Experiments are conducted simulating two-stage, buyer

advertisement

Information Sharing in Asymmetric Buyer-Seller Negotiations: An Experimental Study

Abhik Roy, Quinnipiac University

Michael Menasco, California State University San Bernardino

Anthony Myers, Bechtel Jacobs Company

Presenting author: Abhik Roy, Professor and chair, Marketing & Advertising department, School of Business, Quinnipiac University, 275 Mount Carmel Avenue, Hamden, CT 06518. Telephone:

(203) 582 8465. Abhik.Roy@quinnipiac.edu

Information Sharing in Asymmetric Buyer-Seller Negotiations: An Experimental Study

EXTENDED ABSTRACT

Experiments are conducted simulating two-stage, buyer-seller negotiations over the issue of a contract price. Two factors introduce asymmetries to the bargaining situation — an alternative offer from a rival supplier representing a threat price held by the buyer, and private information, held by either the buyer or seller, on the value of potential outcomes to each party. Hypotheses are developed, which reflect the possible effects of sharing of private information and of a threat price, on negotiated price outcomes. There should be a main effect of threat leading to lower negotiated prices – a credible alternative offer from another supplier skews the bargaining scenario in favor of the buyer. There should also be a main effect of information sharing. A number of explanations are offered for this effect. For example, the sharing of information by a seller might be seen as a giving up of power or a concession, which merits a reciprocal concession on the part of the buyer. A seller providing credible information about itself might reduce the problem of adverse selection faced by the buyer by helping answer questions such as

“is a low-price offer from a supplier because of its inferior quality?” Sharing of information might also cause the buyer to feel that it is being treated fairly. The direction of any information sharing effect should depend on whether the buyer shares information (lower prices) or the seller controls the information exchange (higher prices). Specific interactions are hypothesized. Our major interaction hypothesis is that the magnitude of any information sharing effect should depend on whether a threat price exists; the impact of information exchange should be greater under conditions of threat than when there is no credible alternative for the buyer. Another hypothesized interaction is that the influence of sharing information should depend on which party, buyer or seller, is in control of the information exchange; the seller, especially when faced with a threat, should be able to benefit more from this negotiating strategy.

In each experiment conducted, the bargaining frontier consists of price points corresponding to specific solution outcomes, mostly based on theoretic solutions that might intuitively be considered fair. Among others, these include a price point where both parties achieve the same utility, a point where each gains an equal amount of utility from his minimum utility point, and a price representing equal loss to each from his maximum utility in the game. Subjects are not told about the meaning of each discrete price point and they are not restricted to settling on just these prices. Information is provided on the value (utility) of each price point on the bargaining frontier. In the ‘information-sharing’ condition the party in control of information exchange, knows about the value of each potential outcome, not only to itself but also to its opponent, and has to divulge this knowledge during the negotiation. Experiment 1 is designed so that either buyers or sellers can initiate the information exchange in the ‘sharing’ condition. In experiment

2, in order to focus on selling strategies we allow only sellers to share information. The party initiating the information exchange must share the knowledge that it has – it must reveal details of its own utility function and whatever it knows of its opponent’s utility function – as part of its bargaining strategy. The design of experiment 2, with the factor ‘knows buyer’s utility function/does not know’, allows us to distinguish between the effect of knowing about an

1

opponent’s utility function (and letting the opponent know this fact), and the effect of divulging details of one’s own value for outcomes. Only the latter effect, of private information sharing, is found to be significant in influencing outcomes. In the second study, in addition to observations of the negotiated price (if there is a settlement) measures are taken of the manifest influence exerted by the seller in the opinion of the buyer, and of the buyer’s perception of the fairness of the final settlement. Each of these perceptual outcomes is measured using established scales.

Since there are multiple dependent variables in experiment 2 MANOVA is used to analyze this data. Protocols are collected in real time with participants typing their arguments in support of a price offer on an online discussion board before entering into verbal negotiations.

Results show that, as in previous studies there is a main effect of threat in lowering negotiated prices. Unique to this study, there is also evidence of a main effect of information sharing, and that the impact of sharing differs significantly, depending on whether there is a threat price or not. The information sharing effect also depends on whether the seller or the buyer initiates the exchange process. Interestingly, in the absence of a threat sellers are found to do worse through exchanging private information than when there is a threat. When a threat price exists, sellers can partially mitigate some of the effects of the threat through information sharing. We find that under the conditions imposed, the best a seller can achieve is a settlement a little above the minimum price point in the bargaining set, corresponding to an equal gain of utility from their respective minimum utility points, for each party. The protocols support the idea that the process of arriving at this price solution corresponds to finding a price that provides equal earning from a minimum utility point.

Buyers perceive the outcomes to be fair when sellers share information; this despite feeling that sellers have significantly influenced them, when they use information sharing as a selling strategy. The ‘perceived fairness’ result suggests that an information sharing strategy should not harm customer relationships in the longer term. When buyers share private information themselves, they benefit regardless of whether they possess a threat price or not. The main strategic implication for sellers in a bargaining situation is that a seller can benefit from sharing private information, but only when facing a credible threat. If there is no such threat, a seller might be better off keeping any private information to himself.

