Metropolitan Governance Structures from a Neoprogressive Perspective David Lowery, Thomas J. Pearsall Professor Department of Political Science University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Chapel Hill, North Carolina 27599 (919) 962-0448 / dlowery@email.unc.edu Metropolitan Governance Structures from a Neoprogressive Perspective The debate on metropolitan reform differs in some ways in the United States and Europe. Most notably, the demography of urban centers and their peripheries differ markedly in the two settings (Keating 1995). Still, as in most of the world, America’s metropolitan areas tend to be highly fragmented institutionally with sometimes hundreds of separate municipal jurisdictions. There is, however, some variation across regions. The older metropolitan areas of the northeast and midwest are especially fragmented while the newer metropolitan areas of the south and west are less so given both a tradition of strong county government and more tractable annexation laws. Still fragmentation is more the rule than the exception, and relatively few formerly fragmented metropolitan areas have opted for consolidated government in the post-War era (Rusk 1995). But whether in Europe or the United States, the theoretical controversies surrounding consolidation are the same. These are defined by what Elinor Ostrom (1972) has labeled the two traditions of metropolitan reform. While they actually define the poles of a continuum between which in variety of institutional arrangements might be envisioned (Savitch and Vogel 2001: 161-164), they constitute two starkly different approaches toward metropolitan governance. The earliest approach, associated with the progressive reform movement in the United States, argued that metropolitan areas should be governmentally consolidated. While dominant for most of the 20th century, the newer public choice approach – based on Tiebout (1956) – both exposed the limited theoretical underpinnings of the traditional consolidationist approach and offered an alternative founded on a quasimarket interpretation of the virtues of governmental fragmentation. Over the last 30 years, the public choice case for fragmentation has held the 1 intellectual high ground. While many empirical challenges of the public choice approach have appeared, they have had little cumulative effect. Simply put, once the theoretical underpinnings of the older reform tradition – based on the assumed efficiency advantages of service production by centralized bureaucracies – were exposed as having only limited foundation, an accumulation of negative empirical findings could not in and of themselves rebuilt a case for consolidation (Lowery 1999a). Rather, a new theoretical approach was needed to revitalize the case for consolidation. Such an approach clearly has emerged in recent years. While not part of a conscious agenda, a number of scholars have developed and tested a range of theoretically grounded hypotheses suggesting that consolidation merits renewed attention. I have labeled this emerging approach the “neoprogressive” perspective (Lowery 1999a). Together, these hypotheses constitute a new case for consolidated metropolitan government. At the same time, they abandon the progressives often naïve faith in bureaucratic production in favor reliance on modern social science methods and, quite often, many of the same theoretical tools employed by public choice scholars. Still, the emerging neoprogressive case for consolidation is a creation with many parts, most of which have yet to be fully integrated (Lowery 2000). Yet, three main lines of inquiry are evident in the literature. Local Democracy The first of these considers the individual-level requisites for democratic politics. This issue represents something new in the debate between consolidation and fragmentation. Traditional progressives celebrated professional management over democratic politics, at best reserving the public a right of final judgement via a short ballot. Similarly, public choice scholars have – beyond rather unexamined homage to the New England town meeting – tend 2 to see local governments narrowly as producers of services rather than as political entities. More recently, at least two distinct arguments suggest that consolidated governments offer important advantages over their fragmented counterparts in providing a foundation for local democracy. The first stresses the importance of information. For meaningful democratic control of government, citizens must have valid information about what government is doing and how well it is doing it. While a few public choice scholars have examined political behavior under conditions of limited information (Teske, Schneider, Mintrom, and Best 1993), most simply follow Tiebout (1956) in assuming full information. Comparisons of citizen information about service provision in consolidated and fragmented settings, however, demonstrates that respondents in the latter setting make many more errors in simply identifying the providers of services they receive in a complex institutional setting (Lyons, Lowery, and DeHoog 1990). Moreover, these errors were not random. It appears that local officials are quite adept at shifting the blame for poor services to other levels of government while claiming credit for good services they did not in fact provide. Such findings should not be viewed as alien to the public choice tradition, which has long suggested that self-interest politicians have incentives to manipulate institutions for their own advantage. But these findings also suggest that fragmented institutions provide many more opportunities for such manipulation, thereby weakening democratic accountability. The second advantage concerns citizens’ responses when dissatisfied with local government. Lyons and Lowery (1986; 1989a) have arrayed these responses on two dimensions: an active-passive and a constructive-destructive dimension. Exit, the activedestructive response to dissatisfaction, is Tiebout’s (1956) voting with one’s