespread and have a significant impact on total market supply (e.g. due to an adverse weather event or plant or animal diseases affecting a wide area) can have profound affects on market prices. Such supply shocks do not have to be local to affect the market price for farmers in a particular region; the spatial integration of agricultural markets means that disruptions to supply in one regional market can have some effects on markets in other regions. For example, the drought in Australia in 2006/07 is cited, among other factors, as a cause of the 2007 global price spike for dairy products. 11. Broadly, the market price for agricultural commodities is particularly sensitive to supply shocks due to the generally unresponsiveness of demand for food to price. This means any changes in the level of supply for a particular commodity at any given time requires a relatively large change in price to ensure that market balance is restored or supply equals demand (O’Connor et al 2009). 12. Exposure to output price shocks or the ability to cope with them varies across agricultural commodities. Most arable crops, such as grains and pulses, can be preserved and stored allowing farmers more flexibility over when to sell, which provides a mechanism for coping with some of the output price fluctuations (although in some instances there can be significant storage costs). In comparison, other produce, for example livestock products (milk, finished animals and meat), are highly perishable and can only be stored for extended periods at very high costs, which limits the scope to deal with output price.3 13. Recent studies have suggested that prices of agricultural commodities in the European Union and consequently Scotland are becoming more volatile. In Section 3.1, this paper assesses volatility in UK wheat and cattle prices and reviews other studies measuring volatility in agricultural commodity markets across the EU. 3 Some of the volatility for milk and livestock products is managed using forward/production contracts. These are discussed in Section 5.3.3. 3 Input price risk 14. Unforeseen changes in the prices of inputs to a farm business can result in costs being higher or lower than expected, which is another source of price or market risk in agriculture. Generally, the significance of changes in the price of a given input is determined by the magnitude of the price change and the proportion of total costs accounted for by the input. This varies by farm sector. For example, during 2007/8, input prices for Scottish farms increased considerably (feed costs up by between 50-80%, fertiliser prices up 80%, red diesel prices by 40%),4 but this largely affected enterprises with intensive input use – pig, poultry and beef finishers.5 15. Given a number of key agricultural inputs are derived from crude oil; fluctuations in oil prices attend to be a major driver for variability in agricultural input prices. It also means that prices for key agricultural inputs (fuel, pesticides and fertiliser) show strong positive correlation (i.e. prices tend to move together), which exacerbates the impact of developments in oil markets on the farm business. Additionally, outputs from some farm sectors (e.g. arable) can be inputs for others (e.g. livestock); meaning output price volatility for one sector of farming becomes input price volatility for others. 16. Surveys of farmers consistently rate input price risk lower than output price risk (OECD 2008, Palinkas & Székely 20086). There are a number of possible reasons for this. First, the gap between production decision and purchase of agricultural inputs (e.g. seed, fertiliser) is generally much shorter than the gap to when output is sold, which means there is a smaller window of vulnerability to input price fluctuations. Second, input prices are often positively correlated with output prices in the medium term. For example, a rise in crude oil prices, causing a corresponding increase in fuel and fertiliser prices, generally affects all agricultural operations at the same time. The increase in costs feeds into market price to offset, to some extent, the impact of rising input costs on farm profit margins, although usually with some lag. 7 2.2.2 Production risk 17. Although the variations in yield from agricultural production can occur for a number of reasons, extreme or unseasonal weather conditions, in addition to plant and animal diseases, are often the principal causes. Generally, crops and extensively reared livestock tend to be more exposed to weather risk than intensively reared livestock (e.g. poultry and pigs) that are housed and sheltered SAC (2008) – Assessing the Impact of Increased Feed, Fuel and Fertiliser Costs on Scottish Agriculture. AA211 Special Study for the Scottish Government. 4 5 SGRERAD (2010) – Economic Report on Scottish Agriculture: 2010 Edition. Palinkas, P. and Csaba Székely (2008) – Farmers’ perceptions on risk and crisis risk management, in Meuwissen et al (eds.), Income Stabilisation in the European Union, Ch. 2. Wageningen Academic Publishers, Netherlands 6 7 Indeed, if an input shock is very short-lived, the increase input costs may have little impact on output prices. 4 and the physical environment for their production, to some extent, can be regulated. 18. Animal diseases can contribute to total farm risk in three main ways. First, animal disease can adversely affect yield by either reducing the growth rate of the livestock or increasing morbidity. In the worst case, livestock may have to be culled as part of efforts to contain and eradicate disease, with associated costs. Second, livestock disease can affect demand, due to loss of access to international markets following trade restrictions or lower consumer demand due to public health concerns, or both. This effect often manifests as price risk, as falling demand puts a downward pressure on prices and results in significant losses in farm revenue. Third, movement restrictions to control the spread of disease can lead to market disruptions - leaving farmers unable to sell livestock, which then grow out of specification and lose value. The outbreaks of foot-andmouth disease (FMD) (2001 and 2007) and BSE demonstrate the unpredictable nature of animal disease outbreaks and their potential impact on farm businesses. A 2008 report8 for the Scottish Government estimates that the 2007 FMD outbreak in England to have directly cost the Scottish livestock industry some £32 million due to loss of export market and movement restrictions. An earlier FMD outbreak in 2001 is estimated to have resulted in losses to the UK farming industry amounting to around £355 million – excluding losses that were compensated for by the government. 19. In the long term, climate change is an additional source of yield risk through its effects on weather patterns (changing temperature and rainfall patterns, and potentially generating extreme weather events, etc.) – an effect which is still highly uncertain (OECD 2008). It is projected, however, that changing climate may also result in the introduction and increased frequency of pests and diseases, heightening animal health and crop related risks. 2.2.3 Institutional/policy risk 20. Although some policy interventions in the agricultural sector are often intended to reduce the level of risk faced by farmers, the policy interventions themselves can be a significant source of risk. This is because it is often difficult to foresee changes in government policies, particularly where decisions are influenced by social and political considerations. Changes in agricultural policy can influence prices directly, for example through price support policies, or can affect farm incomes through changes to policies for direct farm payments. Changes in agricultural support can also have longer-term impacts on farm wealth through effects on the value of farmland and other agricultural assets (OECD 2008) – with implications on the financial position of the business. 2.2.4 Other sources of risk 21. Farmers face additional sources of risk that may not be directly related to agricultural activity. Financial risks arise from changes in the price (interest rates) Pareto Consulting (2008) – Foot & Mouth Disease Review 2007: Economic Impact in Scotland. Available at: http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Publications/2008/06/11151009/0 8 5 and availability of credit for financing farm business operations or other farm household activities. Fluctuations in income from off-farm activities and the value of on- and off-farm assets can also be a source of risk, although where off-farm income is weakly correlated to on-farm income, it could be used to reduce the effect of fluctuations in total farm household income. An additional source of financial risk facing Scottish, and more widely UK farmers, arises from agricultural support payments paid in Euros under the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), which are obviously subject to exchange rate fluctuations. 22. Farmers also face personnel risk associated illnesses and injuries to staff. However, given these other risks are not particularly specific to agriculture, there are not often addressed through agricultural policy and therefore do not form the main part of the discussion in this paper. 2.3 Interactions between sources of risk and other issues 23. The overall impact of risks on individual farms or across the agricultural sector depends on the relationships between the different risk sources. Broadly, the correlation between risk factors can differ significantly, which affects the overall risk exposure of farm businesses. Where risks tend to occur together but in the opposite direction (i.e. one effect is positive and one is negative), that is they are negatively correlated, there is a mitigating effect on overall risk exposure and thus on farm income variability. On the other hand, risks that are positively correlated (i.e. tend to occur together and in the same direction) can exacerbate effects on farm income variability. More generally, where risks are not perfectly correlated at farm level, total risk exposure will be less than the sum of individual risks (OECD 2009a). Thus, consideration for the relationships between risk factors allows the possible effects on farm incomes to be determined more accurately and risk management strategies to be formulated more effectively, although in practice the nature of interactions between risk sources may be highly complex. 24. It is also important to consider how risk factors affect different farmers. Some risks are highly correlated between groups of farmers (systemic risk), such as those in a particular region or country, for example droughts and floods. Price risk is particularly systemic, with fluctuations in prices affecting all farmers in a market – often a region or country. On the other hand, some risks are only weakly correlated or unrelated (idiosyncratic risk) between farmers, such as localised weather conditions (hail, frost, etc.) and personnel risks. 25. The distribution of risks among farmers has implications for the level of aggregation at which risk is measured (OECD 2009a). For systemic risks, such as price risk, a high level of aggregation may be suitable (e.g. region or country level), as all farmers will face similar levels of risk. Such aggregation is less suitable for risks that are relatively unsystematic across farmers; for example, country level averages of yield variation would hide significant variability between farms or regions within the country. 26. The implications of the relationships between risks can be seen in the example of price-yield correlations. Conceptually, if a yield shock were large and widespread causing a significant reduction in supply, then, assuming the level of demand is unchanged, the market price would be expected to rise. To some extent, this 6 change in output prices should mitigate the negative impact of the yield shock, as lower output is offset by a higher return for each unit sold. However, although this may be true at the aggregate level, it is important to consider the incidence of yield loss across farm businesses. As price shocks tend to be more systematic across farms than yield shocks, for a given yield shock some farmers will suffer a more adverse impact than others will. As a result, the compensating effect of a rise in output price is not felt equally across all farms. In fact, those businesses least affected by the yield shock benefit the most from the resulting higher prices. 27. In addition to the relationships between risks, it is also important to consider the probability distribution of outcomes associated with a given risk source. Downside risk – the probability that an outcome (for example yield or output price) will be lower or worse than expected – is considered particularly important for agriculture (OECD 2009a). For example, a “normal” season may be one where most or all crops achieve the expected yield. However, this outcome tends to be unlikely as there is a higher probability that yields would be lower than expected. Downside risk has important implications for the economic welfare of farm households, due to the negative impact on farm incomes. However, upside risk (the probability that outcomes will be better than expected) and their impacts on farmer expectations can have implications for economic efficiency (see Section 4.1). 7 3. Measuring Risk in Agriculture 28. Risks are often characterised by the probability of adverse outcomes occurring and the size of the associated losses (OECD 2008). To focus only on the unpredictable fluctuations, seasonal or cyclical fluctuations and other predictable influences must be ‘stripped out’ of data in order to get an accurate measurement of risk (OECD 2009a). An important consideration when using observed data to measure risk, which affects the measurement of almost all risks in agriculture, is that data will already reflect the effect of past and current agricultural support policies and their impacts on the risks facing agriculture. For example, although many agricultural support policies are designed to reduce price volatility and the exposure of farm businesses to risks, changes in agricultural policy can themselves introduce fluctuations in variables such as price and farm incomes, which are often examined when trying to understand the risks faced by farmers. 29. The following section focuses on measuring output price risk on the basis that volatility in output prices is cited as the biggest source of the risks faced by farm businesses. Additionally, the impact of the range of risk sources will manifest, to some extent, through variations in prices. The measures of income variability are also reviewed. 3.1 Trends in volatility in agricultural commodities prices 30. Several studies have observed that price volatility has been increasing for a number of agricultural commodities in recent years. A study by Matthews (2010)9 looked at EU price volatility over three periods relating to different CAP regimes: (i) the ‘unreformed CAP’ (1985-1992); (ii) the ‘MacSharry’ CAP (1993-2004) with coupled direct payments and WTO disciplines on border protection; and, (iii) the ‘Fischler’ CAP (2005-2010) with decoupled direct payments and further WTO disciplines on border protection. Using German prices as a proxy for EU prices, the study found that volatility in the prices of several agricultural commodities (wheat, maize, cattle, and rapeseed) has increased over time with successive CAP reforms. Table 1 shows the results from this study (Matthews, 2010). 31. As can be seen in Table 1, while volatility in world arable commodity prices over the same period did not increase by much (with the exception of sunflower), there is a marked increase in the volatility of German prices with some convergence towards world prices. This could suggest that greater volatility in EU prices may be due, to some extent, to trade liberalisation and reduction in price support interventions through CAP reforms. Matthews, A. (2010) – Paper presented at Joint AES / SFER Conference on ‘The Common Agricultural Policy Post 2013’. Available at: http://www.aes.ac.uk/_pdfs/_conferences/201_paper.pdf 9 8 Table 1 - Coefficient of variation in EU and World prices for various commodities over three periods (from Matthews 2010) Commodity Common wheat Maize Sugarbeet Cattle Rapeseed Sunflower 1983-1992 1993-2004 2005-2010 Germany World Germany World Germany World 5.56 15.09 10.49 20.53 33.53 25.99 6.35 17.73 10.98 20.94 26.01 20.23 1.08 30.17 4.38 19.49 3.08 27.68 4.53 6.93 7.89 15.25 4.85 5.15 11.82 24.14 14.09 21.19 22.13 25.34 18.36 15.91 8.89 21.08 19.97 42.73 Source: Matthews (2010) 32. The results above are consistent with those of an earlier study conducted by the Futures and Options Association (FOA),10 which assessed volatility in wheat prices for several EU countries before and after the 1992 MacSharry CAP reforms. The study finds that volatility in wheat prices increased significantly for most EU countries after 1992, with a particularly sharp increase for the UK. EU prices were also found to move more closely with world prices following the reforms. 