Description

advertisement
Decentralization Reforms
and
Commune-Level Services Delivery
in Cambodia
Leonardo G. Romeo
Luc Spyckerelle
Case Study submitted at a Workshop on
"Local Government Pro-Poor Service Delivery"
Manila, 10th-12th February 2004
Jointly sponsored
by
Asian Development Bank
Asian Development Bank Institute
United Nations Capital Development Fund
December 2003
Table of contents
Acronyms and abbreviations
ii
Executive summary
iii
1. Introduction
1
2. Cambodia’s decentralization reforms: rationale, features and limitations
1
2.1.
Political dimensions
1
2.2.
Administrative and fiscal dimensions
3
3. The emergence of Commune Councils as services delivery units
4
3.1.
Size of jurisdictions and viability of services delivery units
4
3.2.
Legal mandate
5
3.3.
The Commune finance system
6
3.4.
The Commune development planning system
9
3.5.
The Commune procurement and project implementation system
12
4. Commune-level services delivery: the early experience (2002-2003)
12
4.1.
Emerging policy recognition of the Communes’ role
12
4.2.
Communes at work: Local development initiatives (2002-2003)
14
4.3.
Allocative efficiency issues
21
4.4.
Productive efficiency issues
23
5. The way forward
26
5.1.
Maintaining the CSF promise
26
5.2.
Developing a vision for the Communes’ role on services delivery
27
5.3.
Developing local financial management regulations that support
increased Communes’ responsibilities for services delivery
27
5.4.
Investing in a system of State support and supervision to Commune
Councils
27
6. Conclusions
28
i
Acronyms and abbreviations
CDP
Commune Development Plan
CIP
Commune Investment Program
CSF
Commune/Sangkat Fund
DIW
District Integration Workshop
IO
International Organization
LDF
Local Development Fund
MoEF
Ministry of Economy and Finance
NCSC
National Committee for Support to the Communes/Sangkats
NGO
Non-Government Organization
NPRS
National Poverty Reduction Strategy
PBC
Planning and Budgeting Committee
POLA
Provincial Office of Local Administration
ii
Executive summary
Decentralization reforms in Cambodia are only two years old and the system of
decentralized planning and financing of local development is still in its infancy.
The major political development initiated with the 2002 election of Commune
Councils, is yet to be followed by a number fiscal and administrative reforms that
would strengthen the capacity of Communes to deliver services and fight poverty.
Such capacity is currently constrained by a still embryonic local administration
and by system-wide problems that include gaps in the regulatory framework,
limited financial resources, lack of inter-communal arrangements that address
the viability of individual jurisdictions, lack of an effective provincial system of
state support and supervision, and retards in the deconcentration reforms that
could provide for more responsive and cooperative inter-governmental relations
between Communes and the national sector agencies most concerned with propoor services delivery.
In spite of the above, two years into their first mandate, the Councils have started
to deliver services, helped by the devolution of a minimum of freely
programmable resources through the Commune/Sangkat Fund (CSF), a fiscal
transfers facility supported by domestic and external contributions, and by the
adoption of a statutory process of Commune Development Planning (CDP),
jointly regulated by the Ministries of Planning and Interior. Through District
Integration Workshops, a formal step in the CDP designed to harmonize locallevel and provincial sector planning, Communes have also been able to access
some of the resources of programs funded and managed by aid agencies,
provincial departments and NGOs.
The focus of Communes’ action has been on the development of small-scale
infrastructure, whose financing absorbed all CSF resources in 2002 and 2003. In
both years, over 60% went to rural transport projects (roads, small bridges and
culverts). In 2003 the second most important category of projects (absorbing
16.3% of the CSF resources) included the construction and rehabilitation of
canals and other irrigation structures. These two categories of investments, on
which three quarters of the CSF resources were spent, reveal the strong local
preference for economic infrastructures. As for the remaining quarter of CSF
resources for social infrastructures, most went to improve access to drinking
water and build school facilities, with only a minor share going to improve health
care facilities.
This focus on economic infrastructure has been criticized as the product of a too
narrow “roads and canals mentality”, but whether or not Commune Councils
should invest more in other types of activities remains at present open to
question. Councils could certainly do more for the delivery of education and
iii
health services, but this largely depends on the development of clear sector
policies and related inter-institutional arrangements. Councils could also be (and
somehow are starting to be) more active in delivery of traditional municipal
services (urban transport, water supply and sanitation, solid wastes, markets,
etc.). But again this will depend on how urban management responsibilities will
eventually be structured and the mandate of Sangkats will be defined. Finally,
some would like to see more action in the promotion of local “economic”
development, beyond the Councils’ investments in transport and irrigation. But
given their current institutional weaknesses, the risk is high that the Councils
would not be guided by a public policy rationale in their support to private
ventures (funding provision of buffaloes, fertilizers, support to enterprises, etc.)
and that benefits from this kind of projects would be easily captured by the
relatively wealthier and more influential local people with little or no effect on
poverty reduction.
On the other hand, while systematic evaluations are still lacking, recent studies
based on sample surveys, have concluded that Commune residents, including
the poor among them, are generally satisfied with the outcome of the local
planning and resources allocation process, and expect to benefit from the
Commune funded roads, irrigation and schools projects, which then seem to
reflect actual needs and a broad-based local demand. A concern, however, in
terms of allocative efficiency, is the inadequate attention to maintenance, which
may threaten the sustainability of locally created assets. Addressing this issue
may require additional regulations specifying “mandatory development
expenditures” that Communes must undertake to maintain assets for which they
are legally responsible, before embarking on any new construction.
As to the efficiency with which Communes’ resources have been used,
systematic evaluation data are not yet available. However, a recent study
compared the actual costs of a large sample of Commune-funded construction
projects with “reference prices” based on average market costs of materials and
contractors’ overheads, and other agencies’ estimates and found that the costs
of Commune projects were generally lower than the reference prices and those
incurred by other agencies. Instead of being inflated to facilitate corrupt practices,
as some had suggested, Commune-managed contracts prices were possibly
failing to reflect the true costs of the works, resulting in pressures to “cut corners”
during implementation and produce lower quality outputs. Indeed another recent
survey of a sample of 13 Communes suggests that quality problems in
Commune-managed infrastructure projects may be widespread; potentially
reducing any productive efficiency gains derived from local competition and lower
contract costs. A number of reasons seem at play in lowering outputs quality.
Delays in transfer of CSF resources, (as those actually experienced in 2003),
may create cash flow problems for contractors, compromise construction
schedule and result in inappropriate wet-season operations. Also lack of
Communes’ compliance with contractual obligations to provide labor or cash
contributions may be used by contractors to lower their effort and deny
iv
responsibilities. Commune Chiefs are still uncertain about their powers and their
responsibility to stop payments when faced with unsatisfactory performance of
the contractors. They rely entirely on the engineering services of provincial/
district technicians whose accountability to the Councils remains weak and
whose ability to provide the required contracts administration services may be
overstretched. “Social auditing” by users groups and project beneficiaries of the
performance of contractors and services’ providers could help to enhance the
quality of the produced outputs, but its practice has been sporadic and not well
established.
Much remains to be done to enable Communes to play a greater role in service
delivery and poverty reduction. The Government’s commitment to increasing and
predictable transfers via the CSF must be confirmed, reassuring Communes that
the difficulties experienced in 2003 are the exception and not the rule. Local
financial management regulations should be revised or developed to encourage
spending in local assets maintenance and other recurrent costs associated with
services delivery. The experimentation of innovative intergovernmental partnerships for delivery of services in the health, education, agriculture and rural
development sectors must be initiated as soon as possible with credible
commitment by concerned Ministries as to their evaluation and mainstreaming.
The flexibility of provincial departments to respond to Commune requests in the
frame of District Integration Workshops, must be enhanced by deconcentration of
allocation decisions. And finally the government should invest in a
provincial/district system of support and supervision to the Communes, adopting
some of the successful practices and arrangements implemented under the Seila
program and providing this system with a firmer footing than the current exclusive
reliance on external aid.
Ultimately, enabling the Communes Councils to become significant services
providers in the eyes of their local constituencies will also help realize the political
goal of the Cambodia decentralization reforms: establishing a democratic State
presence at the local level.
v
xøwmsarsegçb
RbeTskm<úCa
)ancab;epþImGnuvtþkMENTMrg;vimCÄkar
eTIbEt)anry³eBlEt2qñaMb:ueNÑaH
CamYy
nwgRbB½n§ksagEpnkarnighirBaØvtßúEbbvim
CÄkard¾ekµgx©I
sMrab;karGPivDÆn_mUldæan
.
ehIyCamYyKña
enHEdr
karpøas;bþÚrd¾sMxan;mYyEpñkneya)ay
KWkare)aHeqñateRCIserIsRkumRbwkSaXMu
sgáat; RtUv)aneFVIeLIg kalBIExkumÖ³ qñaM
2002
knøgeTAenH
.
EteTaHbICay:agNak¾eday
rdæaPi)al
enAmankargarCaeRcIneTot
Tak;TgnwgkMENTMrg;Epñkrdæ)alnigsareBIBn
§
EdlcaM)ac;RtUvbnþGnuvtþ
kñúgeKalbMNgBRgwgsmtßPaBXMu
sgáat;
kñúgkarpþl;esvakmµkñúgmUldæan
edIm,Ikat;bnßyPaBRkIRk .
rhUtmkdl;eBlenH
karksagsmtßPaBEdl)aneBalxagelI
KWkMBugCYbRbTHpllM)ak
CaeRcIn
edaysarrdæ)almUldæanEdleTIbCab;eqñatenA
ekµgx©I
RBmTaMgbBaðaepSg²eTot
vi
Tak;TgnwgRbB½n§kargar
PaBxVHcenøaHEpñkRkbx½NÐc,ab;
FnFanhirBaØvtßúmankMNt;
kgVHxatkarcat;EcgeGaymankic©shkarrvag
XMusgáat;nigXMusgáat;
EdlkgVHxatenHGaceFVIeGayXMusgáat;tUc²
CYbkarlM)ak
kñúgkarTTYlykesvakmµ
kgVHxatRbB½n§KaMRTnigRtYtBinitüEdlman
RbsiT§iPaBBIfñak;extþ
nigPaByWty:avkñúgkarGnuvtþn_kMENTMrg;
vishmCÄkarCaedIm
.l.
kMENTMrg;vishmCÄkar
GacCMrujeGaymankarKaMRT
nigkic©shkarkan;Et
RbesIreLIgrbs;Gnþrsßab½nrdæaPi)al
CamYyXMusgáat; nigPñak;garfñak;Cati .
eTaHbICamanpllM)akdUc)anerobrab;xagel
Ik¾eday
kñúgry³eBl2qñaMénGaNtþidMbUgrbs;xøÜnen
H
RkumRbwkSaXMusgáat;)ancab;epþImpþl;esv
akmµnana edayBwgEp¥kelImUlniFiXMusgáat;
(CSF)
EdlraC
rdæaPi)al)anviPaCeGay
ehIyEdlXMusgáat;Gaccat;EcgmUlniFienHtamt
MrUvkarcaM)ac;enAmUldæan
karepÞr
vii
sMPar³BImUldæannigBIGñkpþl;CMnYyxageRk
A
RBmTaMgBwgEp¥kelIdMeNIrkarksagEpnkarX
Musgáat;
Edl)an
erobcMeLIgrYmKñaedayRksYgEpnkarnigRksY
gmhaépÞ
.
