The Irish Economy: Recent Growth, European Integration and Future Prospects Dermot McAleese Address at the Centro Informação Europeia Jacques Delors, Lisbon, Friday 12 October 2001 The author is Whately Professor of Political Economy and Dean of the Faculty of Business, Economic and Social Sciences, Trinity College, Dublin INTRODUCTION Writing a decade ago on Ireland's dismal economic performance, an eminent Irish historian concluded that no other European country, east or west, north or south, has recorded so slow a rate of growth of national income in the twentieth century. Professor Lee's analysis of Ireland's economic ills had a time frame that lasted from Independence in 1922 to 1985. During that period, national income per head had grown by an average 1.8% per year, about the same as the UK, but well below the growth rate experienced in continental Europe. Membership of the European Community was generally seen as having been helpful, but there was little sign of the catch up on European incomes that had been hoped for at the time of accession. Ireland’s GDP per head languished at under two-thirds of the EC average in 1985, up only slightly from 59% in 1973. During the past decade, a profound change in economic performance has occurred. The Irish economy has been transformed from the lame duck economy depicted in Lee's book Ireland 1922-1985 (Cambridge University Press, 1989) to a shining exemplar of the 1990s. In 1994, its performance was likened by a Morgan Stanley economist in London to that of the Asian Tiger economies; whence the birth of the Celtic Tiger. Since 1994, Ireland’s GNP has grown at an unprecedented 8.6% per year. An amazing turnaround was how the OECD described it. The turnaround confounded the best forecasters, native and foreign. In the early 1990s a growth rate of 3% would have seemed highly satisfactory. Estimates of potential growth rates using standard estimation techniques have been at least 3 to 4 percentage points below the growth rate actually achieved (with substantial price stability) for the past decade. Economic success arouses curiosity and demands explanation. The list of publications on the Irish growth experience continues to lengthen. The Irish economy became the equivalent of a Hollywood starlet, with all the wondrous benefits and dangers of that position. Its example has been frequently cited in the international literature. Ireland is among a very select number of comparators in the IMF’s latest (November 2000) Country Report on Portugal; and an insightful analysis of Ireland’s growth experience by Dr 1 Miguel de Freitas is included in a recent edition of the Bank of Portugal’s Economic Bulletin. Why this interest in such a small and relatively insignificant economy? One reason is that Ireland’s experience constitutes a dramatic instance of convergence and catch up in the context of European integration. The poor do not always have to get poorer. A second reason is that the upsurge in growth was accompanied by a sharp shift in economic policy orientation based on three pillars: a) increased reliance on the market system and competition, b) macroeconomic stability and c) globalisation and integration. This coincidence seems like a striking vindication of the new consensus economic policies that have swept through the world during the past two decades. Hence, as a case study, Ireland has appeal for a wide range of specialists: regional economists, core-periphery theorists and policy analysts. This paper is divided into three sections. The first section comments on some key features of the growth process. The second section examines the extent to which membership of the EU contributed to this growth. Third, we comment the implications for Ireland of a) the change in status from below average to above average income, b) the advent of the euro, c) the increasingly active role of Union institutions in fiscal policy and d) Enlargement and the Nice Referendum. Fourth, we briefly examine the effects on the Irish economy of the global economic downturn, and the worsening outlook following the attack on the US on 11 September and the subsequent military action in Afghanistan. CHARACTERISTICS OF IRISH GROWTH Initially many economists thought the post 1993 growth rates were a statistical illusion. There was talk of a soufflé economy, the product of transfer-pricing-inflated multinational profits in high tech sectors rather than ‘real’ bread and butter economic activity. Suspicions were strengthened by the slow reaction of employment to growth – ‘jobless growth’ was another favourite description of the early process. 2 As tax revenues started to boom, these doubts evaporated. The government budget deficit of 13% in 1987 was steadily transformed into an eventual budget surplus of 4% in 2000. The debt/GDP ratio, which had exceeded 120% in the late 1980s, declined to 47% in 2000 and is expected to decline further to 34% by end 2001.1 Moreover, growth eventually did generate jobs, albeit after a certain time lag. Numbers employed rose by 600,000 between 1992 and 2001, a rise of over 50%. This huge expansion in job opportunities had three far reaching repercussions on the labour market and on Irish society: a) unemployment fell from 16% to 3.6%, b) female labour participation rose dramatically and c) Ireland changed from being a country of net emigration to one of net immigration. Ireland: Real Annual Average Growth Rates GDP GDP per capita Employment GDP per worker 1960-80 4.1 3.1 0.5 3.5 1980-93 3.3 2.9 0.0 3.3 1993-2000 8.3 7.4 4.7 3.5 Thus, from being one of Europe’s poorest countries in 1973, Irish GDP per capita at PPP surpassed the UK level in 1996 and the EU average shortly afterwards. By 2000, Ireland’s GDP per person had reached 119% of the EU average, compared with 59% when Ireland joined the then Common Market in 1973.2 The impact of growth on living standards was magnified by the accompanying fall in the dependency ratio. Whereas in 1 An indicator of the extent of the fiscal transformation is the recent award of an AAA rating from Standard & Poors. The S&P rating, which takes account of the world economic downturn, commends the government’s commitment to fiscal prudence, and describes Ireland as an increasingly diverse and resilient economy (Irish Times, 4 October 2001). 