Submission 0330 Issues Paper on a Sustainable Population Strategy for Australia Name: N. L. Carter Suburb and State: Roseville Chase, NSW 2069 Date of Submission: 7 March 2011 Submission to the Sustainable Population Taskforce By N. L. Carter Summary The (mainly economic) arguments for a high population are false. The social, lifestyle and environmental costs are real. Our international obligations to reduce our carbon footprint cannot be met if we continue to increase our population. That planning and lifestyle change can offset the irreversible damaging effects of over-population are fantasies promulgated by individuals and groups with special interests in ever-increasing population and consumption. 1. Real Costs of Increased Population As a child growing up in suburban Sydney I was able to roam in a large tract of bushland, virtually unchanged since the arrival of the First Fleet. Birds, lizards abounded there. A creek of pure, clean water flowed through it to a backwater of Sydney Harbour. Immediately after World War II part of this area was ‘cleared’ and a large number of Housing Commission homes were built there. The creek was covered over and became a storm-water drain. I was deeply shocked by this transformation. A few years later another large tract of land from the same area was devastated. I recall standing and looking at this land, which resembled photos I had seen (in my father’s ‘Anzac Books’) of landscapes in France in World War I ripped to pieces by artillery fire. In 1960-2 a third housing development further reduced this formerly beautiful place so that only a fairly small part of the original bushland remains. This taught me three things: (1) that every house (including the one I grew up in) built on bushland or farmland entails a cost to our environment and ourselves; (2) that such damage can never be restored or replaced; and (3) these losses are very real, even though they are not identified and quantified in money terms. And the more people, the more damage. 1 2. Self Interest-Based Special Pleading for Increased Population I learned later that there no matter how close we get to the end of a finite resource (such as native bushland), there are always those who argue (from financial self interest) that they should consume (‘develop’) it and that they are acting in the interests of all. And they get media support. Example 1.1: In 1968 the Department of Defence indicated that it was planning to vacate certain lands on South Head, Sydney Harbour. Almost immediately, one of the Sydney afternoon newspapers published an interview with the Mayor of Woollahra in which he stated that the land would be a perfect location for “Terrace Development”. Very soon after that, the same newspaper, or its twin, published a photograph of the residual (remnant) bushland on Dobroyd Head and Grotto Point, Balgowlah, under a large print heading ‘Not Used At All’ (or words to that effect). An Editorial cried out in apparent anguish “Return This Land To the People“. It was fairly obvious that ‘these people’ were real estate and development interests, not those looking for a home to raise their kids in, and that they cared not a fig for needs for open space and for kids to experience nature in places close to their homes. Example 1.2: Harry Triguboff, a Sydney developer, asserted in an article published by the Sydney Morning Herald (October 11, 2006) that “Sydney must grow or die” and that coastal national parks should be cleared and used for housing. “If people want to see trees they can go to the mountains” he said. Hyperbole? By his own admission this man contributes heavily to those NSW political parties capable of forming government, which presumably lobbied the Federal Government for increased immigration, and hence demand for housing. No one in the development lobby has ever suggested an upper limit to growth of Sydney or the need to link this with long-term government policies on population. Presumably Sydney will have to grow to Perth and then die, having devastated the environment, and us, on the way. 2. Influence of Wealthy Lobby Groups on Public Policy It is impossible for the ordinary citizen to follow the processes and outcomes of lobbying. There is a reasonable basis for suspecting that governmentsponsored population growth is mainly a response to lobbying by business and property interest groups such as the above. Maurice Iemma’s first public announcements upon becoming Premier of NSW included that he would repeal the ‘Vendor Tax’ (as repeatedly and publicly demanded by the developer lobby), but also that he would ‘… lobby the Federal Government for increased immigration …’, thus increasing enormously the demand for housing and construction (and, of course, for other goods and services). It beggars belief that these two announcements, coming together and straight after Bob Carr’s resignation, were not connected through the influence and political donations of property and business interests. 2 There is a political constituency in Western Sydney which has become a pawn in the game of making money, I believe, by suggesting that any drive to look critically at population targets represents an attack on recent migrants to this country. Of course it does not. All Australians and their children, born and yet to be born, stand to lose if we destroy this country by over-populating it. Many assert the social benefits of increased population through immigration since the Second World War, and in many ways I agree. Because of it we are now a more multicultural society, which is a strength, and I believe in general a more outgoing and tolerant one as well. As in other fields however, it is possible to reach a point of ‘diminishing returns’ beyond which the benefits of each unit increase in population decrease, and may even on balance become negative. I believe we have now reached that point. 