tamry³
sikçasalasmahrNkmµEpnkarfñak; Rsuk (DIW)
edIm,IbnSIúEpnkarfñak;mUldæan
nigEpnkarrbs;mnÞIrvis½yfñak;extþ
XMusgáat;GacTTYl)ankar
KaMRTCaeRcInBIPñak;garpþl;CMnYy
mnÞIrCMnaj
nigBIGgÁkarminEmnrdæaPi)al
ehIyEdlkarKaMRTTaMgenaH
xøH
manenAkñúgEpnkarvinieyaKrbs;XMusgáat;
nigxøHeTotRtUv)anelIkeLIgedayPñak;garpþl;C
MnYyTaMgenaH .
viii
PaKeRcInénmUlniFiXMusgáat;qñaM2002
nigqñaM2003
RtUv)anepþatCasMxan;eTAelIkarksagehdæa
rcnasm<½n§xñattUc
.
kñúgqñaM2002
nigqñaM
2003
fvikaRbmaNCag
60°
énmUlniFiXMusgáat;
RtUv)anepþat
elIKMeragKmnaKmn_CnbT ¬pøÚv s<antUc²
niglU¦ . edayELkkñúgqñaM 2003 RbePT
KMeragEdlsMxan;TI2
KWkarsagsg;nigsþareLIgvijnUvRbLaynigehdæ
arcnasm<½n§FarasaRsþ
EdlRtUveRbIfvikaGs;RbmaNCa
16/3°énmUlniFiXMusgáat;
.
dUecñH
Ep¥kelIRbePTvinieyaKTaMgBIrEdl
RsUbykFnFanRbmaNCa
3¼4
énmUlniFiXMusgáat;enH )anbgðajeGayeXIjfa
mUldæanenAmantMrUvkarx<s;elIvis½yehdæa
rcnasm<½n§
esdækic©
.
1¼4eToténmUlniFiXMusgáat;
RtUv)aneRbIR)as;sMrab;vis½yehdæarcnasm<
½n§sgÁmkic© EdlPaK eRcInénFnFan1¼4enH
RtUv)anepþateTAelITwks¥at
GaKarsikSa
nigmYyPaKtUcénFnFan1¼4enH
RtUv)an
epþateTAelIEpñkEfTaMsuxPaB .
ix
edaysarEtFnFanPaKeRcInénmUlniFiXMus
gáat;
RtUv)anepþatCasMxan;eTAelIehdæarcnasm<
½n§
esdækic©
)aneFVIeGaymanmtiriHKn;CaeRcInfa
lT§plénKMeragTaMgenaHmanlkçN³tUcceg¥ót
¬mann½yfa
vaepþatEteTAelIpøÚvlMnigRbLay¦KWcg;minc
g;
RkumRbwkSaXMusgáat;KYrEteFVIkarvinieya
KelIRbePTskmµPaB
epSg²CaeRcIneTotEdlcaM)ac;
.
RkumRbwkSaXMusgáat;
KYrEteFVIkarvinieyaKelIvis½yepSg²eTot
dUcCa
esvakmµEpñkGb;rM
nigsuxPaB
b:uEnþkarvinieyaKEbbenH
k¾GaRs½ymYyPaKFM elIkarKaMRTBIbNþa
mnÞIrCMnaj
nigsßab½nBak;B½n§
ehIyGaceFVIeTA)anluHRtaEtmnÞIrnigsßab½n
TaMgenaH maneKalneya)ayvis½y nigkic©
shkarGnþrsßab½nc,as;las; . CagenHeTAeTot
RkumRbwkSaKYrEt¬cab;epþIm¦eFVIskmµPaB
eGaykan;Et
skmµeLIgEfmeTot
kñúgkarpþl;esvakmµenAmUldæan
¬dUcCa
KmnaKmn_TIRbCMuCn karpÁt;pÁgTwks¥at
x
nig
Gnam½y
karRKb;RKgkaksMNl;nigTIpSarCaedIm
.l.¦
b:uEnþ
enHk¾GaRs½yelI
faetIkarTTYlxusRtUvkñúg
karRKb;RKgTIRbCMuCn nigGaNtþirbs;sgáat;
RtUv)ankMNt;EbbNa
.
cugbBa©b;
GñkxøHcg;eGayman
skmµPaBbEnßmeTotepþatelIkarelIkkMBs;kar
GPivDÆn_
:esdækic©
:mUldæanbEnßmelIkarvinieyaKelIvis½y
KmnaKmn_nigehdæarcnasm<½n§xagelI.
b:uEnþbc©úb,nñ
edaysarsmtßPaBrbs;XMusgáat;enAmankMNt;
KWvaCa
karRbfuyRbfanx<s;Nas;
sMrab;XMusgáat;pþl;karKaMRTdl;GaCIvkrÉkC
nelIkarpþl;Tun sMrab;TijstV Bahn³ CIKImI
nigkarKaMRTdl;shRKasFuntUcCaedImenaH
ehIyk¾GaceFVIeGayRbeyaCn_PaKeRcInénK
Merag
enH
nwgRtUv)anekþabykedayGñkmanluy
nigGñkmanGMNacmYycMnYn
KWminsUvb¤Kµan\T§iBlesaH
dl;kar
kat;bnßyPaBRkIRk .
mü:agvijeTot
edaysareBlenHenAminTan;mankarvaytMélEdl
xi
manlkçN³CaRbB½n§
karsikSa
mYykñúgeBlfµI²enHedayEp¥kelIkarGegátmYy
cMnYn
)ansnñidæanfa
RbCaBlrdækñúgXMusgáat;rYmTaMgGñkEdl
manCIvPaBGn;exSaypgEdr
CaTUeTAeBjcitþnwglT§plTTYl)anBIkarksagEp
nkarmUldæan
nigdMeNIrkar
viPaCn_FnFanEdl)anGnuvtþknøgmk
ehIyBYkeKEtgEtsgÄwmfanwgTTYlRbeyaCn_B
IKMeragpøÚvlM
Fara
sa®sþ
nigKMeragsalaeron
edayeRbIR)as;mUlniFiXMusgáat;rbs;xøÜn
EdlKMeragTaMgenH
BitCa)aneqøIytb
eTAnwgtMrUvkarCak;EsþgenAmUldæan
.
b:uEnþkarRBYy)armµN_Tak;TgeTAnwgRbsiT
§iPaBkñúgkareRbIR)as;mUlniFi
enAEtman
KWkgVHxatkarykcitþkñúgkarEfTaMelIsmiT§ipl
TaMgLayenAmUldæan
EdlGacKMramKMEhgdl;
cIrPaBrbs;KMeragpgEdr
.
dUcenH
edIm,IrkSacIrPaBKMerag
caM)ac;RtUvmanbTbBaØtþibEnßmepSg²eTot
Edl bBa¢ak;BI :GaNtþicMNayelIkarGPivDÆn_
:
EdlXMusgáat;RtUvGnuvtþ
edIm,IEfrkSasmiT§iplTaMgenaH
Rsb
xii
eTAtamkarTTYlxusRtUvtampøÚvc,ab;rbs;xøÜ
n
munnwgGnuBaØatieGaymankarsagsg;fµImYy
eTot .
mkdl;eBlenH
eyIgenAminGacdwgBIRbsiT§iPaB
énkareRbIR)as;FnFanhirBaØvtßúrbs;XMu)ane
T
edaysareyIgenAminTan;manTinñn½yvaytMéle
nAeLIy
.
EteTaHbICaya:gNa
karsikSamYykñúgeBlfµI²
enH
)aneFVIkareRbobeFobcMNayCak;Esþgrbs;KM
eragsagsg;mYycMnYnEdleRbIR)as;fvikaXMus
gáat;
CamYy
nwg
:tMéleKal
:¬EdlEp¥kelItMélmFüménsMPar³sMNg;enATIp
Sar
nigcMNayepSg²rbs;GñkTTYlkar¦
RBmTaMg)aneRbobeFobCamYynwgtMél)a:n;
sµanrbs;Pñak;garepSg²eTot
eyIgeXIjfa
KMeragTaMgenaH
niyayCarYmKWmantMélTabCagtMéleKal
nigTabCagtMél)a:n;sµanedayPñak;gar
.
eyIgeXIjfa
edIm,I
biT)aMgkarbMe)a:gtMélKMerag
GñkTTYlkarPaKeRcInEtgEt)anbnÞabtMélKMer
aghYsBIkarBit
edIm,IGacman
xiii
»kaskan;Etx<s;kñúgkaredjéfø
EtpÞúyeTAvijeBledjéfø)anKMeragehIyenaH
BYkeK)anBüayambRgYm
TMhMKMeragenAeBlGnuvtþkarsagsg;
nigbnÞabKuNPaBKMerag
.
CakarBitNas;
karGegátmYykñúgeBlfµI²
enHeTAelIXMucMnYn13)anbBa¢ak;bEnßmeT
otfa
bBaðaKuNPaBrbs;KMeragehdæarcnasm<½n§
EdlRKb;RKgeday
XMusgáat;
KWkMBugEtmanbBaðay:agxøaMg
Edlmann½yfa
GacCakarkat;bnßyRbsiT§iPaBKMerag
edaysarEt
tMélKMeragTabeBk
.
enAmanehtuplmYycMnYneTot
EdlGñkTTYlkarykmkeRbIR)as;CamUlehtukñúg
karbnÞabKuNPaBKMerag
dUcCa
karyWty:avkñúgkarepÞrmUlniFiXMusgáat;
¬dUc
EdlekItmankñúgqñaM
2003¦
k¾GaceFVIeGaylMhUrfvikamanbBaðapgEdrdl
;GñkTTYlkar
nigGaceFVIeGaymankarEksMrYlkalviPaK
sagsg;
EdlGaceFVIeGaykarsagsg;mankaryWty:av
edayRtUvBnüaeBleTAsagsg;enArdUvvsSavij
xiv
CaedIm
.l.
cMNucmYyeTotEdlGñkTTYlkarGaceRbICamUl
ehtuedIm,Ikat;bnßykarxitxMRbwgERbg
nig
bdiesFkarTTYlxusRtUvrbs;xøÜnEdrenaH
KWXMusgáat;
min)anGnuvtþkatBVkic©kic©snüarbs;xøÜn
kñúgkarpþl;
kMlaMgBlkmµ
b¤TunbdiPaKkñúgKMerag
.
emXMu
ecAsgáat;enAminTan;yl;c,as;BIGMNacnigtYna
TIrbs;xøÜn
kñúgkarminecjGaNtþicMNayeTAeGayGñkTTYl
karNamYy
enAeBlEdlXMusgáat;BinitüeXIjfa
kar
sagsg;enaHminRtUvGnuvtþtaml½kçx½NÐbec
©keTs
dUcEdlmanEcgenAkñúgkic©snüasagsg;
.
emXMu ecA sgáat;BwgEp¥kTaMgRsugeTAelI
CMnajbec©keTsrbs;m®nþIsMrbsMrYlextþnigR
suk EdlkarTTYlxusRtUv rbs;GñkTaMgenaH
cMeBaHRkumRbwkSaenAmanPaBTn;RCayen
AeLIy
ehIyEdllT§PaBBYkeKenAmankMNt;
kñúgkarpþl;esvaRtYtBinitükic©snüa
.
