REGIONAL INTEGRATION MODELS AND AFRICA’S GROWTH IN THE 21ST CENTURY: A FITNESS EVALUATION By Peter D. GOLIT and Yusuf ADAMU1 Abstract _____________________________________________________________________________________________ The study explores Africa’s regional integration models with a view to determining their suitability or otherwise for rapid economic growth. Using annual data spanning 1980-2012, the study employs the Johansen (1998) and the Johansen and Juselius (1990) method of co-integration and Vector Error Correction Mechanism (VECM) to test for the presence of long-run equilibrium relationships among the variables and estimate their static and dynamic coefficients. The study found a significant positive role for infrastructure financing, and human and physical capital accumulation both of which significantly influenced Africa’s economic growth. Intra-African trade, though positive and significant, was found to be less effective in inspiring growth compared to the above growth fundamentals. Trade openness and government spending were the only variables discovered to significantly influence Africa’s economic growth in the short-run. The study concludes that the traditional approach to regional integration may not provide the best alternative for Africa’s economic growth. It, thus, recommends the adoption of a mixed policy approach to regional economic integration to foster Africa’s economic growth in the 21st century. The contribution of the study lies in its ability to subject Africa’s models of regional integration to practical examination using modern approaches. Key Words: Regional Integration, Economic Growth, Co-integration, Error Correction Model. JEL Classification: I10, C33, C50 Authors’ Email Address: golitson2@yahoo.com; pdgolit@cbn.gov.ng; yadamu@cbn.gov.ng Prepared for the African Economic Conference (AEC); holding in Johannesburg, South Africa, October 28-30, 2013. 1 Golit (Senior Economist) and Adamu (Assistant Economist) are staff of the Research Department, Central Bank of Nigeria. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the Central Bank of Nigeria. 1. INTRODUCTION Over the years, Africa has made concrete efforts to propel growth through advancements in intra-regional cooperation for subsequent integration into the global economy. Many policy makers and opinion leaders across the continent seem to be unanimous in their belief in the capacity of regional integration to promote economic growth. There is, however, no consensus in the literature on the particular form that the integration should take to optimize the continent’s growth and development. The proposed integration schemes appeared to have ignored the countries’ peculiarities, thus jeopardizing their effective implementation. The gradual changes in the socio-political and policy environment have also necessitated changes in orientation and approach to regional integration in Africa. Several scholars have attempted to provide reasons for the failure of the past initiatives. These reasons ranged from the structure of the integration schemes to differences in objectives and approach of rival sub-regional integration agencies; including overlapping memberships and wrangling between and/or among the different integration agencies. For instance, with the exception of North Africa where the Arab Maghreb Union (AMU) remains the single integration agency, all the other sub-regions of Africa have rival sub-regional integration agencies, with West Africa witnessing the deepest rivalry from the uneasy co-existence of the Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS) and the Union Economique et Monétaire Ouest Africaine (UEMOA). The regional integration process envisioned by the Lagos Plan of Action was actually intended to engineer the emergence and growth of a single unifying regional integration agency in each sub-region which will together eventually metamorphose into the African Economic Community (AEC). Infant industries within the integrated regions were to be subjected to gradual competition in 2|Page their protected regional markets until they mature for global competition (Oyejide, 2000). The above perspective to regional integration has been strongly criticized in the light of the present wave of globalization which requires a change of strategy to a more outward-oriented approach to economic integration. The search for new models of regional integration has refocused the minds of development thinkers away from the traditional approaches to growth fundamentals like macroeconomic stability, capital accumulation, transactions costs, and human and physical capital accumulation. The objective of the paper, therefore, is to explore Africa’s regional integration models with a view to determining the right blend of models that is most suited for the continent’s growth in the 21st Century. The paper is structured into seven sections. Following the above introduction is section two which reviews some relevant literature on the nexus between regional economic integration and economic growth. Section three further expands on the review of related literature but with specific interest on the rationale and benefits of Africa’s regional integration. Section four explores the regional integration models in Africa. In section five, the methodology including the sources of data and estimation techniques are discussed. Section six provides the empirical analysis with the conclusion and policy recommendations contained in section seven. 