Part 3. From Federal-State Partnership to

advertisement
From Federal-State Partnership to Advocacy Coalition: The Institutionalized
Organization of Government Support for the Arts in the U.S.
Gordon E. Shockley
Presented at:
14th Annual State Politics and Policy Conference
Indiana University – Bloomington
May 2014
Abstract
Our paper offers a possible explanation for the continued operation and ultimate survival of
the National Endowment for the Arts (NEA) and direct government support for the arts in the
1990s: political institutionalization. The thesis of our paper is that during the 1990s an “advocacy
coalition” (see Sabatier, 1993) consisting of the NEA and the state art agencies (SAAs) emerged
from the institutional environment of American cooperative federalism (e.g., Elazar, 1964) and
“marble-cake” intergovernmental relations (e.g., Grodzins, 1993). The advocacy coalition of the
NEA and the SAAs formed around a deeply shared and embedded belief in the appropriateness of
government support for the arts in the U.S. and the necessity of the federal-state partnership in its
provision. Drawing on Meyer’s General Institutional Model for organizational analysis (Meyer,
1994) and Sabatier and Jenkins-Smith’s Advocacy Coalition Framework for policy analysis (JenkinsSmith & Sabatier, 1994; Sabatier & Jenkins-Smith, 1993), we develop the Institutionalized Political
Organization (IPO) model to demonstrate how the emergence of the NEA-SAA advocacy coalition
had the primary consequence of institutionalizing government support for the arts in the U.S. Thus,
our proposed paper suggests that the political institutionalization of government support for the arts
in the U.S. provided a resilient and stable political environment that shielded the NEA from
congressional threats and enabled American arts policy to continue to operate in and ultimately
survive the 1990s.
From Federal-State Partnership
2
Introduction
By all accounts, the National Endowment for the Arts (NEA) should not have survived the
1990s. For much of its twenty-five years of existence, the NEA, which is the main federal agency
providing direct support for the arts in the U.S., existed in a relatively stable and unthreatening
political environment. Scholarly consensus characterizes the NEA’s political environment through
the 1970s and 1980s as a relatively stable and predictable subgovernment as the federal agency was
comfortably ensconced in the proverbial iron triangle (DiMaggio, 2000, p. 52; Mulcahy, 1988;
Wyszomirski, 1988, p. 19; 1995c, p. 47). However, when the Culture Wars erupted in 1989 over a
pair of controversial art exhibits associated with the NEA, a “negative policy window” (see
Wyszomirski, 1997) opened for the agency. Wyszomirski, who with good reason is considered the
leading scholar on the political dimensions of the NEA in the 1980s and 1990s, argues in a trio of
articles that the NEA’s political environment in the 1990s degenerated into a volatile and
unpredictable issue network1 (Wyszomirski, 1995b, 1995c) as its policy community became
“fragmented and truncated” (Wyszomirski, 1995c). According to Wyszomirski, therefore, the
NEA’s political environment was extremely unpredictable and unstable, leaving the agency
vulnerable to political attack.
The Republican Revolution in the congressional elections of November 1994 seemed poised
to exploit the NEA’s vulnerability and launch a final, fatal political attack on the agency. The new
Republican majority in the House of Representatives was intent on eliminating the NEA along with
several other agencies as part of the Contract With America: “The ‘termination blues’ [were] an
integral part of the hymnal for the Republican ‘Contract With America’” (deLeon, 1997, p. 2197).
According to Bimber (1998), three categories of federal agencies were targeted: (1) “the symbolic
budget trophy” agencies, like the Office of Technology Assessment; (2) “those with significant
budgets,” like the Department of Energy; and (3) “those whose missions conflicted with the new
conservatism brought to Congress by the class of 1994,” like the National Endowment for the Arts
(pp. 204-206). A section of a pivotal House budget resolution from 1995 entitled “Terminate
Funding for the National Endowment for the Arts and the National Endowment for the
Humanities” reads as follows:
1
See Heclo (1978).
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
3
Under this proposal, Federal funding for the National Endowment for the Arts and the
National Endowment for the Humanities would be eliminated. Federal funding for the arts
and humanities is not affordable in a time of fiscal stringency, especially when programs
addressing central Federal concerns are not fully funded. In addition, many arts and
humanities programs benefit predominantly higher-income people, who could pay higher
admission or ticket prices. Finally, there is serious philosophical debate about whether
financing artistic creation is an appropriate government activity in the first place. (Concurrent
Resolution on the Budget--Fiscal Year 1996 (Function 500: Education, Training, Employment, and Social
Services), 1995)
Yet, despite the NEA’s unpredictable and unstable political environment and truncated and
fragmented policy community, as well as the earnest intentions of the new Republican majority in
the 104th Congress, the NEA was not eliminated. The 104th Congress did manage to reduce the
NEA’s appropriation for fiscal year 1996 almost 40 percent and kept it at that level for the
remainder of the 1990s. Nevertheless, the NEA survived. In fact, for fiscal years 2001 and 2002,
Congress actually has modestly increased the agency’s appropriation, perhaps signaling the end of
the NEA’s woes. So the question that inevitably arises is: How did the NEA survive the 1990s?
The purpose of this paper is to develop one possible, though admittedly partial, explanation for the
NEA’s survival: the institutionalized organization of government support for the arts.
The thesis of this paper is that by the 1990s an advocacy coalition consisting of the NEA
and the fifty state arts agencies2 (SAAs) emerged from the institutional environment of American
cooperative federalism and “marble-cake” intergovernmental relations. In his two influential essays
“State Expansion and Organizational Fields” (1983) and “Decentralization of Arts Funding from the
Federal Government to the States” (1991), DiMaggio demonstrates the interdependencies and
changing relationships between the NEA and the SAAs. Expanding on DiMaggio’s two essays, this
paper argues that the federal-state partnership between the NEA and the SAAs that DiMaggio
observed in the 1980s became an “advocacy coalition,” which Sabatier (1993) defines as:
People from a variety positions (elected agency officials, interest group leaders, researchers,
etc.) who share a particular belief system—that is, a set of basic values, causal assumptions,
and problem perceptions—and who show a nontrivial degree of coordinated activity over
time (p. 25).
The advocacy coalition of the NEA and the SAAs formed around a deeply shared and embedded
belief in the appropriateness of government support for the arts in the U.S. and the necessity of
For the purposes of this paper, the term “SAAs” includes the six jurisdictional arts agencies for U.S. territories such as
Guam and Puerto Rico.
2
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
4
federal-state partnership in it provision. This NEA-SAA advocacy coalition, however, did not arise
ex nihilo; rather, an institutional environment of American cooperative federalism (e.g., Elazar, 1964)
and “marble-cake” intergovernmental relations (e.g., Grodzins, 1993) nurtured its development.
Building on Wyszomirski’s characterization of the NEA’s political environmental as fragmented,
truncated, unpredictable, and unstable, this paper suggests that the NEA-SAA advocacy coalition
provided a cohesive and reliable political environment that could resist efforts in Congress to
eliminate the agency. In short, we argue that the emergence of the NEA-SAA advocacy coalition
represents the institutionalization of government support for the arts in the U.S.
In addition to this introduction and a conclusion, we have organized this paper in three main
parts. In the first, an integrated theory of “institutionalized political organization” is developed.
The integrated theory of institutionalized political organization represents an explicit attempt to
meld General Institutional Model (Meyer, 1994), which is part of the new institutionalism in
organizational analysis, and the public policy-oriented Advocacy Coalition Framework (see generally
Jenkins-Smith & Sabatier, 1994; Sabatier & Jenkins-Smith, 1993). Four distinct stages in the
processes of institutionalized political organization are identified in Part 1: American federalism,
intergovernmental relations, federal-state partnerships, and advocacy coalitions. The remainder of
the paper is structured around these stages. The first two stages, i.e., American federalism and
intergovernmental relations, are examined in the Part 2. In Part 3, the federal-state partnership and
advocacy coalition for government support for the arts are discussed. In particular, two eras will be
examined: 1966 to 1974, during which the federal-state partnership was forged, and 1989 to 1997,
during which the advocacy coalition emerged. Wyszomirski’s characterization of the NEA’s political
environment in the 1990s as an issue network and fragmented and truncated policy network is also
explored in this part. The conclusion returns to the question of how the NEA survived the 1990s
and links the institutionalization of the federal-state partnership to the agency’s survival.
Part 1. An Integrated Theory of Institutionalized Political Organization
An integrated theory of institutionalized political organization (IPO) is developed in three
sections. In the first two sections the General Institutional Model (Meyer, 1994) and the Advocacy
Coalition Framework (ACF) (see generally Jenkins-Smith & Sabatier, 1994; Sabatier & JenkinsSmith, 1993) are reviewed in that order. In the third section of Part 1, the integrated theory of IPO
is developed from the General Institutional Model and ACF. We identify four distinct stages in
IPO: American federalism, intergovernmental relations, federal-state partnership, and advocacy
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
5
coalition. The remainder of the paper is structured around the four stages of IPO in relation to U.S.
government support for the arts.
1.1 Institutionalist Analysis of Organizations
1.1.1 Institutional Environments
Institutionalist analysis of organizations3 is a body of theory that is primarily used to explore
interactions between organizations, be they commercial, nonprofit, or governmental organizations,
and institutional environments, which can be defined “as including the rules and belief systems as
well as the relational networks that arise in the broader societal context” (Scott, 1983a, p. 14). “The
visible structures and routines that make up organizations are direct reflections and effects of rules
and structures built into (or institutionalized within) wider environments” (Scott & Meyer, 1994, p.
2). Further, there are “three classes of elements useful for assessing organizational environments:
network, cultural, and historical elements” and “three levels of environments: interorganizational
field, societal, and world-system contexts” (Scott, 1983b, p. 163).