:svnkmµrbs;RbCaCnmUldæan
:
¬GacCaRkumGñkeRbIR)as;
nigGñk
TTYlplBIKMerag¦
xv
elIkarGnuvtþn_rbs;GñkTTYlkar
nigGñkpþl;esvakmµnana
GacCYyFana)anKuNPaB
rbs;KMerag
b:uEnþkarGnuvtþn_Cak;Esþgrbs;Rkumsvnkm
µenH
KwminRtUv)aneFVIeLIgCab;lab;eT
ehIyk¾minRtUv )anbegáIteLIgsmRsbEdr .
enAmankargarCaeRcIneTotEdlRtUveFVI
edIm,IeGayXMusgáat;
GacedIrtYnaTIkan;EtsMxan;
kñúgkarpþl;
esvakmµedIm,Ikat;bnßyPaBRkIRk
.
qnÞ³rbs;raCrdæaPi)alkñúgkarbegáInmUlniFiX
Musgáat;
nigkñúgkarepÞr
mUlniFienH
RtUvEtbBa¢ak;eGay)anc,as;
edayRtUvGHGagmþgeTotcMeBaHXMusgáat;f
a
pllM)akkñúgkarepÞr
mUlniFiEdl)anekIteLIgkñúgqñaM
2003enH
KWCakrNIelIkElg
ehIyvanwgminkøayCaTMlab;enaHeT
.
bTbBaØatþinanaTak;TgnwgkarRKb;RKghirBa
Øvtßú KYrEtRtUv)anBinitüeLIgvij b¤begáIteLIg
edIm,ICMrujeGay
mankarcMNaykñúgkarEfrkSasmiT§iplsMerc)an
kñúgmUldæan
RBmTaMgkarcMNayepSg²eTotsMrab;karpþl;
esvakmµ
.
xvi
tamry³karvaytMél)anbgðajeGayeXIjfa
bTBiesaFPaBCaédKUrvagsßab½nrdæaPi)al
kñúgkarpþl;esvakmµelIvis½ysuxaPi)al Gb;rM
ksikmµ
nigkarGPivDÆn_CnbT
caM)ac;RtUvEtpþÜcepþImeLIg
eGay)anqab;bMput
CamYynwgkarebþCJacitþd¾RsYcRsavBIRksY
g¼
sßab½nBak;B½n§.
caM)ac;RtUvEtCMrujlT§PaB
kñúgkareqøIytbrbs;mnÞIrvis½y
elIskmµPaBGaTiPaBrbs;XMusgáat;
Edl)anelIkeLIgenAkñúgsikçasala
smahrNkmµEpnkarfñak;Rsuk
edayEp¥kelImUlniFivinieyaKextþEdl)anviPaCt
amEbbvishmCÄkar.
ehIyenATIbMput
rdæaPi)alKYrEtvinieyaKelIRbB½n§KaMRTnig
RtYtBinitüdl;XMusgáat;rbs;fñak;extþ¼Rsuk
eday
RtUvTTYlyknUvbTBiesaFnigkarcat;EcgRbkbed
ayeCaKC½ymYycMnYnrbs;kmµviFIsila
ehIyRtUvBRgwg eGaykan;EtrwgmaMEfmeTot
edIm,IEfrkSacIrPaBénRbB½n§TaMgenH
bnÞab;BIkmµviFIsilaRtUv)anbBa©b;
eday
mincaM)ac;BwgEp¥ky:agxøaMgelI
CMnYybreTsenaHeT .
xvii
TIbMput
eyIgnwgGaceFVIeGayRkumRbwkSaXMusgáat
;køayCaGñkpþl;esvakmµd¾sMxan;kñúgRkEs
EPñkrbs;
RbCaBlrdæmUldæan
ehIyvak¾GacCYyeFVIeGaysMerc)annUveKal
edAEpñkneya)ayrbs;raCrdæaPi)alkm<úCa
kñúgkareFVIkMENTMrg;vimCÄkar
KWkarbegáIteLIgnUvrdæmYyRbkbedaylT§iRb
CaFibetyüenAtammUldæan .
xviii
Decentralization Reforms and
Commune-Level Services Delivery in Cambodia
1. Introduction
This paper reviews the emerging role of elected Commune Councils as services
delivery units within Cambodia’s public sector.
Section 2 reviews the ongoing process of Cambodia’s decentralization reforms,
and highlights how such process is still at a very early stage, and is characterized
by a marked asymmetry between the political, the fiscal and, most strikingly, the
administrative, dimensions of the reforms.
Section 3 reviews the basic public expenditure financing and management systems
that were developed and are being extended to the new authorities to enable them
to address local development issues and assume increasing service delivery
responsibilities.
Section 4 reviews the initial role of Commune Councils, two years into their first
mandate, in local development management and services delivery. It looks at the
Council’s role both “on the demand side”, where they may better articulate local
services needs and priorities, and “on the supply side”, where they may actually
improve the provision and production of infrastructure and services. It then reviews
the emerging allocative and productive efficiency issues.
Section 5 suggests ways forward to empower Commune authorities to take on a
bigger role in the provision of local services and become more involved with the
implementation of the national strategy for poverty reduction.
Section 6 provides a summary of the paper’s main conclusions.
2. Cambodia’s decentralization reforms: rationale, features and limitations
2.1. Political dimensions
One of the most significant dates in Cambodia’s recent history was Sunday 3
February 2002. On that day 954 women and 10,307 men in all 1,621 Communes
and Sangkat1 of Cambodia were elected as members of Commune or Sangkat
Councils. Each Council has 5, 7, 9 or 11 members, depending on the population of
the Commune.
The rationale for the decentralization reform was first and foremost political; to
strengthen the presence and legitimacy of the State at the local level through
The ‘Sangkat’ is the equivalent of a Commune in a municipality. Communes are predominantly rural,
and Sangkats are normally urban, but there are also “urbanized” Communes and “rural” Sangkats.
From this point onward, the term ’Commune’ will be used to refer to both the Commune and the
Sangkat.
1
1
democratically elected local Councils2. Before the election, appointed Commune
Chiefs and Commune Deputy Chiefs governed the Communes.
For the whole of Cambodia, the division of the seats between the three main
parties: the Cambodia People’s Party (CPP), the FUNCINPEC and the Sam
Rainsy Party (SRP), by position in the Commune Council, is shown in Table 1.
Political parties
CPP
Number of votes
% of votes
Chief
1st Deputy
2nd Deputy
Other Councilors
Total # of seats
% of seats
FUNCINPEC
SRP
2,674,303
958,326
731,150
61.2%
21.9%
16.7%
Distribution of seats in Commune Councils
1,598
10
13
789
547
285
154
852
615
5,162
802
433
7,703
2,211
1,346
68.4%
19.6%
12.0%
Other
8,934
0.2%
0
0
0
1
1
0.0%
Table 1: Results of Commune Councils’ elections, 2002
The CPP, as the dominant political party, was thus able to extend its dominance in
national politics to the local level as well. Yet, the electoral system (a modified
proportional system) also favored the association of minority parties to the
management of the Councils. While the Commune Chief position went
automatically to the top candidate of the winning party, the electoral rules required
that the positions of First and Second Deputy Commune Chief be given to the top
candidates of the party lists that obtained the second and third highest number of
votes, even if, individually, these candidates had obtained less votes than other
councilors from the winning party3. The intention was to promote sharing of
responsibilities and cooperative behavior between opposing political parties. While,
in practice, this is not without its problems, anecdotal evidence suggests that in
most Communes, differences in political affiliation have not precluded effective
collaboration between Councilors.
Another feature of the Commune-level governance system is the emergence of
complementary forms of “territorial representation” and their articulation with the
formal political / party-based, representation system embodied by the Commune
Councils. Each Commune consists of a number of villages, but the local electoral
system does not ensure that every village in a Commune will have a representative
in the Commune Council. This highlights the risk that the attention and resources
Two other objectives of Cambodia’s decentralization reform were: to promote participatory
development at the local level, and to contribute to poverty reduction.
3 If only two parties obtain votes in a Commune, then the winning party obtains the Commune Chief and
First Deputy Commune Chief positions, and the second party fills the Second Deputy Commune Chief
position.
2
2
of the Council, may be biased in favor of just those villages where the elected
Councilors live, or from which they originate.
Village-based representative structures, playing both an extension and advisory
role vis-à-vis the formal Councils, are essential to address the above risk and
improve local governance overall. One such structure, whose establishment is
mandated by the Commune planning regulations, is the Commune Planning and
Budgeting Committee (PBC). This is an advisory body which has a critical function
in local public expenditures management and in which each village is represented
by two persons (one man and one woman). These representatives may be able to
voice the concerns of their villages, learn about, and assess, higher-order,
commune-level priorities and both influence Commune-level resources allocations
and play a political education role back in their communities.
Overall however, the articulation of village-based structures with elected Commune
Councils remains a critical and somehow controversial point in the effort to foster
community representation and participation in local-level governance. Such
articulation should be clarified and strengthened, once the selection – hopefully the
election – of village chiefs and village chief assistants has been regulated by the
Ministry of Interior. This is one of the important outstanding regulations of the Law
on Commune/Sangkat Administrative Management (the “Commune Law”).
2.2. Administrative and fiscal dimensions
The Commune Law — approved in 2001 — provides the basic legal framework for
the establishment and operation of the Cambodian local Councils. The Law
empowers the Communes with legislative and executive authority and establishes
the Commune Councils as the bodies representing their citizens. The Commune
functions however, are defined by the Law, in broad and permissive, rather than
mandatory, terms and include both the provision of general administration and
local development services. Although Commune Councils may be able to recruit
their own administrative staff, currently the local administration is headed by (and
in most cases only consists of) a Commune Clerk recruited and paid by the
Ministry of Interior.
With respect to local finances, the Law first requires each Commune to have its
own financial resources, budget and assets. Second, it gives Communes the right
to collect direct revenues from local taxes, fees, and other service charges. Third,
it entitles Communes to receive transfers from a share of national revenue. Fourth,
it provides for the central government to compensate the Communes when the
latter perform any function on behalf of the national administration (agency
functions). Fifth, it establishes the Commune/Sangkat Fund (CSF) as a primary
mechanism for fiscal transfers. Sixth, it requires Communes to prepare an annual
balanced budget. Seventh, it prohibits Communes from direct borrowing. Eighth, it
provides for the transfers of certain government assets to the Communes. Finally,
it establishes a local financial management system and entrusts the Ministry of
3
Economy and Finance with the responsibility to monitor and control Commune
finances.
Overall, two years after the local elections, a mixed picture is emerging in which
the newly created Commune Councils: (i) appear to have made a difference and
have the potential to substantially improve local governance at the periphery,
(ii) have obtained, through transfers, a minimum of resources which they are
starting to apply to the promotion of local development and local services delivery,
but (iii) are seriously constrained as services delivery units, by questions of fiscal
and technical viability, the lack of clarity in assignment of responsibilities, the
limitations of their own executive organs, and the difficulties in securing appropriate
support from a national administration whose deconcentration has not yet followed
in the steps of the decentralization reforms.