33. Other studies provide evidence to support this trend of increasing volatility in the prices of agricultural commodities. Looking at US wheat and maize prices for the period 1980-2009, the European Commission (EC, 2009)11 found that the prices for these commodities have become more volatile, particularly since 2006. The EC cites a number of potential causes for this trend, including a positive relationship between prices of crude oil and agricultural commodities, indicating a link between the markets, and a link between low commodity stocks and high volatility (see Section 3.1.2 for a more detailed discussion of causes of increased volatility). A study for the European Dairy Association (Keane and O’Connor, 2009) has also found increased volatility in EU dairy prices for the period 20002009 compared with 1990-1999. Additionally, the FAO Food Outlook (November 2007)12 finds that volatility in world wheat and maize prices has been increasing gradually for the last decade, with a sharp increase in volatility during 2007/8. However, in its December 2009 Food Outlook13 shows that price volatility for a number of agricultural commodities was somewhat higher during the 1970s. 3.1.1 Measuring volatility in UK agriculture commodity prices 34. In this section, the paper attempts to measure volatility in the prices of UK wheat and cattle prices. Time series data for UK wheat and cattle prices is assessed and the degree of variation in price is then measured by calculating the coefficient Alizadeh, A. and Nomikos, N. (2005) – Agricultural Reforms and the Use of Market Mechanisms for Risk Management. Study commissioned by the Futures and Options Association. 10 European Commission DGAGRI (2009) – ‘Historical Price Volatility’. http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/analysis/tradepol/commodityprices/volatility_en.pdf 11 Available at: FAO Food Outlook (November 2007 – Special Feature: High prices and volatility in agricultural commodities. 12 FAO Food Outlook (December 2009) – Special Feature: The food price crisis of 2007/2008: Evidence and Implications. 13 9 of variation (CV) – a measure of the standard deviation (variability) of a set of observations relative to their mean. An alternative, and graphical, approach to assessing volatility is also presented; this measures the percentage of price observations that substantially exceed the trend in prices (measured by a moving average). Figure 1 - UK feed wheat and cattle (liveweight) prices, 1985-2010* Wheat £/tonne 190 Wheat Cattle UK FEED WHEAT AND CATTLE (LIVEWEIGHT) PRICES Average UK Weekly Market Price 180 160 170 140 150 120 130 100 110 80 60 90 40 70 20 50 1985 0 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 Source: Defra Weekly Commodity Prices (May 2010) *To May 2010 35. Figure 1 shows weekly market prices14 for UK feed wheat and cattle between 1985 and 2010. Significant variation in prices is visible over this period – some of it seasonal to reflect annual rises and falls in prices. However, the seasonal fluctuations become less evident as volatility increases in later years. Cyclical variations can also be seen in cattle prices, although these are less pronounced. The spike in cereal prices experienced in late 2007 and early 2008 can be seen clearly in prices for feed wheat. Cattle prices also rose during this period. Table 2 - Coefficients of variation for UK feed wheat and cattle (liveweight) prices over three periods 1985/6-1992* 1993-2004 UK Feed Wheat 7.55 25.18 UK Cattle (liveweight) 7.56 14.76 Note: *UK Feed Wheat – 1985-1992, UK Cattle 1986-1992 (due to data availability) 2005-2010 32.96 17.08 36. Whereas Matthews (2010) calculated coefficients of variation for three periods relating to different CAP regimes, the three periods covered in Table 2 have been chosen to provide, roughly, an equal number of observations in each period. Additionally, the price data used was not adjusted for trend, cyclical or seasonal fluctuations, so the CVs may over- or underestimate the level of unsystematic 14 Weekly market price data are averaged from daily observations, therefore this may disguise volatility in daily prices 10 variation in prices,15 and are thus not directly comparable to those in Matthews (2010).16 Table 2 shows a clear increase in the volatility of both feed wheat and cattle prices, with the increases most pronounced for the former. Assuming that predictable (e.g. seasonal) influences have been reasonably consistent over time, the results in Table 2 are consistent with findings from other studies that show increasing volatility in the prices for these commodities. Figure 2 - UK feed wheat prices two-year moving average with ±10% and ±20% bands Wheat £/tonne 190 UK FEED WHEAT PRICES Average UK Weekly Market Price Feed wheat Moving average +20% -20% +10% -10% 170 150 130 110 90 70 50 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 37. An alternative graphical presentation of the increase in price volatility is shown in Figure 2 and Figure 3. The number of price observations that vary substantially from the trend is assessed to provide a measure of the extent of price variability in each period.17 For the purposes of this exercise, moving averages are calculated (two years for wheat prices and three for cattle prices) in order to smooth out cyclical or seasonal price fluctuations. Price bands of ±10% around the moving average are then calculated and the number of price observations outwith these bands is assessed in order to provide a measure of price volatility.18 15 Where cyclical fluctuations diminish (i.e. move opposite to) the effect of non-cyclical influences on price, CV measurements are likely to underestimate unpredictable volatility. On the other hand, where cyclical fluctuations exaggerate (i.e. move in the same direction as) non-cyclical fluctuations, CV measurements are likely to overestimate the level of unpredictable volatility in prices 16 Additionally, whereas weekly price data is used in this paper, Matthews (2010) uses monthly price data, which will disguise weekly fluctuations in price. 17 This method has been adapted largely from O'Connor et al (2009) 18 An additional interpretation of these results may be that such observations are those that differ substantially from farmers expectations, if it is assumed that farmers formulate expectations based on previous prices. However, there are significant issues with this interpretation. While farmers are generally very responsive to price movements in the previous period when making production decisions, they will also make use of available information on likely future price 11 38. Figure 2 shows the two-year moving average for UK feed wheat prices and the ±10% and ±20% bands around this. Many of the price observations fall outwith the ±10% band, suggesting that prices tend to be volatile and the band might be too narrow to assess trends in volatility. However, fluctuations outwith the ±10% band do indicate where spikes and falls in prices were particularly large. The ±20% band appears to contain all seasonal fluctuations, with only particularly large peaks and troughs, such as those in 2003-2005 and 2007 onwards, falling outwith this band. Table 3 - Frequency of observations substantially outwith trend (2 year moving average), UK feed wheat prices 1988-2010 19 1988-1994 357 71% 16% 13% 29% 100% 0% 0% 0% Number of observations % Within 10% trend % above trend +10% 10% moving % below trend -10% average band % outwith trend ±10% % Within 20% trend % above trend +20% 20% moving % below trend -20% average band % outwith trend ±20% 1995-2001 355 56% 9% 35% 44% 91% 0% 9% 9% 2002-2010 427 19% 36% 44% 81% 58% 29% 13% 42% 39. Table 3 presents the number of price observations that are outwith and within the bands around the moving average shown in Figure 2. The main result in Table 3 is that the percentage of observations that fall outside the ±10% and ±20% moving average bands (i.e. those that could be deemed to indicate unexpected price movements based on historical data) increase over time. This result is consistent with the findings in Table 2, which shows rising price volatility in UK feed wheat prices. movements. One principal source of this information is futures markets, where contracts prices tend to reflect the current expectations of traders regarding future prices (see Section 5.3.3). 19 Measurements from 1988 due to two-year moving average for wheat from 1986 and three-year moving average for cattle from 1985. Dates of periods assessed also differ slightly from those in table 2 in order to achieve a more even distribution of observations in each. 12 Figure 3 - UK cattle (liveweight) prices two year moving average with ±10% and ±20% bands Cattle p/kg liveweight 190 UK CATTLE (LIVEWEIGHT) PRICES Average UK Weekly Market Price Cattle (livesweight) Moving average +10% -10% +20% -20% 170 150 130 110 90 70 50 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 Table 4 - Frequency of substantially different from trend (3-year moving average), UK cattle prices 1988-2010 Number of observations % Within 10% trend % above trend +10n% % below trend -10% % outwith trend ±10% % Within 20% trend % above trend +20% % below trend -20% % outwith trend ±20% 1988-1994 366 72% 28% 0% 28% 95% 5% 0% 5% 1995-2001 321 59% 0% 41% 41% 94% 0% 6% 6% 2002-2010 427 69% 31% 0% 31% 85% 15% 0% 15% 40. Figure 3 and Table 4 present a similar analysis for UK cattle prices. Increases in price volatility are also evident, although increases are more pronounced and consistent for observations outwith the 20% band (i.e. there has been a consistent increase in observations that substantially differ from the trend). Compared to wheat, there are also fewer observations falling outwith the bands around moving averages, which is consistent with the CV measurements in Table 2. 3.1.2 Reasons for increased price volatility in agricultural commodities 41. Trade liberalisation and the removal of price support policies under successive CAP reforms have commonly been cited among the causes of increased volatility in EU agricultural commodity prices, as the European market has become more exposed to shifts in world markets. Several other factors have also been cited to explain the increased volatility in agricultural commodity prices. These include: (i) increased linkages between agricultural commodity markets and energy markets; (ii) relatively low public and private stocks of agricultural commodities; and (iii) activities of investors in futures markets. 13 (i) Agricultural commodity markets are becoming more strongly linked to energy markets 42. Energy markets influence prices of agricultural commodities in two main ways (Defra 2008).20 First, volatility in crude oil prices contributes indirectly through input prices, particularly fuel, synthetic fertilisers and pesticides – all derived from crude oil. The upward trend in real crude oil prices over time and increased mechanisation means that these inputs account for a greater proportion of total costs of agricultural production, particularly for the relatively intensive sectors. Both the EC (2009) and World Bank (2010)21 provide evidence of a relatively strong positive correlation between crude oil and agricultural commodity prices. An example of this relationship is the way high cereal prices in 2007-8 coincided with historically high crude oil prices. 43. Second, volatility in energy markets also affects agricultural commodity prices directly through increased demand for biofuel feedstocks when mineral oil prices are high. While it is not yet clear whether mineral fuel prices have ever risen to levels where liquid biofuels relying on agricultural commodities become competitive and fluctuations in crude oil prices affect demand for biofuels beyond levels required to meet mandated blending requirements, the World Bank (2009) suggests this might be the case for maize. Notably, there is evidence that for oil prices above US$50 per barrel, maize prices tend to move closely with oil prices. 44. Mandates for biofuels in fuel mixtures based on volume (such as in the EU) may also exacerbate price volatility in agricultural markets by reducing the sensitivity of demand to price changes. Given the mandate sets a floor below which quantity demanded cannot fall, short-term fluctuations in supply (e.g. due to a yield shock) require large changes in price in order to bring demand and supply in balance (Matthews 2010). The FAO (2009) argues that increases in mandates, particularly in the USA, contributed to the running down of global grain stocks, which has been cited as part of the cause of the 2007-8 commodity price spikes (see below). (ii) Relatively low public and private stocks of agricultural commodities 45. The management of stocks of agricultural commodities can stabilise market prices by building up stocks when supply is relatively high – protecting prices from falling, and selling back onto the market when there is a shortfall in supply – relieving any upward pressures on prices. Currently, global stocks of wheat and maize relative to demand (stock-to-use ratio) are significantly lower than levels in the 1980s, although the bulk of declines occurred in the early 90s (FAO 2009). The European Commission (EC 2009) provides some evidence of an inverse relationship between stock levels and volatility in US wheat prices over the past three decades; i.e.-low stock levels have generally coincided with higher levels of Defra (2008) – The Impact of Biofuels on Commodity Prices. Available http://www.defra.gov.uk/evidence/series/documents/impact-biofuels-commodities.pdf 20 Baffes, J. and Haniotis, T (2010) – Placing the 2006/08 Commodity Price Boom into Perspective. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5371. 21 14 at: price volatility. FAO (2009) and Defra (2010) cite low stocks as the key factor in rising price volatility in 2007/8, caused by high grain demand from China and India, in addition to rising global demand for feedstocks for biofuels. This would have left commodity markets more vulnerable to supply-shocks, such as drought in Australia, which significantly affected wheat supplies. However, the World Bank (2010) suggests that rising grain demand from developing countries could not have been a significant cause of the price spike, citing data showing the rate of growth in world grain demand slowed during the past decade. In addition, the greatest price rises were in wheat and rice, for which demand was relatively stagnant during past decade. (iii) Investor activity in futures markets 46. Futures markets allow farmers to hedge against price risk by fixing prices in advance of the actual delivery of commodities (see Section 5.3.1 for full discussion of futures markets). The activity of investors in futures markets is important in ensuring an adequate supply of funds to agricultural markets and increases the number of buyers and sellers, which is essential for markets to function effectively. Investors use commodity futures to diversify their portfolio of financial assets as part of their risk management strategies. Some investors also seek to gain in futures markets by ‘betting’ on the direction of movement in the value of futures contracts or options in order to earn a profit. Under certain conditions, such activity (or ‘speculative trading’) may create false trends and drive up futures prices (EC 2009). The potential gains from investor trading are greater in markets were price fluctuations are wider and less predictable. Therefore, the increased volatility in agricultural markets may be both a result of, and driver for, speculative activity in futures markets. 