2 The extent of catch up in terms of GNP per person is less impressive. Because of large net dividend and royalty payments abroad by foreign (mostly US) multinationals established in Ireland, there is a 15 percentage-point gap between Ireland’s GDP and GNP. 3 1990, every 10 people at work had 21 dependants to support, a decade later the figure has fallen to 14 (and it will decline further to 12 in the year 2006). A crucial feature of the Irish experience has been the expansion of employment. From 1993 to 2000, employment increased by 4.7% per year. This compared with a situation of zero increase for the previous three decades. With astonishing rapidity, Ireland was transformed from a labour abundant economy with a chronic shortage of job opportunities to a situation of full employment and labour scarcity. As employment grew, many low productivity workers, who were previously either unemployed or considered unemployable, were drawn into the labour market. In these circumstances, a sharp fall in labour productivity growth might have been expected. Most of the additional employment was generated in the services sector where productivity growth has always tended to be lowest and this would be further reason for anticipating a weakening productivity performance. In fact, no such decline occurred. GDP per worker grew by 3.5% per annum 1993-2000 compared with 3.3% 1980-94. Disaggregated figures suggest that this can be explained by a rise in productivity in the services sector from 0.8% to 1.6% between the two periods. The combined force of rising employment and maintained productivity growth ensured a major acceleration in the rise in living standards. De Freitas (2000) draws attention to one further twist in the productivity story. Total output growth is determined by growth of inputs such as labour and capital, and also by improvements in the way these inputs are deployed. This is called total factor productivity or the Solow residual. The Solow residual rose significantly during the boom years. Kennedy estimates this as rising from 2.3% in 1980-93 to 3.6% per annum 1993-2000. These figures are consistent with de Freitas’ estimates for the shorter period to 1998. This growth in TFP is highly significant in so far as it relates to the influence of improved economic policies and stronger integration within Europe (see below). 4 Another remarkable feature of the decade has been the decline in labour’s share of total value added. It fell from 57% at the start of the decade to 50% in 2000. The corollary is a significant increase in the share of corporate profits and earnings of the self-employed. Kennedy estimates an increase in the share of profits in industry’s net domestic product from 47% in 1993 to 58% in 2000 and a rise from 25% to 38% in the services sector during this period. This radical factor income shift from labour to capital needs careful interpretation. (Lane 1998). It is not due to increased capital intensity of production. The exceptional profitability of multinational subsidiaries has certainly had an impact. There is abundant evidence of a quantum leap in profitability, which took place against a background of pay restraint across the economy. Pay restraint was organised through Social Partnership. Ireland adopted a unique model of wage determination, involving extensive consultation and agreement between the social partners. The key element was: wage restraint in return for income tax cuts and ongoing participation in economic decision making through social partnership committees. This policy is not favoured by economic orthodoxy but it has produced tangible benefits for Irish employees and employers alike. Business received a boost to profits, and employees got more jobs and better pay. Compensation per employee in the business sector rose by 43% since 1993, compared with a cumulative consumer price increase of 25%. National pay agreements kept the lid on pay claims during a period of unprecedented output growth and thus enabled this growth to translate into higher employment and lower unemployment. Reductions in income tax meant that take home pay increases substantially exceeded nominal pay increases.3 THE EFFECTS OF EUROPEAN INTEGRATION It is sometimes said that economists have been unable to explain the causes of Ireland’s boom. This is only partly true. There is general agreement on the list of factors that contributed to growth and that these contributory factors interacted positively with each 5 other -- in a Myrdalian process of cumulative and circular causation. The main subject of contention concerns the weight to be attached to the different causal factors. Thus while the OECD stresses foreign investment and Ireland’s education policy, others emphasise the role of macroeconomic policy and the introduction of competition and lower taxes. Another view stresses the role of Ireland’s social consensus model of wage determination and policy formation. De Freitas considers the boom as the result of transient, self-limiting factors and long run factors. Thus transient factors such as the decline in unemployment and the rise in female labour participation made a big impact on growth, but they can be sustained only up to the point. After this point (full employment for instance), further improvement of living standards requires growth in long run productivity. It will be some time before there will be sufficient data to determine which of these various interpretations carries most weight. What part did membership of the European Union play in delivering faster growth to Ireland? This is a question of enduring interest to all countries and regions with living standards below the EU average, and especially to the 12 new applicants. In Ireland, this has been a comparatively neglected topic to date, but in the light of the NO vote in the Nice Referendum and the Commission’s reprimand of the Irish government’s handling of fiscal policy earlier this year, now might be a timely occasion to consider this issue. In principle, economic integration can affect economic growth in several ways. First, it ensures access to other members’ markets, an important advantage to countries with a competitive cost structure. Integration