2. REVIEW OF RELEVANT LITERATURE Regional economic groupings in Africa have had a long history. The regional integration initiatives were ab initio intended to boost Africa’s development by widening opportunities in regional communities for faster economic growth. Among such opportunities include shared knowledge of technological innovations which is in turn expected to broaden regional specialization and 3|Page enhance Africa’s productive efficiency for better competition in the global environment. Furthermore, Africa needed regional integration to keep pace with the rest of the world towards her full integration into the world economy to better exploit the opportunities in the global markets. As Ouattara (1998) stated, Africa could not afford to leave the shaping of its future to chance or some special interests, or a few potentates lacking in vision or warlords with transient alliances. Regional economic cooperation was, thus, planned to elicit the interest of individual countries in the policies of regional partners towards ensuring mutual commitment and attainment of convergence standards. Regional integration was also to allow for greater coordination of national economic policies thereby enabling African countries to pool together their small economies into larger markets to benefit from economies of scale. Ouattara (1998) also observed that member countries in regional organizations enjoy the benefits of stronger regulatory and judicial systems (as is the case in the CFA franc zone), rationalized payments facilities and relaxed restrictions on capital transactions and investment flows (as in the Cross- Border Initiative) and a shared or common economic infrastructure as in the Southern African Development Community (SADC). All the above benefits have the potential to enhance trade links among African countries and strengthen their ability to participate in trade on a global scale. What remains uncertain, however, is whether or not the regional initiatives have really achieved the goal of integrating the sub-regional partners on the one hand and African countries into the world economy on the other hand. Although African countries have made considerable efforts in opening their economies to global trade, there is no substantial evidence to show that the regional initiatives have delivered on their ultimate goal of sustaining growth 4|Page and development. Some scholars have described the regional organizations as mere defensive mechanisms tailored towards the protection of member countries against the adverse consequences of globalization without necessarily delivering on the objective of trade facilitation and sustainable growth. Several studies have attempted to investigate the interactions between regional economic integration and economic growth, but the literature remains widely divided on the nature of the relationships existing between them. Yang and Gupta (2005), in their study of the performance of Regional Trade Arrangements (RTAs) in Africa, argued that Africa’s RTAs have not been effective in fostering trade and Foreign Direct Investment (FDI). They noted that external trade barriers are comparatively high, in addition to low complementarity of member country resources, thereby constraining both intra and extra-regional trade. They also blamed the small size of the markets; inefficient transport systems and high transactions costs for the frustrations confronting African countries in reaping the potential benefits of RTAs. They finally submitted that African countries should streamline the existing RTAs and embrace trade liberalization on a much larger scale, while improving on physical infrastructure and expanding on their domestic revenue base to lessen the losses accruing from trade liberalization. On the other hand, Vamvakidis (1998) provides empirical evidence showing that countries whose neighboring economies are large, open and relatively more developed grow faster than those bordering small, closed and relatively less developed neighbors. The robustness of the results given alternative specifications and separate measures of openness indicates that small economies are likely to grow faster when involved in regional trade agreements with larger and more developed economies. But, the growth impact of the five 5|Page regional trade agreements tested during the 1970s and 1980s were found to be inconsistent with the above preliminary findings, implying that none of the regional trade initiatives was found to facilitate economic growth. The author attributed the divergence in the results to the preponderance of small, closed, and less developed countries involved in the trade arrangements. In his investigation of the relationships between regional economic integration and some macroeconomic variables, Fernandez (1997) discovered that regional integration creates reciprocal benefits by enthroning a peaceful environment which in turn works as an insurance against any form of trade war. Using Global Computable General Equilibrium (GCGE) model to analyze Indonesia’s current and potential international trade relationships with other countries, Hartono, et al. (2007) found a significant positive impact of regional economic integration on Indonesia’s real GDP, output and welfare; with the exception of the free trade agreement with India. Ezaki and Nguyen (2008) also used Computable General Equilibrium Model to quantify the impact of institution-led regional economic integration on economic growth, income distribution and poverty reduction. The study found that the East Asian FTAs generally have positive effects on growth, coupled with improvements in income distribution and poverty reduction. With the exception of the impact on China, the results indicate a positive and significant impact and positive longrun effects on East Asia, though it recognized that the requirement for structural adjustment must have accounted for the problems associated with the short-run effects. In another development, Frankel and Rose (2002) examined the implications of common currencies for trade and income of over 200 countries and found that their involvement in currency union tripled trade with other members of the 6|Page currency union without any evidence of trade diversion. Furthermore, a one percent increase in a country’s overall trade was found to raise income per capita by at least one-third percent. The results support the hypothesis that the key