Institutionalist organizational analysis, however, is not merely descriptive; it has strong
cognitive and normative undercurrents as well. Scott, for example, argues that “the essence of an
institutional perspective resides in focusing on the cognitive and normative frameworks that provide
meaning and stability to social life” (Scott, 1994a, p. 81). In their foundational work
“Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony” (1977/1991), Meyer and
Rowen summarize the normative concerns of institutionalist organizational analysis as institutional
legitimacy and organizational survival:
Organizations are driven to incorporate the practices and procedures defined by prevailing
rationalized concepts of organizational work and institutionalized in society. Organizations
that do so increase their legitimacy and their survival prospects, independent of the
immediate efficacy of the acquired practices and procedures. (p. 41)
Institutionalist analysis of organizations comes in many forms. Scott (1983a) observes:
“Shared belief systems and relational frameworks come together in complex and shifting ways” (p.
15). One important strain of new institutionalist research focuses on institutionalization as the
independent variable: “A substantial number of studies have examined institutional factors in
intermediate environments that influence the structure or activities of organizations” (Scott, 1994a,
p. 85). Or, as Scott and Meyer (1994) phrase it, “The environmental patterns that create and change
organizations can be described as rationalized and rationalizing” (p. 3).
3
Also commonly known as “new institutionalism in organizational analysis” (see Powell & DiMaggio, 1991)
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
6
Meyer (1994) devised a General Institutional Model that captures this line of institutional
analysis of organizations (see Figure 1).
Figure 1: Elements of a General Institutional Model (Meyer, 1994)
4. Origins of
Environmental
Rationalization
3. Dimensions of
the Rationalized
Environment
2. Mechanisms
Influencing
Organizing
Situations
1. Institutionalized
Organization
Structure
Working backward, Meyer’s model operates according to the following enumerated steps:
1. Institutionalized Organization Structure: “There is the extant set of organizations, with
their identities, structures, and activity patterns;”
2. Mechanisms Influencing Organizing Situations: “Clear causal connections can be found
linking organizational identities, structures, and activity routines to institutionalized elements
in the environment”
3. Dimensions of the Rationalized Environment: “Development or change in the rules or
ideologies describing or prescribing proper organizational practice lead organizations to
develop or change isomorphically—or to arise, in a given domain, in the first place”; and
4. Origins of Environmental Rationalization: “Macro-sociological processes prominently
affect or control development of the rationalized environment of organizing.” (pp. 33-35)
One limitation of Meyer’s General Institutional Model, however, is its uni-directionality: only
institutional environments affect organizations. An appropriate supplement to Meyer’s model may
be Giddens’ (1984) “duality of structure” in which “the structural properties of social systems are
both medium and outcome of the practices they recursively organize…Structure is not to be equated
with constraint but is always both constraining and enabling” (p. 25). In other words, not only does
an institutional environment affect an organization within its sphere of influence, but an
organization will also affect the institutional environment in which it is embedded.
1.1.2 Organizational Fields
The unit of analysis implied not only in the first step of Meyer’s General Institutional Model
(“Institutionalized Organization Structure”) but in most forms of institutionalist organizational
analysis is the organizational field. An organizational field consists of the “sets of organizations that
together accomplish some task in which a researcher is interested,” much like an “industry”
(DiMaggio, 1983, p. 148). In fact, the preferred, though not the only, unit of analysis in
institutionalist analysis is indeed the organizational field: “Neoinstitutionalists view
institutionalization as occurring at the sectoral or societal levels, and consequently
interorganizational in locus” (DiMaggio, 1991, p. 14). Similarly, Scott (1994b) favors the
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
7
organizational field : “The application of institutional arguments to organizations occurs, in my view,
most appropriately and powerfully neither at the level of the entire society not at the level of the
individual organization but at the level of the organizational field” (pp. 70-71). In fact, one of
DiMaggio’s first examples of an organizational field is the National Endowment for the Arts and the
state arts agencies.
1.1.3 Institutional Isomorphism
Institutional isomorphism is another important element of institutionalist organizational analysis.
Institutional isomorphism, which is “the tendency for organizations to take on the formal and
substantive attributes of organizations with which they interact and upon which they depend”
(DiMaggio, 1983, p. 158), is invoked in the third step of in Meyer’s General Institutional Model
(“Dimensions of the Rationalized Environment”): “Development or change in the rules or
ideologies…lead organizations to develop or change isomorphically” (emphasis added). Institutional
isomorphism is the specific mechanism by which institutional environments influence organizational
fields.
Through the operation of institutional isomorphism, organizations in a given institutional
environment will typically behave in a predictable and orderly way. First, organizations “incorporate
elements which are legitimated externally, not necessarily efficient ones.” Second, “they employ
ceremonial assessment criteria to define the value of structural elements.” And third, the
“dependence of externally fixed institutions reduces turbulence and maintains stability” in
organizations (Meyer & Rowan, 1991, p. 49). Moreover, DiMaggio and Powell (1983) identify three
varieties of isomorphic activity: (1) coercive isomorphism, which results from political influence and the
problem of legitimacy; (2) mimetic isomorphism, which results from the standard response to
uncertainty of imitating organizations in an organizational field that are successful; and (3) normative
isomorphism, which results from shared beliefs and community norms, such as those that stem from
professionalization (see DiMaggio & Powell, 1991b).
1.2 The Advocacy Coalition Framework
Pure, unassisted institutionalist analysis of organizations is difficult to apply in policy
analysis4 (to be fair, Meyer names his model the General Institutional Model). Its main impediment
Many new institutionalist scholars explicitly differentiate institutionalism in organizational analysis from the “new
institutionalisms” in political science and economics. They also doubt that any rapprochement is possible (see, for
example, DiMaggio & Powell, 1991a; Meyer, 1994). The integrated theory of institutionalized political organization
4
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
8
is the lack of any explicit or even implicit political dimension component in organizational analysis,
which, as March and Olsen (1984) demonstrated nearly two decades ago, is necessary for balanced
political or public policy analysis. In order to redress this limitation of institutionalist organizational
analysis, we enlist Sabatier and Jenkins-Smith’s Advocacy Coalition Framework (ACF) (JenkinsSmith & Sabatier, 1994; Sabatier & Jenkins-Smith, 1993) and seek to integrate ACF with
institutionalist analysis of organizations.
In its essence, ACF is a theory of gradual, incremental policy change over a long period of
time through the interaction of advocacy coalitions. Sabatier summarizes ACF as follows:
I have concluded that the most useful means of aggregating actors in order to understand
policy change over fairly long periods of time is by ‘advocacy coalitions.’ These are people
from a variety of positions (elected agency officials, interest group leaders, researchers, etc.)
who share a particular belief system—that is, a set of basic values, causal assumptions, and
problem perceptions—and who show a nontrivial degree of coordinated activity over time.
(Sabatier, 1993, p. 25)
Four premises underlie Sabatier’s summarization above: time, policy subsystems, intergovernmental relations,
and belief systems (Sabatier, 1993, p. 16). First, the time frame of policy analysis must be a decade or
more. Second, the policy subsystem, which consists of the “interaction of actors from different
institutions who follow and seek to influence governmental decisions in a policy area,” is the proper
level of analysis for an advocacy coalition. Third, ACF emphasizes the “intergovernmental
dimension of policy subsystems.” Lastly, belief systems, not interests, are the causal agent: “public
policies (or programs) can be conceptualized in the same manner as belief systems.” Briefly, ACF
contends that the long-term interaction of advocacy coalitions formed around a belief system within
an intergovernmental policy subsystem produce incremental, gradual policy change over a long
period of time (see Figure 2).
developed in this paper obviously assumes otherwise and is consistent with a growing, perhaps even established,
tradition of political institutional analysis.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
9
Figure 2: The Advocacy Coalition Framework of Policy Change (Sabatier & Jenkins-Smith, 1993, p. 18)
RELATIVELY STABLE
PARAMETERS
1. Basic attributes of the
problem area (good)
2. Basic distribution of
natural resources
3. Fundamental
sociocultural values and
social structure
4. Basic constitutional
structure (rules)
POLICY SUBSYSTEM
Constraints
and
Coalition A
a. Policy beliefs
b. Resources
Policy
Brokers
Coalition B
a. Policy beliefs
b. Resources
Resources
of
Strategy A1
re guidance
instruments
Subsystem
Strategy B1
re guidance
instruments
Actors
EXTERNAL (SYSTEM)
EVENTS
Decisions
by Sovereigns
1. Changes in
socioeconomic conditions
2. Changes in systemic
governing collation
3. Policy decisions and
impacts from other
subsystems
Agency resources
and General Policy
Orientation
Policy Outputs
Policy Impacts
The fourth premise (i.e., “public policies (or programs) can be conceptualized in the same
manner as belief systems”) requires further elaboration. “Within the subsystem,” Jenkins-Smith
(1994) maintains, “the ACF assumes that actors can be aggregated into a number of advocacy
coalitions composed of people from various governmental and private organizations who share a set
of normative and causal beliefs and who often act in concert” (p. 180). The belief system around
which an advocacy coalition forms is hierarchically arranged in three levels. At the top is the deep core
that consists of “basic ontological and normative beliefs, such as the perceived nature of humans or
the relative valuation of individual freedom or social equality, which operate across virtually all
policy domains” (Jenkins-Smith & Sabatier, 1994, p. 180). The next level is the policy core that is “a
coalition’s basic normative commitments and causal perceptions across an entire policy domain or
subsystem” (Jenkins-Smith & Sabatier, 1994, p. 180). At the lowest level are the secondary beliefs:
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
10
A large set of narrower beliefs concerning the seriousness of the problem or the relative
importance of various causal factors in specific locales, policy preferences regarding desirable
regulations or budgetary allocations, the design of specific institutions, and the evaluations of
various actors’ performance (Jenkins-Smith & Sabatier, 1994, p. 181).
This three-level, hierarchical belief system lies at the heart of each advocacy coalition.
ACF generates at least eleven hypotheses for testing policy change over long periods of time.
For the purposes of integrating ACF with institutionalist organizational analysis, only three are of
interest for the purposes of this paper:
1. Hypothesis 1: “On major controversies within a policy subsystem when policy core beliefs
are in dispute, the lineup of allies and opponents tends to be rather stable over periods of a
decade or more” (Jenkins-Smith & Sabatier, 1994, p. 184; Sabatier, 1993, p. 27).
