Submission from the South Western Regional Fisheries Board to the Joint Committee on Communications, Marine, and Natural Resources 1.0 Principles of fishery management There are just two principles of fishery management. Both are equally important. Firstly you protect your stock so that you have optimum spawning. This is so that you can generate the maximum surplus. In relation to salmon this means that you must protect against habitat degradation, destructive physical work in rivers, excessive water abstraction, pollution, theft (poaching) and excessive predation from predators such as cormorants, mink, seals, fishermen and anglers. The second principle is that you maximise the benefits you get from the surplus you produce. This means you get the best use out of the resource - the highest value from the product from the most cost effective inputs. While these two principles may appear obvious and sequential they are regularly confused. 2.0 Clarity of objectives So let’s reduce predation – buy out a fishery –why? Is it because we are not getting the highest value from our salmon or because we are not optimising spawning? These are two entirely different objectives and we need to analyse which of these objectives, (if either or both), would be efficiently achieved by the proposed buy out. Ireland has fisheries in surplus and fisheries where we have yet to optimise spawning. The primary management objective is different in both circumstances and we need to clearly recognise this from the outset. From one perspective fishermen and anglers are primarily predators that must be controlled but from the other they are the key partners in delivering the highest value from the surplus. 3.0 Policy -generating the best climate Where necessary fishery managers must be prepared to work against the short-term interests of stakeholders who want to exploit the stock when it is not in surplus. However it is much more effective and efficient to work with these interests persuading, demonstrating and producing the longer term benefits which they will be needed to deliver. This means that a policy climate needs to be maintained where cooperation can flourish, where your partners see their interests persisting into the longer term, and where there can be a reasonable expectation that everyone will benefit from the necessary sacrifices and contributions. The South Western Region has the biggest commercial fishery in the country at present. This fishery is scientifically sustainable. Based on the models used by scientists the quota for the southwest should be about 60% higher than it is currently. However the scientists recommend that there should be no increase over the average catches for the past five years even though their model supports such an increase. This is a management recommendation rather than scientific advice. From a management perspective it sets a 1 disturbing precedent. It signals that even where sacrifices have been made, discipline agreed and applied, and benefits result, those benefits are not to be shared. This undermines a co-operative approach to salmon management and therefore discourages a long term responsible approach being adopted by stakeholders. 4.0 The buy out debate Our angling industry wants more of the resource. This is to be expected. If the angling industry value fish more highly than commercial fishermen you could expect that the parties would try to do a deal and when done they would then request the State to facilitate it. The State would either facilitate the deal or not depending on the implications for the public interest. This has not happened, fundamentally because the angling sector is not generating the resources that render it capable of mounting a ‘take over’. In these circumstances the angling sector wants the tax payer to buy out the commercial fishermen to enable this transfer. They support their case by presenting arguments on environmental, economic and social grounds. If these arguments are valid then the tax payer could consider their investment worthwhile. However many of the arguments presented to date do not stand up to in-depth analysis. 4.1 The environmental arguments: The first principle of fishery management outlined above applies. In those parts of the country where we need more fish to spawn, we have to limit the killing of fish by all sectors. Transferring a point of kill has no beneficial effect. The environmental requirement in these districts puts the State, as the conservators of the resource, at odds with the short term objectives of both commercial fishermen and rod angling interests. Regulation is the prime management tool and the State can either enforce at high cost or gain the assistance of the sectors it is regulating. To be successful in achieving its objective efficiently it is necessary that the State applies necessary restrictions in an impartial and even handed manner and therefore must resist and be seen to resist unilateral efforts from either side to pass their burden on to the other. However the implication from the scientific advice is that sooner rather than later we must stop all exploitation in seven of our seventeen districts. This should be done with equity i.e. no killing by either commercial or rod fisheries. There is no legal requirement on the State to buy out the fishery if the purpose is for conservation from which the sectors will benefit in the future. Indeed it is in the State’s interest to retain the capacity of the fisheries for when a surplus is reproduced. However while the rod fishery can continue on a catch and release basis there will be some hardship resulting for the commercial sector. While the State has no legal requirement to do so it should alleviate this hardship by introducing a series of measures. Some of the measures outlined by the commercial fishermen in the Southwest in their recently published strategy document, following further development, should be made available on a voluntary basis. In addition there should be a significant programme on a new scale of habitat improvement and environmental protection directed primarily at these districts. While some districts may recover quickly, unfortunately on the eastern coast salmon productivity has been low over the past fifty years, and there are significant environmental problems to be addressed. It is unrealistic to expect that some of these 2 fisheries will produce surpluses and become commercially viable even in the medium term and it may be better if these are designated now as conservation areas (no killing allowed) on a permanent basis. In this context investment in alternative long term enterprises (such as ranching) is justified to offset income loss for displaced commercial fishermen. 