beneficial effects of currency unions stem from trade facilitation. They argued that currency union promotes trade by reducing cost of international transactions and eliminating the possibility of exchange rate changes between members of the currency union. Combining endogenous growth models and economic geography to study the impact of regional economic integration on the member and non-member countries of a regional union, Dion (2004) further established that regional economic integration impact growth through interregional technology diffusion as knowledge spillovers originating from leading countries spread to lagging partners. Access to bigger stock of knowledge, therefore, fosters growth and convergence in the member countries. In another study of the impact of regional economic integration on economic growth and welfare in Iran and its northern neighbors, Naveh, Torosyan and Jalaee (2012) found a positive role for trade links and regional economic integration in relation to the GDP and welfare of the selected countries. However, beyond a certain level, the welfare generated for the society decreases as the share of trade in output increases. 3. THE RATIONALE FOR AFRICA’S REGIONAL INTEGRATION Africa remains the most deprived continent in the world with fragmented component parts, tiny domestic markets and declining shares of world trade. The combined Gross Domestic product (GDP) of 19 Sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries stood at less than US$5 billion below the US$281.8 billion recorded by the smallest European Union (EU) member country (the Republic of Ireland) in 2008. The GDP of the largest African economy (South Africa) was also said to 7|Page have fallen below that of the smallest EU economy. What is more? The combined GDP of all SSA countries, excluding South Africa fell short of the total recorded by Netherland over the same period (McCarthy, 2010). Majority of the African countries are known to be of small size and population, with low per capita income, thus limiting their market sizes and the benefits derivable from economies of scale. Africa’s regional integration was, therefore, primarily aimed at overcoming the constraints on African countries to achieve sustainable economic growth via improvements in intra-regional trade and investments. The quest for regional integration, consequently, led to the reduction of trade barriers among member countries towards enhancing intra-regional trade, creating regional markets and engendering competition for rapid industrialization. Regional integration was, also, considered the most appropriate means of linking the individual countries to create larger markets, a precondition for better competition, allocation efficiency and economies of scale. It was believed that the continent would certainly miss out of the new economic order if African countries failed to cooperate and reposition their development efforts along regional blocs towards ensuring competition, expanding export capacities and accessing global markets. However, several decades after the implementation of regional integration arrangements, Africa is yet to succeed in meaningfully expanding intra-regional trade or increasing her overall GDP to levels that are comparable with those of other regions. The above inadequacies may not be unconnected with the countries’ structural problems that are apparently incompatible with the integration mechanisms in practice. Oyejide (2000) pointed to the non-complementarities (no product differentiation) in the goods and services existing among the regional partners as part of the reasons accounting for the low level of trade among the member countries. 8|Page Others include the generally low per capita income and similarities in the countries’ consumption patterns. The deficiencies in design and implementation of the various integration schemes made it extremely difficult for Africa to deliver the kind of growth projected from the outset. The liberalized and enlarged regional markets still remain largely inadequate to compete in the global markets and achieve high levels of growth. Furthermore, most of the regions are not fully integrated given the deviations in individual country policies from the common goals of the regional blocs. As Oyejide (2000) argued, the design and implementation of some of the regional integration schemes impede rather than stimulate intra-regional trade. The institutions charged with the responsibilities of monitoring and implementing trade agreements equally lack the capacity to enforce important decisions, particularly, when countries are become increasingly unwilling to relinquish powers to regional agencies. Non-compliance and/or delayed compliance with established benchmarks have, thus, continued to stifle the realization of regional goals, particularly, the free movement of production factors. “There is clear, abundant and well-documented evidence that the regional integration arrangements in Africa have, in general, not significantly improved intra-regional and intra-African trade.” In virtually all cases, the volume of intra-regional trade has stagnated or even declined slightly, and there have been no changes in the composition of trade that would suggest that integration has led to any significant structural change in the economies concerned” (Fine and Yeo, 1997, P. 433). The aspirations of the different regional groups (ECOWAS, PTA, COMESA, CEAO, SACU, UEMOA, UDEAC, etc.) vary widely. The intra-group trade ratios were also observed to be higher than the intra-African trade ratios. 9|Page 4. AFRICA’S REGIONAL INTEGRATION MODELS We attempt a classification of the regional integration models based on their focus, orientation and implementation strategy. 