2. Hypothesis 2: “Actors within a an advocacy coalition will show substantial consensus on
issues pertaining to policy core but less so on secondary aspects” (Jenkins-Smith & Sabatier,
1994, p. 184; Sabatier, 1993, p. 31).
3. Hypothesis 3: “An actor or coalition will give up secondary aspects of a belief system
before acknowledging weaknesses in the policy core” (Jenkins-Smith & Sabatier, 1994, p.
184; Sabatier, 1993, p. 33).
1.3 An Integrated Theory of Institutionalized Political Organization
In this final section of Part 1 we attempt to integrate ACF and institutionalist organizational
analysis. The result of our integration is the Institutionalized Political Organization model. Our
integration seeks to preserve the basic institutional environment-organizational field framework of
institutionalist analysis described above while at the same time explicitly incorporating the political
and policy dimensions, thus ameliorating the main limitation of institutionalist analysis and making it
more appropriate for political analysis.5
ACF introduces to new institutionalism three kinds of greater political specificity. First,
ACF at once refines the institutionalist level of analysis into a political unit of analysis and maintains the
same level of analysis by moving from organizational fields to policy subsystems. In other words, policy
subsystems are distinctly political group actors that occupy the same level of analysis as new
institutionalist organizational fields. Sabatier’s definition of a policy subsystem as the “interaction of
It should be noted that ACF itself is not a complete model. Although ACF is a robust theoretical apparatus for policy
analysis, it suffers from at least one weakness that institutionalist organizational analysis might address: namely, the
creation and maintenance of advocacy coalitions. Schlager (1995), for example, attempts to ameliorate this weakness of
ACF with the Ostrom’s Institutional Analysis and Design framework (e.g., see E. Ostrom, 1999) as well as Moe’s theory
of structural choice. Similarly, Sato (1999) augments ACF with Policy Process Analysis in order to provide “details of
how coalitions evolve and how they actually translate their beliefs into governmental behaviors are examined” (p. 28).
One of the benefits of integrating ACF with institutionalist analysis of organizations might also be providing an
explanation of how advocacy coalitions are created and maintained: namely, through the influence of institutional
environments.
5
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
11
actors from different institutions who follow and seek to influence governmental decisions in a
policy area” corresponds with DiMaggio’s original formulation of organizational fields as “sets of
organizations that together accomplish some task in which a researcher is interested.” Policy
subsystems, however, are distinctly political actors in that they can be conceptualized to have their
own internal and external political economies (see Wamsley, 1985). Policy subsystems are also
explicitly concerned with public policy, or what Rainey and Milward (1983) call the “primacy of the
program”: “In governmental processes in the United States, the most important focus of activity is
frequently not a specific public organizations but a complex network of organizations and other
entities whose activities are often centered on a particular public ‘program’” (p. 140). In other
words, ACF policy subsystems maintain the same level of group actors as new institutionalism while
recognizing the political intentions of their actions.
The second political dimension ACF introduces into institutionalist organizational analysis is
intergovernmental relations. Intergovernmental relations allows for greater specificity in the kinds
of interaction between group actors. Kenis and Schneider (1991) observe,
Policies are formulated to an increasing degree in informal political infrastructures outside
conventional channels such as legislative, executive and administrative organizations.
Contemporary policy processes emerge from complex actor constellations and resource
interdependencies, and decisions are often made in a highly decentralized and informal
matter. (p. 27)
The ACF emphasis on intergovernmental relations reduces the possible scope of new institutionalist
analysis by limiting the analysis to interaction between policy-making actors.
The third political dimension ACF introduces is an exclusive focus on public policy.
Specifically, ACF incorporates accommodates the normative basis of policy subsystems in general
and advocacy coalitions in particular. Milward and Wamley (1984) observe that a policy subsystem’s
“normative structure gives meaning to the action of the members of the subsystem/network and the
use to which the tools are put” (p. 13), which sounds very similar to the cognitive and normative
dimensions of institutionalist organizational analysis. Moreover, they assert, the paramount value in
a policy subsystem’s normative structure is survival: “Self-perpetuation of the policy subsystem is the
most consistently shared goal of the participants. If authority and funding of its correlated programs
or its functional autonomy are threatened, this will tend to enhance consensus” (p. 16). These three
political dimensions introduced by ACF, we argue, transform institutionalist organizational analysis
into a framework for policy analysis, specifically, into our integrated Institutionalized Political
Organization (IPO) model.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
12
Figure 3: Elements of the Institutionalized Political Organization (IPO) model
1. American
Federalism
2. Intergovernmental Relations
3. Federal-State
Partnership
4. Advocacy
Coalition
Belief System
Deep Core
|
Policy Core
|
Secondary Beliefs
1.
2.
3.
4.
Origins of Environmental Rationalization  American Federalism
Dimensions of the Rationalized Environment  Intergovernmental Relations
Mechanisms Influencing Organizing Situations  Federal-State Partnership
Institutionalized Organization Structure  Advocacy Coalition
We present the IPO model in Figure 3. The model is explicitly structured around Meyer’s
General Institutional Model (Figure 1 above) and incorporates ACF terminology into each boxprocess caption. Three annotations are appropriate. First, the cascading process boxes of Figure 3
indicate a general-specific, hierarchical relationship between the components. Second, the box
containing the “Belief System” makes explicit the normative, creedal component of the model.
Third, Figure 3 shows that the overtly political elements of IPO model supplant the more general
elements of Meyer’s General Institutional Model. And the process works forward this time. The
IPO model depicted in Figure structures the remainder of this paper in order to explore the
institutionalized organization of government support for the arts in the U.S.
Part 2. Institutional Environment of Federal-State Programs
In Part 2, we present the application of the first two steps of IPO. Together Step 1
(“Federalism”) and Step 2 (“Intergovernmental Relations”) of IPO constitute the institutional
environment surrounding not only government support for the arts in the U.S. but also federal-state
programs in general. The institutional environment therefore originates in American federalism,
which in turn gives rise to “complex” and “interdependent” web of federal and state relationships
categorically called “intergovernmental relations” (generally see O'Toole Jr., 1985).
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
13
2.1 American cooperative federalism
On its face, the American federalist political system6 does not seem to be designed for
cooperative relations between the national and state governments. In Federalist No. 51, James
Madison conceived of American federalism as a “compound republic” in which state power was
subdivided so as to provide a check on its concentration: “In the compound republic of America,
the power surrendered by the people is first divided between two distinct governments, and then the
portion allotted to each subdivided among distinct and separate departments.” Nevertheless, a
tradition of “cooperative federalism” between the national and state governments has emerged in
the U.S. in which positive and mutually beneficial relationships between federal and state actors
could form. In operation, it requires a willingness both to cooperate across government lines and to
exercise restraint and forbearance in the interests of the entire nation” (Leach, 1970, pp. 1-2).
Grodzins (1993) and Elazar (1964; 1966) have been instrumental in articulating the American
tradition of cooperative federalism. Cooperative federalism, according to Elazar (1966), is “an intricate
framework of cooperative relationships that preserve their structural integrity while tying all levels of
government together functionally in the common task of serving the American people” (p. 2).
The tension in American federalism between shared rule and self-rule might be considered
the distinguishing feature of American federalism (Watts, 1998). The Framers intentionally built the
tension into the U.S. Constitution: “Hamilton and Madison recognized that a proper federal system
involves concurrent jurisdiction on the part of a limited national government and limited state
governments that independently exercise concurrent jurisdiction with reference to individuals” (V.
Ostrom, 1991, pp. 90-91). There is a growing body of literature that argues that the tension has
been alleviated, if not resolved, through cooperative federalism. Inman and Rubinfeld (1997), for
example, define cooperative federalism as follows:
The principle of cooperative federalism is to prefer the most decentralized structure of
government capable of internalizing all economic externalities, subject to the constitutional
constraint that all central government policies are agreed to unanimously by the elected
representatives from each of the lower-tiered governments” (p. 48)
The tradition of cooperative federalism may have its origins in the nineteenth century. Elazar
(1964) argues that cooperative federalism was the most common modal relationship between the
national and state governments in the 19th century: “Federalism in the United States, in practice if
Watts (1998) observes that there are at least three substantially different meanings of the concept of “federalism”:
federalism as a normative concept, federal political systems, and federations. In this paper, federalism means federal
political systems: “The term federal political systems, distinct from federalism or federations, is the descriptive term
referring to the genus of political organization that is marked by the combination of shared rule and self-rule” (p. 120).
6
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
14
not in theory, has traditionally been cooperative, so that virtually all the activities of government in
the nineteenth century were shared activities, involving federal, state, and local governments in their
planning, financing, and execution” (p. 249). Zimmerman (2001) delineates five tenets of
cooperative federalism (p. 20):
1. “Each plane of government possesses certain autonomous powers that may be exercised
cooperatively, with such cooperation initiated by either plane.
2. “One place of government does not coerce the other place of government.
3. “The roles of Congress in terms of national-state relations are facilitating and leadership
ones.
4. “Congress uses its power to regulate interstate commerce to assist states by prohibiting use
of such commerce in violation of state laws.
5. “Cooperation is negotiated.”
Similarly, the cooperative component of Rich’s “transformed federalism” in the context of
American health care “recognizes the interdependence of two levels of government, the necessary
sharing of functions, the need for the revenue of both levels, and it further recognizes the leverage
one level can exert on the other” (Rich, 2002). In short, as Elazar (1966) puts it, cooperative
federalism is “an intricate framework of cooperative relationships that preserve their structural
integrity while tying all levels of government together functionally in the common task of serving the
American people” (p. 2).
2.2 Marble-cake intergovernmental relations
Grodzin devised the metaphor of “marble-cake” federalism to describe the national-state
intergovernmental relations that arise from cooperative federalism. Grodzin (1993) writes, “The
American form of government is often symbolized by a three-layer cake. A far more accurate image
is the rainbow or marble cake, characterized by an inseparable mingling of differently colored
ingredients, the colors appearing in vertical and diagonal strands and unexpected whirls” (p. 57).
