The Economic Implications of the Public Trust Doctrine Gary D. Libecap University of California, Santa Barbara National Bureau of Economic Research PERC Hoover Institute October 3, 2006 “Existing water users are distraught by decisions like the Mono Lake case, and understandably so. Enormously valuable, long-recognized interests in water are at stake. Such cases portend major changes in the status of water rights. Traditional water users understand full well that a fundamental transition is taking place in the conception of how water ought to be used in the West…. Let me start by saying that as a matter of legal analysis, the holders of existing water rights are in deep trouble.” Joseph Sax (1989, 4756). I. Introduction. This paper examines the role of the public trust doctrine in the re-allocation of water in the American West and the doctrine’s implications for the security of water rights and incentives for effective stewardship of water. In the West, farmers historically have used roughly 80 percent of the region’s water, often in low-valued or subsidized crops, such as alfalfa, cotton, or rice. Farmers typically pay only for the pumping or conveyance costs for the water and not for its scarcity value.1 At the margin, however, water values are much greater in meeting growing urban, recreational and environmental demands. As a result, there are significant allocative gains from moving some water from agricultural to these new uses. The issue is the mechanism to be used for transferring this water. The public trust doctrine raises the question of whether or not water transfers will occur through market transactions or through the police power of the state. Market transactions rely on and reaffirm (through precedent) secure property rights to water. State re-allocation through the public trust doctrine relies instead on judicial and agency actions and can weaken property rights and their ability to support water exchange and to encourage private investment in water quality, riparian and aquatic habitat, and other infrastructure. Because it emphasizes the “publicness” of water, the doctrine encourages open-access. Open-access, however, brings rent dissipation and the losses associated with 1 the “tragedy of the commons” as more and more individuals seek to use the limited water resource.2 For “public” resources, those losses can be mitigated only through central, command-and-control regulation, but the record of centralized regulation in limiting rent dissipation has not been encouraging. Regulated fisheries continue to be depleted; air pollution abatement targets have not been achieved; and technological change in the radio spectrum has been retarded. For these reasons, there is an accelerated trend toward assigning property rights of some type to resources in order to mitigate the losses of the common pool.3 Re-allocation of water under the public trust doctrine also is costly, contentious, and slow. Because private property rights in water are rejected in favor of public ownership, there is no compensation to current users who lose water. Hence, they can be expected to resist such efforts even if they are in the aggregate, in the public interest. Moreover, disputes over water allocation are much more likely to go to trial than to be settled out-of-court through private negotiation. The public trust doctrine gives standing to any member of the “public,” to contest uses thought to be inconsistent with the public trust. Hence, any private agreement between parties can be undermined by challenges brought by a third party. Drawn-out litigation and trial become inevitable. Finally, water allocation decisions made by the courts and administrative agencies under the doctrine, occur without information on relative water values that market trades would otherwise provide. Accordingly, too-little or too-much water will be applied to new uses. 4 These problems associated with the public trust doctrine are examined in more detail below in the context of the Mono Lake case and Los Angeles’ water rights in California and 2 stream access and wildlife ownership in Montana. Before turning to the public trust doctrine and its impact on water rights, however, it is important to first review the evidence regarding pressure to re-allocate water and how private water markets are responding to them. II. Evidence on Water Prices and Water Exchanges. Some numbers demonstrate the social benefits of moving some irrigation water to urban, recreational and environmental uses in the West. About 14 years ago, Griffin and Boadu (1992, 274-5) reported that the value of water used in agriculture, capitalized over 50 years, was $300 to $2,300 per acre-foot (approximately 326,000 gallons) in the Rio Grande Valley of Texas. Urban water values, capitalized over the same period, ranged instead from $6,500 to $21,000 per acre-foot. The average transfer produced net benefits of $10,000 per acre foot. More contemporary data gathered from the leading trade journal Water Strategist by Glennon, Ker, and Libecap (2006) for 2,189 water transfers with price information from the 12 western states from 1987 to 2005 also demonstrate the economic gains of further water exchanges.5 Table 1 provides mean price data across the 19-year period for all states. All values are converted to 1987 dollars and water flows associated with longterm leases and sales are discounted at 5 percent to provide comparable per acre-foot water prices with one-year leases. As shown in the table, there are substantial welfare gains from water transfers from agriculture to other uses. Environmental prices are somewhat lower on average than agriculture-to-urban and urban-to-urban water exchanges. But this reflects the dominance of one-year leases in most agriculture-to- 3 environmental transfers, whereas urban transactions are more likely to involve long-term leases or sales. Water prices for sales and long-term leases typically are higher than for short-term leases because they reflect ownership or long-term certainty of supply. Water involved in sales and long-term leases also may be from higher-priority water rights (allowing for such trades) and of higher quality, which often is required if water is moved out of sector—from agriculture to urban uses, for example. Table 1 Water Transfer Price Differences by Category Number of Observations Mean Price 351 $57 Type of Trade Agriculture-toAgriculture 1,211 203 Agriculture-toUrban 274 120 Urban-to-Urban 161 57 Agriculture to Environmental Source: Water Strategist. Glennon, Ker, and Libecap (2006). The data in Table 2 illustrate that large amounts of water in fact have been