4.1 The Traditional Approach Africa’s traditional approach to regional integration was focused on increasing intra-regional trade and industrialization to spur growth in various integrated regions through an import-substitution in the different integration regions. The growth of the various integrated regions was expected to eventually translate into the growth of the entire African continent. Africa has experimented with the trade-focused regional integration model for more than a half century expecting to motivate member countries towards producing and exporting to one another, thus replacing non-member countries’ exports with those of member countries. Such protective mechanisms have since given way to more proactive and outward-oriented development strategies that offer learning opportunities against global competitive pressures for quicker access to the global markets. The failure of the traditional approach to regional integration has motivated opinion leaders and development thinkers in Africa to call for an overhaul of Africa’s trade policy or a paradigm shift in search for alternative approaches. The new approaches should as a matter of necessity pay attention to the pitfalls of the earlier experiments, particularly, the design and implementation glitches. The preferential trade liberalization scheme was, ab initio prone to problems knowing that African countries export primary products that are common to most countries, making them to rely on non-African imports. It is, therefore, counter-productive to rely on such schemes to transform African countries and enhance growth. It is also argued that African countries would end-up diverting 10 | P a g e low cost imports (cheap intermediate inputs) from developed countries for high cost imports from other African countries. Radelet (1997) affirmed that tradefocused regional integration performs best when built on earlier liberalization efforts. The approach may, therefore, be unsuitable for African countries in view of their structural characteristics. The above traditional approach pre-supposes a unidirectional hypothesis indicating that intra-regional trade promotes economic growth, and that the magnitude of impact is high. But, as established earlier, Africa’s intra-regional trade is low and as Oyejide (2000) puts it, it will be a tail that is too small to wag the much bigger body (Africa’s overall economic growth). Better still, Africa’s intra-regional trade and growth may be bi-causal in relationships. Ndulu and Ndung’u (1997. P.21) established that Africa’s trade and trade policies impact growth with a feedback effect from growth to trade performance, but the latter (growth performance) was found to be the main driver of the relationships between export and growth. These other factors which simultaneously influence trade and growth suggest that Africa’s regional integration needs to be refocused away from intra-regional trade expansion to the direct factors that stimulate growth while at the same time facilitate trade. 4.2 The Alternative Approaches In recognition of the inherent weaknesses of the traditional approach to regional integration, famous academics and development think-tanks have envisioned new ideas that significantly depart from the traditional approaches. The new perspectives proceed from the knowledge of the prevailing conditions in member countries and the need for individual countries to first engage in some self-cleansing by refocusing domestic reforms to growth fundamentals, 11 | P a g e key of which include macroeconomic stability, transactions costs, physical infrastructure, and human and physical capital accumulation. 4.2.1 Human and Physical Capital Accumulation Modern growth models have identified human and physical capital accumulation as key in the growth process of developing countries. This is in view of the low levels of domestic and foreign direct investments in these countries. The rapid transformation of the Asian Tigers has been attributed to their ability to accumulate vast human and physical capital. New regional integration models must necessarily emphasis these key growth factors if they must deliver growth to the African continent. 4.2.2 Macroeconomic Stability Contemporary development economists have argued that, what Africa largely needs to boost economic growth at its present level of industrialization is not trade facilitation because the member countries still rely on primary exports which do not command high prices and are subject to frequent price fluctuations. Rather than dissipating energies on stimulating trade, Africa needs to enthrone a sound and stable macroeconomic environment for speedy factor accumulation and efficient use of scarce production resources, including human and physical capital. The fulcrum on which the above argument is based is that sustainable macroeconomic stability is a double-edged sword that on one hand sharpens domestic investments and on the other hand induces huge foreign direct investment. 4.2.3 Transactions costs Reducing transactions costs is crucial to investment drives in Africa. Collier (1998) attributed Africa’s unimpressive performance in enhancing growth to its high transactions costs arising from transport difficulties in many landlocked African 12 | P a g e countries, highly inefficient and uncompetitive telecommunication networks, poor judicial systems that frustrates contract enforcements, information asymmetries and poor ancillary services. For Africa to witness any reasonable growth, it needs to develop schemes that are capable of bringing transactions costs to international levels to enhance its competitive status and attract huge capital inflows for investment in labor-intensive industries. Regional cooperation arrangements that address such underlying problems in addition to facilitating shared standards and common investment policies would hasten cross-border investments and are, thus, more fitting for Africa’s growth. Shared facilities involving high-cost transport and communications infrastructure and regional power, water and educational projects would go a long way to reduce unit cost in member countries than when provided on discrete basis. 