3. Planning As a Tool For Mitigating Effects of Overpopulation It is often asserted that all will be well if we ‘plan for’ increased population (code for ‘… large increases are inevitable and therefore it is useless for you to oppose them…’). The history of European settlement of coastal Australia shows that we cannot rely on ‘Planning’ to offset the effects of too rapid population increase. Here are just a couple of examples from NSW and Queensland. Example 3.1: In 2006 a Sydney developer wished to build a number of residences on certain farming lands on the Hawkesbury River. At the same time (October 6, 2006) The Sydney Morning Herald published an editorial stating that “Sydney must grow” and that if they get in the way “lettuces can be grown somewhere else”. The developer won out. Most of Sydney’s lettuces are now freighted from an area of Queensland was recently devastated by cyclone Yasi. If those demanding more growth of Sydney get their way, there will be millions more people in Sydney and few, if any, market gardens to feed them. So when cyclones hit again, as they surely will, where will Sydney’s “lettuces” come from? Not from backyards, since again due to the population growth protagonists, high-rise (’chook house’) dwellings will predominate. Example 3.2: In another irony almost too ludicrous to bear, most of Sydney’s bananas now come from North Queensland farms, because banana plantations on coastal NSW became much more lucrative for developers, in a market fed by people cashed up from selling their Sydney homes at prices pushed sky-high by demand due to population increase (combined with tax breaks and unlimited bank borrowings from overseas). These Queensland banana farms have been wiped out twice by storms in the last five years, even though climate change with its predicted more frequent and intense storms has only just begun. Why is it not asked whether these banana plantations are in the wrong place? 3 The history of residential development on the Australian coast also provides many dismal examples of destruction caused by dysfunctional planning. Example 3.3: In 1972 I wrote to our then local MLA, Mr. Healey, pointing out that a particular NSW North Coast beach would be ruined by erosion if developed for housing and suggesting that the sole structures (two wooden shacks) on the dunes be resumed. The Minister for Local government (Mr. Cutler) replied in a letter dated 30 June 1972 that he could not do that but that the State Planning Authority had now brought the NSW coast under planning control. The Premier Mr. Carr also noted in a letter to me of 11 October 1985 that the NSW Government had enacted a Coastal Protection Act, which with the Environmental Planning and Assessment Act of 1979 would prevent further inappropriate rezonings of coastal land. These measures must surely have been subverted because recent reports by the CSIRO have identified many thousands of homes on the coast threatened by sea-erosion (as well as some Sydney suburbs at risk from future rises in sea level). Many of these properties are at risk even without the anticipated sea level rises and storms associated with climate change. The damage to beaches and natural foreshores caused by the interaction of natural forces and property development will be even more complete. (The NSW Government recently rejected a strategy of ‘planned retreat’ to mitigate future sea-erosion). Who will count that cost to ordinary Australian citizens, who love their beaches and coastal landscapes? No one. Why? Because the losses will not show up as debits to that absurd measure of ‘growth’, the GDP, and because there are short-term financial gains to be had from these developments. They were, and are, never ‘mistakes’. They make money. The history of coastal development in Queensland is redolent of the same destructive processes. Who will forget the coastal development and erosion of the Gold coast in the 1960’s when sand had to be transported from elsewhere to repair beaches which had been formed and maintained by natural forces without human help for thousands of years? And how will future generations ever comprehend why Brisbane was built on a flood plain, its vulnerability to flood increased by even more frenzied development after the tragedy of the 1974 floods? We all sympathise with people affected by the Queensland floods, and for those whose homes on the coast were swept away by the ‘wave surge’ associated with cyclone Yasi. I don’t have any qualifications as a civil engineer or town planner, but even I can see that these homes should never have been built where they were, and that they will inevitably be impacted by storms again and again in the future. This situation has come about in Australia because of rapid population increase fuelling and fuelled by a money-based, short-sighted planning 4 system. With continued population increase there are many more disasters to come. 4. Lifestyle Change It has been argued to me that since we have been able to change attitudes to such things as smoking and the use of car seat belts we can change our use of resources such as water and energy (open space and biological diversity are seldom mentioned). But we are not meeting e.g. Kyoto commitments to reduce greenhouse gas emissions now. How will we meet any future international commitments with the increases in population which property and business interests keep on telling us (falsely) are inevitable? Where will the political will to change come from when a large proportion of the members of Federal Parliament (including the leader of the National Party) do not accept the overwhelming view of the world’s scientific community that imminent climate change is due to human