moving across sectors. The table reports the number and amounts of water transacted over nearly 20 years. The amounts of water shown are those that are “committed” by water exchange contracts, ranging from one-year leases to longer-term leases and sales. As above, for sales and long-term leases, the flow amounts for the term of the contract (perpetuity for sales) are discounted at 5 percent and brought back to the present. As shown, agricultural to environmental water transfers account for 7 percent of all exchanges and 13 percent of all water moved from agriculture. Most agriculture to environmental water transactions involve either federal or state agencies or non-profit organizations in efforts to build riparian or aquatic habitats, in many cases to meet Endangered Species Act requirements. In the transactions, irrigation water is leased or 4 sometimes purchased to augment stream flows. Instream flows are examined in more detail below. Table 2 Western Water Transfers, 1987-2005 Classification Agricultural to Agricultural Agricultural to Urban Agricultural to Environmental Urban to Agricultural Urban to Urban Urban to Environmental Environmental to Agricultural Environmental to Urban Environmental to Environmental Combination Total Number of Transfers 471 1,825 233 38 440 54 0 1 6 164 3,232 Frequency 15% 56% 7% 1% 14% 2% 0% 0% 0% 5% 100% Amount of Water (af) 16,241,926 39,747,583 18,186,143 2,549,986 26,600,020 8,925,447 0 62 4,171,200 21,636,937 138,059,303 Frequency 12% 29% 13% 2% 19% 6% 0% 0% 3% 16% 100% Source: Water Strategist. Glennon, Ker, and Libecap (2006) data set. The data then reveal that water transfers based on private water rights are responding to price signals of increasing values in urban and environmental uses. To understand the role of private water rights in water re-allocation and investment, it is worthwhile reviewing the nature of private rights under the appropriative doctrine. III. Appropriative Water Rights. The appropriative rights doctrine dominates in the American West. It allows rights holders to withdraw a certain amount of water from its natural course for private beneficial purposes on land remote from the point of diversion.6 Hence, it allows for the separation of water from the land in a way not possible under the riparian water rights system that exists in the eastern United States. Under the appropriative system, ownership of water is assigned through the rule of first possession or priority of claim. Through this 5 process individuals gain a usufructuary or possessory right to water. The maintenance of appropriative rights has been based on placing claimed water into beneficial use. This use-it-or-lose-it requirement historically has led to devoting water to low-valued uses because water diverters, such as irrigators, could do little else with it and maintain their rights. As we will see, this, though, is changing. Because appropriative rights can be separated from the land and sold or leased, they are the foundation for private water transfers in response to changing economic conditions described in Table 2. Trades that change the location of water diversion, nature of use, and timing, especially if they are large relative to stream flow, however, are restricted by state law and regulated by state agencies because of their potential impact on third parties. Changes in location of diversion to points upstream, for example, could harm other rights holders downstream by reducing the water flow available to them. Changes in the location of use, particularly those that are out-of-basin, can even more substantially affect return flows and available water to other rights holders because none of the water exported migrates back to the stream. To mitigate these effects, state water agencies typically allow changes in diversion and location for only historical consumptive uses—water that they would consume in any event.7 The reliance of appropriative rights on diversion as a means of definition and enforcement reduces the quantity of flowing water in the stream. But valuable instream uses require the maintenance of flows. Historically, only diversion has been accepted as evidence of beneficial use and as the basis for property rights under the appropriative doctrine. This condition has meant that instream uses have not been protected under the prevailing rights structure. Recently, however, instream uses, such as maintenance of 6 fishery habitat, recreation, and amenity values, been added to the list of beneficial uses in western states, and thereby potentially subject to formal claiming and market transactions.8 On heavily appropriated streams, where virtually all water is claimed, acquisition or leasing (during drought conditions) of senior rights, which otherwise would be used for irrigation, to support instream flows is an effective option for enhancing aquatic habitat. The most active states have been Oregon, Montana, California, and Washington, where state agencies, such as the Montana Department of Fish, Wildlife, and Parks, and in some cases, private environmental groups, such as the Oregon and Washington Water Trusts and the Trout Unlimited Montana Water Trust have been able to lease or purchase water rights from farmers and retain the water within streams. Leases often involve dryyear options, where they are activated only during dry years and the farmer is compensated to allow purchase of the crops foregone, and split-season leases, where farmers irrigate during the critical crop growing period and release water at the end of the summer when stream flows would otherwise be very low.9 Federal agencies also are involved in water exchanges to augment stream flows. In 2000 when the National Marine Fisheries Service required that the Bonneville Power Authority on the Columbia River and its tributaries mitigate the effects of drawdown for hydroelectric power generation on species listed under the Endangered Species Act, the agency indirectly engaged in water rights purchases and leases from irrigators. It did so by providing funds to state agencies and private organizations to negotiate with farmers. Additionally, the federal Bureau of Reclamation is an active purchaser of water rights to retire the water for environmental objectives. 