4.2.4 Infrastructural Services The availability, efficiency and cost of key infrastructural services like power, communication and transport determine the speed of integration of African countries into the swiftly evolving global markets. Apart from enhancing the factor productivity, it facilitates the access to useful information by economic agents, thus, enhancing competition. The externalities and spillovers that would emerge from linking Africa through regional infrastructures like commodity exchange, stock market and clearing house facilities are capable of assisting the less resource-endowed African countries in escaping from their present pathetic development levels. The benefits associated with large market sizes and economies of scale would transform Africa into an investment destination, thus, further inducing foreign investment. 13 | P a g e 4.2.5 Other Alternative Models The other alternative models of regional integration suggested in the literature involve linking a group of African countries with a given industrialized country under a free trade agreement. The ongoing trade agreements between China and various African countries constitute a good example. Oyejide (2000) also cited the post-Lome IV proposed integration between a certain group of African countries and the EU, and the free trade agreements between the United States and Africa. Another alternative model suggested by Oyejide (2000) encompasses multilateral agreements among individual African countries within a framework that provides for both intra-African linkages and sufficient linkage with the rest of the world under the platform provided by the World Trade Organization (WTO). 5. METHODOLOGY 5.1 Data Sources and Variable Definitions The study uses annual data series of real GDP, Africa’s Intra-Regional Trade (IRT), Africa’s Trade Openness (TOP), Inflation Rate (INF), Gross Capital formation (GCF), General Government Expenditure (GGE) and Electricity Consumption (ELTR) to evaluate the suitability or otherwise of regional integration models for Africa’s growth in the 21st century. The data which covers 1980-2012 were sourced from the World Bank and the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) Statistical database. The time frame chosen was considered to be long enough to capture both the short and long run dynamic relationships. The estimations were carried out using e-views (version 7) econometric software. We performed minor interpolations in view of the gaps observed in some of the series. This, therefore, calls for caution in the interpretation of our findings bearing in mind that interpolated series have the tendency to bias the results and create some problems for forecasting. The 14 | P a g e Augmented Dickey-Fuller and Phillips-Perron tests were used to verify the time series properties of the individual series. It has been proven that the ADF and PP tests deliver the same results “asymptotically” (that is, in the hypothetical case of an infinitely large sample). All the variables entered the model in their logarithm form with the exception of inflation rate. 5.2 The Estimation Technique The study employs co-integration and error correction techniques to test for the existence or otherwise of long-run equilibrium relationships among the variables and estimate their short- and long-run parameters for the 1980-2012 period. The approach provides a more powerful tool for testing hypotheses about the relationships among non-stationary variables where data sets are of limited length. As stated earlier, the risk of using non-stationary time series in a linear regression model is the tendency to produce spurious correlations that may bias the parameter estimates. The presence of unit roots in our series informed our choice of a superior methodology, the Johansen (1998) and the Johansen and Juselius (1990) multivariate Maximum Likelihood method within a Vector Autoregressive (VAR) framework to verify the number of co-integrating equations in the Vector Error Correction Model (VECM). The approach also provides the best estimation mechanism as the Gauss-Markov theorem indicates that the least squares technique provides the best linear unbiased estimator (BLUE) through which straight line trend equations could be estimated. 5.3 Model Specification The functional form of our econometric model is specified as follows: = F (GCF, ELTR, INF, GGE, IRT, TOP)…………………………………. ………… (1) (+) (+) (-) (+) (+) (+) The signs in parenthesis are the apriori expectations. 15 | P a g e Where: GDP = Real Gross Domestic Product. An increase in GDP is expected to boost the level of economic activities, while a decline may create a dampening effect, and undermine trade efficiency within the African sub-regions. IRT = Intra-Regional Trade proxied by the volume of exports among the subregional groups in Africa, thus reflecting the level of trade among the integrated regions. INF = Inflation rate which reflects the presence or absence of macroeconomic instability within the African continent. The movements in the general price level affect the returns on investment and thus determine the level of income. Macroeconomic stability is crucial for effective planning and thus a major attraction to both domestic and foreign investors. GCF = Gross Fixed Capital Formation which constitutes accretion to stock of fixed assets; in this case the additions to the stock of inventories. This variable proxied the level of physical accumulation and thus useful in modern growth models that advocate for the accumulation of vast human and physical capital. (GGE) = General Governments’ Expenditure which stands for spending of the general governments on key infrastructure services like communications and transport, excluding power; and thus expected to boost the level of economic activities within the continent. But, beyond a certain level, excessive spending may create distortions that are counter-productive. ELTR = Consumption of Electricity which together with the spending on other infrastructure capture the response of growth to changes in government’s infrastructure spending. TOP = Trade Openness which measures Africa’s trade with the rest of the world and thus, reflects Africa’s competitiveness in trade relations with other countries. The impact of this variable is to be compared with that of intra-regional trade to 16 | P a g e determine whether or not Africa’s economic growth would be better improved by trading with the rest of the world as suggested by the alternative models or by relying on intra-regional trade as implied by the traditional approaches. The logarithmic transformation of equation (1) yields the following: + + + + ………………………………………………………………….