Marble-cake federalism may have a role in increasing state governmental powers: “[‘Marble-cake
federalism’] in state-national intergovernmental relations suggests that national policymakers may
play a role in determining state and local public sector capacity” (Bohte & Meier, 2000, p. 41).
Marble-cake federalism might best be characterized as the incarnation of cooperative federalism in
the real world of national-state intergovernmental relations. Perhaps marble-cake federalism is more
appropriately called “marble-cake intergovernmental relations.”
Cooperative federalism has provided the structure in which “marble-cake”
intergovernmental relations could develop. The notion of marble-cake intergovernmental relations
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
15
is primarily distinguished by a high degree of interdependence between the national and state
governments. Hall (1989) writes,
The states and the federal government—participate in a wide sharing of functions. This
theory of shared governance has moved American federalism out of the age of ‘layer cake
federalism’ and into the age of ‘marble cake federalism.’ The various governments share—at
least partially—in the decisions regarding governmental actions as well as cooperating in the
implementation of public policies (p. 27).
The cooperative spirit in marble-cake intergovernmental relations are at odds with Walker’s (19801981) “dysfunctional federalism”: “The prime symptom of this deepening dysfunctionalism is the
continuing tendency to ‘intergovernmentalize’ seemingly everything that becomes a public issue-and,
increasingly, everything becomes a public issues [sic]” (p. 1194). In marble-cake intergovernmental
relations the “tendency to ‘intergovernmentalize’ seemingly everything” is a sign of functional
health, not dysfunctional malaise.
When the national government seeks to implement a program, American federalism creates
what Stoker calls the “implementation paradox.” Stoker (1991) writes, “It can be argued that the
implementation process is a paradox if reluctant partners dilute the authority of federal officials and,
thereby, diminish the ability of national government to achieve its ends” (p. 15). As a result, he
continues, “a diffuse distribution of authority complicates the development and implementation of
national policy and implies that cooperation among numerous centers of authority is often the key
to effectiveness” (p. 18). In the intergovernmental context of ACF, Ellison (1998) describes this as
the “autonomy-policy fragmentation continuum”. Ellison defines autonomy as “the struggle to
build jurisdictional control over substantive policy areas by members of a coalition” (p. 42); and,
according to Ellison, policy fragmentation “occurs when responsibilities for the delivery of public
goods and services are shared by agencies from different governments, and also when legislatures
give agencies disparate goals” (p. 42). But Stoker’s paradox only holds true if on the federal and
state governmental actors in a governmental program truly are “reluctant partners” with a high
degree of policy fragmentation. If the spirit of cooperation instead of reluctance predominates,
however, then it follows that the paradox dissolves.
Beer’s concept of the intergovernmental lobby (see Beer, 1976, 1977, 1978) implies that
modern intergovernmental relations are more appropriately characterized as a positive feedback
loop. Premised on Anton’s (1989) notion that government actors are not “passive instruments” (p.
33), Beer (1977) characterizes the “intergovernmental lobby” as “the governors, mayors, county
supervisors, city managers, and other officeholders, usually elective, who exercise general
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
16
responsibilities in state and local governments…” and who attempt to influence national
government policy (p. 11).7 In fact, Beer (1976) argues, the positive feedback loop has driven the
growth in the size of government. “In intergovernmental relations, the flow of power was not
unidirectional, but complex and interactive” (pp. 163-164). DiMaggio (1983) makes a similar point
from the sociological perspective: “As the bureaucratization of organizations was stimulated by the
growth of the modern economy, so the ‘structuration’ of relations among organizations is promoted
by the expansion of the modern state” (p. 150). The intergovernmental lobby grew with the general
increase in the post-WWII powers of the state.
The intergovernmental lobby most likely is so successful because of its advantage in gaining
access to national policy makers in the same policy arena. O’Toole (1985) suggests that the
intergovernmental lobby arose under Johnson’s “creative federalism” (see immediately below) as the
interests in national governmental programs multiplied: “Those concerned with specific
intergovernmental programs, whether on environmental pollution or juvenile delinquency,
increasingly looked to Washington as they tried to influence legislation and implementing
regulations, to monitor the actions of the federal agency involved, and to maintain contact with
other interested parties” (p. 11). Then, on top of state actors’ interests, their ‘public official status’”
(Cammisa, 1995, p. 23) allowed them greater access to national policy makers. Their persistence no
doubt also helped: “Coalition and alliance building is a way of life for the government interest
groups, specially on maters of important legislation or funding” (Haider, 1974, p. 233). The
intergovernmental lobby thus facilitated a vibrant cooperative federalism and effective marble-cake
intergovernmental relations to emerge from the American federalist system during the last four
decades.
2.2.1 The Johnson Administration’s Great Society programs
The Johnson Administration’s Great Society programs were typically designed under the
assumption that government had not only the capacity but also the responsibility to intervene in
social relations. “Johnson,” O’Toole writes, “proposed a ‘creative federalism that would signify
multiple new national commitments to assist states, localities, and private individuals and
organizations in their efforts to solve many of the domestic difficulties afflicting society” (p. 10).
Further, as Lowi (1979) notes, “The mark of the new liberalism was its assumption that the
instruments of government provided the means for conscious inducement of social change” (p. 42).
Anton’s (1989) “benefit coalition,” in which “any association of individuals, often representing other individuals, who
mobilize to develop, support, and implement government benefit programs,” is similar to Beer’s lobby (p. 32).
7
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
17
Governmental intervention usually took the form of social programs providing services: “The main
thrust of the Great Society was expressed in programs providing, not money, not regulation, but
specialized services delivered by technically trained people for the benefit of defined categories of
persons. This services strategy arose from the new professionalism” (Beer, 1977, p. 13). Conlan
(1998c) summarizes the major growth in the power of the state during the late 1960s as follows:
“The number of new federal grant programs—especially narrow and often unpredictable
programs—nearly tripled between 1960 and 1968, from 132 to 379” (p. 6). “The federal
government,” Conlan summarizes, “became more involved in virtually all existing fields of
government activity…In addition, new public functions were established” (p. 5).
The intergovernmental lobby fully developed under the Johnson Administration’s Great
Society programs. The intergovernmental lobby grew from the national government’s increased
reliance on the state government for the implementation of national programs: “As the federal
government in the Great Society period extended its responsibilities by means of state and local
governments, it also became dependent on them for the successful discharge of these
responsibilities” (Beer, 1976, p. 163). Thus state governments’ “heightened the concern and
increased the contacts” (Beer, 1976, p. 163) with the national government motivated the
development of the intergovernmental lobby. Conlan (1998c) observes:
Then in the 1960s the intergovernmental system began to evolve at an accelerated pace. The
ensuing changes in the scope, content, and structure of federal assistance programs not only
made the system far more complex, but also upset the temporary balance of
intergovernmental power that had been achieved. Sweeping changes were ushered in by the
Great Society. (p. 5)
Not surprisingly, as the national government became more dependent on the state government for
implementation, the state governments became more dependent on the national government for
resources. “State and local governments’ financial dependence on federal funding increased by 35
percent. Federal aid increased from 17 percent of state and local own-source revenues in 1960 to 23
percent in 1970” (Conlan, 1998c, p. 6). Marble-cake intergovernmental relations under the Johnson
Administration were incarnate in the complex interdependencies between U.S. national and state
governments.
2.2.2 Federalism in the 1990s
Of course it should be emphasized that national-state interdependencies in
intergovernmental relations should not be construed as a diminution of the national government’s
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
18
power. During the 1990s the federal government was still immensely powerful. Derthick (2001)
notes that “the trend in this most important area of government activity [i.e., intergovernmental
relations] is toward centralization…Major steps have been taken toward nationalization of income
support programs.” The centralization of power, however, has not been accompanied by growth of
the state as it was under the Johnson Administration. “The past fifteen years have reversed many of
these trends [in growth in federal government activity and influence, increasing centralization of
activities, and rising proportions of federal budget spending on grants to state and local
governments]” (Cole, Stenberg, & Weissert, 1996, pp. 38-39). Nonetheless, the national government
remains staggeringly powerful.
State governments nevertheless increased their powers in the 1990s. The Republican
Revolution in November 1994 was by most measures an important event in intergovernmental
relations. For example,
By an impressively wide margin, the most important event affecting intergovernmental
relations in this period, as evaluated by the total group of respondents, was the 1994
elections where the Republican party won control of both Houses of Congress and thirty
governorships (Cole et al., 1996, p. 31).
The intergovernmental lobby found two new tactics of influence: “First, they secured the passage of
legislation that forced Congress to take account of their interests [i.e., Unfunded Mandates Reform
Act (UMRA)]. Second, they relied on “relationships between individual governors and congressmen
[i.e., Republican governors and the Republican majority in Congress] in order to advance their goals
in particular policy areas” (Dinan, 1997, p. 136). For its part, the 104th Congress: “Conservatives in
the fourth phase have tried to decrease both federal spending and the ‘strings’ attached to such
spending” (Cammisa, 1995, p. 6). The 104th Congress offered the states great promise.
The promise for intergovernmental relations in the 104th Congress was greater than the
reality. “The budget resolution passed by the House on May 18, 1995, would have launched a true
‘devolution revolution’ if I had been fully implemented. Instead, it represented the high-water mark
of reforms in the 104th Congress” (Conlan, 1998a, p. 238). The result, as Conlan (1998b) observes,
was that devolution of authority and resources to state government has been evolutionary, not
revolutionary: devolution has truly been a “halting and gradual experiments in devolving functions
from the federal government to state and local governments” (Conlan, 1998b, p. 292). Although the
104th Congress hardly spurred the fabled “devolution revolution,” it did enable state governments to
grow still further in power and influence.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
19
Part 3. From Federal-State Partnership to Advocacy Coalition
In Part 3 we present the application of Steps 3 and 4 of IPO to government support for the
arts in the U.S. In Part 2 we developed the institutional environment of IPO (Steps 1 and 2). The
main themes of Part 2 were cooperative federalism, the growth of the power of the states, and the
parity of the power of states and the intergovernmental lobby vis-à-vis the national government. In
Part 3, these elements of the institutional environment components are used to explain the
emergence of a federal-state advocacy coalition for government support of the arts in the U.S.