7 In the face of this record of market exchange, what are the advantages of reliance upon markets rather than centralized state regulation under the public trust doctrine? IV. The Advantages of Market Transactions for Re-allocating Water. There are numerous advantages to relying on clearly-defined and secure appropriative water rights to promote the transfer of water from agriculture to environmental and recreational uses. One is that the negotiating parties, farmers, government agencies, private recreational/environmental groups, gain information about the value and amount of water really required. Would-be purchasers must figure out how much water they want to buy and how much they are willing to pay for it. Sellers have to determine the value of their water. If the offer matches these values, some trade occurs. If it does not, then the buyer has to recalculate willingness to pay, give up the purchase, or wait until a later time when conditions may have changed. Or the seller has to recalculate how much the water is worth. It is the case that environmental and recreational values often are difficult to assess, but market transactions force such an assessment in a manner that does not occur with arbitrary state re-allocation through the judiciary under the public trust doctrine. As described below, because public trust rulings lead to all-ornothing re-allocations without compensation, the contesting parties have incentive to develop extreme values for their claims rather than to seek convergence as is the case with market exchanges. Rulings based on these extreme values are likely to lead to either excessive re-allocation or too little adjustment in water use. Another advantage of a market approach is that it recognizes existing property rights as a basis for exchange. There is a legal framework for bargaining among the 8 parties to redistribute water. There is a recognized owner and a potential buyer. They may agree or disagree at any point in time. The structure elicits negotiation and cooperation, and provides for routine, timely re-allocation as values change. It reduces social conflict and division because in voluntary trade both parties benefit. A final and related advantage of a market approach and secure property rights is that they encourage investment in water conservation, storage, distribution, and quality as well as in related riparian and aquatic habitat. Incentives for private investment by landowners in such habitat are at stake in the stream access cases examined below. The alternative to markets is centralized state regulation and re-allocation of water, often under the public trust doctrine. V. The Public Trust Doctrine. The “public trust” is a common law principle creating the legal right of the public to utilize certain lands and waters, such as tidewaters or navigable rivers, and other waters and natural resources with high amenity or public goods values.10 Under the doctrine, the rights of the public are vested in the state as owner of the resource and trustee of its proper use. It historically came from the notion that government has an affirmative duty to administer, protect, manage, and conserve access to navigable waters, and there may be strong economic arguments for such regulation to promote the low-cost flow of commerce by limiting holdup by riparian landowners. Broader interpretations are developing beyond care for navigation that have more potentially pernicious effects respect to private property rights and resource access and use. In a far-reaching ruling by the California Supreme Court in 1983 in the Mono Lake 9 case (National Audubon Society v. Superior Court 685 P.2d 709) the court stated that the “core of the public trust doctrine is the state’s authority as sovereign to exercise a continuous supervision and control over” the waters of the state.11 This opinion energized expansion of the public trust doctrine in a growing number of western states to restrict “excessive” diversions from non-navigable streams to protect aquatic environments and to guarantee public recreational access to streams on private lands and wildlife.12 In these cases, the public trust is used as the basis for state, rather than private allocation and investment in water. The state, however, may lack the information to determine the right amount of water to be devoted to habitat and stream flows, and as is well known, state agency actions are molded by constituent group politics that also may lead to excessive or inadequate actions. At the same time, despite the advantages of markets as described above, private parties would be unlikely to invest in recreational and aquatic habitat if it is solely a public good. In Montana stream access cases where landowners are denied the ability to limit entry on their lands, the courts insure that stream habitat is a public good and thereby reduce private motives for investment. Importantly, the public trust doctrine can be applied retroactively to roll back preexisting appropriative water rights that appear inconsistent with the public trust.13 There apparently is no constitutional basis for taking challenges of public trust restrictions of private water rights.14 Much of the extension of the doctrine has occurred through judicial opinions that have broadened state discretionary authority over water rights. A Lexus/Nexus search reveals 32 court cases between1985 and 2004 in 12 western states involving public trust issues with three-fourths of them in California, Colorado, and Idaho. In general, the 10 rulings have held that state responsibilities under the public trust doctrine may extend to maintenance of stream flow and water levels in rivers and natural lakes, including groundwater systems linked to them in order to guard for health, amenity values, and fish and wildlife habitat.15 As another example, a 1988 Oregon statute that authorized appropriators to sell or lease water they saved requires that about 25 percent be allocated to the state and held for instream flow maintenance.16 This “tax” is apt to lower incentives to redirect water through market exchange. Other examples of stream and wildlife access are examined in more detail below. VI. The Economic Implications of the Public Trust Doctrine. Because water is a mixed resource providing private and public goods, there can be justifiable concerns about private water use that potentially harm public values. The public trust doctrine is so elastic and potentially expansive, however, that it can lead to extensive government intrusion in water rights. Accordingly, the benefits of public trust interventions have to be weighed carefully against the value of the private uses and investment that will be restricted or prohibited. In writing about the Mono Lake controversy that led to the 1983 California Supreme Court public trust ruling, John Hart (1996, 3, 181) saw the opinion as offering a powerful way of balancing public and private demands for water by stressing its common property nature. But for those who are concerned about water quality, supplies, and flexible allocation in the presence of growing scarcity, as are most westerners, caution is in order. 