47. However, the evidence is mixed on whether speculative trading contributed significantly to price volatility. The OECD (2010)22 finds no relationship between the number of trades in index and swap funds with the increase in price volatility during the 2007/8 spike (or in other periods). Additionally, a Defra/HM Treasury (2010)23 report finds that the number of contracts on index funds was relatively stable between 2006 and 2008, which is contrary to the argument that greater levels of trading resulted in the 2007/8 price spike.24 The FAO Food Outlook (December 2009) asserts that low stock levels were the cause of the price spike, and that the fall in stock levels was not consistent with high prices caused by speculative trading.25 The World Bank (2010), however, suggests that while the Irwin, S. H. and D. R. Sanders (2010), “The Impact of Index and Swap Funds on Commodity Futures Markets: Preliminary Results”, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Working Papers, No. 27, OECD Publishing. doi: 10.1787/5kmd40wl1t5f-en 22 Defra (2010) – The 2007/08 Agricultural Price Spikes: Causes and Policy Implications. Annex 6: Speculation and the food price spikes of 2007/8. 23 24 During this period, the total value of contracts rose. However, the report views this as a symptom of high futures prices (as higher prices increase the value of contracts) rather than a cause. 25 An increase in prices due to speculative trading would be expected to increase stocks, as high prices reduce demand while no physical trade of commodities takes place through speculative trades. 15 fundamentals of demand and supply will be the main drivers for commodity markets in the long term, speculative activity does appear to affect prices in the short-term and can amplify price cycles (including variation caused by the other factors discussed here). 48. What is not clear from the literature is whether the trend for greater volatility is expected to persist. Low commodity stocks are a sign of sustained increases in demand relative to supply. Stocks for some commodities have recently increased significantly, as supply expands in response to higher prices. Moreover, while evidence suggests that reforms to the EU CAP have so far contributed to higher volatility in EU prices, more general reform of agricultural support policies and the removal of trade barriers may in the long-run have a dampening effect on volatility in world markets, by allowing countries more freedom to import produce when supply is low and export when supply is high. 3.2 Income variability 49. If the policy concern about risks in agriculture is the impact on the economic welfare of those earning income from agriculture, then an assessment of farm income variability is also important.26 Volatility in farm incomes can adversely affect economic welfare, particularly where credit markets are imperfect and opportunities to borrow to smooth consumption are limited. Additionally, unpredictable variations in farm income, by affecting farm liquidity, can reduce the ability of farm businesses to invest in order to improve productivity and profitability, and consequently affect the future economic welfare of those working in agriculture. 50. Farm incomes tend to vary significantly over time due mainly to price and yield fluctuations, changes in variable costs, and changes in the value of agricultural support payments - particularly if payments are subject to exchange rate movements (e.g. direct payments to Scottish farmers under the CAP). The degree to which individual risk sources (described in Section 2.2) manifest in variations in income depends on the relationships between sources of risk, as discussed in Section 2.3, and the effect of public and private risk management strategies in reducing and mitigating risks. Farm incomes also vary, not only with time, but also across businesses, even for those of the same type and size. As a result, measuring volatility of aggregated farm income can hide significant variations at the individual farm level. 51. Several studies have assessed variability in incomes at the farm level. Vrolijk et al (2009)27, using data from the Farm Accounts Data Network (FADN), conducted a detailed assessment of income variability at farm-level for different farm types 26 Strictly, the entire farm household income should be assessed, including on- and off-farm incomes, in order to deduce impacts on farm household economic welfare (Phimister et al 2004). However, there is often insufficient data on off-farm incomes to include in analyses. Vrolijk et al (2009) – Volatility of incomes, prices and yields in the European Union. Report 2009-005, LEI Wageningen UR, The Hague. 27 16 across EU countries. Some of the main results from this study are summarised below. Table 5 - Volatility in farm incomes EU-15 (1996-2004) Type of farming Field crops Horticulture Wine Other permanent crops Dairy Grazing livestock Intensive livestock* Mixed Coefficient of variation of family farm income 31 37 33 33 28 31 53 29 Source: Vrolijk et al (2009) * Mostly pigs and poultry. 52. Table 5 shows the coefficient of variation (CV) in farm incomes at the farm level for different farm types across EU-15 countries. It is clear that the variations are considerably higher in intensive livestock farms (mainly pigs and poultry), which may be due, at least in part, to the much lower level of market support for these enterprises. The results also reveal substantial variation between countries. Table 6 - Index of income volatility for different farm types by selected EU countries 1996-2004 (index = 100 equals CV = 31.4) Field Crops Horticulture Belgium 87 101 Denmark 109 158 France 113 126 Germany 134 130 Ireland 82 Italy 78 82 Netherlands 217 174 Portugal 116 111 Spain 97 145 Sweden 186 UK 137 89 Source: Vrolijk et al (2009) Other permanent crops 145 177 182 144 85 146 184 122 98 Dairy 61 102 85 101 73 75 113 112 99 177 109 Grazing livestock 81 99 121 121 75 291 112 90 140 171 Intensive livestock 193 264 179 191 200 85 475 169 153 231 173 Mixed 94 118 96 158 84 61 216 126 76 148 131 53. Table 6 shows relative (indexed) income volatility for different farm types across EU-15 countries. Although there is considerable variability between countries, the highest volatility in farm incomes is evident among the North West EU Member States, which the authors attribute to the financial structure of farms in these countries. The difference in volatility across countries and farm types is also explained by differences in the risk environment and the nature of agricultural systems. The general high variability in incomes for intensive livestock farms can be seen in Table 6. 54. In common with output prices, while variation in farm incomes is important, the level of down-side risk in farm incomes – that is, the probability that incomes will be lower than expected, is often more important from an economic welfare and 17 investment perspective. If low income in one year is offset by high income in the next, then farm households are more able to ‘smooth’ their income and minimise impacts on welfare. Conversely, persistently low incomes over extended periods can pose severe liquidity constraints and ultimately affect the economic viability of the farm business. However, persistently low incomes can also indicate structural issues rather than problems of volatility per se. 55. A study by Phimister et al (2004)28 assesses the dynamics of farm incomes in Scottish agriculture between 1988 and 2000. The study uses FADN data to assess the length of time spent by farms in ‘low income’ groups (a relative measure defined by bottom fifth of farm business incomes), and the degree of mobility of farms between income groups. The study found that there was a high degree of mobility in relative income of farms, with most farms spending only a short period in the ‘low-income’ group. If credit markets function efficiently, these farms will be able to smooth income through borrowing and therefore minimise welfare impacts associated with income volatility. However, a significant number of farms experienced repeated spells in the ‘low income’ group, suggesting that low-income risk is an important issue for Scottish farm businesses. Phimister, E., Roberts, D. and Gilbert, A. (2004) – The Dynamics of Farm Incomes: Panel data analysis using the Farm Accounts Survey. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 55, 2, pp197-220. 28 18 4. Effect of Risk on Farm Production and Investment Choices 56. The presence of risks in agriculture influences farm production and investment choices in a number of ways, including (a) the choices farmers make for the specific mix of commodities they produce and inputs used to produce these commodities; (b) strategies to manage and cope with risk; and (c) dynamic or investment impacts when the resolution of uncertainty results in a negative impact on farm incomes. 57. The nature of the first two of these impacts on farm businesses will depend principally on the attitude of farmers towards risk. In general, farmers may be riskaverse (i.e. they dislike riskier outcomes), risk loving (prefer riskier outcomes) or risk neutral. However, studies within the agricultural sector have found that farmers tend to be averse to risk (OECD 2008); preferring outcomes that are more certain, although larger farms are relatively less risk-averse.29 4.1 Effects on production 58. Of the risk sources discussed in Section 2, price and yield risk tend to influence farm production decisions most directly. In the absence of instruments for managing risks, economic analysis of production under uncertainty often suggests that farmers will base their choices on some “expected outcome” (e.g. expected yield or price – a weighted average of the possible outcomes taking into account the probabilities of different outcomes being realised). Risk-averse producers will tend to prefer “low-risk and low-return” outcomes at the expense of higher payoffs that are more uncertain. In practice, this means that producers may choose low-risk production technologies and low risk crops at the expense of innovation and riskier choices that potentially offer higher returns. This will generally lead to a lower average income and lower levels of economic efficiency, as resources may not directed towards the most profitable farm enterprises. 59. This may be reflected in a reluctance of farmers to adopt new production techniques and technologies that may improve farm efficiency and profitability but result in some (perceived) increase in the variability of returns. Where support policies reduce income variability, either through direct payments or indirectly through, for example - market price support, farmers may be more willing to undertake riskier activities, effectively maintaining the riskiness of their portfolio (Vrolijk et al 2009).30 60. It is important to highlight here that it is not only the risk that output prices will be lower than expected (‘downside’ risk) that affects economic efficiency. Higher than expected prices (‘upside’ risk) has implications for economic efficiency, as a profit-maximising farmer would choose to produce more of a particular commodity Agricultural support policies can affect farmers’ attitudes to risk. See Section 5.2 for further discussion. 29 Vrolijk et al (2009) – Volatility of incomes, prices and yields in the European Union. Report 2009-005, LEI Wageningen UR, The Hague. 30 19 at a higher price (assuming input costs and prices of other commodities are unchanged), reallocating resources towards the more profitable enterprise. 4.2 On-farm risk management strategies and efficiency 61. There are several institutional mechanisms for reducing or managing risks (see Section 5.2), however, agricultural producers may implement on-farm strategies to manage risk. One such approach is the diversification of farm business income by redirecting investment and labour time away from the farm towards non-farm activities, especially those generating income not strongly correlated with on-farm business income. To the extent that such diversification will compete for resources (e.g. labour time and capital) with agricultural production, it may reduce agricultural production or capacity. 62. Diversification can also occur at farm business level. In this case rather than specialising in enterprises that gives the highest rate of return, the farm business is diversified to include other enterprises where returns are not positively correlated or that are less risky. However, this will result in a lower average income and lower economic efficiency, as resources are not directed towards the most profitable farm enterprises. 63. In the face of increasing trade liberalisation, farmers may experience conflicting pressures arising from the need to specialise activities in order to exploit production efficiencies and maintain competitiveness, while ensuring that risk exposure is minimised through on- and off-farm diversification. However, where risks can be managed efficiently and effectively through market-based risk management (see Section 5.4), businesses will be more able to specialise while mitigating the level of risk faced. 4.3 Impacts on investment 64. While there are several risk management options available to farmers, these often only provide partial protection for potential losses. Where the remaining risk exposure causes returns and farm income to vary, and this variation is uncertain, it can make it difficult for farm businesses to plan long-term investment. For example, volatility in output prices can make it more difficult for farmers to identify trends in prices, which is often a basis for making long-term investment decisions. In the presence of such volatility, the level of investment by risk averse producers is likely to be lower than in a risk free environment, which in turn has negative impacts on long-term productive capacity in agriculture. 65. In addition, where unexpected shocks result in significant income losses, this can constrain future farm investments. This is largely a product of inefficient credit markets; otherwise, farm businesses should be able to borrow to smooth their income for any fluctuations. 66. The impacts described above provide a conceptual discussion of how levels of input use, output and investment in agriculture may fall below optimal levels in a production environment characterised by risk or uncertainty. In reality, farmers’ levels of risk exposure and responses to risk vary with the policy environment and this is discussed in the following sections. 20 5. Dealing with Risks – Risk Management Tools and Strategies in Agriculture 67. There is a broad range of tools that can be employed in agriculture to manage risks. The aim of this section is to outline the main risk management tools and strategies, including policies that may be implemented by government, mechanisms provided by the market, and actions that may be undertaken privately on-farm to reduce and cope with risks. Due to a lack of data across a sufficient number of risk management strategies, this section does not assess the evidence on the success or otherwise of such strategies. 68. Tools for managing risks in agriculture can be split into those that reduce or mitigate risk or those for coping with risks (OECD 2009a). First, risk reducing strategies are generally preventative measures aimed at reducing overall risk exposure e.g. vaccination of livestock to promote herd immunity to disease. Second, risk-mitigating strategies allow farmers to lessen the potential effect of remaining risks, such as insurance against disease outbreaks. Finally, risk coping strategies involve measures to assist in dealing with the impacts of risk once an adverse event has occurred e.g. disaster relief payments in the event of a disease outbreak. Table 7 sets out the range of risk management tools. Table 7 – Summary of risk management tools in agriculture Risk Reduction Farm / household / community Market Technological Training on choice risk management Risk Mitigation Diversification in production Crop sharing Risk Coping Borrowing from neighbours / family Intracommunity charity Government Macro policies Disaster prevention (flood control…) Prevention of diseases Futures Tax system income /options smoothing Insurance Counter-cyclical Vertical Programme Integration Border and other Production/mar measures in the case of ket contract contagious disease Spread sales outbreak Diversified Market-price support finance (intervention buying, buffer Off-farm work stocks) Selling Disaster relief financial assets Social assistance Saving / All agricultural support borrowing programs Off-farm income Source: adapted from OECD (2009a) 69. As discussed in Section 5.2, interventions by government can alter the incentives for farmers to act privately to manage risk. Conversely, private actions taken by farmers, using a combination of farm-level and market-based means to manage risk, reduce the need for publically provided risk management support. Indeed, 21 there will be a considerable level of interaction between most strategies and tools to manage risk. For this reason, the OECD (2009a) recognises the importance of taking a holistic approach when assessing risk management tools in agriculture. Such an approach needs to consider the whole risk landscape faced by farmers and the impact of current agriculture policy interventions on farmers’ exposure and responses to risk when formulating risk management strategies. 