activity? To the extent that they are open to government control, population increases should be required to follow demonstrated changes in lifestyle and improved planning processes, and a rational case then made for such population increases. Instead, we find that fantasies of a future change in lifestyle and creation of a perfect planning system are being used to justify increases in population motivated by quite different considerations. Recent surveys have shown that the bulk of Australians are opposed to further rapid increases in population. This is not bigotry as some have suggested. It is common sense. We have all seen the failure of infrastructure to keep up with population growth and we don’t believe that can be changed by changing governments. Road congestion and other infrastructure, including hospital waiting lists are often discussed. But there are other things which we Australians once took for granted, which are seldom mentioned. I get back to beaches. Most of us live on the coast near cities. Climate change will reduce the size of all our beaches (each one centimetre rise in sea level will reduce the width of beaches by one metre). Storms will become more frequent and intense. Even without climate change some beaches near Sydney have been utterly destroyed by erosion due to high-rise development (e.g. Collaroy, near Sydney). A future of coastal megalopolises with many more people, smaller and fewer beaches, less and less urban bushland and open space - harder to get to and more and more crowded when we do. Why should we put up with that? 5. Arguments For Increased Population Australia’s population is increasing at a greater rate than any other developed country, and we are the second worst polluters per head of population in the world. The more of us there are, the worse for ourselves and the world. But still, it is argued this is a ‘good thing’. The arguments for increased population are mainly along the following lines. 5 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. A bigger economy means more wealth; We need more skilled workers; We need many more people for Defence; Immigration counters population ageing; A larger population means more creativity. We owe it to the rest of the world. 1. A bigger economy. That a bigger economy means more wealth (all else equal) may be true of gross GDP. It is not remotely true if by more wealth is meant a higher per capita GDP. Most countries with the highest per capita GDP have populations half that of Australia. Measuring wealth solely by GDP is transparently wrong. We all know that some of our most precious public assets (uncrowded spaces, natural bushland and beaches) have no economic value. It becomes quite farcical when newspaper columnists rate our community’s wealth by the prices of its houses. Rather like saying we are richer if food prices go up. 2. More skilled workers. We are told we need more skilled workers. If we lack skilled workers it is because we have failed to train them at the rate they are needed, and the need is increased by increased population. Mining companies may need them in the short term but only if it is assumed that we must get the minerals out before the world no longer wants them. This may be true of coal, but then our long-term wealth (in farming land, water security, biodiversity) may depend upon some of these coal deposits being left where they are. On visiting the Pilbara recently I was amazed at how non-labour intensive extraction and transport processes were. Ore-trains several kilometres long driven by a single driver? We have had 60 years of government-sponsored population increase through immigration, plus natural increases of more than 100,000 every year since 1982. Why do we still have a skills shortage if population increase and immigration are the answer? 3. Defence. It is said that a larger population is needed for our defence. Surely this is the modern version of the “Yellow Peril” argument. There are so many nations in our region with vastly greater populations that if this were valid we might as well give up the game now. The truth is that our defence depends primarily on diplomacy, technology, a committed and skilled defence force, and defence treaties, not on population. 4. Population Ageing. Some believe that population ageing, which affects all developed countries, is bad, and can be prevented or slowed by immigration. Both notions are humbug. A letter to the editor of the SMH by Professor Catherine Betts of Swinburne University (6 July 20010) succinctly explains why. Her views are supported by reports from the Productivity Commission among others. 6 Professor Betts concluded that the only way to avoid population ageing was to “… have a large family and die young”. Join the Third World economies? 5. Creativity. Recently it has been suggested that we need many more people because large populations are more creative. I have not seen any evidence that there is a causal connection here. Radar and the jet engine, the antibiotic era (beginning with penicillin), television, even the digital revolution began in medium-sized countries with a history of academic freedom and excellence. Their commercialisation and development were done elsewhere. The U.S.A. may be given as an example of high population and high creativity. Other countries with vastly greater populations may be cited to support the reverse. On the other hand, by their own admission the differences between rich and poor are possibly greatest in the U.S.A., an immigration-based country like ourselves (National Geographic Atlas of the World Sixth Edition). 6. We owe the world. We owe it to the rest of the world (to overpopulate) because they have. We are a world food producer in some categories. The more of us, the more we eat, the less for them. 7