11 One problem as noted in the introduction is that the doctrine stresses water as a regulated commons, and the experience with regulated commons often has not been that satisfactory. Indeed, dissatisfaction with the past performance of centralized regulation of common resources has led to adoption of more formal, property arrangements. These include individual transferable quotas (ITQs) in common fisheries, tradable emission permits for air pollution reduction, and shares in unitized oil and gas fields. In so doing, the resources involved have been moved from being considered “public” to more “private” in order to instill incentives for better stewardship and conservation. Where ITQs have been adopted, fishery stocks generally have rebounded and the value of the fisheries increased. Tradable emission permits have lowered the costs of achieving air quality standards. Oil field unitization has brought important efficiency gains.17 Judicial expansion of the public trust doctrine in water appears to move in just the opposite direction. The doctrine as interpreted by the courts holds that bodies of water (navigable and non-navigable) belong to the public (common property) and that the government has a special and inescapable duty to protect them. Accordingly, state agencies are charged under the trust to regulate allocation and use with adjustments made as public values change. This is a broad regulatory mandate: “Thus, the function of the Water Board has steadily evolved from the narrow role of deciding priorities between competing appropriators to the charge of comprehensive planning and allocation of waters. This change necessarily affects the board’s responsibility with respect to the public trust.”18 It is not obvious why greater regulation of this “common” resource (water) would perform more effectively than has been the case in fisheries, air pollution, or oil pools. 12 Another problem with the doctrine is that it clearly weakens appropriative water rights. Their non-vested, usufruct nature is stressed, subject to continued re-evaluation of their position vis-à-vis changing trust values. Use rights previously granted can be revoked without payment: “…the foregoing cases amply demonstrate the continuing power of the state as administrator of the public trust, a power which extends to the revocation of previously granted rights,” and “Once again we rejected the claim that establishment of the public trust constituted a taking of property for which compensation was required.”19 The doctrine, then, potentially adds uncertainty to water ownership, weakening existing property rights and their ability to promote investment, trade, and efficient use of water. The foregone private uses may be of higher social value than the public goods at stake, or there may be gradients whereby some of the private uses are more valuable at the margin than some of the public values. In this case, society would be better off if only a partial re-allocation occurred. Regulation, however, is not very effective in handling such gradations. Moreover, regulatory takings under the public trust doctrine would reduce information about both private and public values. Collection, measurement, and consideration of alternative values are not required under the doctrine. Any information gathered as part of public trust court challenges of existing water rights is unlikely to be of much help because, as described above, it is presented by both parties in an adversarial setting to bolster their respective claims. Hence, it is not apt to be inclusive or balanced. Alternatively, negotiation to purchase water rights to safeguard public values forces the parties involved to gather information about the true values of both and to consider the tradeoffs involved in the public trust action. 13 A broad public trust mandate for state regulation also would lower the private costs of holdup strategies by providing legal standing for parties to contest private water diversions, investments, or proposed trades as violations of the doctrine. As the costs of private holdup are reduced, there is potential for abuse. Maximizing social welfare requires consideration of these tradeoffs and adoption of the least costly approaches in applying them. Where there is a case for regulatory action, the most effective response is for state agencies to purchase and retire the water right as part of their mandates, rather than to use the doctrine to arbitrarily revoke water rights, limiting past uses and potential exchange. These problems would presumably apply not only to private water users, but to public ones as well, suggesting that current distributions for recreational or environmental protection, at a later date, could be found to be inconsistent with the public trust if values were to change. As emphasized throughout this paper, an advantage of secure property rights is that they can be a basis for routine re-allocation through exchange. Public trust re-allocations, however, would be through regulatory rulings and not be compensable. Conflict and delay are therefore assured. A related third problem with the public trust doctrine is that legal disputes brought under it may be more difficult to privately settle because of the broad legal standing it authorizes. When parties enter into litigation they weigh the expected benefits of trail versus settlement. Settlement typically is less costly than trial. If the net benefits of trial decline for one of the parties (higher cost, lower probability of winning, reduced damage expectations for plaintiff, higher damage expectations for defendant), settlement is more likely.20 Under the public trust doctrine, however, settlement costs could be driven up as 14 the number of potential plaintiffs grows. With extensive legal standing available for groups to challenge existing water uses as implied by expansive notions of the public trust, any settlement agreement with one party could be thwarted by the appearance of another plaintiff. Successive settlement negotiations would drive up settlement costs, and as they increased, disputes would be more likely to go to trial. Public trust suits are also more likely to go to trail if the plaintiffs generate more information on their behalf at lower cost than the defendant. The contesting parties invest in lawyers, experts, and other resources to improve their chances of winning. Greater investments in litigation expenditures by one party relative to the other, all else equal, can