also enhances the attraction of a lower cost country to foreign investors. Second, membership provides access to financial assistance of various sorts from the centre to the less prosperous member states. Third, new members operate in the context of an agreed institutional framework and policy guidelines. Fourth, membership can help growth by moderating extreme nationalist sentiments and subsuming them in a broader “European” context. Each of these issues will now be considered in turn. 3 The radical left interprets things differently; labour in their view was denied its proper participation in the 6 a) Trade and Foreign Direct Investment Export growth contributed significantly to overall growth, as one would expect in a highly open economy like Ireland’s. Export volume increased by 16.5% per annum 19932000 compared with 9.2% 1980-93. The contribution of total net exports to real GDP growth averaged 3.8% p.a. 1991-99 compared with 1.4% in the previous decade (Arora and Vamvakidis 2001). The EU economy was in the doldrums for most of the 1990s, so there was limited direct stimulus from that source that differed from earlier periods. OECD market share statistics indicated that Irish export growth owes slightly more to increased market share, both in Europe and in the US, than to market growth. The performance of the US economy proved to be of crucial importance. During the 1990s, American corporations enjoyed exceptional levels of profitability and as a result were ready to invest abroad. The level of US FDI flows into Ireland increased significantly during the 1990s. Ireland’s share of US FDI within the EU doubled, from 3% to 7%. This FDI was concentrated on fast growing high tech industries with a predominantly export orientation. For these industries, the single market reforms were of crucial importance and came just at the right time. Ireland’s favourable regime of corporate profits taxation (CPT) was an additional investment incentive. This took the form of a preferential tax rate of 10% on all corporate profits earned in manufacturing and traded services industry. In 1998, under pressure from the European Commission, a new CPT regime was negotiated. The CPT rate was raised to 12.5%, applicable to all sectors, effective from 2003. The 10% rate was ‘grandparented’ up to 2010 for companies already enjoying this preference. In addition to tax incentives, financial grants are offered to new enterprises in respect of capital spending, R&D and labour training, but these were being pared back during the 1990s. The European Commission showed considerable flexibility and helpfulness to Celtic Tiger’s success.(see Allen 2000). 7 Ireland in these negotiations. Also, the Commission’s restrictions on state aids in the more developed regions were necessary in order to make the Irish incentives effective. The more developed member states would have been willing to match Irish incentives had the Commission not prevented it and the inward investment boom would have been halted in its tracks. EU membership was also important to the development of the International Financial Services Centre (IFSC) in Dublin. Contacts developed through EU institutions helped to get the project started, and the common institutional framework within the EU made Dublin a credible alternative to other financial centres (White, 2000). With over 8,000 people now at work in IFSC activities (strictly defined), the IFSC has turned out to be an important employer and a source of significant tax revenue.4 In 2000, tax revenues were estimated at £500 million or 0.5% of GDP. FDI is important in explaining the Irish catch-up but it is not the whole story, no more than FDI is just a tax incentives story. American subsidiaries accounted for only about 10% of the total economy-wide increase in employment since 1989. Even if each of these jobs generated a multiplier effect of one further job elsewhere in the economy (as is often assumed), this still leaves 80% of the employment growth unexplained. Besides the FDI programmes had been operating successfully through much of the previous decades in terms of attracting new industries to Ireland. As was often pointed out at the time, there were no comparable successes in the domestic economy. During the 1990s something dramatic was going on in the services sector, where 80% of the new jobs were being generated, and in the entrepreneurial climate in the domestic economy generally. Without explanation of what that something was, no account of the Celtic Tiger can be complete. b) Financial Assistance 4 Certification of new activities at the IFSC ceased in 1999, but growth in existing activities has continued to increase. Employment grew by over 1,400 jobs in 2000. The 8,000 figure refers to end 2000. IDA Annual Report 2000 8 Integration agreements usually include provision for economic and technical co-operation and modest financial transfers from the richer to the poorer members. The amount of transfers provided by various EU development and convergence programmes over time has been quite exceptional. While modest amounts of aid had been disbursed through the ERDF and the ESF since the early 1970s, a major stimulus came with the launch of the Structural Funds programme in 1989.5 These programmes were set up as "regional counterbalancing" measures, designed to avoid any widening in regional inequalities, especially in regions where innovative sectors were absent and scope for exploiting economies of scale limited. Irish Receipts from the European Union 1975-2000 1975 1986 1991 1997 2000 GROSS RECEIPTS 109 1147 2201 2504 2049 PAYMENTS TO EU BUDGET 10 240 348 514 847 NET EU RECEIPTS 99 907 1853 1990 1202 (% GNP) 2.9 5.9 7.6 4.8 1.8 IR£m current prices Source: Department of Finance, own estimates, figures for 2000 are provisional During the decade 1989-99, Ireland's structural fund receipts have averaged about 2.6% of GNP per annum. This scale of assistance can be compared with aid flows to middle income developing countries of 1% of GNP (World Bank estimates). Aid to populous poor countries such as India and China amounts to even less than this. 5 Structural Funds include the European Regional Development Fund (ERDF), European Social Fund (ESF) and the Guidance Section