3.1 Federal-State Partnership, 1966-1974
3.1.1 The National Endowment for the Arts
In 1965 Congress established the National Endowment for the Arts (NEA) by passing the
National Foundation on the Arts and Humanities (NFAH). Support for the arts before (and after)
1965 was decidedly private in nature. But a national governmental program to promote excellence
in the arts was consistent with the spirit of public policy during the Johnson’s Great Society
initiatives. “The theme from the Kennedy years of the quest for excellence in American civilization,
subsequently adopted by Johnson’s Great Society, was perhaps the most persuasive argument of all
[for passing the National Foundation on the Arts and Humanities]” (Larson, 1983, p. 193).8 As in
most Great Society programs, the implementation of NFAH would rely on a federal-state
partnership. Roger Stevens, the NEA’s first chairman and one of only a handful of individuals
responsible for setting up and implementing NFAH, “pushed for ‘grassroots’ support in the
enabling legislation, which included state arts council provisions as part of a "definite program of
assistance for the arts” (Mark, 1991, p. 49). Chairman Stevens got his wish.
The federal-state partnership in government support for the arts in the U.S. formed very
much in the spirit of American cooperative federalism and marble-cake intergovernmental relations.
Horowitz (1986) writes that the federal-state partnership was “being done through a very broad
range of programs and done not as a partnership in the sense of formal contract, but as a sharing of
responsibilities and a set of working relationships between the several levels of government” (p. 1).
From the beginning, the national program for government support of the arts would be
decentralized to the states: “it is through the NEA/SAA [i.e., federal-state] partnership in the Basic
State Grants that the states are enabled to reach all congressional districts, including those the NEA
8
Also see Cummings, Jr. (1982; 1991) for further insight into the early NEA.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
20
does not” (Love, 1991, p. 218). The introduction to a manual on the federal-state partnership for
the arts reads as follows:
Our system of state governments, though cumbersome and antiquated in many respects,
creates an unexpected framework of diversity for the distribution of arts patronage. The
diffusion of this patronage through a series of local, autonomous authorities throughout the
country provides a way of resisting and counteracting any trend to an ‘official establishment’
culture controlled by a single authority or source of funds. (Adams, 1966, p. ix)
Thus, the system of government support for the arts in the U.S. by design would be cooperative and
marble-caked.
3.1.1.1 Grants and implementation
More specifically, the implementation of federal-state partnership was structured as a block
grant program with the purpose of stimulating the vast majority of the fifty states and (at that time)
four U.S. territories to establish state arts agencies (SAAs). Urice (1992) observes that “virtually all
the literature on the formative stages of state arts agencies cites the essential role and stimulus of the
federal government” (p. 21). Indeed, Netzer in his seminal work The Subsidized Muse (1978) asserts:
“With a few exceptions, these state arts councils resulted not from an autonomous rise of interest in
patronizing the arts on the part of state governments but from the availability of NEA funds for that
purpose” (p. 90).
Stein (1984) describes the generic federal-state implementation process in evolutionary
terms: “I conceive of implementation in a federal system as a multi-staged process that occurs over
an extended period of time (i.e., the life of the grant). During this time effects form one stage
structure or restructure successive steps in the implementation process” (p. 141). Stein identifies
four specific steps in the implementation process:
1.
2.
3.
4.
Utilization/participation in the federal aid system
Allocation of aid monies to recipients
Donor-recipient negotiations
Feedback to the legislative process (i.e., policy reformulation)
In sum, Stein conceives of the federal-state implementation process as laced with financial
incentives—in a word, grants.
The use of the grant is one of the most powerful government tools available to the federal
government for the implementation of national programs on a state and local level. The basic
economic theory of grants “commodifies” them and gives the federal government monopoly
powers: “In essence, the economic theory of grants conceptualizes state and local governments and
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
21
the citizens within them as consumers whose consumption the national government seeks to
influence by manipulating their income and the process that pay for public goods” (Chubb, 1985, p.
997). The federal government’s monopoly on national grants, therefore, is a source of power in
intergovernmental relations.
The federal-state partnership between the NEA and the state arts agencies (SAAs) was laden
with financial incentives. According to the guidelines of the Federal-State Partnership Program,
State Arts Agencies are eligible to receive assistance under established guideline for any of
the Endowment’s 12 major programs. However, the Endowment’s Federal-State
Partnership Program specifically reflects the national interest in the very existence of
effective State Arts Agencies which play an important part in strengthening the cultural life
of the nation. This program recognizes that the Federal and State interests in cultural
development are intertwined, and that cooperation between the National Endowment and
State Arts Agencies strengthens the help each can provide their mutual constituencies.”
(NCA, 1975, p. 1)
NEA grants were therefore the sine qua non for the creation of most SAAs; SAAs were “creatures of
the NEA” (see DiMaggio, 1991).
Figure 4: A General Model for State Participation in Federal Grant-in-Aid Programs (Hofferbert & Urice, 1985,
p. 313)
State
Institutional
Attributes
State
Sociopolitical
Contexts
Federal
Stimulus
State Level of
Policy
Participation
Institutional
Attributes
State
Policy
Norms
Hofferbert and Urice’s conception of the NEA-SAA partnership and the “federal stimulus”
is depicted in Figure 4. Most SAAs did not exist before the availability of the NEA grants: “Most
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
22
legislatures, however, required further justification for state arts patronage. Two reasons ultimately
proved persuasive: free federal money and urban economic relief” (Svenson, 1982, p. 197). Many
SAAs were created only to be eligible to receive such grants: “In some states, however, arts councils
began as little more than skeletal structures set up to qualify for federal grants” (Arian, 1989, p. 99).
Hofferbert and Urice (1985) observe,
While simultaneous creation cannot be totally disproved, it is highly unlikely that movement
toward state arts funding, through specifically identified and designated agencies, would have
spread universally in so short a time without incentive offered through NEA programs (p.
312).
A milestone year in the program was 1974 because “it was the first year, when all 50 states as well as
the District of Columbia, Guam, American Samoa, Puerto Rico and the Virgin Islands had an arts
agency in operation for the full year” (Simmons, 1978, p. 1). As a consequence, the federal-state
partnership between the NEA and the SAAs was widely hailed a success. As Mulcahy (1988)
observes,
If there is one great success story emerging from these [set of eight, pre-1989] hearings, it is
the partnership forged by the Arts Endowment with the ‘little NEAs’ in the states and
localities. The mutually beneficial nature of this relationship—politically and
administratively—was cited repeatedly. So, too, was the value of the state programs in
spreading the benefits of the arts to diverse constituents. Fostering the growth of state arts
agencies may have been the NEA’s single most important achievement. It gave the arts a
strong local visibility and elicited state governments’ permanent commitment. (p. 79)
The federal-state partnership in government support for the arts might have been the quintessential
Johnson Administration program.
3.1.1.2 Constituency-building
Constituency-building under Nancy Hanks, the NEA’s second chair (1968–1977), was a
deliberate augmentation of the federal-state partnership that at once sought to maintain the
partnership while garnering support from other sectors. The tenure of Hanks was “marked by the
maturation of each of the components of the potential arts-policy triangle, as well as by the
enhancement of presidential support for the new agency and its programs” (Wyszomirski, 1988, p.
19). The NEA operated according to a “logic of constituency formation” in which the agency
worked to build a national constituency to support its efforts to garner larger appropriations from
Congress” (DiMaggio, 2000, p. 52). Wyszomirski (1995a) identifies five “axioms” of national arts
policy under Hanks’ leadership (p. 72):
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
1)
2)
3)
4)
5)
23
Growing public interest and financial support;
Increasingly positive political regard with low visibility;
Largely unchallenged artistic control of the grant decision making process;
Recurrent pattern of awards gave the appearance of entitlements; and
Reliance on federal validation and legitimation of art world trends.
To build these constituencies, the NEA used the same instruments and levers as they did to nurture
the federal-state partnership. “But in terms of pure political clout, the grant money the agency
dispenses has helped it build allies in communities across the nation…The availability of federal
subsidies explains why it draws Republican support not only from moderates, but also many
conservatives, especially in the Senate” (Freedman, 1997 p. 626). One of the salutary effects of the
NEA’s constituency-building was “the creation of a vertical network of public and private art
agencies from Washington to local communities” (DiMaggio, 1983, p. 151).
Figure 5: Cultural Subgovernment (The Arts Policy Making Triangle) (Mulcahy, 1988, p. 62)
National Endowment for the Arts
(also National Endowment for the Humanities
and Institute for Museum Services
State and Local Arts Agencies, Cultural
Institutions and Arts Service Organizations
Agencies
Interest
Groups
Congressional Subcommittees
House Select/Postsecondary Education Subcommittees
Senate education, Arts, and Humanities Subcommittee
House and Senate Appropriations Subcommittee
Another salutary effect of the Hanks-driven constituency-building was the NEA becoming
comfortably ensconced in an “old iron triangle.” In addition to the NEA and the relevant
authorizing and appropriations congressional subcommittees occupying two angles, “interest
groups” such as state and local arts agencies and arts service organizations occupied the final vertex
(Mulcahy, 1988). Consequently, for the first two decades of its existence, NEA management of
direct government support for the arts was a “relatively simple distributive policy sub-government
focused on increasing financial resources for the NEA and, through it, to the arts constituency”
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
24
(Wyszomirski, 1995c, p. 47). Figure 5 illustrates this “cultural subgovernment.” In short, the Hanks’
gains for the NEA were impressive:
When Nancy Hanks took office in October 1969, the NEA was a small, threatened, drifting
agency teetering on the brink of its initial survival threshold. By the time she resigned with
years later, the NEA had become institutionalized and could claim both programmatic and
political successes. (Wyszomirski, 1996, p. 122)
An irony of the federal government’s use of grants, however, is that they have stimulated a
concomitant increase in the power and influence of the states.