5.1 Rationale for management government intervention in agricultural risk 70. Government intervention in markets can incur costs and create economic distortions. Thus, any interventions to manage risks in agriculture must be justified with a clear rationale, with any costs outweighed by benefits or returns to intervention. Ideally, governments should intervene only when the market has ‘failed’ (or is expected to fail) to provide a satisfactory outcome, and this outcome can be improved by government policy. The HM Treasury Green Book 31 sets out the two main grounds for policy intervention by government: i. to address inefficiencies in the operation of markets and institutions; or, ii. on equity or distributional grounds. 71. With this in mind, the relevant question in the context of managing agricultural risk is whether there is any efficiency or distributional issues arising from private risk markets, i.e. is there a market failure. Inefficiencies can arise in agricultural risk markets from three sources: (i) imperfect (or costly) information; (ii) the existence of ‘externalities’; or (iii) where insufficient competition in agricultural risk markets give rise to market power for providers of risk management instruments (e.g. insurers). (i) Information costs 72. Markets for risk management services in agriculture require information on the magnitude and probability of losses faced by farm businesses in order to function efficiently (Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al. 2009). The highly unpredictable and diverse nature of risks in agriculture means this information is often unknown or very costly to acquire, both for farmers and for providers of risk management services. The result is that the coverage of information is incomplete and unequal between participants in risk markets (e.g. farmers and insurance companies). In agriculture, problems of incomplete or asymmetric information tend to be greater in yield risk than price risk as farmers have more control over the former. Asymmetric information can lead to some farmers being ‘priced out’ of markets for risk management services, as providers cannot distinguish between high and low risk businesses and so set premiums based on average risk, making protection (such as insurance) prohibitively expensive for farmers who are less ‘risky’ than average. Additionally, informational problems provide scope for ‘moral hazard’, as farmers may take fewer measures to reduce risk in the knowledge HM Treasury (2003) – The Green Book: Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government. Available at: http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/data_greenbook_index.htm 31 22 that they will receive compensation, such as an insurance payout, in the event of an adverse outcome. Given the costs of acquiring and processing a suitable level of information are likely to be particularly prohibitive or burdensome for smaller farms, it also gives rise to distributional or equity issues. 73. Thus, regarding information costs, there may be a direct role for government to intervene to facilitate research to generate missing information (e.g. into weather patterns, disease prevalence to quantify risk) (OECD 2009a). Government can also take steps to reduce the costs of sharing information between, for example, farmers and insurance companies, in order to overcome problems of asymmetric information. (ii) Externalities 74. In economic terms, an externality exists when there is some cost or benefit that accrues to an outside party from a market transaction or decision that is not fully factored into market prices (and hence the decision). A relevant example for agriculture is that of animal and plant disease. In these cases, the provision of insurance will require the insurer to obtain information to inform the level of risk that an individual business applying for insurance may suffer a loss due to plant or animal disease. However, for any single business, the risk of a loss will depend not only on the level of investment in bio-security by that business, but also in the bio-security of neighbouring farms. Thus, to be able to determine the premium, the insurer needs information beyond that of the applicant, which can be costly to obtain. In this case, externalities in agriculture can exacerbate information problems, meaning the provision of insurance for potential losses due to animal and plant diseases is most likely to remain incomplete – provided at sub-optimal levels or not provided at all. (iii) Market power 75. Where a market is characterised by very few suppliers, as is the case in many markets for agricultural insurance, the suppliers will tend to have some power to influence market prices and ultimately the ability to generate economic rent or “abnormal profits”. Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al. (2009) and Garrido and Bielza (2009) suggest there is, indeed, a lack of competition in EU agricultural insurance markets. The result is that even subsidies on insurance premiums do not always benefit farmers, as suppliers of agricultural insurance are able to capture such subsidies as economic rent. In such cases, Government may have a role in improving market competition by, for example, removing barriers to entry to increase competition in the insurance market. (iv) Distributional concerns 76. In addition to economic efficiency grounds, government intervention may be justified by concerns over the distribution of market outcomes. It is possible to argue that agricultural enterprises are less able manage risk privately than operators in other industries due to the relatively small size of many farm businesses, and the relatively low profit margins on which they operate (Matthews 2010). Additionally, risk exposure in agriculture may be high relative to other industries, due to the greater uncertainty on the wide range of factors on 23 which agricultural businesses depend. As discussed in Section 2.2.1, agricultural output prices are particularly volatile due to the unresponsive nature of demand for food products to price changes and to the presence of other risk sources, such as weather and disease. The ability to cope with and manage risk also differs within agriculture and between agricultural businesses, due to the type of enterprises, size of business and other factors. 77. Thus, there may be justification for intervention by government on the basis that farm businesses and households are more vulnerable to some risks than those that draw their income from other sectors. This is particularly important if existing social welfare arrangements do not provide them with a sufficient safety net. 78. Any benefits from intervention by government on the above grounds must be weighed against the potential costs or market distortions. Notably, government interventions in agricultural risk markets can ‘crowd-out’ market solutions and reduce the incentives for farmers to manage risk privately. Furthermore, as highlighted in Section 2, policy intervention can itself be a source of risk if provision changes frequently or unexpectedly. 5.2 Risk management related policies in agriculture 79. Table 7 sets out the range of policies that can be implemented by government to reduce the agricultural industry’s exposure to risk and to assist farmers to cope with adverse outcomes. While all agricultural policies affect the risk environment faced by farmers and their responses to risk, certain policies can be seen as more targeted at reducing or mitigating risk or helping farmers cope with adverse outcomes. Within the EU, the CAP is the main driver for agricultural policy and among its objectives is the stabilisation of agricultural markets. 5.2.1 Price stabilisation policies 80. There is a range of policy instruments that have traditionally been used at country or regional levels to reduce the exposure of the agricultural industry to market or price risks. Broadly, these policies are targeted at addressing problems associated with output price volatility. A broad list of these policies is provided below. Intervention purchasing & public storage – reduces price fluctuations in domestic markets by building up public stocks when supply is relatively high to stop prices from falling to very low levels, and selling stocks when supply is relatively low to prevent prices rising to very high levels. Export subsidies – stabilises domestic prices by facilitating exports of excess domestic supply, hence preventing domestic prices from falling. Effectively, subsidies enable price variability in domestic markets to be exported onto world markets. Import tariffs – sufficiently high tariffs can protect producers from variability in world prices by limiting imports. However, this can be at the expense of higher prices and reduced choice for domestic consumers. 24 81. In the EU, direct price support was the main means of supporting farmers up until the early 1990s. It comprised largely of a combination of intervention purchasing, variable import levies and export subsidies. Successive reforms have reduced the level of market price support in the EU, with a reorientation of support towards direct payments, replacement of variable import levies with fixed import tariffs, and a reduction in export subsidies. However, market price support (MPS) for some cereals, dairy products, sugar and fruits and vegetables still accounts for a substantial share of support provided under the CAP. 82. In the USA, considerable market price support is provided for dairy and sugar. The dairy price support programme aims to maintain market prices at the legislated support level through intervention purchasing of dairy products (including butter, cheese and dried milk) from dairy processors. Although support is aimed at dairy processors, the scheme has a stabilising effect on the price that farmers receive. The U.S. Sugar Programme also uses price supports mechanisms, domestic marketing allotments and tariff-rate quotas to keep USA sugar prices above world market levels. Market price support for other commodities is provided indirectly through a system of marketing loans, discussed in 5.3.2, in addition to some import tariffs and quotas. 83. In Canada, price support is provided primarily for milk, poultry and eggs, through a combination of import tariffs and production quotas designed to balance demand and supply. 84. In addition to stabilising markets, market price support policies that maintain domestic prices artificially above world prices also provide transfers to farmers, the burden of which is borne by taxpayers (when public budgets are used to purchase stocks or subsidise exports) and consumers (through higher prices). In fact, in some instances the transfers and their impacts on farm income can be the main driver for price support policies. However, such policies reduce the incentive for farmers to use more effective and efficient measures in private risk markets to manage price risk. 5.2.2 Supporting “on-farm” actions to reduce risk exposure 85. In a range of countries, policies also exist to assist the agricultural industries to manage at farm-level a range of risk factors affecting farming. These measures are different from the price stabilisation policies in Section 5.2.1 in that while they may be available to all farmers in a country or region as a matter of policy, it is often up to agricultural businesses to choose when they want to use them to manage risks. Consequently, the outcomes of these measures reflect, to some extent, the risk perception of farmers. Some of these policies are listed below. Subsidising private storage – assists the agricultural industry in dealing with short-term problems of over-supply by storing excess produce to prevent prices from falling to levels that are too low and spreading sales over time. Support is provided to meet the costs of storage, which can be substantial for perishable produce. Market withdrawals – provides compensation to farmers for the withdrawal of produce from the market. Like subsidies on private storage, it is intended 25 to deal with short term problems of oversupply, especially where it is not feasible to store the excess supply at reasonable costs – e.g. in the case of perishable fruit and vegetables. The withdrawn produce is either destroyed or distributed for free in a way that should not affect market demand. Marketing Loans – allow farmers to keep their crops when prices are low by enabling them to borrow an amount equal to the value of the crop, valued at a given loan rate. The loan provides a cash flow that allows farm businesses to hold onto produce when prices are too low without putting pressure on business finances. Crops effectively act as collateral on the loan until such a time when they are sold and the loan is repaid. In addition to reducing price risk, in the USA where marketing loans have been used, they also provide income support to farm businesses by allowing a repayment lower than the actual loan rate if market prices do not recover above the loan rate in a crop year. Similar to Marketing Loans, Loan Deficiency Payments (LDPs) allow farm businesses to receive the same benefits as through marketing loans when prices are lower than commodity loan rates, without the need to take out a loan and subsequently repay it. Support to production techniques – provides subsidies to reduce the costs to farmers of adopting or investing in technical measures on-farm that would enable them to manage risks. Technical assistance and extension – Advisory services to farmers to provide information and encourage uptake of production and marketing techniques to reduce risk exposure. 86. Marketing Loans and LDPs as used in the USA can improve the stability of farm incomes and stabilise market prices by reducing supply when prices are low. Further, this reduces the need for public intervention purchasing to support market prices, if this is a policy goal. The improved stability of farm incomes may also make it easier for farm businesses to plan investment decisions. Canada also operates a form of Marketing Loans through the Advance Payments Program – providing loan guarantees to farm businesses in order that they can borrow to improve their cash flow if they need to hold onto their stock. Advances are provided through producer organisations, up to a limit of $400,000, with the first $100,000 interest free. Coverage includes livestock and a range of crops and producers have up to 18 months to repay advances. 5.2.3 Ex ante measures to assist farmers to mitigate/cope with risk 87. Ex ante risk mitigating and coping measures include the range of instruments that governments can put in place in order to assist farmers in dealing with adverse outcomes before these are actually realised. Some of the commonly cited ex ante risk mitigating and coping measures include the following: Countercyclical payments 88. Typically, countercyclical payments protect farmers against fluctuations in price or income, with payments triggered if prices or incomes fall below a given level. In the USA, schemes for countercyclical payments have been in place since 2003 26 but the payments account for a relatively small proportion of total farm support (around US$4bn in 2006, compared to US$31bn total US farm support). The USA scheme provides protection against crop price risk and makes payments to producers with historic programme payment acres32 (or ‘base acres’) – with the result that farmers that did not grow any eligible crops in the reference year cannot receive payments. 