…… (2) The augmented Dickey fuller (ADF) and Phillips-Perron (PP) tests were applied to test for the time series properties of our data to avoid the problem of spurious regression. This was done under the null hypothesis that the variables are nonstationary and integrated of order one or I(1). If the time series contain unit roots but are integrated of the same order, then their combination may suggest the existence of co-integration among them. 6.0 ANALYSIS OF EMPIRICAL RESULTS 6.1 Result of the Unit Root Tests Table 1 below presents the results of the ADF and PP unit root tests. From the results, we do not reject the null hypothesis about the presence of unit roots in all our series at their level form at the 5 per cent level of significance. However, the non-stationery series become stationary at their first difference and are thus integrated of order one or I (1). Since the variables are integrated of the same order, it suggests that there may be presence of co-integration, implying that long run equilibrium relationships exist among the variables. 17 | P a g e Table 1: Unit Root Tests ADF PP Order of Integration Variable Level First Diff Level First Diff LGDP 1.979 -3.252* 3.778 -4.238* I(1) LGCF 1.689 -5.045* 0.953 -5.059* I(1) LELTR -2.936* -4.521* -2.762* -5.160* I(1) INF -2.791 -7.871* -2.57 -12.029* I(1) LGGE 2.092 -6.589* 2.101 -6.466* I(1) LIRT -2.936* -4.521* -2.762* -5.160* I(1) LTOP -0.631* -5.142* -0.796* -6.031* I(1) Notes: ADF 1 and PP 1 represent= Unit root tests with constant, while ADF 2 and PP 2 = Unit root tests with constant and trend. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively. With constant and trend: McKinnon (1991) critical values are -4.0496(1%), -3.4540 (5%) and -3.1527 (10%). 6.2 Optimal Lag Length and stability tests An important requirement for the estimation of this kind of model is a choice of an appropriate lag length. A maximum lag of 6 was allowed in the selection given the number of observations and variables. The Schwarz information criterion (SC), Hannan-Quinn information criterion (HQ), Final Prediction Error (FPE), Sequential Modified LR test statistic (LR) and Akaike information Criterion (AIC) all suggest an optimal lag length of 1, thus informing our choice of a lag length of order 1 (see table 2 below). 18 | P a g e Table 2 VAR Lag Order Selection Criteria Lag LogL LR FPE AIC SC HQ 0 117.5689 NA 1.88e-12 -7.13348 -6.80967 -7.02793 1 343.3662 335.0541* 2.28e-17* -18.53976* -15.94933* -17.69534* 2 391.9448 50.14561 3.99e-17 -18.5126 -13.6555 -16.9293 * indicates lag order selected by the criterion 6.3 The Johansen Cointegration Test Since the order of integration of the variables has been established, we applied the Johansen (1988) and the Johansen and Juselius (1990) multivariate maximum likelihood method within the Vector Autoregressive (VAR) framework to verify the number of co-integrating equations in the Vector Error Correction Model (VECM). It is important to note that differencing variables to achieve stationarity leads to loss of long-run properties. Co-integration, therefore, provides a way out of the problem. After establishing that the deviations from the long run trend of two or more non-stationary variables have a stationary long run relationship, the null hypothesis of the Johansen’s method that there are no more than r co-integrating relations becomes valid. The test begins at r = 0 and accepts as rˆ the first value of r for which the null hypothesis will be rejected. Johansen and Juselius (1990) provide two test statistics – the Maximum Eigenvalue Test (λmax) and Trace Test (λtrace) Statistics to determine the number of co-integrated vectors. 19 | P a g e Table 3 Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test Trace H0 r=0 r<1 r<2 r<3 r<4 r<5 r<6 H1 r=1 r=2 r=3 r=4 r=5 r=6 r=7 Eigenvalue Trace Statistic 0.851291 177.9714 0.775993 118.8927 0.639215 72.51434 0.448551 40.91064 0.388642 22.45926 0.199252 7.204985 0.010158 0.316502 0.05 Critical Value 125.6154 95.75366 69.81889 47.85613 29.79707 15.49471 3.841466 Prob.** 0.0000 0.0005 0.0300 0.1915 0.2737 0.5540 0.5737 0.05 Critical Value 46.23142 40.07757 33.87687 27.58434 21.13162 14.26460 3.841466 Prob.** 0.0013 0.0086 0.0912 0.4580 0.2715 0.5024 0.5737 Maximum Eigenvalue H0 r=0 r<1 r<2 r<3 r<4 r<5 r<6 H1 r>1 r>2 r>3 r>4 r>5 r>6 r>7 Eigenvalue 0.851291 0.775993 0.639215 0.448551 0.388642 0.199252 0.010158 Max-Eigen Statistic 59.07870 46.37838 31.60371 18.45138 15.25427 6.888483 0.316502 Notes: The asterisk * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.005 level. Both the Maximum Eigenvalue and Trace tests confirm the presence of cointegrating relationships among the variables (see table 3 above). 