increase the probability of success in the case. With an ease of obtaining legal standing under the public trust doctrine, one could image entry by successive plaintiffs, each more extreme in their demands than the previous. If such plaintiffs are made up of ardent, “true believers,” it is possible that their labor costs for litigation expenditures would be lower than for the defendant. Lower litigation costs, in turn, would lead to greater investment in litigation, a higher probability of winning, and greater likelihood of costly trial. Moreover, judicial or regulatory decision making based on information provided by the low-cost plaintiff may be biased because it would outweigh that provided by the higher-cost defendant. VII. Application: The Mono Lake Case. In the 1930s Los Angeles acquired water rights in the Mono Basin and made investments in infrastructure to connect the basin to the Los Angeles Aqueduct in the Owens Valley to export water to the city. Regional agriculture, recreation, wildlife, and 15 the integrity of Mono Lake were subsidiary in importance to meeting growing urban water demand. Moreover the cumulative impact of withdrawal did not become apparent until much later. Because of a lack of export capacity, the city did not fully exercise its diversion options until completion of the second aqueduct in 1970. Although there were substantial water shipments from the Mono Basin from time to time, amounts over 100,000 acre feet did not occur until after 1970. With these increased diversions, however, concerns about the environmental impact of water export intensified. By 1981 the level of Mono Lake was 46 feet below where it had been in 1940. Fearing further loss, the National Audubon Society, Friends of the Earth, the Sierra Club, and the Mono Lake Committee initially sued the city in 1979 to halt the export of water, citing the public trust doctrine. Environmental groups organized an effective political and public relations campaign to save Mono Lake, its tufa formations, and the habitat it provided for water fowl. A complicated series of legal challenges to Los Angeles’ water rights and diversions took place simultaneously. These were highlighted by the famous public trust ruling in 1983. The litigation process was contentious, slow, and very costly. It likely delayed the response to the diversion problem. In its 1983 opinion in National Audubon Society v. Superior Court (33 Cal 3d 419) the California Supreme Court held that Los Angeles’ water rights were to be limited by the state in order to protect public trust values, and it called upon the State Water Resources Control Board regulate the city’s diversions. Numerous court cases followed for over ten years as the antagonists fought over the extent and nature of Los Angeles’ water rights and the amount of water to be re-directed to the lake. All the while, Mono 16 Lake’s level continued to drop, streams remained dry, and riparian and aquatic habitats remained unrestored. And the warring parties continued to waste resources in the conflicts. By 1991 Los Angeles estimated that it had spent up to $12 million for outside lawyers and consultants since 1979. In the end, Los Angeles lost the water. In 1994 the state halted any withdrawal of water from the Mono Basin for about 20 years until the lake reached a targeted level. The value of the lost Mono water and hydroelectric power was estimated to be $35,460,000 annually, or nearly half a billion dollars over 25 years at 5 percent interest. These costs were borne by the citizens of Los Angeles. The ruling invigorated advocacy groups and they have moved aggressively to extend the public trust to other areas. One result of the public trust case is that current claims to water cannot serve as a foundation for contracting over future allocations. Indeed, the new water flows for Mono Lake that are considered part of the public trust today are not protected over the long-run. They too could be re-assessed by subsequent courts and directed to different uses. It is a subjective process with discrete, abrupt changes that will be unsettling to those who had grown accustomed to a particular water distribution and made investments based on it. VII. Application: Stream Access and Wildlife. The Public Trust Doctrine generally reserves the title to the beds, banks and waters of navigable waterways to the state. The state holds this title “in trust for the people of the State that they may enjoy the navigation of the waters, carry on commerce over them, and have liberty of fishing therein freed from the obstruction or interference of private parties.” As such, the trust denies preferential rights to riparian land holders as 17 against the public who hope to use such navigable waterways for recreation. The public trust also prevents private landowners from excluding the public from navigable streams due to any landowner improvements on their stretch of the waterway.21 Each state determines the extent to which the public trust doctrine applies within its jurisdiction. Montana has adopted a relatively expansive role for the doctrine in stream access disputes and in potentially in wildlife, with important implications for markets and private resource investment. The general test for public trust application is whether or not the waterway is navigable. If it is, then the waterway is held by the state in trust with public access guaranteed between ordinary high water marks. The test of navigability is whether or not the waterway is susceptible of being used commercially, such as for floating logs. But potential use by pleasure craft, including kayaks and rafts during some time of the year can also satisfy the test. If a stream is deemed non-navigable, then riparian owners typically own the streambed, but the public may still use the surface for floating or other recreational activities. This expansive interpretation of the public trust is occurring as the value of fishing and hunting is increasing dramatically, and it could undermine private efforts to invest in habit that would provide greater fishing and hunting opportunities. Rising recreation demand provides an opportunity for land owners to supply improved habitat that increases fish and wildlife stocks and to charge an access fee or to capture the capital gains from the sales of land with greater recreational opportunities. Landowners have incentive to do so to diversify from traditional agricultural production that may have relatively lower returns, at least on some lands. These actions are clearly beneficial to recreationists because they improve fishing and hunting experiences. Since states 18 