89. The USA countercyclical payment scheme reduces the degree of price risk faced by farmers as it provides support to counteract factors having negative impacts on farm market receipts. However, the effectiveness of the scheme in maintaining farm revenues is in some cases limited. First, the effectiveness of countercyclical payments depends on the correlation between the production of the farm in the year paid and production in the reference year. For example, where a farm only grew wheat in the reference year has switched entirely to soybean production; it will not be entirely protected against movements in soybean prices unless soybean and wheat prices move together. Second, the scheme protects only against price risk and does not account for impacts on farm revenue caused by low crop yield. 90. An alternative to the standard USA countercyclical scheme is the Average Crop Revenue Election Scheme (ACRE), which is an area-based crop-revenue guarantee scheme designed to address some of the problems associated with countercyclical payments. The scheme is voluntary and provides farm businesses with protection against both price and yield risk by making payments when farm revenues fall below a minimum level, although farmers must accept reductions in payments made through other schemes. 91. ACRE payments are only made when two conditions are satisfied: if (a) a farm’s revenue is below its ACRE revenue guarantee, and (b) the state’s actual revenue is below the state revenue guarantee. This provides a safeguard against perverse incentives that revenue guarantees can introduce, as a farm with low revenues will only receive a payout if the revenues across the state as a whole are below the guaranteed level, meaning that farms that do not take adequate on-farm risk management are not rewarded. 92. In Canada, countercyclical payments are made through the AgriStability scheme, which is part of a wider Business Risk Management Suite.33 The scheme provides support for larger falls in income. Farmers supply a reference margin based on an average from the last 5 years and payments are triggered if current margins fall below 85% of the reference. As the scheme is based upon margins, it provides coverage of output and input price risk in addition to yield risk. 93. Subsidies to reduce the cost of premiums – the provision of direct subsidies on insurance premiums or support for reinsurance costs to reduce the cost to 32 Base acres are defined as the land on farm that was eligible to receive payments in 2002, along with the area planted to other commodities now covered y support. It refers to total cropland on a farm and not individual land parcels. 33 The suite is comprised of the following: AgriInvest, AgriStability, AgriRecovery, AgriInsurance, and the Advanced Payments Programme. 27 farmers of getting private insurance can increase provision and coverage of insurance in agriculture. In the EU, a number of Member States provide subsidies on insurance premiums varying degrees (see Section 5.3.1). The USA Department of Agriculture (USDA) provides significant subsidies to reduce the cost of premiums for agricultural insurance, which is provided by private companies under the supervision of the USDA Risk Management Agency (RMA). 94. Public insurance – While subsidised agricultural insurance products in most countries are provided by private sector, in some countries, e.g. Greece, Cyprus and Canada, they are publically provided. Under these systems, farmers must take a mandated level of insurance with the Government, which meets some of the costs associated with these products. See Section 5.3.1 for further discussion. 95. Income tax smoothing mechanisms – Allow taxable income to be spread over a number of years or tax to be paid when the farmer is most able (e.g. in high income years) in order to smooth disposable income for those working in agriculture. These are commonly used in other OECD countries including Australia, Canada, New Zealand and the USA. For example, income tax smoothing is provided for Australian farmers through two systems. The Income Tax Averaging Scheme allows farmers to be taxed at their average rate of income over a rolling five-year period. The Farm Management Deposit Scheme allows farmers to reduce their tax liabilities by depositing pre-tax income in good years to be drawn as income in low-income years, with a cap on deposits of AU$400,000. In March 2010, there were 35,084 farmers in the scheme with total holdings of AU$2.4billion. In the EU, arrangements for income tax smoothing mechanisms are at Member State level. 96. Support to diversification of activities – assists farm businesses (through information, training and financial support) to diversify out of agriculture or specific enterprises in order that they can have other sources of income not correlated with traditional farming activities. 5.2.4 Ex post measures 97. Unlike ex ante measures, which are put in place or selected by farm businesses before the uncertainty associated with agricultural production is resolved, ex post measures tend to be reactionary – only deployed to address adverse outcomes after they have already occurred. Below is a range of ex post measures typically deployed across the EU and other OECD countries. 98. Disaster relief and ad-hoc payments – provided to farmers on an emergency basis to fully- or partially compensate losses in output or income. They are essentially countercyclical in nature as payments are made when business conditions are poor, which may be due to many causes, such as animal disease, a natural disaster, etc. Such ad hoc payments are common in the EU, where they are financed from national budgets outside the CAP, although they often have to comply with State Aid rules. Examples in the UK include payments to farmers following the 2001 and 2007 foot and mouth disease (FMD) outbreak. 28 99. In the USA, the Non-insured Crop Disaster Assistance Program (NAP) provides disaster support payments for crops that cannot be covered through insurance markets. Support for other agricultural sectors, such as livestock, is largely through emergency payments, e.g. in the event of natural disasters or difficult economic conditions (low commodity prices, condemnation of milk or animals, bankruptcy etc). In Canada, the AgriRecovery scheme provides disaster relief to fill the gaps not covered by other programmes in the Business Risk Management Suite. Because such payments are ad hoc, there is always some uncertainty as to whether and how they will be paid, thus they tend to have their own risks. To address this problem, both the USA and Canadian schemes have formal processes to determine when payments are triggered, which improves the speed at which payments can be made. 100. The Australian government also provides ad hoc support payments to assist farm businesses incurring yield losses because of droughts – a significant risk factor in Australia. New Zealand also operates an adverse recovery programme but this provides support only in very exceptional circumstances. 101. While ad-hoc payments are designed to assist farmers in coping with an adverse event, they can themselves be a source of uncertainty, as farmers often do not know their level in advance. In addition, ad hoc support can reduce the incentives for farmers to act proactively to reduce or mitigate risk if they believe they can rely on ex post payments. 5.2.5 Direct payments 102. Direct payments to farmers form a significant part of agricultural support in the EU and USA. In Scotland, direct payments under the CAP are made through the Single Farm Payment (SFP) and Less Favoured Area Support Scheme (LFASS). One of the most important changes made as part of 2003 CAP reforms was the decoupling of direct payments from production for most commodities in order to reduce the market-distorting effects of farm payments and encourage farmers to be more responsive to market forces. 103. The primary aim of these payments is to provide income support to farmers. In the EU, farmers are also required to meet requirements on the environmental and agricultural condition of land in order to receive payments. As discussed in Section 3.2, prices for agricultural commodities in the EU have become more volatile with successive CAP reforms, which has led to some (including the OECD) to assert that CAP reform would contribute to greater income volatility (Anton & Giner 2005)34. However, according to the European Commission,35 decoupled direct payments play an income stabilising role, as they provide a fixed stream of income to farm businesses. This is supported by a study by Cafiero et Anton, J. and Giner, C. (2005) – Can Risk Reducing Policies Reduce Farmer's Risk and Improve Their Welfare? Paper prepared for presentation at the 11th Congress of the EAAE (European Association of Agricultural Economists), Copenhagen, Denmark, 24-27 August 2005. 34 European Commission (2005) – Communication on Risk and Crisis Management in Agriculture, COM (2005) 74, Brussels. 35 29 al (2007)36 on risk management under the post-2003 CAP, which finds that the fixed stream of income provided by direct payments can increase the stability of farm incomes even if farm revenues from the market have become more volatile. 104. While this suggests that decoupled payments under the EU CAP can increase the stability of farm incomes, they have several weaknesses as an income stabilisation tool. Firstly, payments are fixed based on either the historic reference period or area, and therefore do not vary to provide additional support to farmers in years of low income; essentially, the payments are not countercyclical (Matthews 2010). Secondly, as the distribution of direct payments is often determined by the size of the farm business (measured by hectares of land or intensity of production), the greatest beneficiaries in absolute terms tend to be larger businesses that are most likely to be able to implement private strategies to manage risk and volatility in income. In the context of Scottish or, more widely, UK agriculture, direct payments represent additional exchange rate risk for farmers, as payments are made in Euros and converted to Pound Sterling at a rate set by the European Central Bank. 105. Despite these limitations, there are some additional risk-related effects of direct payments such as the SFP. The fixed and relatively guaranteed income stream provided by direct payments (depending upon compliance with requirements for good agricultural and environmental condition of land) may improve the access of farm businesses to credit markets, increasing the ability of farmers to borrow to aid cash flow in difficult times. 106. Several studies have demonstrated that agricultural support policies designed to support or stabilise incomes, such as the SFP, significantly affect farmers’ production choices and responses to risk (OECD 2008). Such support influences farmers’ decisions through insurance and wealth effects (Heynessey 1998).37 The insurance effect arises from the risk-reducing effect of such policies. The wealth effect arises when increases in average income affect farmers’ responses to risk by influencing their attitudes to risk. As discussed earlier (see Section 4.1), farmers tend to be averse to risk; that is, they will accept a lower average income in order to achieve an outcome that is more certain. Wealth has been found to be a key determinant of risk aversion, with wealthier individuals tending to be less averse to risk (OECD 2008). Therefore, by affecting the wealth of farm households, agricultural support payments can alter farmers’ attitudes to risk. 107. This is supported by a recent study38 into the effect of the CAP on the risk attitudes of farmers in Finland, which found that Finnish farmers became significantly less averse to risk following accession into the EU in 1995 and adoption of the CAP. Prior to accession into the EU, income support for agricultural enterprises in Finland was provided through price support (primarily Cafiero et al (2007) – Risk and Crisis Management in the Reformed European Agricultural Policy, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 55, 419-441. 36 Heynessey, D.A. (1998) – The Production Effects of Agricultural Income Support Policies under Uncertainty. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 80, 1, pp46-57. 37 Koundouri et al (2009) – The effects of EU agricultural policy changes on farmers’ risk attitudes, European Review of Agricultural Economics, 36, 1, 53-77. 38 30 through target prices for crops). Area and headage payments under the CAP increased support payments to Finnish farmers considerably (due mainly to low average yields in Finland relative to the rest of EU), providing a significant wealth effect, which resulted in farmers becoming less averse to risk (measured by the production decisions made by farmers). While this offers some evidence of the wealth effect, the authors of the study emphasise that caution should be taken when generalising these results, as the study focussed on only one risk source (yield risk) and the results may arise, at least to some extent, due to the particular nature of Finnish agriculture. 108. If risk attitudes are affected by support policies under the CAP, with farmers becoming less risk-averse, this is likely to have impacts for farm production. Farmers who are less averse to risk will be more willing to take riskier options, such as inputs or outputs that have less certain outcomes but ultimately have higher expected returns. Additionally, farmers may seek to specialise farm operations in enterprises with the highest returns, rather than diversify investment. Furthermore, many farmers can use market-based risk management tools as an effective means to manage additional variability in market revenues. 109. Farmers in the USA also receive direct payments that are decoupled from production based upon historic area and yield for supported crops. Direct payments account for a large percentage of total farm support in the USA and are focussed on arable crops. 5.2.6 Summary 110. In summary, agricultural support policies aimed at reducing the level of and assisting farmers in coping with risk can reduce adverse effects of a risk on the production choices of farmers and their economic welfare. However, there are a number of issues with such interventions. Firstly, publically provided risk management is likely to crowd out the development of private risk markets (OECD 2009a). This is problematic when market-based solutions are more efficient at managing risk than those that are provided publically. For example, derivative-based instruments, such as futures and options (see Section 5.3.3) can be a highly efficient way of mitigating price risk compared to price stabilisation policies. Similarly, publically provided agricultural insurance systems may be less efficient and offer a more limited range of services compared to a competitive sector of private insurance companies (albeit a significant level of subsidies would be required to achieve a similar coverage). 111. Secondly, government interventions can introduce perverse incentives where the level of support or compensation is conditional upon an adverse outcome over which the farmer has some control. There is considerable scope for perverse incentives in countercyclical schemes, particularly where these schemes are based on farm incomes or margins (such as AgriStability in Canada). This is because farmers may be less likely to take autonomous actions to reduce or mitigate risk in the knowledge that they will receive payments in an adverse event. Similarly, farmers can become reliant on ad-hoc and calamity payments. This is clearly related to the first point above, with public payments reducing the incentives for farmers to use market-based instruments, which ultimately increases the public costs associated with risks in agriculture. 31 112. These issues arise due to the effect of these schemes in transferring risks associated with agricultural production from farmers to government. This gives rise to an additional issue in that the costs of dealing with agricultural risks are borne ultimately by the taxpayer rather than by agricultural businesses. 5.2.7 Measuring public support for risk management tools 113. All agricultural support policies whether targeted directly at risk or not, affect the risk environment in agriculture and farmers’ behaviour. Nevertheless, by analysing both the share of risk-related measures in the total Producer Support Estimate (PSE) and the share of these measures relative to the size of the agricultural industry in each country, a picture can be drawn of the degree of riskrelated support provided across OECD member countries and regions. The PSE is an indicator compiled by the OECD to provide a measure of annual monetary value of gross transfers to farmers arising from agricultural support policies. The individual policy measures in the PSE database can be categorised according to the type of support provided - including risk-related measures. 