6.4 Normalized Cointegrating Result The coefficient of Africa’s growth proxied by its Real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) was normalized to 1 and the coefficients of the normalized cointegrating equation are according to apriori expectations. Therefore, the estimated longrun cointegrating equation of the GDP and the selected integration variables is specified thus: GDP = 8.291+0.261GCF+ 0.669ELTR – 0.02INF +0.39GGE + 0.11IRT +0.24TOP (2) 20 | P a g e The long-run model indicates that all the variables in the model are statistically significant with the exception of INF, which is a proxy for macroeconomic stability, at the 5 per cent level of significance. The result also shows that gross capital formation, electricity consumption, general government spending, intraAfrican trade (export) and trade openness are positively related to growth, while inflation rate is negatively related with the normalized gross domestic product. From the estimated long-run equation, a one per cent expansion in physical capital accumulation, electricity consumption, intra African export, government expenditure and trade openness leads to 0.26, 0.68, 0.11, 0.39, and 0.24 per cent increase, respectively in Africa’s economic growth. These findings are in tandem with theory and available empirical evidence from developed economies. However, a one per cent increase in Africa’s prices (inflation) depresses growth by 0.02 percent. The expected signs of the coefficients of the variables were in consonance with apriori expectations. Table 4. Long-run cointegration vector estimates GDP GCF ELTR INF Cointegrating vectors 1.00 0.26 -0.67 0.02 (3.62) (-5.79) (1.14) Error correction VECM -0.03 -0.95 0.151 -0.035 -10.62 ((-1.89) 4.63) (1.59) (-1.165) (-0.59) GGE -0.39 (-2.34) 0.25 (2.08) ITE -0.11 (-2.21) TOP -0.24 (-4.66) 0.07 -1.21 (0.19) (-2.20) Notes: values in parenthesis are the t-statistics of the parameter estimates. 6.5 Error Correction Model After confirming the existence of long-run relationships among the variables, the Error Correction Mechanism was used to adjust to equilibrium in the event of a shock to the system. This allows for a distinction between the long-and short-run 21 | P a g e behaviors in the economy by specifying an error-correction mechanism of real output toward its desired level. This also tells us the speed or time it takes the model to adjust for disequilibrium. For stationary time series, no distinction is required between the short and the long run. From the lower panel of table 4, the speed of adjustment which is the coefficient of the vector error correction model (VECM) is -0.03. This implies that about 1 per cent of the deviation of GDP from its equilibrium level can be corrected in a year. The VECM is negative and significant; indicating that GDP has to decline in order to adjust to the long-run equilibrium level since it is above its long-run average position. However, about 1 per cent coefficient of VECM is an indication of a very low speed of adjustment to long-run equilibrium. In the short-run, only trade openness and government expenditure were significant in explaining Africa’s economic growth. All the other variables were insignificant. The negative coefficient of trade openness, however, signifies that Africa’s trade with the rest of the world is not favorable in the short run. However, it pays the continent to refocus efforts on infrastructure development both in the short and long run as the coefficient of government spending on infrastructural services is not only significant but largely positive. The level of impact significantly increases in the long run from 0.25 to 0.39 per cent. 6.6 Diagnostic Tests A battery of diagnostic test was performed on the model to confirm the validity of the system and the predictive ability of the model. Durbin Watson Statistics was used to test for long-run residual autocorrelation; normality test was applied to verify the distribution of the error term. We, thus, tested for skewness and excess kurtosis; the Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (ARCH) test and the Ramsey’s RESET test (Regression Specification Error Test) were also used 22 | P a g e to verify the correctness of the model specification. The White Heteroscedasticity test (with no cross terms) was employed to confirm whether the disturbances truly exhibit the equal variance (homoscedasticity) assumption. Similarly, Weak exogeneity tests on the individual variables were conducted under the assumption of one co-integrating vector in view of the limited length of our data and the risks associated with the possibility of insufficient degrees of freedom. Given the presence of the lagged dependent variable and other nonstochastic regressors, the Breusch-Godfrey Lagrange Multiplier (LM) test was used to check for higher order serial correlation in the disturbances of the estimated short-run dynamic models. 7.0 CONCLUSION AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS The imperative of regional integration is not in doubt especially where there is serious commitment among the regional partners. It is clear from our empirical findings that African countries can substantially improve growth if they can muster the political will to refocus regional trade agreements to growth fundamentals like infrastructure development, and the accumulation of human and physical capital. Though intra-regional trade was found to impact on economic growth, empirical evidence suggests that the long run impact is not comparable to the substantial effect realizable from the growth fundamentals like infrastructure spending, and gross capital formation. The traditional view that African countries should concentrate on trade among themselves is no longer tenable. Most African countries export the same or similar commodities and maintain the same pattern of trade. This clearly demonstrates the lack of absolute and comparative advantage that characterized these countries reflecting in the low volume of intra-regional exports. The findings of this study have serious policy implications for the growth 23 | P a g e of African countries. Policy makers need to understand that regional integration dominated by trade plays less crucial role in spurring economic growth. African governments, thus, need to redefine the goal of regional integration towards ensuring the provision of critical infrastructure, building human capacities and stock of physical capital. Another important finding that may attract the attention of policy makers is the discovery that infrastructure financing impacts more on Africa’s growth than trade with the outside world. This implies that Africa can inspire growth by concentrating on domestic efforts rather than relying on foreign countries. Empirical evidence clearly indicates that Africa’s trade with the rest of the world depresses growth in the short run, though the long run effect is positive. The smaller magnitude when compared to the estimated coefficient of infrastructure spending confirms the superiority of infrastructure spending. African countries should, therefore, intensify efforts to build regional infrastructures networks and link the entire continent for higher productivity. 