Not all of the increase in national power came at the expense of states’ rights. The national
government mandates compliance with some of its objectives, but more often it relies on
inducements to achieve its ends. These inducements or incentives generally take the form of
financial assistance that is made available to governments to pursue national goals. (Hanson,
1999, p. 39)
Largely because of what Beam and Conlan (2002) call the “high automaticity”9 of grants, the more
the national government relied on grants more as incentives, the better state governments were able
to negotiate and bargain with the federal government. Ingram (1977) characterizes “implementation
as bargaining.” “The result is a process of implementation that is a complex succession of bids and
counterbids between the state and federal levels during which the initial aims of each are
substantially modified” (p. 502). Eventually, the market power of state governments increased and
they came away from negotiations with better deals from the national government. Beer (1977)
observes: “In time the intergovernmental lobby acquitted sufficient political influence to initiate
demands more closely reflecting its members’ political interests. A major demand was fewer federal
strings on more federal money” (p. 12). The increase in state powers, however, has not been so
much been the diminution of national power as the increase in the powers of all levels of
government. As Hanson (1999) writes,
The use of incentives to bring about compliance by states with national objectives has
generated a concomitant expansion of state powers. All levels of government have become
more active in the twentieth century, not just the national government. (p. 39)
“Automaticity measures the extent to which a tool utilizes an existing administrative structure (e.g. the market system
or the tax system) to produce its effect rather than having to create its own special administrative apparatus. From the
point of view of the granting government, grants rank fairly high in terms of automaticity since they essentially involve
relying on the administrative systems of other entities to carry out particular functions (e.g. provision of education, social
services, highway construction, policing” (Beam & Conlan, 2002)
9
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
25
DiMaggio warned of the double-edged sword of the NEA’s constituency building nearly
twenty years ago: “The constituencies they encourage may turn into lobbying groups that support
them in times of crisis, or Frankensteins [sic] that level greater and greater demands” (DiMaggio,
1983, p. 155). For a time it looked like the SAAs may have been Frankensteins. By 1975, the state
challenged the Endowment vigorously, demanding more influence in developing guidelines for the
funds they re-granted, more influence in developing guidelines, and symbolic acceptance as partners,
rather than subordinates, in the policy process” (DiMaggio, 1991, p. 219). Platt Jr. (1988) identifies
three reasons for the SAAs’ success relative to the NEA in growing their appropriations in the 1980s
(Platt Jr., 1988p. 99): (1) SAA leadership; (2) citizen-based advocacy coalition: and (3) governor
leadership and interest. Moreover, the SAAs were peeved because of their subordinate status:
“Rather the relationship was one of grantor to grantee and not a partnership working toward common
goals. Feeling the need to have greater independent voice, the state established the National
Assembly of State Arts Agencies (NASAA) to assert their positions and to provide services to
individual states” (Urice, 1992, p. 22).
3.2 Advocacy Coalition, 1989-1997
3.2.1 From subgovernment to advocacy coalition
“A community of interest in cultural policy,” Dwyer and Frankel (2003) observe in their
report Policy Partners: Making the Case for State Investments in Culture, “has emerged in the past five to
eight years at the national level” (p. 3). After approximately three decades of the NEA’s grantmaking and constituency-building, the federal-state partnership in government support for the arts
became an advocacy coalition for government support for the arts in the 1990s as part “community
of interest” at the national level. The major thesis of this paper is that, in the spirit of cooperative
federalism and marble-cake intergovernmental relations, the NEA and the SAAs formed around the
strong normative position that government should support the arts. Thus the SAAs transformed
from being one part of subgovernment constructed around the NEA to taking center stage with the
NEA advocating government support for the arts. Table 1 demonstrates the shifts that accompany
a change from subgovernment to advocacy coalition.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
26
Table 1: Comparison of the Subsystem and Advocacy Coalition Frameworks (Davis & Davis, 1988, p. 4)
Dominant Subsystem
Advocacy Coalition
Source of Change
Subsystem participants
Participants
Federal agencies, clientele groups and
congressional committees
Policy Orientation
Distribution of government largess
Policy Conflict
Coalition
Minimal
Only 1 coalition win which there is
agreement
Major changes result from:
a) socio-economic conditions
b) outputs from policy coalitions with other
interests
c) national or system wide governing
coalition
Agencies and government officials from
local, state and national levels, interest
groups, researchers and media
representatives
Variety of organizations which range from
preservation to development
Considerable
Two or more coalitions each having
members from different organizations who
share similar beliefs
3.2.2 Belief System
Advocacy coalitions form around a belief system that consists of a deep core, policy core,
and secondary beliefs. “Actors within an advocacy coalition will show substantial consensus on
issues pertaining to the policy core,” which are the “fundamental policy positions concerning the
basic strategies for achieving normative axioms of deep core” (Sabatier, 1993). Most subsystems
and networks feature a normative structure that “gives meaning to the action of the members of the
subsystem/network and the use to which the tools are put” (Milward & Wamley, 1984). Even more,
as Wyszomirski (1999) finds, “in the process of value articulation, a policy community is invented
(or re-invented) and a policy system is forged that institutionalizes this value consensus and uses it to
legitimize policy purposes, to operationalize issue definitions, to implement programs, and to
channel policy politics” (p. 26). The main distinction of advocacy coalitions, however, is that the
belief system is the very reason for its existence. The emergence of a consensual belief system is not
exactly commonplace but it does happen. For example, intergovernmental consensus on economic
development in after the mid-1970s: “Sometime after the mid-1970s there emerged on the state and
local scene an intense preoccupation with economic development that has been marked by a level of
consensus and expectation unusual in American politics” (Eisinger, 1988, p. 3). It also happened
with the NEA, the SAAs, and the federal-state partnership in government support for the arts in the
U.S. in the 1990s.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
27
Both the NEA and the SAAs have always acknowledged the necessity of the others. On the
one hand, “the NEA needs the SAAs’ knowledge of local and regional issues and their decentralized
issues system for making grants”; on the other hand, “the state arts agencies need their Basic State
Grants and, looking especially at the projections for 1992 and beyond, they need the NEA’s
assistance in persuading state legislatures of the importance of public arts funding” (Love, 1991, p.
218). The NEA’s recognition of the SAAs is present in its enabling legislation, as explored above.
The SAAs’ recognition of the necessity of the NEA can be traced back to 1981 in a pivotal
document entitled Public Arts Agencies: Toward National Public Policy:
The underlying premise of this report is that a comprehensive national public policy for the
support for the arts is essential to the continued development of private support at all levels,
and that the active and purposeful development of such a policy should be carried out
through joint planning between a strong federal arts agency and its affiliated state, regional,
and local arts agencies. (See Backas, 1981, p. 3)
Joint planning and common interests have always linked the NEA and the SAAs in the federal-state
partnership from the beginning.
In the 1990s, however, that relationship intensified. Nancy Hanks, NEA chair in the middle
third of the 1990s says in her memoirs (2000), “it pleased me that the NEA, arts service
organizations, and lobbyists were working in solidarity to promote the value of arts in communities
and to increase the Endowment's budget” (p. 160). Ironically, the federal-state partnership did not
begin the 1990s auspiciously. “During the Congressional re-authorisation hearings of 1990, one of
the strategies to undermine the leadership of the NEA and to curtail its activities was a proposal by
Republicans in Congress, which was initially supported by the National Assembly of State Arts
Agencies [NASAA; the main advocacy organization for SAAs], for a 60 per cent devolution of arts
funding to the states” (recounted in van den Bosch, 1997, p. 314).10 However, by the mid-1990s,
Hanks observes, “We [the NEA, the SAAs, the NASAA, et al.] were all promoting the same
message, and turf wars had radically diminished” (p. 161).
It is true that “the role of state and jurisdictional arts agencies is to forever make the case for
the value of funding for the arts and a direct connection to the policies of state government”
(Mankin, Cohn, Perry, & Cayer, 2001, p. 9). The difference in the 1990s was that the very idea of
government support for the arts was being questioned. For example, a 1995 House budget
resolution read: “there is serious philosophical debate about whether financing artistic creation is an
It should be noted that this legislation failed, but in 1993 the percentage passed-through to the states did increase from
20 to 27.5 percent, then ultimately to nearly 40 percent toward the end of the decade.
10
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
28
appropriate government activity in the first place” (Concurrent Resolution on the Budget--Fiscal Year 1996
(Function 500: Education, Training, Employment, and Social Services), 1995). Robert Lynch, the CEO of
America for the Arts, which is the main advocacy organization for local arts, wrote with urgency in
1992: “Although local responses are necessary, they are not enough: there is a crucial need now for
federal, state, and local government arts funding policies to be philosophically linked” (Lynch, 1992).
NASAA prominently inserted the belief in national and state government support for the arts in its
grassroots advocacy guide (see Birch, 2000). The NEA and the SAAs formed an advocacy coalition
around the central normative position that government at all levels should support the arts in the
U.S. “Rather than agency clientele, the state arts agencies sought to become policy partners with the
NEA (with NASAA service as their collective representative). State arts agencies called for such a
recast relationship to be reflected both in policy planning and programmatic structure at the NEA
(Wyszomirski & Sharamitaro, 2002, p. 12).
Figure 6: NEA Appropriations and Basic State Grants (Source: 2001 NASAA Handbook)
$200,000,000
$150,000,000
NEA Appropriations*
$100,000,000
Basic State Grants*/ Plan
(1997-present)
$50,000,000
1999
1996
1993
1990
1987
1984
1981
1978
1975
1972
1969
1966
$0
Elazar (1966) argued, “It is possible to chart the scope of those concerns [states interests in
nationwide political concerns] and to treat its impact on state-federal political relations generally, in
regard to groups of states and in regard to individual states, by considering [seven points],” one of
which is “the essential distribution of authority and power between the federal government and the
states” (pp. 23-24). In the federal-state partnership in government support for the arts, the
distribution of fiscal authority shifted in the 1990s. For example, NEA grants to the SAAs increased
from 20 percent when the agency was founded to nearly 40 percent today. Figure 6 demonstrates
that NEA grants to the SAAs remained fairly constant even as the NEA’s own appropriation was
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
29
reduced almost 40 percent in fiscal year 1996. Moreover, Figure 7 shows that the resources of the
SAAs increased dramatically in the 1990s relative to the NEA as state legislatures were far more
benevolent to the SAAs than Congress was to the NEA. This “inversion” of the NEA-SAA historic
relationship (Wyszomirski, 2002, p. 188) prompted Mulcahy (2002) to call for a revision in cultural
policy in the U.S.:11
My overall finding is that the revision in the relative resources of agencies at the national and
subnational levels of government for funding of the arts requires a reconfiguration of
policymaking roles and responsibilities. In particular, the programmatic elements of a
national cultural policy need to be assumed largely at the subnational levels. (p. 67)
Although several SAAs have recently been targeted for severe budget reductions (none have been
eliminated so far), the inversion of the NEA-SAA federal-state partnership remains a fact.