compete with one another for out-of-state recreationists, who pay higher fees for fishing and hunting, greater private investment would improve fishing and hunting opportunities in Montana relative to other states. Unfortunately, these private efforts have led to court challenges to force landowners to open their properties to public access for fishing and hunting and to limit the ability of landowners to charge extra for use of their lands. These legal disputes follow from political objections to private restrictions on the right of access to naturallyprovided and previously-open resources, such as fish stocks and wildlife herds and flocks. Because some of the landowners are from out-of-state, local demands for access coincide with populist objections and resentment of wealthy out-of-staters who are viewed as tying up natural resources that should be available at no cost to Montana citizens. In the 1980s as fishing and wildlife values began to rise in Montana lawsuits were filed to insure unimpeded access for recreation on Montana rivers and streams. The immediate issue was whether or not landowners could restrict floating on navigable waterways as congestion was increasing and as disputes were occurring between rafters and property owners over launch and exit sites and perceived trespass in other areas. Rafters already had some legal protection for the right of access to navigable streams under a 1928 Montana State Supreme Court ruling.22 In 1984, however, the court applied the public trust doctrine (one year after the California Audubon case) to broadly extend the right of access and use to most water in the state, previously navigable or not, even if the streambed and banks were privately owned. 19 The court argued that because Montana’s Constitution specified that “The use of all water…shall be held to be a public use” and that “All surface, underground, flood, and atmospheric waters within the boundaries of the state are the property of the state for use of the people,” the public trust doctrine prohibited the state from granting exclusive property rights to landowners that would violate the state’s trust responsibilities to retain ownership for its citizens. The ruling potentially opened all streams to recreational access between high-water marks.23 To implement the court’s ruling, in 1985 the Montana Legislature passed a broad Steam Access Law. Unresolved by the court or the legislature were where and how the public could obtain access and importantly, whether waterways created and enhanced through private reclamation were to be held open to the public. To implement the new stream access law, the Montana Department of Fish Wildlife and Parks provided written guidance for recreationists and landowners.24 The agency stated that the public may gain access to streams capable of recreational use, regardless of streambed ownership, through public road rights-of-way at bridge crossings. Recreationists can use rivers and streams up to the ordinary high-water mark. It divided state waters into Class I and Class II categories to outline conditions for use and to specify when permission was required from adjacent landowners. Smaller, Class II streams were placed under somewhat more restricted access. Even so, the agency promoted “reasonable” open access for the public to the state’s streams and rivers. The potential dampening effects on private incentives to invest in habitat and overall stewardship, as well as the weakening of overall private property rights to land seem straightforward. An essential characteristic of a property right is the right to 20 exclude, and as this authority is diminished through public trust requirements, the strength of the property right is diminished. Rather than to be able to privately determine where, when, and whom can enter upon their properties to fish or hunt, landowner decisions are constrained by the Department of Fish, Wildlife and Parks’ rules on access and the courtesies (“respect landowner property”) the agency emphasizes to minimize conflict. It is doubtful that these admonishments will be very effective in protecting private property as use increases. Norms and customs can be successful in constraining behavior when group size is small, homogeneous, and subject to peer monitoring, but they break down as populations become larger and more heterogeneous (Ostrom, 1990). As more and more recreationists demand access across private property for fishing and hunting, the strength of these rules is likely to decline, and conflict over access and land use is apt to increase. If extensive, this conflict could weaken property rights and land values with unanticipated spill over effects. Because landownership is a primary source of wealth in western states such as Montana, any regulatory action that potentially lowers land values could have a dampening impact on overall wealth and well-being within the state, reducing commercial activity and employment. It is unclear how extensive these effects might be, but they should be considered in demands to broaden stream and wildlife access. The political debate over access to fish and wildlife is an emotional one. It hinges on distribution of the flow of fishing and hunting opportunities and ignores the long-term impact on the wildlife stock. For example, an editorial in the Bozeman Daily Chronicle, April 23, 2006 illustrates the focus on immediate access and not on more far-reaching 21 stock effects. The editorial criticized a proposed $.25 fee considered by the Department of Fish, Wildlife and Parks to be added to fishing licenses to compensate landowners for allowing public access to streams at bridges on public roads that cross private property. The fee was considered following the state attorney general’s opinion that such access was required under state law. The attorney general’s opinion stemmed from a dispute over the use of electric fences and no trespassing signs on bridge rights-of-way by landowners who claimed they were necessary to keep livestock off roadways. The fences, however, cut off access for fishermen. The $.25 fee was designed to create a fund to pay landowners to install gates that would allow access to the stream or river. While landowners may have multiple reasons for such fences, including controlling entry upon their properties, the need to control the movement of livestock is a real one. Paying for gates recognizes their property rights to land and introduces negotiation in the stream access controversy rather than pure reliance upon the police power of the state. Nevertheless, the editorial dammed the fee and efforts to force fishermen to pay “for