In the following sections we explore in greater details the challenges of the newly
elected Cambodian Commune Councils as local services delivery units.
3. The emergence of Commune Councils as services delivery units
3.1. Size of jurisdictions and viability of services delivery units
The scope for assuming services delivery responsibilities is obviously related to the
size of the Commune jurisdictions. This varies greatly, as shown in Figure 1 which
reflects the distribution of the Cambodian Communes by the size of their
population.
50-80,000
25-50,000
1
14
179
Population
12.5-25,000
173
10-12,500
263
8-10,000
316
6-8,000
312
4-6,000
254
2-4,000
< 2,000
109
No. of communes
Figure 1: Distribution of Communes by population size
The smallest Commune has 205 inhabitants, and the biggest one (a town on the
border with Thailand) has 79,406. The average Commune size is about 7,600
inhabitants. It is generally believed that many Communes are too small to be able
to operate effectively as units of local government that are capable of adequately
providing a minimum level of services. One of the working groups of the National
4
Committee for Support to the Communes/Sangkat (NCSC), which was established
to oversee the implementation of the decentralization reforms and the completion
of their regulatory framework, is responsible for reviewing the Commune
boundaries, determine the viability of the Communes as services delivery units and
assess whether they can operate in a sustainable and effective manner. This
working group may also recommend the establishment of cooperative
arrangements between Commune Councils, or the creation of multi- or singlepurpose service districts, if such arrangements are suggested by the limitations of
the fiscal base of individual jurisdictions or by economies of scale and other
considerations in the service’s delivery. So far, however this NCSC working group
has not indicated how it plans to review the Commune boundaries and develop
proposals of inter-communal cooperative arrangements for services delivery.
3.2. Legal mandate
A basic principle underlying the Cambodian decentralization reforms is that
Commune Councils were not elected only to deliver administrative services,
mediate local conflicts and maintain law and order within their jurisdiction. Indeed
Commune authorities were meant to assume primary responsibility for local
economic and social development. To this effect, the Commune Law gives to local
Councils, broadly defined powers to handle “local affairs”, meet basic needs and
serve the common interests of Commune residents.
Importantly, the Law recognizes that when promoting local development,
Commune authorities may act either as representatives of a local political
constituency, to implement their own policies and programs, with their own
resources, or as “agents” of the State, implementing policies and programs defined
and funded by higher-level authorities. To prevent unfunded mandates, the Law
also stipulates that any State agency requesting Commune authorities to carry out
administrative or developmental functions on their behalf, should ensure that the
Councils have the capacity and obtain the financial and other means to implement
such functions.
However, having stated such principles, the Law remains extremely vague as to
the actual responsibilities of the Councils for services delivery. It stipulates that
Commune authorities should “…arrange necessary public services and be
responsible for the good process of those affairs…”, but does not specify
mandatory responsibilities with respect to any public service. This is true for both
economic and social services in sectors typically regulated by national ministries
(e.g. health, education, water and sanitation, etc.), and for services which are
traditionally the exclusive responsibility of local authorities (like solid waste
collection and disposal, street cleaning, upkeep of parks and gardens, etc.).
The absence of clearly articulated services delivery mandates for the newly elected
Commune Councils, may become an impediment to move forward with
decentralization and the related progressive devolution of responsibilities and
5
resources. However, it should not necessarily be considered a shortcoming of the
early reforms implementation strategy. Decentralization in Cambodia is making its
first steps and besides the unresolved issues of viability of many jurisdictions as
services delivery units, there are real and widespread problems of local capacity
that need to be taken into account before proceeding to wholesale devolution of
functions.
By not imposing a wide array of functions onto the Communes, but letting them
handle primarily administrative tasks (such as civil registration) and experiment
with the contracting of local works, goods or services, the Councils gradually gain
experience and build up self-confidence to take on, in due course, specific, and
more demanding, services delivery obligations.
This point is worth stressing. Decentralization reforms in Cambodia could not be,
and have not been, immediately concerned with the devolution of specific service
delivery responsibilities. Instead they had first to address basic local-level
governance and public expenditure management systems including the promotion
of participatory planning, budgeting and implementation procedures. But to
introduce such improved systems, some initial fiscal decentralization measures (a
general-purpose fiscal transfers facility) were implemented to provide the
resources through which Commune authorities could “learn by doing” the
allocation, spending and accounting of public funds. Defying, in a sense, the
common wisdom of the sequence: (a) create capacity in order to (b) devolve
functions in order to (c) devolve resources, some resources were devolved first, in
order to break a potential vicious circle and provide a powerful incentive to local
capacity development. The following sections briefly describe the financing,
planning and implementation systems that were developed to provide Councils
with a basic public resources management framework within which they could start
to assume local public services delivery responsibilities.
3.3. The Commune finance system
The Commune Law establishes the basic principles on which the Commune
finance system is to be built. Communes have their own financial resources,
budget and assets and certain government assets may be transferred to them.
They have the obligation to prepare an annual balanced budget and to manage
and report their revenue and expenditures according to a local financial
management system established and monitored by the Ministry of Economy and
Finance (MoEF).
Communes have the right to collect direct revenues from taxes, fees and other
service charges (own-source revenue) and they may be entitled to a share of
national revenue instruments (tax sharing)4. They are however barred from
borrowing. They must be compensated by the central government when they
4
The Communes can however not yet exercise their right to own-source revenue generation, because
the Ministry of Economy and Finance has not yet issued the related implementing regulations.
6
perform any function on behalf of the national administration (agency functions).
Finally, and most importantly at this early stage of the reforms, the Law establishes
the Commune/Sangkat Fund (CSF) as a primary mechanism to channel central
government funds, donors’ loans or grants, and other resources, to the financing of
Commune expenditures (fiscal transfers).
Actual CSF resource in 2002 and 2003, and expected funding level in 2004 are
reflected in Table 2 below.
Government of
Cambodia (US$)
Donors’ contributions
(US$)
Total
(US $)
2002
5,000,000
1,417,722
6,417,722
2003
11,184,494
2,000,000
13,184,494
2004
12,500,000
2,000,000
14,500,000
Table 2: Capitalization of the Commune/Sangkat Fund
The total resources of the CSF are divided in two components and allocated by a
formula (see Figure 2).
1. A General Administration Component, which cannot be more than 1/3 of the
total distributable resources of the CSF. This component is distributed to each
Commune Council in proportion to its number of councilors.
2. A Local Development Component, which cannot be less than 2/3 of the total
distributable resources of the CSF. This component is allocated by three
shares: an equal share, a share proportional to the population of the Commune
(using the number of councilors as a proxy), and a share proportional to a
poverty index, weighted by the population of the commune. For the poverty
assessment, a Commune database with data on social indicators, by village, is
used to produce a poverty ranking of the Communes.
1/3
T1
General
Administration
T
Total
Resources
Distributed to all Communes
in proportion to the number
of Councilors in the Council

T21
Distributed as an equal
amount to each of the
Communes
T22
Distributed in proportion to
the population of the
Commune
T23
Distributed in proportion to
the relative poverty of the
Commune
Equal Share
T2
Local
Development
2/3


Population
Share
Poverty
Share
Figure 2: Distribution of CSF resources
7
The CSF provides the Communes with relatively modest but freely programmable
resources that can be used to finance any expenditure (administrative or
development, recurrent or capital) that is reflected in the Council’s approved
budget and does not violate the Commune Law or any other law and regulation
issued by the government. The table below illustrates their classification.
Administrative
Expenditures
Development
Expenditures
Recurrent Expenditures
Capital Expenditures
Allowances to Councilors
Salaries of local staff and other
personnel expenses
Rental of office premises
Routine repair and maintenance of
administrative facilities
Utility charges
Fuel, lubricants and vehicles
maintenance
Other consumables and
miscellaneous
Personnel and other recurrent costs
associated with the operation of the
local infrastructure and the delivery
of related services.
Support of community development
programs managed by local NGOs
and community-based organization,
including education and information
campaigns, environmental
protection and natural resources
management and other programs
impacting on the welfare of local
population.
Routine maintenance of local
economic and social infrastructure
Purchase of the Council’s premises,
Major repair and maintenance
works on administrative facilities
Furniture and office equipment for
the Council's or administration's
facilities
Purchase of vehicles
The survey, design, construction,
and major repair and maintenance
of:
Roads, bridges,
Markets,
Educational and health care
facilities, community centers,
Irrigation networks and structures,
agricultural storage facilities,
Water and power supply and
Other economic and social
infrastructure
Table 3: CSF classification of eligible expenditures
This matrix classification introduces some additional requirements in the process of
local-level budgeting, as Councils will need to convert the general administration
and local development transfers into contributions to recurrent and capital
expenditures in their budgets. In the process, the Councils are expected to take
into account any mandatory administrative or development expenditures that future
regulations may assign to them, as well as the minimum or maximum amounts that
may be earmarked for recurrent and capital expenditures.
It’s important to stress that the CSF resources constitute the bulk of locally
programmable resources for development spending. However they also stimulate
further local resources mobilization since part of the cost of CSF-supported
projects must be covered by local contributions. Depending on the project, such
resources can either come from local taxes paid by all Commune citizens, or from
specific contributions paid by the direct project beneficiaries. The modalities of this
8
local contribution have not yet been regulated, but interim guidelines in the CSF
Project Implementation Manual require that local contributions in cash should be
10% of the estimated cost of the project, minus the cost of labor or materials that
are provided in kind. The in cash contribution for a project should however not be
less than 3% of its estimated cost.
The annual CSF transfers are relatively modest (less than 10,000 US$/year per
Commune, on average), but are comparable to what Communes have been
receiving under the Seila program5 during the period of piloting of the
decentralization reforms prior to the local elections. The Seila experience
demonstrated that, beyond helping to finance a few small-scale investments of
local priority, the greatest value of modest but regular general-purpose transfers for
development spending is in the opportunity that it gives to Commune Councils to
undertake a meaningful local-level participatory planning and budgeting process as
part of a regular commune-level public resources management cycle. Importantly,
this local planning and budgeting process is an autonomous and statutory one
which is not driven by the “supply” of resources by particular national and provincial
agencies/programs that may support local development. At the same time it
provides a local strategic framework within which to access such centrally or
provincially managed resources.
3.4. The Commune development planning system
The Commune Law and its subsequent regulations, mandate all Communes to
adopt and implement a five-year Commune Development Plan (CDP). The Plan is
to be prepared and approved by the Councils in the first of the five years of their
mandate, and must be reviewed and updated yearly. The CDP is meant to provide
the framework for a multi-year Commune Investment Program (CIP) and for the
preparation of the annual budget. The different phases and steps in the CDP
process are summarized in Box 1.
Besides defining the CDP process, the regulations mandate the establishment in
each Commune of a broad-based Planning and Budgeting Committee (PBC): a
structure meant to facilitate the representation of village-level interests and
priorities in the development of Commune policies and programs and in the
allocation of Commune resources.