114. OECD (2009b) decomposes the PSE into categories using two separate typologies. The first differentiates policies according to whether payment rates are variable or fixed. The following categories are used: Market Price Support (MPS) – Transfers from consumers and taxpayers to agricultural producers from policy measures that create a gap between domestic and international market prices for agricultural commodities. This includes intervention purchasing & public storage, export subsidies, and import tariffs and levies. Variable rate payments – Payments based on output, area, animal numbers, revenue or income that are determined at a variable rate. These typically represent countercyclical measures, as payments rates will normally vary according to market conditions. Examples include payments under countercyclical and ACRE support schemes in the USA and payments under AgriStability and AgriInsurance in Canada. Fixed rate payments – Payments based on output, area, animal numbers, revenue or income at a fixed rate. This includes direct payments to farmers at fixed rates, such as the EU Single Farm Payment. Other payments – Is a residual category. This includes a number of policies that are classed as risk-related in Table 7, such as disease prevention measures and support for provision of training to land managers. 32 Figure 4 - Share of MPS, variable and fixed rate payments in the PSE in total farm receipts for selected OECD countries, 1992-97 and 2002-07 Source: OECD 2009b 115. Figure 4 presents the breakdown of PSE as a percentage of total farm receipts (%PSE) into these categories for selected OECD countries and the OECD average. Two bars are shown for each country; the first represents an average of 1992-1997 and the second represents an average of 2002-2007. There are large differences in both the level and composition of support between countries. EU support is highest as a percentage of total farm receipts (~32% in 2002-07). 116. Variable rate (countercyclical) payments are negligible in the EU, and relate mostly to disaster relief payments. This is in contrast with support in the USA and Canada, where variable rate payments make up a much larger share of PSE demonstrating the more countercyclical nature of USA and Canadian agriculture support policies as set out in Section 5.2. In fact, total PSE as a proportion of total farm receipts is considerably lower than in the USA and Canada (~22% in Canada and 14% in USA in 2002-07) when compared to the EU, possibly evidence that farm support policies in these countries currently give higher priority to risk management when compared to direct income support. 117. The levels of support relative to farm receipts are lowest in Australia and New Zealand, with PSE making up only around 6% and 1% respectively of total farm receipts in 2002-07. The level of support in Australia has fallen significantly between the two periods, with MPS reduced dramatically in 2002-07. In both these countries, agricultural reforms have greatly reduced the level of support provided to farmers, with remaining programmes focussed on support to promote self-reliance and enhance international competitiveness. The last remaining 33 income support programme (Farm Help) in Australia was discontinued in June 2008. 118. In summary, decomposing the PSE for the selected OECD countries has shown that while EU support under the CAP has moved towards fixed, decoupled payments, there remains a high level of market price support when compared to the other countries analysed. Additionally, Figure 4 has shown that total support to agriculture in the EU as a percentage of total farm receipts are above the OECD average and considerably higher than support in other comparable countries. This could be a factor explaining the low uptake of market-based risk management tools in the EU relative to the other countries analysed (see Section 5.9.4), as such support lowers the incentives for farmers to invest in these tools. 5.3 Market-based risk management tools in agriculture 119. In addition to risk management tools that may be provided by governments, there is a range of market-based tools that farmers can use to reduce and mitigate risk. The basis of all market-based schemes is risk sharing or risk pooling. Through market mechanisms, agents (farmers, consumers/processors, traders) are able to share risks that are not strongly correlated, thereby sharing the burden and cost of risk. A number of market-based tools work specifically to mitigate price risk. These are derivative-based schemes, such as forward contracts, futures and options. Other tools, namely insurance, can also provide cover for yield risk, although the extent to which they account for the range of factors that contribute to yield risk varies widely. 120. The nature and use of market-based risk management tools differs greatly between countries, largely due to differences in agricultural policy. As discussed earlier, agricultural policy can both discourage farmers from taking private actions to manage risks by directly providing protection against risks, or can incentivise the use of market-based tools by providing subsidies to reduce associated costs (e.g. subsidies on insurance premiums), or by compelling their use (such a mandated level of insurance cover). Indeed, while the provision of these riskpooling tools is made through the market, in the majority of countries there is often significant government involvement in agricultural insurance markets through subsidies in insurance premiums or the direct provision of insurance. 121. Some variation between countries also arises from natural differences in the risk environment (climate and other local factors) and its effects on farming. The Food and Agriculture Organisation (FAO)39 suggests that market-based tools are generally not adequately understood and used by farmers. This view is supported by Alizadeh and Nomikos (2005),40 which asserts that only a few EU farmers have adequate knowledge and resources to make effective use of market-based tools. FAO (2006) – An introduction to market-based instruments for agricultural price risk management. Available at: 39 40 Alizadeh and Nomikos (2005), Agricultural Reforms and the Use of Market Mechanisms for Risk Management. A study commissioned by the Futures and Options Association (FOA). Available at: http://www.foa.co.uk/publications/agricultural_report_2005.pdf 34 122. Section 5.3.1 looks at the nature and use of agricultural insurance systems in the EU and various OECD countries, while Section 5.3.3 looks at the use of forwards, futures and options. 5.3.1 Agricultural Insurance systems 123. Agricultural insurance products are a type of risk-pooling measure for farm businesses, in which premiums paid by participants are used to cover losses incurred by individuals within the pool. Risk pooling is most effective when the risks insured by participants are not strongly correlated (i.e. is not systemic), meaning that payouts in any one period will be small relative to total contributions to the pool through premiums. In the absence of subsidies on premiums or support for reinsurance, agricultural insurance tends to focus on yield risk (and specific factors that contribute to this) rather than price risk, as the latter is highly systemic. In general, price risk is shared most effectively between buyers and sellers where this risk is negatively correlated, through mechanisms such as forwards, futures and options markets. These tools are discussed in Section 5.3.3. 124. A report for EC Joint Research Centre (JRC)41 sets out two requirements that must be met in order for a risk to be insurable: The adverse effects of asymmetric information must be managed The implications of systemic risks (i.e. those that are likely to occur at the same time among insured parties) must be overcome 125. Problems associated with asymmetric information were discussed in Section 5.1, and can result in incomplete markets and provide scope for moral hazard. Systemic risks present a particular issue for insurance due to the probability that the insurer will face a large number of claims at the same time. In order to insure against systemic risks, insurers must charge very high premiums and build up large capital reserves. Government support in the form of state guarantees or reinsurance can reduce these premiums. Alternatively, premiums can be subsidised directly to increase affordability to farmers. Without such government support, therefore, insurance coverage of systemic risks in agriculture tends to be very poor and in many instances non-existent, with coverage confined to single, scattered risks, such as hail and fire. To date, most agricultural insurance systems have remained quasi-market in nature as they rely on government subsidy. 126. In many countries, the private agricultural insurance market has largely been stifled by government support policies. For example, ad-hoc or calamity payments made by governments following adverse events may reduce farmers’ incentives to invest in insurance (OECD 2009) if they believe such payments are 41 Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al (2009), Risk Management and Agricultural Insurance Systems in Europe. JRC Reference Reports. Available at :http://mars.jrc.it/mars/content/download/1515/8548/file/LR_IPSC_Reference_report_agriculture_i nsurance.pdf 35 always going to be made in the event of adverse outcomes in agricultural production. Thus, due to differences in agricultural policy environments, the type and coverage of private insurance products differ widely across countries and between crops and livestock. Table 8 - Summary of crop insurance types Risks covered Yield risk Insurance type Single-risk Combined risk Yield insurance Whole-farm yield insurance Yield & price risk Revenue insurance Yield, output and input price risk Index insurances Income insurance Area-yield insurance Area-revenue insurance Narrowest coverage and most common form, insuring against the occurrence of an adverse meteorological event from a single source (e.g. hail) Also covers other meteorological events, such as frost. Insures against an adverse effect on the yield of a given crop due to a meteorological event, rather than the occurrence of the event itself Accounts for the yield of all crops produced by the farm, paying out only if total production falls below a given level. Insures against price as well as yield risk, paying out if the total value of farm production falls below a threshold Also takes account of costs of production (only exists in USA) Compensation paid to insured farmers if statistical yield for a predefined area falls below trigger level. Compensation paid if average revenue (area yield multiplied area price) falls below trigger level. Source: Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al (2009) 127. Most livestock insurance products mainly cover non-epidemic diseases and accidents. Crop insurance products, which are more developed, are summarised in Table 8 according to the type of risk insured. Coverage of yield risk ranges from single-risk insurance (normally covering hail and some other scattered risks such as fire), which is the most common type of crop insurance, to whole-farm yield insurance, which accounts for all crops produced by the farm. In general, the level of insurance premiums increases with the number of risk factors covered. 128. Revenue insurance accounts for price risk in addition to yield risk, with payout made if revenue falls below a certain level. In principle, revenue insurance products should be cheaper than yield insurance given yield and output price risk tend to be negatively correlated (so that a fall in yield is compensated by a rise in 36 price and vice versa) (Alizadeh & Nomikos 2005). However, as discussed in Section 2.3, while this relationship may exist at the aggregate level, it is much less likely to hold at the farm-level, as the incidence of a given yield shock is likely to differ among farms. Income insurance accounts for the effect of changes in total costs in addition to total revenue on farm income. 129. Broadly, when compensation under the insurance products presented above is triggered entirely by outcomes at the individual farm-level, there is significant scope for “moral hazard” problems, as there is an incentive for farmers to reduce the extent of on-farm measures that reduce risk exposure once insured. This is particularly relevant to income insurance, where there are a number of factors within the control of the farmer (especially production costs) and outcomes are reliant upon how well the farm is managed (Alizadeh & Nomikos 2005). Problems of moral hazard can be overcome by the use of area-based or index insurances. In these instances, area-yield or revenue insurances compensate farmers only if the average yield or revenues for a predefined area fall below a set level (based upon an index), which may be a statistical average of levels in previous years. While this guards against moral hazard problems, area-based insurance is only effective in providing protection if the risk factors covered exhibit relatively strong correlation between farmers in the area – a condition that would also increase the cost of the insurance. 130. In order to address problems of prohibitively high premium costs caused by systemic risks, many governments subsidise reinsurance costs and/or premiums to increase the affordability of insurance. Garrido and Bielza (2009) and Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al (2009) review agricultural insurance systems in the EU and find wide variation between coverage and uptake of insurance between countries. As would be expected, there is a direct relationship between the level of government involvement in agricultural insurance markets and the level of coverage, with subsidies on insurance premiums and reinsurance enabling coverage of more systemic risks and higher uptake by farmers due to reduced premiums. 131. These studies also reveal broadly two different approaches to addressing yield risks in EU countries, as can be seen in Table 9, which summarises data on the level of insurance subsidies and ad-hoc / calamity fund payments in selected EU member states, along with the types of insurance provided. The table shows that Belgium, Netherlands, Germany and the UK (including Scotland) do not provide subsidies to agricultural insurance. Germany and the UK, and to some extent Belgium, have in the past relied mostly on ad-hoc payments to support farmers in adverse events. In the absence of premium subsidies, coverage is limited to single risk insurance in these countries. 37 Table 9 - Level of insurance subsidies and ad-hoc/calamity fund payments in selected EU member states Country Singlerisk ins. Combined insurance Yield insurance Insurance subsidies / Coverage €million / %) (1) Belgium Cyprus France Germany Greece P GC P P P GC P GC+GS+G PS - Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain UK PS P PS PS P PS PS PS PS - PS - 0 4.4 / 50% 5 / 2.4% 0 No data (100% public scheme) 180 / 67% 0 32 / 68% 232 / 41% 0 Ad-hoc and fund payments / year (€million) (2) 17.2 7.2 155.6 (3) 112.3 70.1 113.3 3.0 3.7 379.5 Source: Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al (2009) (1) Annual subsidies. Data year not provided by the source. (2) Yearly average of payments. Period of data varies by country, but mainly over the period 1995-2005. (3) 50% of funding comes through private contributions from taxes on agricultural insurances -: Not existing G: Public non-subsidised P: Private non-subsidised GS: Public partially subsidised PS: Private partially subsidised GC: Public compulsory partially subsidised 132. On the other hand, Spain, Portugal, Cyprus and Greece have extensive government involvement in insurance markets. In Spain and Portugal, publicprivate partnership systems exist, where the state provides premium subsidies and reinsurance while private companies administer insurance programmes and cover a share of the risk; little support is provided through ad-hoc / calamity payments. In Greece and Cyprus, insurance is subsidised and publicly administered, with private companies only covering risks not covered by the public system, although both countries also provide a significant level of ad hoc support. The effect of subsidies on insurance premiums is clear; where no subsidy is provided, private insurance tends to cover only single risks (hail, fire), with higher levels of support increasing coverage to combined risks and yield insurance. 