of the Agricultural Fund (FEOGA). I also include Cohesion Funds. Barry (1999) summarises these estimates with the conclusion that Structural Funds contributed only half of one percentage point of the per annum growth of GNP during the 1990s, leading to a rise in GNP of 4 percentage points above what it would have been.. 9 Although many continental Europeans firmly believe that Ireland has grown rich on the back of the European taxpayer, the actual impact of the Structural Funds seems to be considerably smaller than one would expect. Simulations by Bradley (1992) suggest that Ireland's GNP would be 2.7 percentage points (and GNP per head only 0.8 percentage points) higher by the year 2000 as result of the 1989-93 programme. Later, using a similar methodology based on a large macro model, Honohan (1997) estimated that the combined impact of the two EU structural aid programmes spanning the decade up to 1999 would add only 2 percentage points to GNP in the long run.6 Perhaps some specific areas of spending failed to yield the return they should have. Tansey, for example, argues that while structural funds from 1989 greatly increased participant numbers on active labour market programmes, "the evidence that they have significantly improved the national training effort is at best mixed" (Tansey 1998 p. 133). On the other hand, the Structural Funds programmes boosted confidence and enhanced the acceptability of many of the EU 'level playing field' initiatives that might otherwise have been considered unacceptable. Also the obligation to account to Brussels for the spending of the funds has led to considerable improvements in the way public sector investment is planned and monitored. The adoption of multi-annual programming encouraged national authorities to think beyond the single year planning horizon. As Alan Gray observed, the contribution of the European Commission in influencing Irish planning and evaluation methods "deserves more than a footnote in Irish economic history" (Gray 1998 p 52). The structural funds framework also led to greater coordination in activities co-financed by the Community. Cynics will say that it was all done merely in order to obtain the EU money, and in part they are right. But mind-sets have also changed - for the better. c) Policy guidelines EU economic policy helped the Irish economy in two main ways. First, EU competition and regulation policy helped the Irish government to open up the financial, transport and 6 The finding of only a slight macro-impact is consistent with the economic aid literature (World Bank 10 public utility sectors to competition. Opening up these sectors made the Irish economy more cost competitive and helped to generate job opportunities directly and indirectly (tourism for instance was a major beneficiary of lower air fares). Competition policy had a profound effect in stimulating economic activity in the services sector. For a long time, this sector was comparatively neglected in the mistaken belief that ‘real’ growth happened only in manufacturing, and that if it grew rapidly, employment in services would automatically follow. The threat of competition restrained unions in public utilities with consequent reduced costs of key inputs to business. Second, the Maastricht criteria set down objectives that countries would have to attain in order to qualify for admission to the common currency area and, in so doing, established the parameters for Irish fiscal policy from the late 1980s onwards. The need for a changed policy orientation had been signalled in a report of the National Economic and Social Council in 1986 but the specific targets of Maastricht helped to legitimise and reinforce the process. Reducing debt/GDP ratio to a sustainable level became a priority objective of macro policy. The decision was made to focus attack on controlling public spending and to use whatever leeway emerged to reduce taxes. For a small open economy, curbing public spending proved a productive way forward. It created room for tax cuts while simultaneously lowering the debt ratio. Coming in the wake of penal income tax rates and widespread tax evasion, two tax amnesties, involving legalisation of income and exemption of tax penalties on declared income, were hugely successful revenue earners. Domestic interest rates fell steeply and investor confidence strengthened. In the debate about expansionary fiscal contraction, the importance of investment demand tends to be overlooked. A final item in the macroeconomic ‘story’: lower taxes and a more stable macro background translated into a boom in the private sector. As noted earlier, virtually all of the increase in employment since 1993 was generated by the private sector, and two thirds of this was in marketed services. Lower taxes and confidence in the fiscal integrity of the government were key elements in this process. 1998). 11 Change in fiscal policy in the late 1980s was a critical element in Ireland’s subsequent economic success. It triggered economic growth by a) providing a firm underpinning to Ireland’s low tax regime, b) improving business and consumer confidence and c) ensuring cost competitiveness. Some of the impetus for change stemmed from internal factors but the backdrop of support from Europe made a key difference. The Maastricht fiscal criteria -- in particular the 3% budget deficit/GDP and 60% debt/GDP ratio limits – were the driving force of fiscal policy and gave vital focus to it. The new fiscal parameters coincided exactly with what the Irish economy needed at the time.7 d) Northern Ireland Northern Ireland is rarely mentioned in the context of the Republic’s boom. Yet the peace process, which began in 1994, helped to sustain the boom by giving Ireland a better image abroad and by enabling government to shift focus from security matters to economic development. Meetings of EC committees and council gave frequent opportunities for ministers of the UK and Irish governments to meet and discuss Northern Ireland in an informal way. While it is often asserted that membership allowed Ireland to step out of the shadow of British influence and to play a distinct role on a larger world stage, far more important was the concept of a common European citizenship weaning