access to what is legally theirs to use. Gates through fences at bridges should be installed at the cost of the landowner who is illegally denying public access.” The editorial concluded that game wardens should issue citations to landowners who violate the state’s steam access law and set a dangerous precedent of “conceding rights to the landowners that are not theirs.”25 Instead of seeing the merits of enlisting the stewardship of landowners in protecting aquatic habitat and the stock, the populist distributional conflict emphasized in the editorial sets landowners and fishermen as competitors for the value of the land and the fishery, rather than collaborators in enhancing both. As argued above, competition instills a “tragedy of the commons” potential as each party takes 22 action that dissipates the rental value of the resource, whereas collaboration makes them joint parties in investing in resource stocks. Consider what landowners could do voluntarily and routinely, when their property rights are recognized and respected. During times of drought or dry periods at the end of summer and early fall when fish stocks are under stress from warm water temperatures and low stream level, landowners can release some irrigation water to the stream, mitigating these fish-threatening conditions. Landowners will have incentive to do this if they view aquatic habitat and the fishery as part of the overall value of their property, not as a competitor to it. The ability to limit access in some manner to protect livestock, fences, pastures, and crops contributes to this outcome. The ability to directly capture some of the benefits of enhanced fishing through sale of access privileges contributes even more. Landowners would not have to restrict all access in all parts of the streams crossing their properties for this beneficial effect to occur. There could be negotiated solutions whereby certain areas were open to all, while others had more limited access, subject to landowner discretion. Everyone, fishermen and landowners alike would benefit from conservation and investment in the fish stock. A larger, more vibrant and healthy stock of fish means more fish for all, even if access to some of the stock required payment of a fee. Landowners are particularly essential for such stewardship because they are more likely to be on site to monitor stream and stock conditions, whereas fishermen (or state fish and game officials) are more likely to be transient, with higher monitoring and investment costs. And under open access conditions, they are not the residual claimants to such actions. Similarly, if landowners invested in repairing the riparian and aquatic 23 habitat of a man-made waterway, such as an old irrigation or drainage ditch, to make it a fishery, the stock of fish is enhanced. But there are disputes as to whether or not a waterway is truly man-made. In the recent Mitchell Slough case in Bitterroot County, for example, on-going litigation hinges on whether the Mitchell Slough was a natural stream (part of the Bitterroot River) or a ditch. Landowners along the slough cleaned and improved its habitat for fishing and hunting. They sought to have it listed as a ditch so as to restrict entry and avoid open access under the 1985 Montana Stream Access Statute. Not incidentally, many of the landowners are wealthy and from out-of-state. Various sports groups, including the Bitterroot River Protection Association and the Montana Fish, Wildlife and Parks Department challenged the designation. In 2006, a District Judge ruled that Mitchell Slough was a ditch and not subject to public access. But the State agency is appealing the ruling to the Montana Supreme Court. There are similar political pressures to mandate public access on private lands for hunting. Just as water was held in trust by the state of Montana for its citizens so that access could not be denied even if it flowed across private property, wildlife was owned by the state for its citizens. Therefore, they too could not be denied access even when wildlife moved across private property.26 But if landowners cannot control entry for hunting and benefit in some manner from investing in wildlife habitat (such as leaving some wheat unharvested for pheasants and turkeys, or brush uncleared for deer), perhaps through marketing a certain number of game licenses as is possible in Colorado, they have less incentive to engage in these beneficial actions. Even if the Montana Legislature were to grant such marketing opportunities to landowners who invested in wildlife habitat, however, an expanded view of the public 24 trust doctrine could allow the courts to invalidate the law and any landowner investments would be lost without compensation. Hence, the uncertainty of any commercial right authorized by statute due to the public trust doctrine would reduce its value and potential to improve wildlife stocks. VIII. Concluding remarks: Implications of the spread of the Public Trust. In 1989 Joseph Sax (1989, 483), the major legal scholar on the public trust, wrote: “The new era is one of reallocation. The direction is changing from agriculture to urban uses and in-stream flows for water quality, recreation, and ecosystem protection…No private property claims are going to halt this transformation.” The message of this paper agrees with Sax’s assessment of water re-allocation pressures. It disagrees, however, with his conclusion that private property rights are an obstacle to this process. Instead, the message is that private property rights and water markets can be an extremely effective vehicle for promoting smooth, low-cost, and uncontentious water transfers to meet new recreational and environmental demands. The public trust doctrine, by contrast, in weakening property rights and in calling for a more expansive role of the state in water investment and distribution, is more likely to slow the transformation Sax refers to, make it more costly and less complete. Advocates of the public trust doctrine stress re-allocation and access to the flow of recreational and environmental services. As noted above, they fail to see the implications of their demands for maintenance and investment in the stock. By stressing the publicness of fish and wildlife resources, the public trust doctrine insures access to existing resources, while reducing private incentives to invest in them. It may be that the 25 state could invest to supplement private investment and stewardship. But the record with other natural resources—public timberlands and public rangelands does not bring much confidence. And with a lack of controls on access, excessive use and dissipation are likely. Accordingly, to meet the growing demands for water re-allocation, the most effective response is not expansion of the public trust doctrine, but rather greater emphasis on private water rights and markets to insure enhanced supplies of high-quality waterways and aquatic and riparian habitat. 