133. There are merits and drawbacks to both approaches. Agricultural insurance, as cover is determined ex ante, avoids to some extent the uncertainty associated with ad-hoc payments, which are determined only once an adverse event has occurred. However, both approaches can introduce perverse incentives, as farmers may reduce the level of autonomous or on-farm measures to reduce or mitigate risks. 134. Outside of the EU, the USA also provides a high level of subsidies on insurance premiums. USA subsidies to insurance premiums amount to around 38 US$1.9billion42 including support for administrative costs of insurance companies and reinsurance costs. In sum, total effective support to insurance amounts to around 72% of premiums in the USA, compared to an average of around 32% in the EU. As a result, US agricultural insurance markets are highly developed, with around 45% of total crop production value insured (compared to around 23% in the EU), and yield and revenue insurance is provided widely (Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al 2009). 135. In Canada, agricultural insurance is provided publicly through the AgriInsurance scheme, (part of the Business Risk Management Suite), which covers yield risk for a range of commodities, including crops and livestock. Payments are made to producers in the event of a yield shock on an individual crop basis, rather than whole-farm yield. The scheme is partially subsidised, with total subsidies accounting for 66% of premiums. 136. Subsidies are not provided to agricultural insurance systems in Australia and New Zealand and, as a result, the coverage of private insurance schemes tends to be limited to single perils, such as hail, fire and other isolated risks. 137. Although premium subsidies greatly increase the coverage of risks offered by insurance markets and the uptake of insurance by farmers, there are downsides to subsidy insurance, not least the costs to government. It is likely that the efficiency of premium subsidies, that is the benefit per unit of expenditure, falls as the size of the subsidy increases, as additional risks become increasingly more expensive to insure. According to the World Bank (2010)43, government subsidised insurance schemes have, historically, performed very poorly, with the level of claims far exceeding the premiums paid by farmers, although this has improved as provision of insurance has been transferred to private companies. Further, if agricultural insurance markets are dominated by a small number of large insurance companies (i.e. are not competitive) subsidies will, at least in part, be captured by insurance companies rather than being passed onto farmers in the form of lower premiums. Subsidies may also ‘crowd out’ other marketbased risk management tools, such as those discussed in 5.3.3. 5.3.2 Mutual funds 138. Mutual funds can be considered a special type of insurance in which participants tend to be the owners of the fund. Risk is shared between members, who pay a participation premium to cover administration and possible reinsurance costs, with funds paid out to businesses to partially or fully compensate for economic losses incurred. 139. Often, funds operate on a local or regional basis. Generally, this is an effective and sustainable risk management tool when risks are not correlated among 42 Figures here are taken from Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al (2009) Mahul, O. and Stutley, C. (2010) – Government support to agricultural insurance: Challenges and opportunities for developing countries. World Bank report. 43 39 affiliated farmers.44 However, where risks are correlated among members of a mutual fund, economic losses to members will most likely occur at the same time – with the result that the paying out of compensations can put a strain on financial resources of the mutual fund and ultimately its sustainability, especially where opportunities to borrow are limited. Funds that operate on a local or regional basis may be more susceptible to systemic risks, as some risks (such as weather and contagious animal diseases) tend to affect geographically proximate farmers. One benefit of regionally based funds is that they can reduce scope for moral hazard, as farmers will be more familiar with the risks faced by other members and there may be a degree of social control. To address problems of systemic risks, funds may seek to reinsure risks (at the cost of a greater premium) or link with funds in other regions that have a difference incidence of risks in order to share the burden of losses. 140. Following from the above discussion, yield risks, particularly those that are relatively isolated, are more suited to coverage through mutual funds than price risk, which tends to be highly correlated among farmers. Price risk is more effectively shared through other market-based mechanisms, such as forward and futures contracts (see Section 5.3.3). 141. Mutual funds have the added advantage that where they are professionally managed on behalf of the farmer, they provide small farm businesses with a professional service for risk management, which may otherwise be prohibitively costly for individual fund members. 142. In Canada, a form of mutual account for farm businesses is provided through the AgriInvest scheme, which is designed to cover small or short-term falls in income. The Canadian government, through Agriculture and Agri-Food Canada (AAFC), matches farmer contributions up to CAD$22,500 each year, upon which two withdrawals can be made by the farmer. Producers have the flexibility to draw upon the funds to cover small declines in margins (of less than 15%), or for risk mitigation and other investments, and earn interest on deposits. An advantage of this scheme is in incentivising farmers to invest funds in order to provide for future falls in income, caused by either output or input price risk or yield shocks. However, as separate funds are not linked in order to pool risks, the scheme may not be the most efficient way of managing these risks. Pooling funds and risks, where risks are not perfectly correlated, would allow greater coverage of risks for a given contribution to the fund. Provisions under the CAP 143. Article 68 of Council Regulation (EC) No 73/2009 makes provisions for Members States to grant, from their national ceilings for the Single Farm Payment (SFP), support for a range of measures including the establishment by farmers of mutual funds for animal and plant diseases and environmental incidents. The mutual funds will provide affiliated farmers financial compensation for economic losses caused by outbreaks of animal or plant diseases or environmental incident. When economic losses are less likely to occur at the same time for all members – i.e. there is systemic risk. 44 40 144. It appears from the regulation that Article 71 aims to encourage farmers to take responsibility in managing risks affecting their businesses – most notably through the pooling of risks across businesses that is offered by mutual funds. Specifically, the mutual fund option will provide farmers with a mechanism to contribute to a common pot of money, from which affiliated farmers incurring economic losses can receive compensation. 145. The EC regulations do not make any specific provisions for how mutual funds should be organised or managed, although there are requirements for co-funding and the conditions on which the fund will pay out. It is left up to Member States to determine the form that the mutual funds may take.45 Thus, if the mutual funds for farmers in Scotland were to be supported through Article 71, the Scottish Government would need to establish through domestic legislation a framework through which farmers can organise themselves to share risks and make compensation to members of their fund who incur economic losses as a result of outbreak of animal and plant diseases or an environmental incident. 5.3.3 Hedging price risk – forward contracts, futures and options 146. As highlighted in Section 2.2, output price risk – that is, the probability that output price may change during the production cycle of a commodity – is the key risk faced by farmers and the mechanism through which many other sources of risk manifest. A number of market-based tools are designed specifically to mitigate price risk. Forward contracts, futures and options work to share risk by exploiting the negative correlation of price risk between producers and buyers; that is, a fall in price is a benefit to the buyer but a cost to the producer and vice versa. These mechanisms allow price risk to be ‘hedged’ by enabling producers (buyers) to sell (buy) a commodity at a future time, at a price (tentatively) fixed today (FAO 2006), reducing price risk for both buyer and seller. 147. It should be noted that these instruments are not aimed at improving the financial outcome (i.e. expected price) for participants; rather, they are designed to reduce the uncertainty around the expected price. The main features of each of the three instruments are briefly outlined46 and then the nature and use of the instruments in the UK/EU and other OECD countries is discussed. Alizadeh and Nomikos (2005) outline four key benefits of market-based risk management tools in dealing with fluctuations in prices: They give risk-averse producers the opportunity to participate in risky activities (i.e. activities that have uncertain outcomes) which they would not otherwise undertake; Consequently, trading away price risk using agricultural derivatives gives more efficient outcomes than managing risk through on-farm methods (e.g. diversification of investment into other enterprises), as farmers can pursue the most profitable activities; Article 71(2a) provides that “‘mutual funds’ shall mean a scheme accredited by the Member States in accordance with its national law…” 45 46 Much of the detail in this section is based upon FAO (2006) and Alizadeh and Nomikos (2005). 41 By mitigating price risk, market-based tools can stabilise farmers’ incomes, resulting in more stable expenditure on farm inputs and family consumption. This can improve the resilience and security of rural businesses and employment, reducing their reliance on government support policies. Following from the previous point, the effective use of market-based tools by farmers can reduce pressure on taxpayer-funded support policies and can be the least-cost way to manage market risks in many circumstances. Forward contracts 148. Forward contracts are a private agreement between the seller and buyer to deliver a specified quantity of a commodity at an agreed time and price. Contracts detail arrangements for outcomes in which quantity and/or quality do not meet the agreed level (e.g. discounts, premiums). As payment is not normally made at the beginning of the contract yet the seller is obliged to produce the commodities, there is an inherent default or credit risk in forward contracts. Despite this, the guarantee of the contract can improve farmers’ access to credit markets. 149. There are different types of forward contracts. The most common is the fixedprice contract, which protects producers and buyers against down-side risk (for sellers, the possibility that market prices will fall, for buyers, the possibility that they will rise) but leaves sellers (buyers) open to the possibility that market prices will rise above (fall below) the fixed contract price (upside risk). Minimum price contracts give farmers the opportunity to benefit from price rises, usually at the expense of some premium, but these are much less common. The agreed price in forward contracts is often set using some reference point, for example by assessing prices in the futures market (see next section). Futures markets 150. Futures are a more sophisticated means of sharing price risk. In the simplest form, futures are standardised forward contracts (i.e. futures contracts for a given commodity are of a set quantity) that are traded on exchanges. The exchange house guarantees payment of a contract in case of default, removing credit risk. There are significant transaction costs to users of futures exchanges in the form of commission and brokerage fees. 151. Futures markets are primarily a means of hedging price risk rather than buying and selling goods as only a very small percentage of trades in futures result in the delivery of the commodity. Indeed, a futures contract (i.e. a promise to supply goods) can be sold without actually producing or selling the commodity, as long as an equivalent contract is bought before the due date (‘closing’ the position). An important factor for participants in futures markets is basis risk. ‘Basis’ is the difference between local cash prices and the relevant futures contract price and a greater difference reduces the effectiveness of futures markets in hedging price risk. 152. Farmers can also benefit indirectly from futures markets without participating in the markets. Trading prices of contracts will generally reflect the current expectations of traders regarding future prices. Farmers can therefore use this 42 information on expected future prices to make better-informed production decisions, although price risk will still exist because of unexpected influences on price not foreseen by traders (i.e. those risk sources discussed in Section 2.2). Options 153. Options differ from futures contracts in that they can be used to guarantee a minimum price rather than a fixed price. Therefore, options give producers the opportunity to benefit from upwards movements in price in addition to providing protection against price falls. This is because under an options contract (specifically a ‘put’ option), the buyer of the contract (e.g. a producer) is not obliged to sell the commodities whereas the seller of the contract (e.g. a processor) is obliged to buy them – therefore, the producer can choose to sell if the movement of price is favourable and choose not to sell if price falls. 154. The cost of this function is the option premium, which is a non-refundable payment that the buyer of an option pays to the seller at the time of buying an option. In practice, opportunities for farmers to utilise options are limited, as options premiums tend to be prohibitively high. Use of forwards, futures and options in the UK/EU and other OECD countries 155. Detailed data on the use of these tools in different countries is relatively scarce. Available information suggests their use in the UK and EU is low relative to other countries, such as the USA and Australia. Alizadeh and Nomikos (2005) assess the ratio of trade in wheat futures contracts over physical production in the UK, USA and South Africa, with a higher ratio indicating greater use of futures markets.47 Figure 5 presents the results.48 Trade in wheat futures relative to physical production is much lower in the UK than the USA throughout the period, and is lower than South Africa from 1999 onwards following reforms to market price support and price control measures in South Africa, which significantly increased the demand for private risk-management tools. 47 Some of the difference in ratios could also be explained by greater activity of investors in markets, who trade but do not produce commodities. 48 This ratio in all countries is much greater than one, as quantities traded on futures exchanges are much higher than physical production – few trades actually lead to the delivery of goods, and positions are ‘closed’ (i.e. an equivalent contract to buy a quantity of commodities is bought to cancel a position to sell) before delivery / payment is required. 43 Figure 5 - Ratio of trading in wheat futures contracts relative to physical production in the UK, USA and South Africa, 1989-2003 Source: Alizadeh and Nomikos (2005) 156. Palinkas and Székely (2009) have reviewed the use of various risk management tools by farmers in the USA and several EU countries (Germany, Hungary, Netherlands Poland, and Spain). Using data from a survey of EU farmers and secondary data from farmers in the USA, the study finds that although the use of hedging through futures markets is lower in the EU countries surveyed (around 2.3% farmers49), around a third of EU farmers used forward contracts compared to around 10% of US farmers. The use of derivatives markets in the EU is expected to rise due to 2003 CAP reforms and increased price volatility. 