4.2 The economic arguments: The second principle of fishery management outlined above applies. The economic arguments presented by those who advocate the stopping of the commercial fishery fail, fundamentally, because in those districts where we have a surplus that we can exploit, the marginal value, i.e. the value of selling another rod caught fish or another commercially caught fish will change depending on market conditions but not to the extent that it is better to sell all fish in either way. As availability of either rod caught fish or commercially caught fish decrease the price per fish increases to a point which exceeds yet another fish caught by the other method. As the State wishes to maximise the benefits to the economy it will remain in the State’s economic interest to maintain both industries. While this region has one of the best rod fisheries in the Country and the scientists are indicating we are and have been exceeding our spawning requirements for many years (and therefore the stock is there to support our rod fishing industry) we consider that the commercial fishery is currently making a greater contribution to our economy than the rod fishery. More importantly we consider that its potential for development in the future is greater than the rod fishery as currently organised. The inherent difficulties in the organisation of the rod sector (ownership pattern, lack of clarity in relation to ownership, and lack of respect for ownership including State ownership where established) are such that this situation is unlikely to change in the short to medium term. However this should receive prime focus for future policy change. The Board notes the analysis presented in the strategy statement published recently by the commercial fishermen in the region as follows: “State investment is not justified in the transfer of the fishery to the rod sector. While we reject the premise (based on our economic consultants analysis) outlined in the Indecon Report we accept that an individual salmon caught by a tourist angler may be worth more to the economy currently than that fish caught by the commercial sector. However the frequent extrapolation that therefore it is in the public interest that there should be a transfer of fish to the angling sector is erroneous. The fact is that if we forgo 100 fish only 3 of them will be taken by tourist anglers. This is because of the way the inland fishery is organised and we see no likelihood that this inherent inefficiency in the inland fishery will be addressed. Even if we were to accept that these fish are worth €423 each to the economy (Indecon),the commercial fishery is contributing and can contribute many times more than a mere €1269 (plus a marginal contribution for the consumption value of fish caught by locals) for 100 wild salmon. In these circumstances that exist and will persist in Ireland the transfer of additional fish to the rod fishery is inherently wasteful and should not be supported by the use of public funds.” In these circumstances and given the current structure a tourist rod caught fish would need to be worth more than 33 times a commercially caught one to justify a transfer, and 3 it simply is not, nor will it be in the future until a concerted effort is made to create an environment where investment by fishery owners is allowed to deliver a viable return. 4.3 The Social arguments The second principle of fishery management outlined above applies. The social arguments are derived from the economic ones and relate to the importance of maintaining people and businesses in remote rural areas. These arguments are made by both industries. Both industries support people from the same or similar communities. In these circumstances the social interests closely reflect the economic ones – the maintenance of both industries. 5.0 The interceptory fishery Much of the pressure applied for a change in policy utilises arguments against the concept of an interceptory / mixed stock fishery. We are asked to take account of our international responsibilities. The Board agrees with many of the comments made by the commercial sector in their recently published strategy document in this regard. In addition we wish to point out that while there are risks to a mixed stock fishery there are some safeguards as well. Healthy fisheries contribute most to mixed stocks. If a fishery is not achieving its spawning requirement you are better off fishing the allocated quota in a mixed fishery environment where some of the quota will be provided by healthy fisheries rather than fishing the quota solely from your own depleted stock. If for instance fisheries on the Northern and Western coastline are taking fish destined for the Southwest this is preferable to their entire allocated quota coming from their own stock. In this way the interceptory fishery enables the strength of the southwest fisheries to support fisheries in other districts. From a management perspective it would be easier to manage on a single stock basis. However we are not asked to do what is easy for managers but what is best for our citizens. The concept of a single stock fishery if taken to its logical conclusion would bring exploitation down to each tributary as our scientists state that they are genetically discrete. A move to a single stock management regime would fragment the commercial fishery and the necessary economies of scale to deliver a viable return on effort and to ensure efficiency in distribution and marketing would be undermined. While more difficult it is not beyond our capability to manage fisheries on a mixed stock basis and we have demonstrated our capacity to do so in the past. The demand for a single stock management regime ignores the reality that all fisheries in the sea are potentially mixed stock fisheries and it singles out the salmon for special treatment for no other reason than we know where it spawns. By the same logic once we know where any species spawns we should then stop exploiting that species anywhere except on its spawning area (after we have ensured sufficient spawning). This of course would negate the traditional fisheries of many maritime nations around the globe. The United Nations Agreement for the Implementation of the Provisions of the United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea of 10th December 1982 relating to the Conservation and Management of Straddling Fish Stocks and Highly Migratory Fish Stocks (in force as from 11 December 2001) which arose from Agenda 21 adopted by the United Nations Conference on Environment and Development deals with these fisheries. 4 The agreement recognises in article 7 ‘the sovereign rights of coastal States for the purposes of exploring and exploiting, conserving and managing the living marine resources within areas under national jurisdiction as provided for in the convention, and the rights of all States for their nationals to engage in fishing on the high seas in accordance with the convention’. It also specifies among its provisions that coastal States shall ‘take into account the interests of artisanal and subsistence fishers’. There has been a national effort in Ireland, matched by none, over the past few years to conserve our salmon. We have done much more than meeting our international commitments. We are entitled to benefit from our efforts, both at sea and in our rivers. 6.0 Scientific advice It is important that scientists produce the best advice possible so that the managers of the resource are enabled to make sound management decisions. These are distinct disciplines with distinct roles to play. Scientists must point to what ought to be done. Management must focus on what can be done, what is practicable and deliverable within the constraints that exist. We all need to maintain confidence and trust in our scientific advice. It must just not be impartial but be seen to be so. It will be even more important in the future that there is increased and continued investment in scientific research and equally important is the presentation of that advice in a manner that builds public confidence and support. 7.0 Conclusion Anglers and commercial fishermen must both come to accept that their interests are secondary to those of society as a whole. Current policy derived from what is considered best for society is to assist and support both industries and to maximise the collective benefits. This Board considers that the current policy to share this resource among the current beneficiaries is the correct one and it advocates the continuation of this policy. In this context, it is important that where fisheries are well managed or have recovered that all sectors benefit and are seen to benefit swiftly and in proportion to the contribution they have made to the recovery effort. It would be beneficial for this policy to be reaffirmed so that an environment is created where interest groups would see the need to focus their efforts on working with each other and with State agencies so that we can protect and develop this resource and increase the benefits for all. 5