5
The Seila program is a Royal Government of Cambodia program which started in 1996 as a
collaboration between seven ministries to promote rural development. During 1996-2001, the program,
with financial and technical assistance support from a multi-donor project, created opportunities for
government agencies and their staff at national, provincial and district levels to develop processes and
procedures to support rural development. During the current phase (2001-2005), the focus of the
program has been reformulated as support for decentralization and deconcentration to contribute to
poverty alleviation through good governance.
9
BOX 1 - The Commune Development Planning (CDP) Process
Planning
Phase 1
Analysis
Phase 2
Strategies
Phase 3
Projects
1
Phase 4
Programs
Phase 5
Approval
9
11
6
Commune-level
needs
assessment
3
medium-term
revenue
forecast
4
prioritization of
issues
5
Identification of
strategies &
projects
7
projects
formulation and
costing
2
8
Village-level
needs
assessment
formulation of
integrated
programs
projects
selection
Approval of
CDP/CIP
10
district
integration
workshop
Drafting of
CDP/CIP
In February 2002, the government issued a planning regulation to guide the communes in
preparing their development plan in a participatory manner. The Planning Process is articulated
in five phases as illustrated in the above diagram. Schematically:
Phase 1 is concerned with the identification of service needs and development problems that
affect individual villages and the Commune as a whole and eventually with the prioritization of
critical issues that the Council wants to address during its mandate.
Phase 2 is concerned with generating a vision for the Commune development, transforming the
selected critical problems/issues into goals and objectives and identifying the strategies and
projects to address them.
Phase 3 is concerned with the preliminary formulation and costing of the identified projects, their
ranking and final selection, in light of the opportunity for financing that are offered to the Council
by existing State, donors and NGO programs, as well as by the Council’s revenue, be it from
own sources or CSF and other intergovernmental transfers.
Phase 4 is concerned with the integration of the selected projects and other routine activities of
the local administration into sector or cross-sector programs of action that translate into
concrete activities the local government’s vision for development of its jurisdiction. It results in
the actual production of a draft Commune Development Plan (CDP) and Commune Investment
Program (CIP)
Phase 5 is concerned with obtaining and integrating into the draft CDP/CIP comments and
suggestions from both the local people and the provincial administration. It results in the
approval by the Council of the CDP/CIP
10
A critical step in the CDP process is the “District Integration Workshop” (DIW).
Here Commune authorities formally interact with other agencies involved in local
development, including provincial departments of national ministries, donor-funded
program implementation units and NGOs and negotiate the financing and
implementation of projects and activities that either emerge from their needs
identification or are otherwise worth including in their plans.
Once the DIW is concluded with the commitment of other actors to support certain
local activities and projects, the Commune authorities can proceed with the final
allocation of “their own” resources including any own-source revenue and the
allocation of the Commune Sangkat Fund. The importance of the DIW is clear. It
provides an institutional mechanism for the Communes to articulate the local
demand of infrastructure and services, with the potential supply by line agencies
and other actors, which currently remain the source of financing and the
implementing agencies for the bulk of local investments and services.
The institutional innovation represented by the DIW is worth stressing. Consultation
between different tiers of government, for the purpose of coordination of multi-level
planning processes, is not in itself a novelty. What makes the Cambodia DIW
different from similar consultative practices is that they directly and immediately
result in clear commitments by participants about what local development activities
will be supported in a given Commune and who will support them. At District
Integration Workshops:
- Line departments and aid agencies make commitments with the Communes
against known levels of resources available; they do not just collect Commune
requests on which the decision to support will be taken later.
- The mutual commitments of line departments, aid agencies and Commune
authorities are formalized in “Temporary Agreements”. These are temporary not
because the possibility of funding is uncertain, but because the projects and
activities the agreements are about may still have to undergo a feasibility study,
which would confirm, inter alia, that their actual cost remains within the
available resources.
District Integration Workshops are meant to be a specific step, common to the
planning processes of both Communes and provincial sector departments. While
this is still a new concept for sectors, and the ability of provincial departments to
interact with Commune Councils remain constrained by their own limited autonomy
with respect to central planning and funding of sector activities, there are signs that
the DIW are starting to influence sector programming of government resources. In
2003, some provinces also committed some of their own resources, to be allocated
together with donor funds in support of local activities.
At the District Integration Workshops there is not only discussion on the integration
of commune, line department and aid agency development plans for the next year.
The Communes also reflect on the implementation of development activities in the
previous year. One important aspect of this is the review of the Temporary
11
Agreements that were signed the previous year, and the possibility for the
Communes to ask for public accountability of line departments or aid agencies, for
the Temporary Agreements that were not honored.
3.5. The Commune procurement and project implementation system
As already mentioned, responsibilities for managing the delivery of specific public
services, are not yet clearly assigned to Commune Councils and the Communes’
administrations are still embryonic, consisting in most cases of just one centrallyappointed Commune Clerk dedicated to the provision of some basic administrative
services and supporting the Commune Council in general. As a result, so far, the
Councils’ involvement in direct implementation of local development activities has
been essentially limited to the procurement of small scale infrastructure facilities,
by contracting out construction and other services.
Most contractors are based at district or provincial level and are registered by the
provincial administration which certifies their general capacity to implement
projects. Contractors are selected through competitive bidding processes, and sign
contracts directly with the Commune Councils. A technical team at provincial level
assists the Communes to monitor implementation of the projects and administer
the contracts.
4. Commune-level services delivery: the early experience (2002-2003)
4.1. Emerging policy recognition of the Communes’ role
The developmental rationale of decentralization reforms suggests that the newly
elected Commune authorities of Cambodia may be able to improve local public
services delivery:
- On the demand side, by giving voice to local communities and improving the
way in which local service needs are assessed and prioritized. This is expected
to lead to a more effective allocation of public sector resources, both those
managed by the Councils themselves and those managed by other government
agencies (including external aid)
- On the supply side, by direct provision or co-provision of services using their
own administration or co-operative arrangements with other government and
non-government agencies. This is expected to lead to more efficient production
of local infrastructures and delivery of services (greater value-for-money).
It is in view of these potential allocative and productive efficiency gains, that the
National Poverty Reduction Strategy (NPRS) document adopted by the
government in December 2002, supports the involvement of Commune Council in
the implementation of the strategy.
12
The NPRS expects the involvement of Communes to result in pro-poor outcomes
through:
- The promotion of participatory governance, which enables the poor to have a
voice, and to influence Commune spending for activities that are of benefit to
them;
- The development of fiscal transfers, to finance local development and local
delivery of services;
- The adoption of participatory Commune development planning and budgeting;
- Capacity building of Commune Councils and communities;
- Partnerships for local development and poverty reduction between Commune
Councils, civil society and the private sector;
- The promotion of linkages and coordination between Commune Councils and
sectoral agencies; and
- The delegation of agency functions for basic services (with corresponding
resources and support) to the Commune Councils.
However, the practical inter-governmental arrangements through which Commune
Councils should provide or co-provide basic services in the sectors with greater
potential impact on poverty reduction (education, health, water and sanitation, rural
infrastructure and agriculture) are not specified in the NPRS document.
Nevertheless, some Ministries are already starting to associate the Commune
Councils to their service delivery systems.
The Ministry of Education sees the Commune Councils as key local stakeholders
in the schools system management. As a result:
- Commune Councils are represented in a “provincial education facilities
committee” responsible for the provincial schools construction program. (The
committee is chaired by the provincial Departments of Education and includes
also the Departments of Economy and Finance, and Public Works).
- A Commune Councilor elected in one of the Communes served by a “cluster
school” is the head of the “cluster school committee”. These committees, which
include teachers and parents representatives, make most decisions on cluster
schools management and handle their own financial resources.
- The Ministry is trying to introduce a system of report cards for schools, which
are to be prepared by local inspectors and submitted to Commune Councils
The Ministry of Health is also increasingly associating Commune Councils to the
management of the health system. Approaches are being experimented in which
the Councils do monitor the performance of health centres, and allocate
exemptions of service payment to the poor.
13
The move towards a greater role of Commune Councils in services delivery is less
clear in other sectors such as water and sanitation, or rural transport, in spite of the
fact that it is perhaps in these sectors that a greater devolution of provision
responsibilities to the Communes would produce the greatest benefits. The
departments responsible for water supply (mostly wells) and sanitation projects
(mostly latrines), or roads, still make their allocation decisions independently from
the Communes. Decisions, on where and to what standard, to provide such
services are still largely seen as purely technical. Consultation with the local
communities is deemed useful (such as the consultation that takes place during the
district integration workshops), but not obligatory.
4.2. Communes at work: Local development initiatives (2002-2003)
Whatever the limitations imposed on their role by the lack of definition of their
responsibilities and the still embryonic inter-governmental arrangements,
Communes have nevertheless started to address local development issues and to
influence the delivery of local infrastructure and services. Articulating local
demands through the mandatory local planning process outlined above, they have:
- Influenced, through the District Integration Workshops, the allocation of sector
resources managed by provincial departments, NGOs and donor-funded
programs;
- Allocated their own resources for development spending (essentially the
Commune Sangkat Fund transfers), and
- Assumed responsibility for implementation of local development projects
(mostly small scale rural/urban infrastructures and health and education
facilities) worth about 4 and 7 million US dollars respectively in 2002 and 2003.
4.2.1.
Influencing the allocation of domestic and external resources at the
District Integration Workshops (DIW)
We look first at the way in which Communes have attempted to access technical
and financial resources managed by provincial agencies and other sources of
funds through the DIW. The typical outcome of a DIW can be illustrated with data
from the 2002 local planning exercises in the Otdar Meanchey province. Located in
the northwest of the country, and bordering with Thailand, the province is divided in
five districts and 24 Communes, with a total population of about 90,000 people.
During the planning process in 2002, the 24 Communes submitted a total of 1,260
requests for a wide range of development projects and activities. Table 4 shows
these requests6 by sector and type of project/activity demanded.
6
The numbers in the table are the number of Commune requests. When looking at the figures, one has
to keep in mind that one request may well cover more than one unit of the requested item (e.g. a
Commune request for health posts may be for two or three health posts).
14
Commune
Requests at DIW
(total)
Project/Activity Type
Sector
Agriculture
Transport and
Power
Local Infrastructure and
buildings
Equipment and material
/financial inputs
Services and in-Service
training programs
Education and vocational
training Programs
No.
No.
No.
No.
Description
- Reservoirs,
Dams
- Canals
77
construction and
rehabilitation
- Wells
- Rural Roads
150 - Bridges
- Culverts
Description
196
3
Agricultural Tools
Pumps
Livestock
Seeds
Fertilizers
Credit
- Electricity
Generators
Health
- Ambulance
Motorbikes
19
- Mosquito Nets
and Sprayers
Water Supply and
Sanitation
- Water Ponds
94 - Wells
- Latrines
21
Education
98
- Schools
- Training Centers
0
NONE
Natural
resources &
environment
Administration
and security
Gender
Total Number
Total (%)
0
- Water Storage
(Jars, pots)
3 - School Materials
20 - Trees seedlings
- Commune Office
- Village Meeting
36
Halls
- Security Posts
NONE
2
0
475
38%
- Landmines
clearance
37
- Village-level
veterinarians
0
- Health Posts
- Health Centers
20
- Child Care
Centers
- Bicycles for
Village Chiefs
NONE
NONE
0
NONE
- Teachers
56 - Teachers training
- Literacy classes
0
NONE
3 - Land Titling
NONE
NONE
- General Hygiene
- Births spacing
72
- HIV/AIDS
prevention
22
%
Description
- Agricultural
production
68
- Agro- processing
techniques
0
- Vaccination
Campaigns
56 - Health workers
professional
development
0
264
21%
Description
No.