nationalists in particular away from excessive preoccupation with irredentist ambitions. So far the emphasis has been on the positive impact of Europe on the Irish economy. A recurrent theme of debate has been the possibility of integration membership leading to cumulative economic decline. Drawing on the core-periphery school, the case was made that integration would exacerbate regional disparities. An Irish MEP argued that, following the implementation of the Single Market, the poorer regions of Europe could face collapse in the near future without continuous large scale transfers of funds from 7 Honohan (2001) argues the contrary on the basis that the deficit had been reduced considerably by 1989, ahead of the ratification of the Maastricht Treaty. I would counter-argue first that the end 1980s figures were favoured by the once-off effect of the tax amnesty and second that the Maastricht criteria were crucially helpful in gaining public acceptance of the 3% target as a valid national objective, not just a bookkeeping exercise. 12 strong regions to weak (O'Malley 1988 p 10). This outcome would be brought about because economies of scale would favour big firms in the large member states, and because poorer regions would bear the brunt of adjustment costs following the liberalisation of EC trade with third world countries. The Community’s labour market policies were another source of concern. unemployment and low employment growth. These have been associated with high As labour market inflexibilities were imposed on Ireland by EU social legislation, some feared that the unemployment problem would worsen. While, the above arguments have been vigorously debated over the past 25 years, with hindsight, we see that convergence, not divergence, has been the outcome of integration. Specialisation has led more to higher incomes than to greater vulnerability. The wage gap between white-collar and blue-collar employees has widened, but the relationship between the wage gap and Ireland's imports from developing countries seems to have been statistically insignificant (Figini and Görg 1998). The evidence suggests that Ireland’s poor economic performance in the past originated as much in bad policy as in objective external events. High taxes, high labour costs, excessive regulation and anti-competitive practices would be prime culprits. These defects inhibited development in the potentially most employment-intensive sector of the economy, the services sector. It is easy to forget how effectively the fiscal stabilisation package dealt with these structural defects. Incomes policy, tax reductions, improved competitiveness and spending cutbacks were part of a coherent policy initiative. The introduction of new de-regulation and competition policies was also important. European integration generated forces that in various ways directed the Irish economy onto a superior growth trajectory. 13 NEW CHALLENGES Long before 11 September, the consensus view in Ireland was that the economy would not be able to sustain the Celtic Tiger growth rates much longer. The second annual update of Ireland’s Stability Programme, published in December 2000, projected a fall in real GNP growth rates from 8.6% in 2000 to 5% in 2002 and to just 2% from 2015 onwards. As Ireland reaches European living standards, high GDP growth will be less needed and, as it happens, less attainable. The focus of policy should be on securing sustainable growth rather than maximum growth, and on ensuring a soft landing to these lower growth rates. Both the economic success of the recent past and the future trajectory of the economy have implications for Ireland’s evolving relations with Europe. We comment on some of them below. a) The EU Budget: from Beneficiary to Donor Ireland's status as a large net recipient of EU funds is now in process of rapid transformation. As GNP increases, Ireland's annual contribution to the EU also rises. It has increased from £283 million in 1990 to an estimated £847 million in 2000. In future, CAP funding for Irish agriculture is likely to be increasingly restrained. As Table 2 above shows, these have comprised around half of Ireland’s gross receipts from the EU for many years. Even more significant, structural fund inflows will diminish. Net receipts from the EU are projected to fall by half over the next few years, from £1,910 m in 1999 to £827million in 2006. The change in status to a net contributor, while entirely a welcome development, will no doubt have a profound impact on how the Irish see themselves and on how they view the EU. b) Advent of the euro area (without the UK) While the process of attaining eligibility for EMU has proved highly beneficial for the economy, membership of the euro area will bring new challenges to the economy. 14 The standard benefits of a single currency apply with particular force to an open economy such as Ireland. There will be a saving in transactions costs (a small gain), and increased price transparency (possibly much larger gain). The elimination of exchange rate risk vis a vis the euro area is expected to reduce Irish interest rates by somewhere between 1 and 2 percentage points over the long run. This will stimulate investment and generate faster growth (Baker et al 1996, De Buitleir et al 1995). Against this there are drawbacks.8 Irish firms will be vulnerable to changes in sterling and the dollar, more so than other euro area countries since the proportion of total trade with the euro area is the lowest of all members (30%) and fluctuations of output have been very weakly correlated with other members also. Irish business was badly scarred by the rise in the Irish pound relative to sterling during the 1992-93 currency crisis. Similar unwarranted revaluations in an euro context will create adjustment problems but they at least will not be accompanied by the short run interest rate hikes to defend the currency that wreaked havoc in past currency crises. Another problem is that the European Central Bank’s monetary policy has to be determined by the needs of the euro area, not those of the Irish economy. However, all members of the euro area are in the same position in this respect. The argument that Ireland is especially vulnerable because of its