24 | P a g e References Colier, P. (1998), “Globalization: Implications for Africa,” in Z.Igbal and M.S Khan (ed), Trade Reform and Regional Integration in Africa, IMF, Washington, D.C. Dion, D. P. (2004): “Regional Integration and Economic Development. A Theoretical approach”: Department of Economics, University of Mannheim; Discussion Paper No. 20. Available at: http://epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de/13528/1/20.pdf Ezaki, M. and Nguyen, T. D. (2008): “Regional Economic Integration and Its Impact on Growth, Income Distribution and Poverty in East Asia: A CGE Analysis”, Graduate School of International Development (GSID) Discussion Paper, No. 167, Nagoya University, Nagoya, Japan. Fernandez, R. (1997): “Returns to Regionalism: An Evaluation of Non Traditional Gain from Regional Trade Agreements”, NBER Working Paper No. 5970, March. Fine, J. and Yeo. S. (1997):“Regional Integration in Sub –Saharan Africa : Dead End or a Fresh Start ?”, in Oyejide, T. Ademola, Ibrahim Elbadawi and Paul Collier (eds), Regional Integration and Trade Liberalization in Sub – Saharan Africa , Vol I, London: Macmillan Frankel, J. and Rose, A. (2002): “An Estimate of the Effect of Common Currencies on Trade and Income”, the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, Issues 2, Pp. 437-466. Hartono, D; Priyarsono, D.S.; Nguyen, T. D. and Ezaki, M. (2007): “Regional Economic Integration and its Impacts on Growth, Poverty and Income Distribution: The Case of Indonesia”, Working Paper in Economics and Development Studies, No. 200702, Department of Economics, Padjadjaran University, Jalan Cimandiri, Bandung, Indonesia. Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1990): “Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on Co-integration with Applications to the Demand for Money”. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52: 169-210 McCarthy, C. (2010): “Reconsidering Regional Integration in sub-Saharan Africa”, Supporting Regional Integration in East and Southern Africa -A Review of Select Issues, Tralac, Danida. 25 | P a g e Naveh, M. H.; Torosyan, T. and Jalaee, S. A. (2012): “Regional Economic Integration and its Effects on Economic Growth and Economic Welfare”, World Applied Sciences Journal, 17(10): 1349-1355, ISSN 1818-4952. Ndulu, B. J. and Ndung’u N. S. (1997): “Trade and Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa” IMF/AERC Seminar on Trade Reforms and Regional Integration in Africa, Dec. 13; IMF, Washington, D. C. Ouattara, A. D. (1998): ‘’Africa: An Agenda for the 21st Century”, Brown Journal of World Affairs, Volume V, Issue 1, Winter/Spring. Oyejide, T. A. (2000): “Africa and the World Trading System: Project Summary Report”, mimeo, AERC, Nairobi. Vamvakidis, A. (1998): “Regional Integration and Economic Growth”, World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 12, Issue 2, Pp. 251-270. Yang, Y. and Gupta, S. (2005): “Regional Trade Arrangements in Africa: Past Performance and the Way Forward”, IMF Working Paper, WP/05/36. Bibliography Baldwin, R.E (1997): “Review of Theoretical Developments on Regional Integration” in Oyejide, et al (eds) , Regional Integration and Trade Liberalization in Sub – Saharan Africa, Vol I, Macmillian, London. Collier P. (1999): “On Economic Consequences of Civil War”. Oxford Economic papers, Vol. 51(1): 168-83. Collier P. and Hoeffler A. (1998): “On economic causes of Civil War, Oxford Economic papers”. Elbadawi, I. (1997):“The impact of Regional Trade and Monetary Schemes on Intra- Sub – Saharan African Trade” , in Oyejide A. et al (eds), Regional Integration and Trade Liberalization in Sub – Saharan Africa , Vol I, I Macmillan London. Harrold, P. (1995): “The Impact of the Uruguay Round on Africa: Much Ado About Nothing?” World Bank Conference on “The Uruguay Round and the Developing Economies”, Jan. 26-27, 1995, World Bank, Washington, D. C. 26 | P a g e Oyejide, T.A. (1997): “Regional Integration and trade Liberalization in Sub – Saharan Africa”: An AERC Collaboration Research Project Summary Report”, AERC Special Paper, No 28, AERC, Nairobi. Oyejide, T. A. (1999): “Options for future Trade Liberalization in Sub-Saharan Africa”, In Oyejide, A. B. Ndulu and Greenaway .D. (eds), Regional Integration and Trade Liberalization in Sub-Saharan Africa. Vol. 4: Synthesis and Review, Macmillan, London. Rodrik, D. (1998): “Why is Trade Reform So Difficult in Africa?”, Journal of African Economies Vol. 7, Supplement 1, June, pp. 10-36. 50: 563-73. Yeats, A. J. (1998): “What Can Be Expected from African Regional Trade Arrangements? Some Empirical Evidence” Policy Research Working Paper 2004, World Bank, Washington, D. C. IMF (2010): Sub-Saharan Africa Regional Economic Outlook: Resilience and Risks Morrissey, O. (2007): “Trade Policy and Transport Costs: What can the EU do to Promote Export Growth in East Africa?’”, in W. Hout (ed.), EU Development Policy and Poverty Reduction: Enhancing Effectiveness, Aldershot: Ashgate UNCTAD (2009): “Economic Development in Africa”: Strengthening Regional Economic Integration for Africa’s Development. Wang, Z. K. and. Winters L. A (1997): “Africa’s Role in Multilateral Trade Negotiations”, Policy Research Working Paper No, 1846, World Bank, Washington D.C. 27 | P a g e