26 References Anderson, Terry and Ronald N. Johnson (1986), “The Problem of Instream Flows,” Economic Inquiry 24 (4): 535-53. Blumm, Michael C. and Thea Schwartz (1995), “Mono Lake and the Evolving Public Trust in Western Water,” Arizona Law Review, 37: 701-38. Brewer, Jedidiah and Gary D. Libecap, 2006, “The Economic Costs of the Public Trust Doctrine: Implications for Settlement and Trial,” working paper, Bren School of Environmental Science and Management, University of California, Santa Barbara. Brewer, Jedidiah, Robert Glennon, Alan Ker, and Gary Libecap, (2006), “Water Markets: Western Water Transfers from Agriculture to Urban Uses, 1987-2005,” Economic Inquiry, forthcoming. Getches, David H. (1997), Water Law in a Nut Shell, St. Paul, West Publishing Co. Glennon, Robert Jerome (2005), “Water Scarcity, Marketing, and Privatization,” Texas Law Review, 83(7): 1873-1902. Glennon, Robert Jerome, Alan Ker, and Gary D. Libecap (2006), Western Water Data Set, Bren School of Environmental Science and Management, UCSB. Gordon, H. Scott, (1954), “The Economic Theory of A Common-property Resource: The Fishery,” Journal of Political Economy 62(2): 124–142. Griffin, Ronald C. and Fred O. Boadu (1992), “Water Marketing in Texas: Opportunities for Reform,” Natural Resources Journal, 32 (1992): 265-88. Hardin, Garrett, (1968), “The Tragedy of the Commons,” Science 162: 1243-8. Hart, John (1996), Storm Over Mono: The Mono Lake Battle and the California Water Future, Berkeley: University of California Press. Johnson, Ronald N., Micha Gisser, and Michael Werner, (1981), “The Definition of a Surface Water Right and Transferability,” Journal of Law and Economics 24 (2): 273-88. Landry, Clay J., (1998), Saving Our Streams Through Water Markets, Bozeman, Montana: PERC. Leal, Donald R., 2005, Evolving Property Rights in Marine Fisheries, Lanham: Md.: Rowman and Littlefield. 27 Libecap, Gary D. (2005), Rescuing Water Markets: Lessons from Owens Valley, PERC Policy Series, PS-33, Bozeman: Property and Environment Research Center. Libecap, Gary D., 2006, “Refilling Mono Lake: Why the Public Trust Doctrine Weakens Property Rights And Is Bad for the Environment,” Hoover Digest Libecap, Gary D., 2007, “Chinatown:” Owens Valley and Its Meaning for Western Water Today, forthcoming Stanford University Press. Meyers, Gary D. (1989), “Variation on a Theme: Expanding the Public Trust Doctrine to Include Protection of Wildlife,” Environmental Law 19: 723-35. Montana Department of Fish, Wildlife, and Parks, 2000, Stream Access in Montana: Rights and Responsibilities of Landowners and Recreationists, Helena. Newman, Janet C., 2004, “The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly: The First Ten Years of the Oregon Water Trust,” Nebraska Law Review, 433-46. Ostrom, Elinor, (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sax, Joseph, (1970), “The Public Trust Doctrine in Natural Resource Law: Effective Judicial Intervention,” Michigan Law Review 68: 471-566. Sax, Joseph, (1989), “The Limits of Private Rights in Public Waters,” Environmental Law, 19: 473-83. Sax, Joseph L. (1990), “The Constitution, Property Rights and the Future of Water Law,” University of Colorado Law Review 61: 257-82. Simms, Richard A. (1995), “A Sketch of the Aimless Jurisprudence of Western Water Law,” in Kathleen Marion Carr and James D. Crammond, eds., Water Law: Trends, Policies, and Practice, Chicago: American Bar Association, 320-29. Stavins, Robert N., (2003), “Market-Based Environmental Policies: What Can We Learn from U.S. Experience (and Related Research)?” Workshop, August 23-24, Donald Bren School of Environmental Science and Management, University of California, Santa Barbara. 28 1 Glennon ( 2005,1883-85). Hardin (1968), Gordon (1954). 3 See Stavins (2003) for discussion of the movement toward market-based instruments. 4 Brewer and Libecap (2006) model and test these hypotheses. 5 Texas, New Mexico, Arizona, California, Nevada, Oregon, Washington, Idaho, Montana, Wyoming, Utah, Colorado. Data collection procedures are described in Brewer, Glennon, Ker, and Libecap (2006). 6 Getches (1997, 74-189). 7 Anderson and Johnson (1986) and Johnson, et al (1981). 8 Getches (1997, 98-146), Simms (1995, 323). 9 Landry (1998), Newman (2004), Water Strategist, selected issues, “Transactions Summaries.” 10 Getches (1997, 217, 224-8). The discussion below borrows from Libecap (2006, Chapters 7 and 8). 11 National Audubon Society v. Superior Court, 685 P.2d. 712. 12 See Blumm and Schwartz (1995). See also, Sax (1990, 270) for discussion of subsequent cases in California that expanded the public trust doctrine. See also Gray (1994, 262-69). For public trust application to wildlife, see Meyers (1989). 13 Simms (1995, 321). 14 Sax (1990, 264, 269). 15 Shokal v. Dunn, 109 Idaho 330, 707 P.2d 441, 1985; Mineral County v. State of Nevada, 117 Nev 235, 20 P.3d. 800, 2001; Golden Feather Community Ass’n v. Termalito Irrigation District, 199 Cal. App. 3rd 402, 244 Cal Rptr. 830, 1988. 16 Sax (1990, 277). 17 Stavins (2003), Leal (2005). The following discussion of the public trust doctrine and the Mono Lake case builds on Libecap (2007), Chapter 8 and Libecap (2006). 18 Audubon Society v. Superior Court 33 Cal 3d 444. 19 Audubon Society v. Superior Court 33 Cal 3d 440. 20 These issues are explored more formally in Brewer and Libecap (2006). 21 Ryan v. Harrison & Harrison Farms L.L.L.P. 306 Mont. 534, 200, WL 828068 (Mont.), 2001 MT 128N. 22 Herrin v. Sutherland 241 P.328 (S.Ct. Mont., 1928), held that if navigable in fact, navigable in law and pubic can use the stream because the streambed is not privately owned. 23 Montana Coalition for Stream Access v. Hildreth, 648 P.2d. 1088 (S.Ct. Mont.1984) Hildreth had erected fence across Beaverhead River restricting navigation, but the court ruled that because the Montana Constitution asserts that the state owns the waters for the peoples’ benefit, they may use a waterway for recreation purposes if the waterway is capable of supporting that use. A commercial test was not required. Title to the stream bed was irrelevant in determining navigability. 24 Montana Department of Fish, Wildlife and Parks, Stream Access 2000. 25 Bozeman Daily Chronicle, “Angler fee puts access cost on the wrong party,” Sunday April 23, 2006. 26 Meyers (1989). 2 29