- Sanitation
practices
- Vocational
Training
- Culture education
- Environmental
Protection
41
- Waste
management
- Commune and
other Laws
44
- Govt.
Regulations
- Gender in dev.
- Human rights
72
- Domestic
violence
50
152
12%
Table 4: Priority requests presented by Communes at DIW in the Otdar Meanchey province (2002)
369
29%
378
30%
153
12%
167
13%
137
11%
207
16%
61
5%
85
7%
72
6%
1,260
100%
100%
Almost 60% of the requests referred to the construction, repair or rehabilitation of
physical infrastructure and the provision of equipment and material inputs. The
emphasis on basic infrastructure is understandable as most rural Communes do
perceive inadequate facilities and reduced accessibility as the greatest constraints
to the better delivery of health, education and other services. Of the other
requests, 12% were related to services that the Communes knew provincial
departments and donor-supported programs could deliver. These included posting
and training of teachers, vaccination campaigns, support to village veterinarians,
clearing of landmines as well as the all important regularization of property rights
by delivery of land titles. The remaining 29% of the requests referred to general
education and vocational training activities. Obviously, if this distribution of
Communes priorities was assessed in terms of costs involved, the claim on
resources by infrastructure and material inputs requests would be greatly amplified
and stand out even more clearly.
Commune requests to the DIW are generated within an autonomous Communelevel planning process. Nevertheless the outcome of such process, when it comes
to the requests to be tabled at the DIW, is bound to be influenced by two important
and often related factors. The first is the assistance that Communes might have
received in the implementation of their planning process. The second is the
knowledge that they might have of the potential “supply” of resources by existing
domestic and externally-funded programs. For example in the case of Otdar
Meanchey the very high number of requests for training and education activities
related to health is due, at least in part, to the assistance given by UNICEF staff to
Communes during the needs identification steps of the local planning process. It
might also reflect the fact that Communes knew that such requests had a good
chance of receiving a positive response. Such subordination of the “demand” to the
perceived potential “supply” at DIW may also have occurred for other sectors and
types of projects (such as landmine clearance, agricultural training and gender
training activities).
Care should also be exercised in reading the data in Table 4 because they may be
under-representing the requests for “natural resources and environment” activities,
because many of the requests for agriculture projects and other sector’s
infrastructures do also have clear environmental protection and natural resources
management dimensions. The same applies to requests for “gender” projects,
whose importance may be underestimated by the fact that many of the requests
classified under “health” have also important “gender” dimensions.
Commune requests were presented at five district integration workshops held in
the Otdar Meanchey province in October 2002. The participating line departments,
NGOs and international organizations (IOs) gave a positive response to 407 of the
1,260 commune requests (32% of the total) and this was reflected in the signature
of 407 “temporary agreements” that committed these agencies to fund the
Commune projects, subject to the verification of their actual feasibility (see Table
5). But the response was not limited to “accepting” some of the Communes’
requests. The line departments, NGOs and IOs also “offered” to fund some 271
16
additional projects, which were not prioritized in the Commune-level planning
exercises, but were nevertheless considered beneficial by the Commune
authorities. The types of projects that were “offered” to Communes, which had not
initially asked for them, are shown in Table 6. By and large, the project and
activities covered by these additional offers, are not qualitatively different from what
other Communes may have requested. Most of the projects that provincial
departments pledged to support will eventually be financed from external aid
resources.
Type of project
Sector
Agriculture
Transport and
Power
Health
Water and
sanitation
Education
Natural
resources &
environment
Administration
and security
Gender
Total
Local
Infrastructure
and buildings
Equipment
and material
/financial
inputs
Services and
in-Service
training
programs
Education &
vocational
training
Programs
Original requests
Positive responses
Additional offers
Original requests
Positive responses
Additional offers
Original requests
Positive responses
Additional offers
Original requests
Positive responses
Additional offers
Original requests
Positive responses
Additional offers
Original requests
Positive responses
Additional offers
Original requests
Positive responses
Additional offers
Original requests
Positive responses
Additional offers
77
13
18
150
1
2
20
3
0
94
55
0
98
20
1
0
0
0
36
0
1
0
0
0
196
39
20
3
0
0
19
12
10
21
4
1
3
0
13
20
0
0
2
0
0
0
0
0
37
21
6
0
0
0
56
41
25
0
0
0
56
23
17
0
0
0
3
0
4
0
0
0
68
43
34
0
0
0
72
60
1
22
24 7
16
50
1
33
41
0
0
44
1
47
72
46
22
378
116
78
153
1
2
167
116
36
137
83
17
207
44
64
61
0
0
85
1
52
72
46
22
Original requests
475
264
152
369
1,260
Positive responses
92
55
85
175
407
Additional offers
22
44
52
153
271
Number of …
Total
Table 5 - Response to commune priority requests and additional offers for projects/activities,
Otdar Meanchey, 2002
7.This
figure may appear as a mistake, because the number of positive responses is higher than the
number of original commune requests. This is not a mistake, but is due to the fact that various parties
can respond to one commune request. A request for sanitation education has been filled partly by the
Department of Health, partly by UNICEF funding, and partly by a national NGO.
17
Type of project
Sector
Agriculture
Infrastructure
Local infrastructure
and buildings
Feasibility studies
for dams ;
community rice
stores
Drainage canal ;
culvert
Health

Water and
sanitation

Education
Natural
resources &
environment
School repair

Equipment and
material/financial
inputs
Water cans ;
agricultural tools ;
seeds

Emergency support
for flood and
drought victims
Rubbish bins
Books on
Buddhism

Gender
Water quality
testing for arsenic
content ;
Training for health
workers

Land titling


Training for clean
water committee
Education on the
use of latrines
Training for monks ;
vocational training



Education and
vocational training
programs
Training on
agricultural
techniques

Teacher training
Security fence
Administration
and security
Services and inservice training
programs
Training for village
veterinarians


Administration
training ;
dissemination of
knowledge on laws
Training on
trafficking
prevention ; human
rights education
Table 6 - Type of additional projects/activities, Otdar Meanchey, 2002
The results of the Otdar Meanchey’s DIWs are generally in line with national
averages. In 2002, 1,283 Communes in 17 of Cambodia’s 24 provinces submitted
33,553 requests. There were 9,372 positive responses (28%) by departments and
aid agencies, and 14,010 temporary agreements were signed for additional
projects. However the data for Otdar Meanchey show a fairly high response to
requests for water-related infrastructure projects which is not typical for other
provinces where local authorities have complained about the mismatch of demand
and supply for all types of infrastructure projects. The difference in Otdar
Meanchey stems largely from the fact that most of the water and sanitation
infrastructure requests were supported by UNICEF, which had had also helped the
Communes to finalize their plans and include those requests in them. The supply
therefore influenced the demand. Nevertheless, even in Otdar Meanchey, the gap
between local demand for transport infrastructure and the ability of provincial
departments to even partially address it, remains huge. Some local leaders have
characterized such mismatch as the “We ask for a road, and we get a… gender
training” syndrome.
18
More generally, the outcome of the District Integration Workshops draws some light
on the relations between the provincial administrations and the newly elected
Commune Councils. The ability of provincial agencies, to respond to Commune
requests, integrate local demands in their own sector planning process, and devise
new partnership arrangements with Commune Councils for local services delivery,
is still very limited. It is constrained by the lack of deconcentration and provincial
autonomy in programming national sector resources, and by the limited resources
available for provincial-level planning and budgeting exercises. In most cases it is
easier for a provincial line department to offer to include a Commune in a program
that the department is already executing, and whose general scope and timeframe,
if not the location and sequencing, are already set, than to adjust flexibly the
content of the programs it manages to better fit the demand from local planning
exercises.
4.2.2.
Making use of the resources of the Commune/Sangkat Fund (CSF)
Besides attempting to influence the allocation of the resources of line departments
and aid agencies, through the DIW mechanism, Commune authorities do also
allocate directly those local development resources that are transferred to them
through the CSF.
In 2002, the first year of operation of the CSF, 506 Communes in 12 provinces
received funds for development spending which averaged US $ 8,533 per
commune. These funds were used to implement the following types of projects.
Type of project
Rural Transport
Rural water supply
Education facilities
Irrigation
Health facilities
Other
Community buildings
Total
Number of
projects
501
183
80
71
6
6
Commune
Fund
Amount ($)
2,665,546
643,583
641,099
333,374
10,145
14,970
% of total
By number
59.1%
21.6%
9.4%
8.4%
0.7%
0.7%
By value
61.9%
14.9%
14.9%
7.7%
0.2%
0.3%
6
14,970
0.7%
0.3%
847
4,308,717
100%
100%
Table 7: Commune/Sangkat Fund use by project type, 2002
In 2003, the second year of operation of the CSF, all 1,621 Communes had access
to resources for local development. The type of projects on which these resources
were invested, as well as the number of villages and people that benefited from
them, are given in Tables 8 and 9 below.
19
Type of project
Rural Transport
Rural water supply
Education facilities
Irrigation
Health facilities
Other
Urban Transport
Urban Drainage
Urban Water Supply
Domestic Sanitation
Rural Drainage
Environ. management
Social interventions
Waste Disposal
Total
930
223
85
297
6
58
Commune
Fund
Amount ($)
4,318,736
728,395
574,506
1,136,207
18,407
193,597
14
28
2
7
3
1
2
1
1,599
Number of
projects
% of total
By number
By value
58.2%
13.9%
5.3%
18.6%
0.4%
3.6%
62.0%
10.5%
8.2%
16.3%
0.3%
2.8%
76,642
73,528
3,341
13,743
10,932
8,970
5,191
1,249
0.9%
1.8%
0.1%
0.4%
0.2%
0.1%
0.1%
0.1%
1.1%
1.1%
0.05%
0.2%
0.2%
0.1%
0.1%
0.02%
6,969,848
100%
100%
Table 8: Commune/Sangkat Fund use by project type, 2003
Type of project
Number of
projects
Rural Transport
Rural water supply
Education facilities
Irrigation
Health facilities
Other
930
223
85
297
6
58
Urban Transport
Urban Drainage
Urban Water Supply
Domestic Sanitation
Rural Drainage
Environ. management
Social interventions
Waste Disposal
14
28
2
7
3
1
2
1
Beneficiaries
Total Population of
Cambodia
Beneficiaries
% of total
Number
population
2,312,601
18.75%
404,522
3.28%
165,492
1.34%
734,911
5.96%
10,289
0.08%
121,079
0.98%
62,580
33,239
2,765
9,899
2,389
8,549
1,237
421
0.51%
0.27%
0.02%
0.08%
0.02%
0.07%
0.01%
0.00%
3,748,894
30.4%
12,331,888
100%
Table 9: Commune/Sangkat Fund: beneficiaries by project type, 2003
In 2003, about 30.4% of the total population and 28.6% of all women living in the
Cambodian Communes, would benefit from about 7 M.US$ worth of local smallscale public investments located in 4,726 villages (over one third of all villages of
Cambodia) and planned, financed and managed by Commune authorities.