157. The use of derivatives is a major focus of risk management in Australian agriculture. Agricultural policy reforms in Australia have all but removed market price support policies in order to create a more market-oriented agricultural sector, and the level of agricultural support from other policies is low relative to other OECD countries. Australian farmers are highly exposed to volatility in world price markets due to the openness of the Australian market to international market and the low level of agricultural support, which itself is made more volatile by the domestic price support policies of regions such as the USA and the EU. In response, Australian farmers have become highly sophisticated in the use of commodity derivatives (OECD 2000, Alizadeh & Nomikos 2005), although evidence in the USA suggests that these tools are also widely used in that country probably reflecting the structure of USA agriculture. Involvement in these markets is often at the individual farmer level, facilitated mostly through farmers’ cooperatives and financial institutions. 49 It should be noted that although only 2.3% farmers in the survey use futures markets to hedge price risk, the proportion of production hedged is likely to be significantly higher as larger farm businesses are more likely to use futures markets than smaller enterprises. 44 Increasing the use of market-based risk management tools in the EU 158. Alizadeh & Nomikos (2005) discuss a number of barriers to the use of derivatives in the EU and provide a range of recommendations to promote greater use. In addition to the crowding-out of market-based instruments by CAP policies discussed in Section 5.3, the report cites insufficient knowledge and training on the part of the farmers in the use of market based tools. Another key issue, particularly for smaller farm businesses, is affordability. Transaction costs can be high, and farm businesses are often required to pay significant deposits to open a trading account with brokers. Arising partly from this, a mixed perception of derivatives among farmers is also a cause for low uptake, with farmers instead preferring alternative risk management methods, such as diversification of activities and production contracts, which are likely to be less efficient in managing risk. 159. The authors provide a number of recommendations to promote the use of marketbased tools. These are summarised below: Establishing an educational and training programme for agricultural risk management: providing training on both the mechanics of agricultural commodity markets and the use of market-based tools to producers, consultants and organisations that farmers use to seek advice on managing risk. Channelling market based risk management products through farmerfocussed organisations: Investing and building relationships with farmerfocused organisations, such as Cooperatives, Farmer Controlled Businesses and Merchants. This can help particularly in reducing the costs of marketbased tools for small-scale farmers, by improving opportunities for collective action in risk management activities. Development and marketing of flexible derivative instruments: Improving the range and flexibility of market-based risk management tools to reflect better the diversity of agricultural businesses in the EU. Proactive involvement of exchanges, banks and financial institutions: Encouraging financial institutions to work more closely with the farming community to provide more suitable market-based risk management instruments, in addition to providing appropriate infrastructure and training. Agricultural policy management: Reducing the barriers to development and growth of derivatives markets for agricultural commodities caused by support arrangements under the CAP. 160. An additional cost and barrier to the use of derivatives is basis risk, which is the difference between cash and futures prices. The OECD (2009a) cites evidence that there is an increasing lack of convergence between cash and futures prices on world exchanges for agricultural commodities, which increases the costs to farmers of using futures markets. However, analysis by Alizadeh and Nomikos (2005) provides evidence that the European futures exchange Euronext.liffe has 45 provided good performance, as measured by basis risk, for UK and French farmers, although less so for farmers in Germany, Spain, Portugal and Ireland. 46 6. Summary 161. This paper has reviewed risks in agriculture and tools that can be used to manage them, both through public policy and through the market. The main findings emerging from this review are discussed below. 162. It is clear that agriculture faces a range of risks, many of which are specific to the industry. Fluctuations in the market price for agricultural products are often cited as the principal risk source by farmers and the insensitivity of demand for agricultural produce means prices have to change by relatively large amounts to bring demand and supply into balance following a supply shock. Additionally, production risks arising from changes in weather or animal and plant diseases are a significant source of risk, and can cause fluctuations in price due to effects on market supply and demand. Fluctuations in input prices are also a significant source of risk. These risks ultimately affect farm businesses through fluctuations in income, and the precise nature of this impact depends upon the relationship between risk sources, which is highly complex. Production decisions are also likely to be affected by the presence of risks, as farmers tend to be risk averse, meaning that farmers may accept lower returns in exchange for outcomes that are more certain. Furthermore, fluctuations in income can constrain the ability of farm businesses to invest, which can affect future income. 163. Analysis of fluctuations in UK feed wheat and cattle prices undertaken for this paper supports findings in the literature of a trend for increased volatility in prices of agricultural commodities. Additionally, a range of evidence is available in the literature of increased volatility in EU and world market prices. Evidence suggests that some share of increased volatility in EU prices may be the result of successive CAP reforms, which have reduced the level of market price support and liberalised trade with third countries, bringing EU prices more in line with world prices. Additional sources of volatility were also cited in the literature: growing linkages between energy and agricultural markets and volatility in crude oil prices; biofuels mandates, which create artificial demand for feedstocks and make demand for agricultural produce less responsive to price changes; relatively low global public stocks, with evidence that volatility in cereals prices increases when stocks are low; and speculative activity of investors in futures markets, although there mixed evidence about whether such activity led to the 2007/8 price spike. 164. The uncertainty associated with other factors that affect agricultural production is potentially greater in the long-term due to climate change, which may have as yet unknown effects on temperatures and rainfall, including extreme weather events, and the range of animal and crop diseases and pests. 165. A range of instruments is available to help (a) reduce the level of risk, (b) mitigate remaining risks, and (c) cope with the adverse effects of risks. Some are policies that can be implemented publically by government, while others are provided through the market or implemented on-farm. 166. A review of policies finds there is a significant level of government intervention in agriculture through direct payments and other risk-related policies, in both the EU 47 and other OECD countries. Analysis suggests that there is some rationale for governments to intervene in risk management in agriculture. This arises primarily due to problems of costly information, which can lead to incomplete markets. Additionally, high transaction costs associated with market-based tools can give rise to an equity motive for intervention, where these costs are disproportionately high for smaller businesses. However, government interventions can incur significant costs and can reduce the incentives for farmers to take private actions to reduce or manage risks. 167. Price stabilisation policies, such as intervention purchasing, import tariffs and export subsidies, to reduce price risk are present in the majority of OECD countries, but are gradually being phased out in order to reduce market distortion. Market-based solutions, such as futures and options contracts, can be highly efficient ways of mitigating price risk and use of these tends to be highest where support provided by price stabilisation policies is particularly low, such as Australia and South Africa, as these policies reduce the incentives for farmers to invest in market-based solutions. 168. Two broad approaches to managing crop risk through government policy were identified; (i) through subsidies to agricultural insurance systems to increase uptake and broaden coverage (e.g. Spain, Portugal, USA, Canada, Greece), and (ii) compensate farmers through ah-hoc or calamity payments (e.g. UK, Netherlands, Germany). Some countries, such as Australia and New Zealand, provide little support either for agricultural insurance or through ad-hoc payments. Support that is more comprehensive is provided in the USA and Canada in the form revenue and income stabilisation schemes. 169. Direct agricultural support payments account for the majority of EU agricultural support under the CAP and a substantial proportion of support in the USA. While these payments tend to distort markets less than direct price support, there is still a significant effect on farmers’ behaviour through wealth and insurance effects, which can affect farmers’ attitudes to risk. 170. Additionally, farmers can implement a number of on-farm measures to reduce and mitigate risks, such as diversification within and outwith agriculture, investment in appropriate risk prevention technologies and collaboration with other farmers through mutual funds to pool risks. Private actions undertaken by farmers, either on-farm or using market-based tools, can reduce the public burden of agricultural policies designed to assist farmers in mitigating or coping with risk. 171. Thus, in choosing when and how to intervene in risk management in agriculture there is need to assess the feasibility and cost-effectiveness of the various risk management strategies. Such an assessment needs to consider the full range of instruments available for managing risks and, in particular, take into account the effect of current agricultural policies on farmers’ risk environments and responses to risk. 48 References Alizadeh, A. and Nomikos, N. (2005) – Agricultural Reforms and the Use of Market Mechanisms for Risk Management. Futures and Options Association. Anton, J. and Giner, C. (2005) – Can Risk Reducing Policies Reduce Farmer's Risk and Improve Their Welfare? Paper prepared for presentation at the 11th Congress of the EAAE (European Association of Agricultural Economists), Copenhagen, Denmark, 24-27 August 2005. Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al (2009), Risk Management and Agricultural Insurance Systems in Europe. JRC Reference Reports. Available at: http://mars.jrc.it/mars/content/download/1515/8548/file/LR_IPSC_Reference_report_agri culture_insurance.pdf Cafiero et al (2007) – Risk and Crisis Management in the Reformed European Agricultural Policy, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 55, 419-441. Defra (2008) – The Impact of Biofuels on Commodity Prices. Available at: http://www.defra.gov.uk/evidence/series/documents/impact-biofuels-commodities.pdf Defra (2010) – The 2007/08 Agricultural Price Spikes: Causes and Policy Implications. Annex 6: Speculation and the food price spikes of 2007/8. European Commission (2005) – Communication on Risk and Crisis Management in Agriculture, COM (2005) 74, Brussels. European Commission DGAGRI (2009) – Historical Price Volatility. Available at: http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/analysis/tradepol/commodityprices/volatility_en.pdf FAO (2006) – An introduction to market-based instruments for agricultural price risk management. Available at: http://www.fao.org/ag/ags/subjects/en/ruralfinance/pdf/ag_price_risk.pdf FAO Food Outlook (November 2007 – Special Feature: High prices and volatility in agricultural commodities. FAO Food Outlook (December 2009) – Special Feature: The food price crisis of 2007/2008: Evidence and Implications. Heynessey, D.A. (1998) – The Production Effects of Agricultural Income Support Policies under Uncertainty. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 80, 1, pp46-57. HM Treasury (2003) – The Green Book: Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government. Available at: http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/data_greenbook_index.htm Irwin, S. H. and D. R. Sanders (2010), “The Impact of Index and Swap Funds on Commodity Futures Markets: Preliminary Results”, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Working Papers, No. 27, OECD Publishing. doi: 10.1787/5kmd40wl1t5f-en Baffes, J. and Haniotis, T (2010) – Placing the 2006/08 Commodity Price Boom into Perspective. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5371. 49 Keane, M. and O’Connor, D. (2009) - Price Volatility in the EU Dairy Industry: Causes, Consequences and Coping Mechanisms. Report prepared for the European Dairy Association. Koundouri et al (2009) – The effects of EU agricultural policy changes on farmers’ risk attitudes, European Review of Agricultural Economics, 36, 1, 53-77. Matthews, A. (2010) – Perspectives on Addressing Market Instability and Income Risk for Farmers. Paper presented at Joint AES / SFER Conference on ‘The Common Agricultural Policy Post 2013’. Available at: http://www.aes.ac.uk/_pdfs/_conferences/201_paper.pdf Mahul, O. and Stutley, C. (2010) – Government support to agricultural insurance: Challenges and opportunities for developing countries. World Bank report. O’Connor, D., Keane, M. and Barnes, E. (2009) – Measuring Volatility in Dairy Commodity Prices. Paper prepared for presentation at the 113th EAAE Seminar “A resilient European food industry and food chain in a challenging world”, Chania, Crete, Greece, date as in: September 3 - 6, 2009. OECD (2008) – An assessment of risk exposure in agriculture: A literature review. Part of the Trade and Agriculture Directorate project on Risk Management in Agriculture. OECD (2009a) – Risk Management in Agriculture: A Holistic Conceptual Framework. Part of the Trade and Agriculture Directorate project on Risk Management in Agriculture. OECD (2009b) – An Overview of Risk-Related Policy Measures. Part of the Trade and Agriculture Directorate project on Risk Management in Agriculture. Pareto Consulting (2008) – Foot & Mouth Disease Review 2007: Economic Impact in Scotland. Available at: http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Publications/2008/06/11151009/0 Phimister, E., Roberts, D. and Gilbert, A. (2004) – The Dynamics of Farm Incomes: Panel data analysis using the Farm Accounts Survey. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 55, 2, pp197-220. RERAD (2009) – An Overview of USA Farm Support Policy. Report prepared by the Scottish Government for the Inquiry into the Future of Support for Agriculture in Scotland. Available at: http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Topics/farmingrural/Agriculture/inquiry/background/usa RERAD (2010) – Economic Report on Scottish Agriculture: 2010 Edition. SAC (2008) – Assessing the Impact of Increased Feed, Fuel and Fertiliser Costs on Scottish Agriculture. AA211 Special Study for the Scottish Government. Vrolik and Poppe (2008), Income volatility and income crises in the European Union, in Meuwissen et al (eds.), Income Stabilisation in the European Union, Ch. 2. Wageningen Academic Publishers, Netherlands Vrolijk et al (2009) – Volatility of incomes, prices and yields in the European Union. Report 2009-005, LEI Wageningen UR, The Hague. 50