weak degree of synchronisation with core euro area economies may also have to be revised in the light of recent history.9 The business cycle has become dramatically more synchronised worldwide than in the past. Is there any European country in October 2001 that would want the ECB to raise interest rates? Needless to say, the net benefits of the euro to Ireland would be greatly enhanced if the UK were to adopt the single currency. As a member of the euro area, the most feared scenario is that a fall in the value of sterling and the dollar will lead to an erosion of Ireland’s competitiveness just at a time when exports are already being hit by a slowing world economy. Of course, opting out of 8 The case against Ireland joining EMU is made in Thom (1997), Thom and Neary (1997), Neary (1997). The counter-factual implicit in this argument – of a high-octane Irish central bank, fine tuning the economy from year to year and providing soft landings or quick recoveries a la carte, is not entirely plausible. It relies on an exaggerated faith in the effectiveness of counter-cyclical monetary policy in a small open economy such as Ireland. 9 15 the euro area would also have involved risks. Foreign investors might have interpreted such action as evidence of a weakening commitment to Europe. Also there are intangible benefits to being close to the centre of decision taking in European monetary policy. Even more important, abstention from EMU might have weakened the government's commitment to fiscal control and a lower debt/GDP ratio. Such an eventuality would have been calamitous. c) Fiscal policy and the Broad Economic Policy Guidelines Over the long run, the hope is that EMU will consolidate the benefits of fiscal prudence, low inflation and fast growth. There have been deviations from this expectation in the recent past. Thus, the first two years of EMU have been associated with rising inflation in Ireland, not price stability. Consumer prices rose by 5.5 % in 2000 and another 4% rise is expected this year. The Department of Finance estimated that 2.5 percentage points of inflation in 2000 was attributable to the impact of interest rates, energy prices and excise taxes. The remainder was due to a mixture of the Balassa-Samuelson effect and overheating. There has been a rapid escalation of prices of services (7% in 2000), and in construction costs (up 15% in the each of the past two years). This rise in Ireland’s inflation has not gone unnoticed in Brussels. The 2000 Broad Economic Policy Guidelines (BEPG) recommended that “given the extent of overheating in the economy” the Irish Government should “gear the Budget for 2001 to ensuring economic stability”.10 Even though the budget surplus exceeded 4% of GDP, the implication of the Commission’s guidelines was that this surplus should be increased in 2001. Instead the government felt justified in reducing the surplus, thereby on its own figures implementing an expansionary fiscal policy, arguing that it was obliged to increase spending by the terms of the social partnership and that continuation of this partnership was essential to avoid a wage explosion. Much was made of projections indicating a reversion to more restrained budgets in subsequent years. The ensuing reprimand from the Commission led to a much-hyped, unnecessary and unfortunate 10 Text in the Official Journal of the European Communities 12 February 2001 16 disagreement about who controlled budgetary policy. In the context of the slowdown in recent months, both the Commission and the Central Bank of Ireland have expressed concern about the extraordinary growth of public current spending, at a rate of 21% a year according to the Revised Estimates, much of it accounted for by special public sector pay increases and higher service prices. In a deteriorating atmosphere relations were further aggravated by proposals for action against harmful tax competition among member states, interpreted in Ireland as an indirect attack on the low corporation tax regime. In an historical sense the tax regime has been important to Ireland. Honohan (2001) uses estimates derived from a paper by NBER to infer that Ireland’s FDI stock was 70% higher than it would have been had Ireland’s effective corporate tax rate been the same as the next lowest tax rate in an EU member state. Had he taken the average EU effective tax rate the effect would have been all the more dramatic. The competitive advantage to Ireland has however been diminished in recent years as corporate and other taxes in Europe are falling rapidly, a trend even more pronounced in East European. Experience shows that periods of rapid growth can be brought to a halt by economic policy mistakes. Governments are vulnerable to pressure for more spending from special interest groups. While a reversal of the Irish government’s prudent approach seems unlikely, not least because of the restraining influence of Brussels and Frankfurt, procyclical spending is hard to resist. d) Enlargement and the Nice Treaty Referendum It is paradoxical that in June 2001 the Irish electorate voted No to the Nice Treaty at the peak of the economic boom, just at a time when one would have thought that the rewards of EU membership were never more apparent. The outcome was determined not by a rise in the number voting No but rather by the vertiginous decline in the number of voters prepared to go out and vote Yes. What happened to these missing 600,000 voters? 