20
All CSF resources in 2002 and 2003 were used to finance civil works construction
contracts. In both years, over 60% went to rural transport projects, involving the
construction, improvement and/or repair of roads, small bridges and culverts. In
2003 the second most important category of projects (absorbing 16.3% of the CSF
resources) included the construction and rehabilitation of canals and other
irrigation structures. The prominence of these two categories of investments
(claiming almost 80% of the CSF resources) suggests a strong preference of local
authorities for economic infrastructures. As for social infrastructures, the greatest
claim on CSF resources was made by projects improving access to, and quality of,
drinking water. Investments in school facilities have also been relatively important,
while only a minor share of the CSF resources has gone to improve health care
facilities.
Two sets of questions are associated with public expenditures management and
services delivery by Commune Councils. The first one concerns the efficient
allocation of resources for local development and poverty reduction. The second
concerns the efficient use of the resources directly managed by Communes (the
value for money in the Commune-managed provision and production of local
infrastructure and services). We turn to these questions in the two following
sections.
4.3. Allocative efficiency issues
As noted, CSF resources have been invested in physical infrastructure facilities,
with rural roads and irrigation works claiming the lion’s share. Even before the
establishment of Commune Councils in 2002, the Commune Development
Committees, which were the forerunners of the elected Councils during the piloting
period of the decentralization reforms (1996-2001), showed very strong
preferences for investments in infrastructure. As a result, many external agencies
expressed concern with what they perceived as a too narrow “roads and canals
mentality” of the Commune Development Committees. Whether or not Commune
Councils could or should invest more in other types of projects however remains
open to question.
There is certainly scope, and an important pro-poor potential, for a greater
involvement of Councils in the delivery of education and health services, but, this is
currently constrained by the lack (or inadequate development) of an appropriate
division of labor and related cooperative arrangements between Councils, sector
agencies, other potentially important NGO providers, the private sector and users’
communities. Another area where local action should (and somehow is starting to)
expand is that of the traditional municipal services (urban transport, water supply
and sanitation, solid wastes, markets, etc.). But again this will depend on how
urban management responsibilities will eventually be structured and the mandate
of Sangkats will be defined. Finally, some would like to see more action by the
Commune Councils in the promotion of local “economic” development. To be true,
this is what Councils are already focusing on when they improve the transport and
irrigation economic infrastructure, but what the proponents of a “more-than-only-
21
infrastructure” local governance agenda have in mind are other, more direct ways
of local public support to private ventures (provision of buffaloes, fertilizers, support
to enterprises, etc.). Given the current institutional weaknesses of the Councils the
risk is high that they would not develop and follow a public policy rationale for
specific support to private ventures and that this kind of projects would end up
benefiting only the relatively wealthier and more influential local people with little or
no effect on poverty reduction.
In assessing the merits and feasibility of diversifying the portfolio of Commune
investments into non-infrastructure projects, a key question is whether or not the
Commune authorities’ choice to allocate the bulk of locally programmable
resources to roads, irrigation and schools projects, actually reflect broad-based
local needs and demand. While systematic evaluations are still lacking, a couple of
recent studies based on sample surveys, have concluded that Commune residents,
including the poor among them, are generally satisfied with the outcome of the
local planning process, and expect to benefit from the choices made by Commune
authorities.
An evaluation of the impact of the earlier Local Development Fund (LDF) on which
the CSF was modeled, had already suggested that “… the intended beneficiaries
have benefited well from the [LDF] project. Women would seem to particularly
benefit from the expansion of public transport and marketing opportunities that
accompanies the road improvements” (Tracey-White and Petts, 2001).
More recently a study aiming to assess the people’s empowerment resulting from
decentralization reforms also concluded that “… people were satisfied with the
choice that had been made [by Councils in allocating CSF resources]”. Based on a
sample of 120 randomly selected villagers in villages where CSF-funded projects
were located, the study reports that 88% of the total number of villagers expected
to benefit from the project. When the sample was restricted to 120 very poor
villagers, 73% declared also to expect to benefit from the project. The study then
concludes that “The fact that a large proportion of villagers who lived in the village
where a project was located reported that they would benefit from it seemed to
indicate that elite capture was not generally an issue”. The study however also
suggests that this general conclusion may not apply equally to all the decisions
made by the Councils. While investments in roads and schools do distribute
benefits in a rather egalitarian way, irrigation facilities do benefit the poor (mostly
landless) only to the extent to which they result in an overall increase in the
demand for day labour. Also, unless the rules of access to newly constructed water
wells allow for their use by the whole community, wells end up benefiting only few
and usually the wealthier and more influential members of the community.
(Biddulph, 2003).
With the above qualifications, and considering the still widespread lack of basic
infrastructure throughout the rural areas of Cambodia, the allocation of the bulk of
CSF resources to basic (economic and some social) infrastructure facilities seems
to match broad based local needs and demands. The focus on infrastructure does
22
not seem to point to inefficiency in resource allocation. In terms of the allocative
efficiency of Communes’ decisions, therefore, the immediate concern is not so
much to diversify Communes’ development spending, but to ensure that adequate
resources are allocated to the operation and maintenance of the built
infrastructure. The lack of proper plans and clearly specified responsibilities for
maintenance remain a serious threat to the sustainability of locally created assets.
A way to address this issue could be the specification of “mandatory development
expenditures” covering Communes obligations for local assets management. This
would ensure that before embarking on new construction, Communes would cover
the maintenance expenditures for which they are legally responsible. While the
establishment of mandatory development expenditures for operations and
maintenance was discussed at the time of formulation of the CSF, a specific
regulation providing guidance to the Communes is still to be developed by the
MOEF.
Another key issue in the process of allocation of Commune-managed resources is
the need to strengthen the Councils’ accountability to their constituency by
ensuring the proper functioning, and enhancing the role, of the Planning and
Budgeting Committee (PBC): the main structure for village level representation and
participation in Commune decisions making. A recent survey of 96 people
representing their villages in Commune PBC, found that only 55% of them felt they
had participated in, and influenced, the projects selection at Commune level. On
the other hand, 49% of randomly selected villagers reported that they had been
involved in project identification at village level. The two figures suggest a situation
in which village-level participation in project identification and prioritization is
relatively high, while village representation and participation in the projects
selection and resources allocation processes, is still inadequate. (Biddulph, 2003).
4.4. Productive efficiency issues
Beyond their ability to allocate resources in a way that matches local needs and
preferences, Communes need also to demonstrate that they can deliver
infrastructures and provide services efficiently, i.e. that they can deliver better value
for money, as compared to different, more centralized services delivery systems.
The first question is therefore whether the cost of the infrastructure and buildings
for which Communes have taken planning, financing and implementation
(managing construction contracts) responsibility, is higher or lower that that of
similar facilities of comparable quality built by other public agencies or NGOs. A
particularly relevant comparison is with the Ministry of Rural Development which
commonly manages local small scale investments of the type the Communes have
started to implement themselves.
A recent study sheds some light on this question (Abrams, 2003). The study was
meant to check whether the prices of CSF-funded construction contracts were in
line with expected normal values or inflated for corrupt reasons, as some external
observers and government officials suspected. The study then assesses whether
23
CSF prices are “too high” either generally, or for specific provinces or specific types
of output. The study makes use of an extensive Project Information Database
containing technical information and unit costs for contracts funded from CSF
resources in 2003 and worth a total of US$ 7 million. Because of differences in the
estimation techniques, the results of the study are presented separately for
(i) wells, schools, bridges and culverts and (ii) earth and laterite roads.
4.4.1.
Wells, road structures and schools
For this category of outputs the study compares actual contract prices with a
“reference” or “normative” price constructed for each of the most common types of
outputs using “average” material prices from three provinces and allowing for
transport costs at $6 per ton (approximately equivalent to a transport distance of 20
km) and for overhead costs and profit, at 10% of the direct costs.
Description
VN6 Well
Afridev Well
Open Mixed Well
Single 60cm culvert
Single 80cm culvert
Single100cm culvert
Double 60cm culvert
Double 80cm culvert
Double100cm culvert
Box Culvert 2 x 5m
Concrete bridge 4m long
Brick School room
Quantity
Average
Contract
Price
“Reference”
Cost estimate
Difference
66
59
78
74
65
61
41
40
46
16
4
95
$ 372
$ 1,198
$ 429
$ 313
$ 428
$ 604
$ 480
$ 703
$ 986
$ 1,882
$ 5,069
$ 3,898
$ 463
$ 867
$ 509
$ 403
$ 606
$ 819
$ 641
$ 980
$ 1,332
$ 2,006
$ 6,628
$ 4,784
-20%
38%
-16%
-22%
-29%
-26%
-25%
-28%
-26%
-6%
-24%
-24%
Table 10: Comparison of contract prices for CSF-funded wells, road structures and
schools with reference cost estimates
With the exception of the Afridev-type wells, the average price of CSF outputs are
found to be substantially lower than the corresponding estimated reference cost
based on market prices of materials and reasonable transport and overhead costs.
In fact the difference may be a cause for concern, as if the reference estimates
reflect the true cost of constructing these outputs, it will not be possible for the
contractor to construct in accordance with the specification, and to make a profit.
4.4.2.
Laterite and earth roads
For this category of outputs again the study compares the actual cost of road
construction contracts in a sample of nine projects, with a reference cost,
constructed through field interviews with contractors and exploring the real costs
they face in implementing road projects. In estimating the reference prices the
24
study assumes a depreciation of 15% of the value of the equipment annually, and
a capital charge of 20% per annum on the value of equipment employed. The
reference costs additionally include 10% for overhead and profit. The following
table reflects the results of the comparison.
Commune
Snoeng
Kdol Tahen
Kampong Preah
Boeng Reang
Thipakdei
Thma Pun
Thma Pechr
Krang Leav
Khvav
Robas Mongkol
Outputs
Laterite road
Laterite road
Laterite road
Laterite road
Laterite road
Laterite road
Laterite road
Laterite road
Laterite road
Earth road
Contract
Price
$ 12,231
$ 6,463
$ 6,868
$ 5,455
$ 3,170
$ 1,231
$ 10,810
$ 9,720
$ 6,964
$ 6,896
$ 69,808
Reference
Difference
cost estimate
$ 12,807
$ 6,077
$ 6,511
$ 5,392
$ 3,251
$ 1,359
$ 6,944
$ 14,232
$ 8,204
$ 7,775
$ 72,553
-5%
6%
5%
1%
-3%
-10%
36%
-46%
-18%
-13%
-4%
Table 11: Comparison of contract prices for CSF-funded roads
with reference cost estimates
While the picture that emerges is less clear than in the case of other type of
projects, probably because of the greater difficulties involved in estimating
reference costs for road projects, on average for the entire sample, contract prices
are below the corresponding calculated reference value. This is in line with the fact
that the average cost of the Commune-managed, CSF-funded, laterite roads
(about 3,000 US$/Km for a 4m. wide road) compares favorably with prices
commonly cited as average values for similar projects managed by the Ministry of
Rural Development or other agencies (for example, a recent ILO publication
suggests $8,980 as an approximate cost for laterite road within 10km of the laterite
quarry8).