Figure 7: NEA and SAA Appropriations (Source: 2001 NASAA Handbook)
Appropriation
500000000
SAA Appropriations (incl.
line items)
400000000
300000000
200000000
SAA Appropriations (excl.
line items)
100000000
NEA Appropriations*
19
66
19
70
19
74
19
78
19
82
19
86
19
90
19
94
19
98
0
Fiscal Year
The advocacy coalition between the NEA and the SAAs formalized with the federal-state
“partnership agreements” that were a major component of the NEA’s restructuring in fiscal year
1996. “During the consequent institutional reorganization, NEA administrators deployed the term
‘partnership’ to describe a variety of new relationships and projects necessitated by the economic
and political pressures the Endowment faced” (George, 1997). Michael McLaughlin (NEA staff
member) was quoted on December 6, 1995:
11
In light of recent struggles of the SAAs, I did recently hear Mulcahy wish to retract portions of this article.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
30
I think it’s positive that our relationships with States Arts Agencies are now going to be
partnership agreements instead of hands-off grants, because they’ll b negotiated almost like
cooperative agreements. So, it will be clearer what the states are responsible for with Federal
money.” (George, 1997, p. 24)
Conclusion
Our main thesis in this paper is that the federal-state partnership in government support for
the arts in the U.S. transformed into a NEA-SAA advocacy coalition for government support for the
arts in the U.S. We applied our Institutionalized Political Organization (IPO) model, which we
developed from Meyer’s General Institutional Model and Sabatier and Jenkins-Smith’s Advocacy
Coalition Framework, to demonstrate that the political organization of government support for the
arts in the U.S. had become institutionalized in the 1990s. The federal-state partnership managed by
the NEA in the late 1960s and 1970s became an advocacy coalition formed around the belief in the
appropriateness of government support for the arts in the 1990s. The advocacy coalition, however,
emerged from the factors in the institutional environment: namely, cooperative federalism and
marble-cake intergovernmental relations. The institutionalized political organization of government
support for the arts helped to save the NEA. It provided a reliable and stable ballast on which the
NEA could lean to demonstrate its continued utility in American culture, thus helping the federal
agency to survive the 1990s.
References
Adams, W. H. (1966). The Politics of Art: Forming a State Arts Council. New York: Arts Councils of
America.
Alexander, J. (2000). Command Performance: An Actress in the Theatre of Politics. New York: Public
Affairs.
Anton, T. J. (1989). American Federalism and Public Policy: How the System Works. New York: Random
House.
Arian, E. (1989). State Arts Agencies. In The Unfulfilled Promise (pp. 69-102, 135). Philadelphia:
Temple University Press.
Backas, J. J. (1981). Public Arts Agencies: Toward National Public Policy. Washington, D.C.: National
Assembly of State Arts Agencies.
Beam, D. R., & Conlan, T. J. (2002). Grants. In L. M. Salamon (Ed.), The Tools of Government. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Beer, S. H. (1976). The Adoption of General Revenue Sharing: A Case Study in Public Sector
Politics. Public Policy, 24(2), 127-195.
Beer, S. H. (1977). Political Overload & Federalism. Public Policy, 10, 5-17.
Beer, S. H. (1978). Federalism, Nationalism, and Democracy in America. American Political Science
Review, 72(1), 9-21.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
31
Bimber, B. (1998). The Death of an Agency: OTA and Trophy Hunting in U.S. Budget Policy. Policy
Studies Review, 15(2/3), 202-225.
Birch, T. E. (2000). Strategies for Building Arts Support. The NASAA Advocate, 5.
Bohte, J., & Meier, K. J. (2000). The Marble Cake: Introducing Federalism to the Government
Growth Equation. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 30(3), 35-46.
Cammisa, A. M. (1995). Governments as Interest Groups: Intergovernmental Lobbying and the Federal System.
Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers.
Chubb, J. E. (1985). The Political Economy of Federalism. American Political Science Review, 79(4), 9941015.
Cole, R. L., Stenberg, C. W., & Weissert, C. S. (1996). Reversing Directions: A Ranking and
Comparison of Key U.S. Intergovernmental Events, 1960-1980 and 1980-1995. Publius: The
Journal of Federalism, 26(2), 25-40.
Concurrent Resolution on the Budget--Fiscal Year 1996 (Function 500: Education, Training, Employment, and
Social Services), House, 104th Congress, 1st Sess. (1995).
Conlan, T. J. (1998a). A Devolution Revolution? Federalism in the 104th Congress. In From New
Federalism to Devolution: Twenty-Five Years of Intergovernmental Reform (Revised ed., pp. 230-256).
Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Conlan, T. J. (1998b). Evolutionary Devolution: The Saga of Mandates and Welfare Reform. In From
New Federalism to Devolution: Twenty-Five Years of Intergovernmental Reform (pp. 257-293).
Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
Conlan, T. J. (1998c). Federalism Reform and the Modern State. In From New Federalism to Devolution:
Twenty-Five Years of Intergovernmental Reform (Revised ed., pp. 1-18). Washington, D.C.:
Brookings Institution Press.
Cummings Jr., M. C. (1982). To Change a Nation's Cultural Policy: The Kennedy Adminstration and
the Arts in the United States. In K. V. Mulcahy & C. R. Swaim (Eds.), Public Policy and the
Arts (pp. 141-168). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Cummings Jr., M. C. (1991). Government and the Arts: An Overview. In S. Benedict (Ed.), Public
Money and the Muse (pp. 31-79). New York: Norton.
Davis, C., & Davis, S. (1988). Analyzing Change in Public Lands Policymaking: From Subsystems to
Advocacy Coalitions. Policy Studies Journal, 17(1), 3-24.
deLeon, P. (1997). Afterward: The Once and Future State of Policy Termination. International Journal
of Public Administration, 20(12), 2195-2212.
Derthick, M. (2001). The Paradox of the Middle Tier. In Keeping the Compound Republic: Essays on
American Federalism (pp. 43-55). Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
DiMaggio, P. J. (1983). State Expansion and Organizational Fields. In R. H. Hall & R. E. Quinn
(Eds.), Organizational Theory and Public Policy (pp. 147-161). Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.
DiMaggio, P. J. (1991). Decentralization of Arts Funding from the Federal Government to the
States. In S. Benedict (Ed.), Public Money and the Muse: Essays on Government Funding and the
Muse (pp. 216-256). New York: Norton.
DiMaggio, P. J. (2000). Social Structure, Institutions, and Cultural Goods: The Case of the United
States. In G. Bradford, M. Gary & G. Wallach (Eds.), The Politics of Culture: Policy Perspectives for
Individuals, Institutions, and Communities (pp. 38-62). New York: The New Press.
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1983). The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and
Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2), 147-160.
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1991a). Introduction. In W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.),
The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (pp. 1-38). Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
32
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1991b). The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and
Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields. In The New Institutionalism in Organizational
Analysis (pp. 60-82). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Dinan, J. (1997). State Government Influence in the National Policy Process: Lessons from the
104th Congress. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 27(2), 129-142.
Dwyer, M. C., & Frankel, S. (2003). Policy Partners: Making the Case for State Investments in Culture: The
Pew Charitable Trusts.
Eisinger, P. K. (1988). The Rise of the Entrepreneurial State: State and Local Economic Development Policy in
the United States. Madison, WI: The University of Wisconsin Press.
Elazar, D. J. (1964). Federal-State Collaboration in the Nineteenth-Century United States. Political
Science Quarterly, 79(2), 248-281.
Elazar, D. J. (1966). American Federalism: A View from the States. New York: Thomas Y. Crowell Co.
Ellison, B. A. (1998). Intergovernmental Relations and the Advocacy Coalition Framework: The
Operation of Federalism in Denver Water Politics. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 28(4), 3554.
Freedman, A. (1997, March 15, 1997). Replaying the Battle Scene over NEA Funding. Congressional
Quarterly Weekley Report, 55, 624, 626.
George, L. (1997). Cross-Sector Partnerships and Corporate Involvement in the Reinvention of the National
Endowment for the Arts (Program on Non-Profit Organizations Working Paper No. No. 240).
New Haven, CT: Institution for Social and Policy Studies, Yale University.
Giddens, A. (1984). The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Berkeley: University
of California Press.
Grodzins, M. (1993). The Federal System. In L. J. O'Toole Jr. (Ed.), American Intergovernmental
Relations: Foundations, Perspectives, and Issues (2nd ed., pp. 57-60). Washington, D.C.: CQ Press.
Haider, D. H. (1974). The Government Groups in the Policy-Making Process. In When Governments
Come to Washington: Governors, Mayors, and Intergovernmental Lobbying (pp. 212-256). New York:
The Free Press.
Hall, W. K. (1989). Two Hundred Years of Federalism: The American Experiment. In The New
Institutions of Federalism: The Politics of Intergovernmental Relations, 1960-1985 (pp. 9-36). New
York: Peter Lang Publishing, Inc.
Hanson, R. L. (1999). Intergovernmental Relations. In V. Gray, R. L. Hanson & H. Jacob (Eds.),
Politics in the American States: A Comparative Analysis (7th ed., pp. 32-65). Washington, D.C.:
CQ Press.
Heclo, H. (1978). Issue Networks and the Executive Establishment. In A. King (Ed.), The New
American Political System (pp. 87-124). Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute.