17 35 V o te s C a s t I n F iv e I r i s h R e fe r e n d a O n E u r o p ea n T r e a ti e s S i n c e 1 9 7 2 30 25 1 ,2 0 0 ,0 0 0 20 15 10 Food 1 ,0 0 0 ,0 0 0 Gas 8 0 0 ,0 0 0 Motel Y e s 6 0 0 ,0 0 0 N o 4 0 0 ,0 0 0 5 2 0 0 ,0 0 0 0 0 1972 Jan Feb 1987 Mar 1992 1998 Apr May 2001 Jun Studies of the economic impact of Enlargement concluded that there would be small net gains to Ireland in trade in industrial goods, and some benefits from migration in easing Ireland’s labour shortage since east European migrants would be relatively easy to integrate and would bring needed skills. Effects on foreign investment would also be mildly positive. Ireland might benefit from the larger FDI inflows attracted by the enlarged market. There is a lingering fear of displacement of Ireland’s FDI by competition from low labour cost applicant countries, but the type of FDI being attracted to Ireland in recent years consists of high value added areas of the knowledge economy such as infomatics, digital media, eBusiness and healthsciences. The developed areas of the EU (Scotland, Wales, Germany) are Ireland’s main competitors for these industries, not low labour cost regions. The net impact of enlargement on Irish agriculture is likely to be negative. Initial prices on accession will stimulate production in the candidate countries, adding to surpluses and putting downward pressure on future price increases. The budgetary implications under the Common Agriculture Policy (CAP) will largely depend on decisions with respect to direct payments to farmers. The impact on Structural Funds will also impose costs on Ireland. Originally this effect was expected to be very considerable, on the assumption that new members would receive the same per capita amount of structural funds as 18 Greece/Portugal. (400 euro per capita). However, the imposition of a 4% of GDP limit on the amount receivable by the new members has reduced the overall budget impact considerably, from an original estimate of 42 billion euro to a relatively modest 9 billion euro. In economic benefit-cost terms, therefore, the impact of Enlargement on the Irish economy is likely to be broadly neutral, with probable downsides for agriculture and budget (NESC 1997, Institute of European Affairs 1999). This feature distinguishes the Nice referendum from previous ones where there were clear financial gains to large sectors of the Irish electorate to the proposed change and which consequently produced comfortable majority Yes results. (The Amsterdam Treaty vote in 1998 is an exception but here the Yes vote already was showing signs of slippage.) This illustrates the difficulty facing the government in securing a yes vote in a new referendum before the end of 2002. The case for Enlargement will have to be argued in political as well as in economic terms, and latent fears about its consequences for migration will have to be frankly addressed. But the economic consequences of Enlargement may not be the problem; most Irish people interviewed in the polls claimed to support it. Underlying the no vote three major non-economic issues have to be confronted: a) genuine concerns (however misplaced) about neutrality, b) the sense among the electorate that they were being steamrolled into a decision without adequate time for debate and reflection and c) a fear that the revised institutional framework would weaken Ireland’s power in EU decision making. The government has set up a National Forum on Europe to publicise and explore these issues and we can expect a much more vigorous effort to persuade a majority to vote yes on this occasion. There is no evidence as yet of a detailed strategy having been worked through to confront difficult questions such as: what if any concessions can the government win from its EU partners which might induce a higher ‘yes’ turnout? What 19 the implications of a second ‘no’ vote would be for Ireland, the EU and the candidate countries is unclear, but certainly they would be not be trivial. EFFECTS OF THE WORLD DOWNTURN The September attack on New York came at a time when forecasts of global economic growth were already being revised downwards very rapidly. The downturn was led by the US economy which during the 1990s had played a major role in stimulating world growth. The impact of reduced US growth on a country depends significantly on the share of US trade in its total trade and its total GDP. On this basis, the Irish economy is likely to be far more vulnerable than any other EU member state. Allowance however must be made for the extent to which a fall in exports to the US may be counterbalanced by a fall in imports from the US. This can be done by estimating the contribution to real GDP growth rates of net exports to the US. An IMF study indicates that during the period 1991-99, net exports to the US contributed on average 0.9 percentage points annually to Ireland’s growth, but virtually nothing to the EU generally and a zero effect for Portugal and Spain (Arora and Vamvakidis, 2001). There are of course many linkages between the US and the rest of the world in addition to merchandise trade; foreign investment, services trade, stock markets and business confidence. Using a more comprehensive analysis the concludes of US growth is correlated one to one with developing countries’ growth but shows a much weaker (0.20.4 percentage point) and less statistically significant linkage with industrial countries’ growth. These estimates are consistent with this year’s observed deterioration in Asia and Latin America’s economies. They may underestimate the impact of the US on industrial countries given the degree to which the interdependence of our economies has increased in recent years. Europe is already feeling the contagion effects: on its stock markets, exports and unemployment and business confidence. Merchandise Trade with the US as % of GDP 1990 1999 20 Ireland 9.1 Portugal 2.6 Spain 1.7 UK 4.5 Germany 3.2 Netherlands 6.2 Singapore 49.4 Canada 30.4 Source: Arora and Vamvakidis (2001) 18.5 2.2 1.9 5.4 3.9 7.1 41.7 56.1 In Ireland, there is agreement that this year’s GDP will decline to around 6%. There are different views on the outlook for 2002. The ESRI’s scenario on the basis of a “sharp slowdown” in the US and EU economies projects a GNP growth of only 1.8%, and a consequent rise in unemployment to 6.3% in 2002 and 7.6% in 2003. Official estimates are less bleak. The Central Bank anticipates GDP growth of 4% in 2002 and private sector economists generally favour the view that the downturn will be short-lived, rather as in the case of the Gulf War. Experience teaches us the unhappy lesson that official forecasts in these circumstances tend to be over-optimistic. The economic downturn will have further implications for Ireland’s relations with the EU. The first concerns the fiscal targets of the Stability and Growth pact. Estimates of Ireland’s general government surplus were 3.3% of GDP prior to 11 September, compared with a Budget target of 4.3%. The outturn might well be around 2%. According to the