The study therefore concludes that, as a general rule, the costs of Communemanaged, CSF-financed projects, are lower than those incurred by other agencies
and instead of being “too high” may in fact be “too low” and fail to reflect the true
costs of the works as specified in the contracts. During implementation, this may
result in strong pressures on the contractors to “cut corners” and produce lower
quality outputs.
Indeed, the empowerment study mentioned above suggests that quality problems
in Commune-managed infrastructure projects may be widespread; potentially
denying any productive efficiency gains derived from lower contract costs. In a
sample of 13 Communes where CSF-funded projects were implemented the study
found that in 9 out of 13 cases, the Commune chiefs had approved payments, but
8
Bamboo Reinforced Concrete: Pavement Options Series 2: MRD / ILO December 2002
25
that in 10 of the same 13 cases, villagers (including users and village
representatives in the Commune PBC) were not satisfied with the quality of the
construction, while opinions were divided in the remaining three cases. (Biddulph,
2003).
A number of reasons seem at play in lowering outputs quality. They reflect both
contracts financing and contracts administration capacity problems. Delays in
transfers of CSF resources, (as experienced in 2003), may delay payments, create
cash flow problems for contractors, compromise construction schedule and result
in inappropriate wet-season operations. Also lack of Communes’ compliance with
contractual obligations to provide labor or cash contributions may be used by
contractors to lower their effort and deny responsibilities. Commune Chiefs are still
uncertain about their powers and their responsibility to stop payments in front of
unsatisfactory performance of the contractors. They rely entirely on the engineering
services of provincial/district technicians whose accountability to the Councils
remains weak and whose ability to provide the required construction contracts
administration services may be both limited and overstretched. “Social auditing” by
users groups and project beneficiaries of the performance of contractors and
services’ providers can help to enhance the quality of the produced outputs. Such
activities have happened on a number of projects, but it is not an established
formal mechanism that is practiced for all projects.
5. The way forward
Throughout this case study we have stressed the limitations that affect the ability of
the newly elected Commune Councils to take a more prominent role in managing
local development, delivering services and reducing poverty. Expanding this role
depends essentially on a continuing commitment of the central government to
move forward with the decentralization and deconcentration reforms. As we noted
at the beginning of this paper the fundamental thrust of the reforms was political. It
is essential that the momentum be maintained and that further substantial progress
be made on the fiscal and administrative fronts.
5.1. Maintaining the CSF promise
The CSF was established to transfer a gradually increasing level of locally
programmable resources for local development spending. The predictability of
these resources is critical to sustain meaningful local planning and budgeting
exercises, provide the means for Commune authorities to learn-by-doing and build
the confidence of the communities and stimulate their participation in public
decision making, thus building local democratic polities. The delays and
uncertainties that affected the 2003 transfers of the CSF funds to the Communes,
after the initial promising experience of 2002, may bring into question the
government’s continuing commitment to this critical mechanism for fiscal transfers
and diminish the obvious advances made in the last two years. To counter such
26
risk, and as required by the Commune Law, the government should announce the
minimum level of state funding to the CSF for at least the next three years period.
5.2. Developing a vision for the Communes’ role on services delivery
Most local services delivery will require a combination of decentralization,
deconcentration and private sector involvement. This calls for in-depth discussions
between the Ministry of Interior and key line ministries (especially health,
education, rural development and agriculture) on a thorough assessment and
possible reorganization of the delivery of local services, based on the principle of
subsidiarity. The aim would be to locate powers and functions in service delivery to
the lowest possible level of government that is still capable to deliver the service
effectively and efficiently. Such restructured services can then best be piloted in a
few places, to get the experience and develop the support mechanisms. The
approach can then be expanded to other Communes, to give them the choice – or
the obligation in case of a mandatory function – to engage in the delivery of such
services.
Part of this discussion with the line ministries will concern the agency functions. At
this moment, the only agency function which the Communes implement is civil
registration, on behalf of the Ministry of Interior. The discussions with the line
ministries should explore what agency functions are suitable for Communes to take
on, and what steps should be taken at the various levels for this to happen.
5.3. Developing local financial management regulations that support
increased Communes’ responsibilities for services delivery
The current exclusive focus of Commune development spending on physical
facilities construction is also due to the lack of well-developed regulations and
guidelines of the CSF and local-level financial management. Such regulations and
guidelines could encourage local spending on maintenance, operation costs and
non-infrastructure services delivery. Importantly also are the rules to reflect in local
budgets the proceedings of the CSF and the related expenditures should specify
both the administrative and development mandatory expenditures (essentially
maintenance and assets management related) that Communes would be required
to cover before embarking in the development of new facilities. The development of
these regulations is critically important to allow Communes to diversify their
spending patterns as their responsibilities for services delivery also expand.
5.4. Investing in a system of State support and supervision to Commune
Councils
Support for decentralization is provided at national, provincial and district level. At
national level, to facilitate the implementation of the Commune Law, an interministerial National Committee for Support to Communes/Sangkats was created,
together with a Department of Local Administration in the Ministry of Interior, and a
Department of Local Finance in the Ministry of Economy and Finance.
27
In each province, support to local Councils is provided through a “Provincial Office
of Local Administration” (POLA)9, but these offices only have one or two staff
members assigned to them and in no way can assume the rather diversified range
of tasks associated with an effective system of central support and oversight of the
local authorities system. Currently therefore most of these tasks are carried out by
donor-supported staff, and coordinated by a donor-supported Provincial Rural
Development Committee whose operational Executive Committee is chaired by the
provincial Governor and includes representatives of several provincial
administration departments, not only the POLA. These arrangements seem to work
well, but are not – or at least not yet – institutionalized leaving unresolved the issue
of developing a much-needed multi-functional provincial structure fully dedicated to
support and supervise local authorities. There is therefore the need for the
government to invest in a provincial/district system of support and supervision to
the Communes, and to establish such system on a firmer footing than exclusive
reliance on external aid.
6. Conclusions
The Commune Councils elected in 2002 are meant to assume an important
function in the promotion of local development and delivery of services. However
the Commune Law that provides the regulatory framework within which Communes
operate, while permitting a wide range of development initiatives, does not give
them either specific services delivery mandates or substantive fiscal powers.
Nevertheless a minimum of locally programmable resources for local development
spending are devolved to Communes through the Commune Sangkat Fund (CSF),
a national fiscal transfers facility capitalized through both domestic budgetary
allocations and external aid contributions.
In essence the CSF resources, while too limited to finance more than one or two
small scale projects per year in each Commune, do provide an incentive for the
adoption of an improved local planning and budgeting process that provides for the
formal association of village communities to the Commune Councils’ decisions on
local public resources allocation.
With – in most Communes – only the CSF resources to allocate to development
activities in 2002 and 2003, Communes invested the bulk of them in small-scale
infrastructure projects, mainly roads, bridges and culverts, but also irrigation works,
education facilities and domestic water supply. The limited evidence available from
ad hoc sample surveys and other qualitative studies indicates that the allocation of
funds by the Councils generally reflected broad based needs and local demand,
and limited the elite capture of the CSF benefits. Still the efficiency of Commune
level resources allocation could be improved by local financial management
9
This name is not completely correct, since no decree has been issued to give these provincial units
the official status of an “Office”.
28
regulations that encourage investing in operation and maintenance of local assets,
which the Ministry of Finance should develop as a matter of priority.
There is also evidence that overall the costs of the Commune-managed
constructed facilities compare favorably with those of similar structures
implemented by central agencies and NGOs. Concerns however have arisen about
the quality of such works pointing at the need to improve both the system of
technical supervision, currently entrusted to province and district-based
technicians, and the ability of user groups to monitor the performance of
contractors and request that corrective actions be enforced by Commune Councils
and provincial authorities.
The prospects for Communes to assume a greater role in services delivery,
beyond their development of some basic infrastructure facilities, remains however
clouded by a number of issues that reflect both national policy choices and local
capacity constraints.
There are issues of viability of many Communes which may be too small to be
effective as delivery units for most local services. In spite of their potential
importance, little has been done so far by the central government to develop and
regulate joint single or multi-purpose service delivery units.
Also, and perhaps most critically, services in the sectors that have the greatest
potential impact on poverty reduction (health, education, agriculture and rural
development, water and sanitation) do often require inter-governmental
arrangements associating Communes with provincial departments, community
organizations and private sector providers. These arrangements are better
developed through flexible experimentation and subsequent institutionalization.
While some Ministries have shown interest for developing such arrangements, too
little experimentation is currently going on to assume that major breakthroughs in
intergovernmental cooperation, which will redefine and enhance the Communes’
role in services delivery are around the corner.
The recent decentralization reforms in Cambodia have positioned the Communes
as potentially important providers of local services. However, for this potential to be
realized, the central government must provide more resources to the Communes,
and elaborate a framework which indicates clearly the service delivery roles
Communes can – or should – take on, and how such Commune roles relate to
those of established, or emerging, other service providers (like government
agencies, NGOs and the private sector). Enabling the Communes Councils to
become significant in the eyes of their local constituencies will ultimately help in
realizing the original rationale for decentralization in Cambodia: establishing a
democratic State presence at the local level.
29
References
Abrams, Julian
2003 Analysis of costs of Commune/Sangkat Fund projects, email message to
Seila/PLG staff on 26 November 2003
Azam, Mustafa I., Samer Al-Fayadh and Fergus Gleeson
2002 Bamboo Reinforced Concrete Pavement, Pavement Option Series No. 2,
Ministry of Rural Development (Cambodia) and International Labour
Organisation
Biddulph, Robin
2003 PAT Empowerment Study – Final Report, Consultancy report to the
Permanent Advisory Team on the Seila program, and to the Partnership for
Local Governance project
European Union, Election Observation Mission
2002 Cambodia Commune Council Elections, 3 February 2002, Final Report
Romeo, Leonardo G.
2001 Towards a Regulatory Framework for Decentralized Financing and
Planning in Cambodia, Consultancy report for UNOPS/UNDP
2002 Cambodia, in “Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers in Asia” (P. Smoke, YunHwan Kim editors) Asian Development Bank
Royal Government of Cambodia
2001 Law on Commune/Sangkat Administrative Management
2002 National Poverty Reduction Strategy
Royal Government of Cambodia, National Committee for Support of
Communes/Sangkats (NCSC)
2002 Sub-Decree on the Establishment of the Communes/Sangkats Fund
2002 Sub-Decree Commune/Sangkat Financial Management System
2002 Sub-Decree on Commune/Sangkat Development Planning
2002 Guideline on Commune/Sangkat Planning
2003 Commune/Sangkat Fund Project Implementation Manual
Tracey-White, John, and Robert Petts
2001 Study into the Socio-Economic Impact of the Local Development
Fund/Local Planning Process 1996-2000, United Nations Capital
Development Fund, Phnom Penh
30
Download