feet. Voice, the 3 active-constructive response, entails efforts to change the policies generating dissatisfaction. Neglect is the passive-destructive response of despairing of change and withdrawing support from the government while remaining within the jurisdiction. And loyalty, the passiveconstructive response, is expressed through continued support for the government while expecting conditions to improve. Lowery, Lyons, and DeHoog (1992) report that local government structure has a strong indirect effect on how citizens select among these responses. That is, they found that psychological attachment to the community was much higher in consolidated settings than in their fragmented counterparts. More to the point, they found that attachment made the constructive responses to dissatisfaction of voice and loyalty more likely and the destructive responses of exit and neglect less likely. They further suggest that vital democratic government is more difficult when the primary responses of citizens to inevitable episodes of dissatisfaction are flight or disaffection. Citizen Satisfaction The neoprogressive argument for consolidation, while emphasizing the political role of local government, does not reject the public choice emphasis on service production. Still, this part of the debate has been rather narrowly framed by comparisons of the efficiency of production processes in different settings. But the ultimate issue is one of citizen satisfaction with services provided and those not provided. Importantly, simple comparisons of satisfaction levels in matched neighborhoods in consolidated and fragmented settings have failed to find the mean differences hypothesized by either traditional progressives or public choice scholars (DeHoog, Lyons, and Lowery 1990). Overall citizen satisfaction did not vary systematically across the two types of governmental settings. Still, there were two ways in which citizens in the consolidated settings were found to have a satisfaction advantage. 4 First, while government structure had no direct impact on satisfaction, it had two powerful indirect effects. DeHoog, Lyons, and Lowery (1990) examined a range of hypothesized determinants of citizen satisfaction, including individual-level, jurisdictional-level, and city specific variables. Only four variables were found to influence service satisfaction – the individual-level variables of political efficacy and psychological attachment to the community and the jurisdiction-level variables of number and quality of services provided. And two of these – attachment and number of services – are related to local government structure. Psychological attachment, which was positively related to satisfaction, was higher in consolidated settings. Citizens were also more satisfied when they receive – and pay for – more services, and more services are provided by consolidated governments. Thus, if indirectly, citizens are more satisfied with services under consolidated government. Second, while the structure of metropolitan government has little direct effect on mean levels of service satisfaction, it does have a direct effect on its variance. In comparisons of survey data on overall satisfaction (Lyons and Lowery 1989b) and satisfaction with an array of specific services (Kelleher and Lowery 2001) in matched neighborhoods in the two settings, the variance of satisfaction was substantially greater under fragmented government. This runs counter to the public choice assumption that, by allowing citizens with varied tastes to match their preferences to a menu of tax-service packages offered in fragmented settings, most citizens should be equally satisfied. Instead, Kelleher and Lowery (2001) suggest that preferences for services do not vary much across citizens. Rather, it is access to wealthy and poor jurisdictions that varies across citizens in fragmented settings. Thus, fragmentation works to ensure that some will be much more satisfied with local services than others. 5 Metropolitan Problems Despite this attention to individual-level traits, the bulk of work within the neoprogressive perspective focuses on metropolitan-wide policy issues. That is, many critics have raised concerns about the capacity of fragmented local institutions to meet metropolitanwide problems. This argument, of course, is not new to the case for consolidation. It, along with attention to service efficiency, has been part of the consolidationist argument for decades. Still, the argument has been revitalized in recent years via analyses of both old and new problems in America’s metropolitan areas. Two problems, especially, have attracted attention. First, the social stratificationgovernment inequality (SSGI) thesis first developed by Hill (1974) and Neiman (1976) suggests that fragmented institutions perpetuate income inequality within metropolitan areas by systematically mismatching resources and needs. Indeed, many proponents of this view suggest that fragmented institutions are designed to do just that. While the SSGI thesis has been revised in many ways over time (Massey and Denton 1993; Lowery 1999b; Kelleher and Lowery 2001), it both remains a major challenge to the public choice case for fragmentation and is a central part of the neoprogressive case for consolidation. Similarly, many scholars, often working under the rubric of “the new regionalism” have argued that fragmented local governments are poorly positioned to address the housing, environmental, and transportation problems associated with urban sprawl (Rusk 1995; Downs 1994; Savitch and Vogel 2000). Indeed, they suggest that not only does fragmentation preclude concerted responses to the problems of sprawl, it is a major source of the problem. Public choice scholars do not usually deny these problems. Rather, this portion of the debate addresses the efficacy of their preferred “solutions.” The consistent response of public 6 choice scholars to the metropolitan-wide problems of income distribution and sprawl has been a call for inter-jurisdictional