ESRI, we cannot rule out the possibility that this year’s surplus could change into a “significant” deficit next year in a worst case scenario when tax revenues fall, unemployment compensation rises, public pay commitments made in more prosperous times have to be met and so on. Before this happens, however, it is likely that some of EU partners will have breached the 3% deficit threshold. In such an eventuality, we can expect a vigorous debate about the degree of flexibility to be applied, above and beyond that already embodied in Pact. A second issue relates to competition and state aids. Already the Commission is involved in discussions about the amount and form of financial assistance the Irish government can provide to the state owned Aer Lingus, a highly charged, politically sensitive issue with national elections due to be held next year. 21 CONCLUSION … the Irish success story of the last decade has been built on the basis of EU membership and the completion of the single market. Enlargement of the EU will provide an important opportunity for Ireland to expand into new markets. Within the EU there will be a need to rethink our strategy and priorities. By the end of the decade, as one of the wealthiest members of the EU, Ireland will have new responsibilities and changing needs. Duffy et al (2001) p.xiii The economic boom has brought major benefits to the Irish people and serious wealth to a substantial minority. Inevitably, some have done better than others and a small minority may not have seen much improvement in their living standards. In many ways, the economic boom is a case study of the good consequences that follow from adopting policies built around the three pillars of macroeconomic stability, globalisation and competition in the market system to which the European Commission strongly subscribes. The challenge now is to convince the electorate – in Ireland and throughout the Union -- that the benefits from European integration are not past tense, but continue into the future, while changing in form and substance as integration itself intensifies. As we face into a sharp reduction in growth in 2002, the durability of the last decade’s gains will be put to the test. Economic history shows that countries that become prosperous tend to stay prosperous. Enough physical and human capital has been accumulated in the good times to enable these countries to survive the stresses of recession. This is encouraging for Ireland. Maintaining social consensus and reasonable pay increases is proving difficult. The education system needs continuous upgrading. There is need for ongoing focus on long run policy issues: traffic congestion, housing supply, and provision for pensions – but these problems are partly the result of prosperity and they seem more soluble from our present position than they did a decade ago. 22 REFERENCES Allen, Kieran The Celtic Tiger: the myth of social partnership in Ireland Manchester University Press 2000 Arora, V and A. Vamvakidis (2001) “The Impact of US Economic Growth on the Rest of the World: How Much Does It Matter?” IMF Working Paper WP/01/119 Washington DC Baker T, FitzGerald J and Honohan P (1996) Economic Implications for Ireland of EMU Economic and Social Research Institute Barry, Frank (1999) (ed) Understanding Ireland’s Economic Growth London Macmillan Bradley J et al (1992) The role of Structural Funds: Analysis of the Consequences for Ireland in the context of 1992 Dublin Economic and Social Research Institute De Buitleir Donal and Thornhill D J (1993) EMU and Irish Fiscal Policy Dublin Institute of European Affairs De Freitas, M L (2000) “Quantity versus Quality: The Growth Accounting of Ireland” Bank of Portugal Economic Bulletin Doyle M F (1989) "Regional Policy and European economic integration" in Report on economic and monetary union in the European Community (the Delors Report), Brussels Duffy et al Medium Term Review 2001-2007 Dublin The Economic and Social Research Institute Drudy P J and Dermot McAleese eds (1984) Ireland and the European Community Cambridge University Press Cambridge Figini P and Görg H (1998) "Multinational Companies and Wage Inequality in the Host Country: The Case of Ireland" Trinity Economic Papers no 16 July Gray Alan (1998), "Challenges for Ireland in the Integrated European Union" in F O Muircheartaigh (ed) Ireland in the Changing Times: Essays to celebrate TK Whitaker's 80 Years Dublin Institute of Public Administration Honohan P et al (1997) Evaluation of Structural Funds Dublin ESRI Honohan P (2001) “European and International Constraints on Irish Fiscal Policy” in T Callan et al Budget Perspectives Dublin The Economic and Social Research Institute Institute of European Affairs (1999) Agenda 2000: Implications for Ireland Dublin 23 Kennedy, K A (2001) “Reflections on the Process of Irish Growth” Symposium of the Statistical and Social Inquiry Society of Ireland, 26 April 2001 Lane, Philip (1998) “Profits and Wages in Ireland, 1987-1996”, Journal of the Statistical and Social Inquiry Society of Ireland 1997-98 Lee, J J (1989) Ireland 1922-1985 Cambridge University Press McAleese, Dermot (2000) “The Celtic Tiger: Origins and Prospects” Policy Options Politiques July-August 2000 McAleese, Dermot (2000) “Twenty-five Years a’ Growing” in R O’Donnell (ed) Europe: the Irish Experience Dublin: Institute of European Affairs Ireland in Europe McAleese, Dermot (2001) Economics for Business: Competition, Macrostability and Globalisation London: Financial Times Prentice Hall National Economic and Social Council (1997) European Union: Integration and Enlargement, Dublin Government Publications Office March Tansey Paul (1998) Ireland at Work: Economic Growth and the Labour Market 19871997 Dublin: Oak Tree Press White Padraic (2000) “The International Financial Services Centre: A National Development Dream” in R Mac Sharry and P White The Making of the Celtic Tiger: the Inside Story of Ireland’s Boom Economy Dublin: Mercier Press World Bank (1998) University Press Assessing Aid: What Works, What doesn't and Why Oxford Acknowledgements: I am grateful to Colette Ging and Michael Sanfey for comments on a first draft. They are of course not responsible for any remaining errors. irish economy/lisbon1001rev 24