Hofferbert, R. I., & Urice, J. K. (1985). Small-Scale Policy: The Federal Stimulus versus Competing
Explanations for State Funding of the Arts. American Journal of Political Science, 29(2), 308-329.
Horowitz, H. (1986). The Federal and State Partnership in the Support of Culture in the U.S.A.
Journal of Cultural Economics, 10, 1-25.
Ingram, H. (1977). Policy Implementation through Bargaining. Public Policy, 25(4), 449-526.
Inman, R. P., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (1997). Rethinking Federalism. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(4),
43-64.
Jenkins-Smith, H. C., & Sabatier, P. A. (1994). Evaluating the Advocacy Coalition Framework.
Journal of Public Policy, 14(2), 175-203.
Kenis, P., & Schneider, V. (1991). Policy Networks and Policy Analysis: Scrutinizing a New
Analytical Toolbox. In B. Marin & R. Mayntz (Eds.), Policy Networks: Empirical Evidence and
Theoretical Considerations (pp. 25-59). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
33
Larson, G. O. (1983). The National Foundation on the Arts and Humanities. In The Reluctant Patron:
The United States Government and the Arts, 1943-1965 (pp. 181-218). Philadelphia: University of
Pennsylvania Press.
Leach, R. H. (1970). American Federalism. New York: W.W. Norton & Co., Inc.
Love, J. (1991). Sorting Out Our Roles: The State Arts Agencies and the National Endowment for
the Arts. Journal of Arts Management and Law, 21(3), 215-226.
Lowi, T. J. (1979). The New Public Philosophy: Interest-Group Liberalism. In The End of Liberalism:
The Second Republic of the United States (2nd ed., pp. 42-63). New York: W.W. Norton &
Company.
Lynch, R. L. (1992). Cultural Crossroads. Journal of Arts Management, Law and Society, 22(1), 33-43.
Mankin, L. D., Cohn, S., Perry, R. W., & Cayer, N. J. (2001). The National Government and the Arts:
Impressions from the State and Jurisdictional Arts Agencies. Washington, D.C.: The Center for Arts
and Culture.
March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1984). The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political
Life. The American Political Science Review, 3(78), 734-749.
Mark, C. C. (1991). Reluctant Bureaucrats: The Struggle To Establish the National Endowment for the Arts.
Dubuque, IA: Kendall/Hunt Publishing Company.
Meyer, J. W. (1994). Rationalized Environments. In W. R. Scott & J. W. Meyer (Eds.), Institutional
Environments an Organizations: Structural Complexity and Individualism (pp. 28-54). Thousand
Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1991). Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and
Ceremony. In W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational
Analysis (pp. 41-62). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Milward, H. B., & Wamley, G. L. (1984). Policy Subsystems, Networks and the Tools of Public
Management. In G. C. Edwards III (Ed.), Public Policy Implementation (pp. 3-25). Greenwich,
CT: JAI Press Inc.
Mulcahy, K. V. (1988). The Politics of Cultural Oversight: The Reauthorization Process and the
National Endowment for the Arts. In M. J. Wyszomirski (Ed.), Congress and the Arts (pp. 6386). New York: American Council for the Arts.
Mulcahy, K. V. (2002). The State Arts Agency: An Overview of Cultural Federalism in the United
States. Journal of Arts Management, Law and Society, 32(1), 67-80.
NCA. (1975). Federal-State Partnership: National Endowment for the Arts Program and Funding Information.
Washington, D.C.: National Council on the Arts.
Netzer, D. (1978). The Subsidized Muse. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Ostrom, E. (1999). Institutional Rational Choice: An Assessment of the Institutional Analysis and
Development Framework. In P. A. Sabatier (Ed.), Theories of the Policy Process (pp. 35-71).
Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Ostrom, V. (1991). The Meaning of Federalism in The Federalist. In The Meaning of American
Federalism (pp. 69-97, 273-274). San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies.
O'Toole Jr., L. J. (1985). American Intergovernmental Relations: An Overview. In L. J. O'Toole Jr.
(Ed.), American Intergovernmental Relations (pp. 1-18). Washington, DC: CQ Press.
Platt Jr., G. (1988, May/June). The State of Arts Agencies. Museum News, 66, 99.
Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. (Eds.). (1991). The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Rainey, H. G., & Milward, H. B. (1983). Public Organizations: Policy Networks and Environments.
In R. H. Hall & R. E. Quinn (Eds.), Organizational Theory and Public Policy (pp. 133-146).
Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
34
Rich, R. F. (2002). Presentation to the School of Public Policy, George Mason University (April 23).
Fairfax, VA.
Sabatier, P. A. (1993). Policy Change over a Decade or More. In P. A. Sabatier & H. C. JenkinsSmith (Eds.), Policy Change and Learning: An Advocacy Coalition Approach (pp. 13-39). Boulder:
Westview Press.
Sabatier, P. A., & Jenkins-Smith, H. C. (Eds.). (1993). Policy Change and Learning: An Advocacy Coalition
Approach. Boulder: Westview Press.
Sato, H. (1999). The Advocacy Coalition Framework and the Policy Process Analysis: The Case of
Smoking Control in Japan. Policy Studies Journal, 27(1), 28-44.
Schlager, E. (1995). Policy Making and Collective Action: Defining Coalitions within the Advocacy
Coalition Framework. Policy Sciences, 28, 243-270.
Scott, W. R. (1983a). Introduction: From Technology to Environment. In J. W. Meyer & W. R. Scott
(Eds.), Organizational Environments: Ritual and Rationality (pp. 13-17). Beverly Hills: Sage
Publications.
Scott, W. R. (1983b). The Organization of Environments: Network, Cultural, and Historical
Elements. In J. W. Meyer & W. R. Scott (Eds.), Organizational Environments: Ritual and
Rationality (pp. 155-175). Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.
Scott, W. R. (1994a). Institutional Analysis: Variance and Process Theory Approaches. In W. R.
Scott & J. W. Meyer (Eds.), Institutional Environments and Organizations: Structural Complexity and
Individualism (pp. 81-99). Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications, Inc.
Scott, W. R. (1994b). Institutions and Organizations: Toward a Theoretical Synthesis. In W. R. Scott
& J. W. Meyer (Eds.), Institutional Environments and Organizations: Structural Complexity and
Individualism (pp. 55-80). Thousand Oaks: Sage.
Scott, W. R., & Meyer, J. W. (1994). Developments in Institutional Theories. In W. R. Scott & J. W.
Meyer (Eds.), Institutional Environments and Organizations: Structural Complexity and Individualism
(pp. 1-8). Thousand Oaks: SAGE Publications.
Simmons, J. (1978). The State Arts Agencies in 1974: All Present and Accounted For (No. Research
Division Report No. 8). Washington, D.C.: National Endowment for the Arts.
Stein, R. M. (1984). Policy Implementation in the Federal Aid System. In G. C. Edwards III (Ed.),
Public Policy Implementation (pp. 125-155). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press Inc.
Stoker, R. P. (1991). The Implementation Paradox. In Reluctant Partners (pp. 3-19). Pittsburgh:
University of Pittsburgh Press.
Svenson, A. (1982). State and Local Arts Agencies. In K. V. Mulcahy & C. R. Swaim (Eds.), Public
Policy and the Arts (pp. 195-210). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Urice, J. K. (1992). The Future of the State Arts Agency Movement in the 1990s: Decline and
Effect. Journal of Arts Management, Law and Society, 22(1), 19-32.
van den Bosch, A. (1997). Arts Policy and Funding in the United States: Some Critical Perspectives.
Cultural Policy, 3(2), 305-322.
Walker, D. B. (1980-1981). Tackling Dysfunctional Federalism. Policy Studies Journal, 9(8, Special
Issue 4), 1193-1205.
Wamsley, G. L. (1985). Policy Subsystems as a Unit of Analysis in Implementation Studies: A
Struggle for Theoretical Synthesis. In K. Hanf & T. A. J. Toonen (Eds.), Policy Implementation
in Federal and Unitary Systems. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.
Watts, R. L. (1998). Federalism, Federal Political Systems, and Federations. Annual Review of Political
Science, 1998(1), 117-137.
Wyszomirski, M. J. (1988). Budgetary Politics and Legislative Support: The Arts in Congress. In M.
J. Wyszomirski (Ed.), Congress and the Arts (pp. 9-33). New York: American Council for the
Arts.
DRAFT
From Federal-State Partnership
35
Wyszomirski, M. J. (1995a). Federal Cultural Support: Toward a New Paradigm. Journal of Arts
Management, Law and Society, 25(1), 69-82.
Wyszomirski, M. J. (1995b). Policy Communities and Policy Influence: Securing a Government Role
in Cultural Policy for the Twenty-First Century. Journal of Arts Management, Law and Society,
25(3), 192-205.
Wyszomirski, M. J. (1995c). The Politics of Arts Policy: Subgovernment to Issue Network. In K. V.
Mulcahy & M. J. Wyszomirski (Eds.), America's Commitment to Culture: Government and the Arts
(pp. 47-73). Boulder: Westview Press, Inc.
Wyszomirski, M. J. (1996). From Nancy Hanks to Jane Alexander: Generating Support for Art's
Sake at the National Endowment for the Arts. In R. A. Loverd (Ed.), Leadership for the Public
Service: Power and Policy in Action (pp. 121-149). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Wyszomirski, M. J. (1997). Through the Policy Window: The Context of Cultural Policy. Arts
Education Policy Review, 98(5), 9-12.
Wyszomirski, M. J. (1999). Shifting Values and Cultural Policy in the United States. Boekmancahier,
39, 25-36.
Wyszomirski, M. J. (2002). Arts and Culture. In L. M. Salamon (Ed.), The State of Nonprofit America
(pp. 187-218). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Wyszomirski, M. J., & Sharamitaro, L. M. (2002). Advocacy and Policymaking Involvement in the Cultural
Sector: An Associational Perspective: Final Report of the Associational Infrastructure of the Arts
and Culture: A Cross-Sectoral Exploration (Grant #2000-NSRF-14).
Zimmerman, J. F. (2001). National-State Relations: Cooperative Federalism in the Twentieth
Century. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 31(2), 15-30.
DRAFT
Download