2

FULL PAPER REFERENCES

Alexander, Joe F., Patrick L. Schul and Emin Babakus (1991), “Analyzing Interpersonal

Communications in Industrial Marketing Negotiations,”

Journal of the Academy of

Marketing Science 19 (2), 129-139.

Binmore, Ken, Avner Shaked and John Sutton (1989), “An Outside Option Experiment,”

Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, 753-770.

California Processor Board (1993), Management Update , (October).

Cannon, Joseph P. and William D. Perreault Jr. (1999), “Buyer-Seller Relationships in Business

Markets,” Journal of Marketing Research , 36 (August), 439-460.

Chatterjee, Kalyan and Larry Samuelson (1988), “Bargaining Under Two-Sided Incomplete

Information: The Unrestricted Offers Case,”

Operations Research , 36 (4), 605-618.

Christen, Markus and Miklos Sarvary (2007) “Competitive Pricing of Information: A

Longitudinal Experiment.”

Journal of Marketing Research , 44 (February), 42-56.

Clopton, Stephen W. (1984), “Seller and Buying Firm Factors Affecting Industrial Buyers’

Negotiation Behavior and Outcomes,” Journal of Marketing Research , 21 (February), 39-53.

Eliashberg, Jehoshua, Stephen A.LaTour, Arvind Rangaswamy and Louis W.Stern (1986), “Two

Utility-Based Theories in a Marketing Channel Negotiation Context,” Journal of Marketing

Research , 23 (May), 101-110.

Ganesan, Shankar (1993), “Negotiation Strategies and the Nature of Channel Relationships,”

Journal of Marketing Research , 30 (May), 183-203.

Greenhalgh, Leonard and D.I. Chapman (1998), “Negotiator Relationships: Construct

Measurement, and Demonstration of their Impact on the Process and Outcomes of

Negotiation,”

Group Decision and Negotiation , 7 (6), 465-489.

Gupta, Sunil and Zvi A. Livne (1988), “Resolving a Conflict Situation with a Reference

Outcome: An Axiomatic Model,”

Management Science, 34 (November), 1303-1314.

Harsanyi, John C. (1995), “Games with Incomplete Information,”

American Economic Review ,

85 (4), 291-303.

Hunt, Shelby D., Nina M. Ray and Van R. Wood (1985), “Behavioral Dimensions of Channels of Distribution,” Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science , 13 (3), 1-24.

Kahneman, Daniel (1992), “Reference Points, Anchors, Norms, and Mixed Feelings,”

Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 51, 296-312.

Kristensen, Henrik and Tommy Garling (2000), “Anchor Points, Reference Points, and

Counteroffers in Negotiations.”

Group Decision and Negotiation , 9 (6), 493-905.

Maxwell, Sarah, Peter Nye and Nicholas Maxwell (2003), “The Wrath of the Fairness-Primed

Negotiator when the Reciprocity Norm is Violated,”

Journal of Business Research, 56 (5),

399-409.

McFarland, Richard G., Goutam N. Challagalla and Tassaduq A. Shervani (2006), “Influence

Tactics for Effective Adaptive Selling,”

Journal of Marketing 70 (4), 101-117.

Menasco, Michael B. and Abhik Roy (1997), “Simulated Negotiations in the Hiring of a

Salesforce Manager,”

Marketing Letters 8 (4), 381-392.

Mishra, Debi Prasad, Jan B. Heide and Stanton G. Cort (1998), “Information Asymmetry and

Levels of Agency Relationships,” Journal of Marketing Research 35 (August), 277-295.

Mumpower, Jeryl L., Jim Sheffield, Thomas A. Darling and Richard G. Milter (2004), “The

Accuracy of Post-Negotiation Estimates of the Other Negotiator’s Payoff,” Group Decision and Negotiation, 13, 259-290.

3

Myerson, Roger B. (1977), “Two Person Bargaining Problems and Comparable Utility.”

Econometrica, 45 (October), 1631-1637.

Perdue, Barbara C. and John O. Summers (1991) “Purchasing Agents Use of Negotiation

Strategies. Journal of Marketing Research 28 (May), 175-189.

Pruitt, Dean G. 1981. Negotiation Behavior . New York, NY: Academic Press, Inc.

Raiffa, Howard 1982. The Art and Science of Negotiation . Cambridge, MA: The Harvard

University Press.

Sebenius, James K. (1992), “Negotiation Analysis: A Characterization and Review.”

Management Science, 38 (January), 18-38.

Srivastava, Joydeep, Dipankar Chakravarti and Amnon Rapoport (2000), “Price and Margin

Negotiations in Marketing Channels: An Experimental Study of Sequential bargaining under

One-Sided Uncertainty and Opportunity Cost of Delay,” Marketing Science, 19 (2), 163-184.

Zwick, Rami and Ching Chyi Lee (1999), “Bargaining and Search: An Experimental Study,”

Group Decision and Negotiation, 8 (6), 463-487.

4

Download