agreements and higher levels of government to step in and fill the void (Ostrom 1972; Parks and Oakerson 2000). But neoprogressives have used the economic tools of public choice theory to argue that at least the former solutions are unlikely to work. The higher transactions costs, conflicts of interests, and framing and even distortion of preferences associated with adopting coordinated policy responses in fragmented setting ensures that a tragedy of commons is far more likely than effective polycentric government (Lowery 1998; 2000; Downs 1994). There is still the possibility of higher levels of government stepping in. But given the long-term devolution of U.S. social policy and continued inaction by most states (Fleischmann 2000), consolidationists place little faith in these solutions. Public choice scholars have, in turn denied the efficacy of consolidation as a solution (Ostrom 1972; Parks and Oakerson 2000). But while consolidation is hardly a complete solution, substantial evidence suggests that the problems of sprawl and income redistribution are less severe when local government is consolidated (Rusk 1995; Down 1994). Conclusion The debate between the poles of consolidation and fragmentation has changed markedly in recent years with the emergence of neoprogressive arguments for the former. Several of these have been reviewed here. Two final issues merit comment. First, these new issues are often far more difficult to explore empirically than traditional comparisons of service efficiency. Valid comparisons of citizens’ service satisfaction, democratic political behaviors, and metro-wide policies and their consequences require ambitious and well-crafted research designs. Far more research is required, but is likely to be slow in coming given the demands inherent in doing this kind of research. Still, enough research has been conducted to date to 7 suggest that such investments are likely to generate substantial returns. Second, public choice scholars have hardly recognized the new arguments raised by neoprogressive research. Indeed, the responses offered in 1972 by Ostrom are nearly identical to those of Parks and Oakerson in 2000. So, the debate has been a bit one-sided of late. To the extent that truth emerges only from a rigorous testing of ideas by opponents, this is unfortunate. 8 References DEHOOG, Ruth Hoogland, David LOWERY, and William E. LYONS (1990). “Citizen Satisfaction with Local Government: A Test of Individual, Jurisdictional, and City Specific Explanations”, Journal of Politics 52(3): 807-837. DOWNS, Anthony (1994). New Vision for Metropolitan America. Washington: Brookings Institution. HILL, Richard Child (1974). “Separate and Unequal: Governmental Inequality in the Metropolis,” American Political Science Review 68(4): 1557-1568. KEATING, Michael (1995). “Size, Efficiency, and Democracy: Consolidation, Fragmentation, and Public Choice”, in David JUDGE, Gerry STOKER, and Harold WOLMAN (eds.) . Theories of Urban Politics. London: Sage. KELLEHER, Christine and LOWERY, David (2001). “Tiebout Sorting and Selective Satisfaction with Urban Public Services: Testing the Variance Hypotheses”, Urban Affairs Review, in press. FLEISCHMANN, ARNOLD (2000). “Regionalism and City-County Consolidation in Small Metro Areas”, State and Local Government Review 32(3): 213-226. LOWERY, David (2000). "A Transactions Costs Model of Metropolitan Governance: Allocation Versus Redistribution in Urban America”, Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 10(1): 49-78. ------ (1999a). “Answering the Public Choice Challenge to Progressive Reform Institutions: A Neoprogressive Research Agenda”, Governance 12(1): 29-56. ------ (1999b). “Sorting in the Fragmented Metropolis: Updating the Social StratificationGovernment Inequality Debate,” Public Management 1(1): 7-26. ------ (1998). “Consumer Sovereignty and Quasimarket Failure”, Journal of Public 1 Administration Research and Theory 8(2): 137-172. LOWERY, David, William E. LYONS, and Ruth Hoogland DEHOOG (1992). “Citizenship and Community Attachment in the Empowered Locality: An Elaboration, a Critique, and a Partial Test”, Urban Affairs Quarterly 28(3): 69-103. ------ (1990). “Institutionally-Induced Attribution Errors: Their Composition and Impact on Citizen Satisfaction with Local Governmental Services”, American Politics Quarterly 18(2): 169-196. LYONS, William E. and David LOWERY (1989a). “Citizen Responses to Dissatisfaction in Urban Communities: A Partial Test of a General Model”, Journal of Politics 51(4): 842-868. ------ (1989b). “Governmental Fragmentation Vrs. Consolidation: Five Public Choice Myths About Creating Informed, Involved, and Happy Citizens”, Public Administration Review 49(6): 533-543. ------ (1986). “The Organization of Political Space and Citizen Responses to Dissatisfaction in Urban Communities: An Integrated Model”, Journal of Politics 48(2): 321-334. MASSEY, Douglas S. and Nancy A. DENTON (1993). American Aparteid. Cambridge: Harvard University. NEIMAN, Max (1976). “Social Stratification and Government Inequality”, American Political Science Review 53(4): 474-493. OSTROM, Elinor (1972). “Metropolitan Reform: Propositions Derived from Two Traditions”, Social Science Quarterly 53(4): 474-493. PARKS, Roger B. and Ronald J. Oakerson (2000). “Regionalism, Localism, and Metropolitan Governance: Suggestions from the Research Program on Local Public Economies”, State and Local Government Review 32(3): 169-179. 2 RUSK, David (1995). Cities Without Suburbs (2nd Ed.). Washington: Woodrow Wilson Center. SAVITCH, H. V. and Ronald K. VOGEL (2000). “Paths to New Regionalism”, State and Local Government Review 32(4): 158-168. TESKE, Paul, Mark SCHNEIDER, Michael MINTROM, and Samuel BEST (1993). “Establishing the Micro Foundations of a Macro Theory: Information, Movers, and the Competitive Local Market for Public Goods”, American Political Science Review 87(3): 702-713. TIEBOUT, Charles (1956). “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures”, Journal of Political Economy 64(4): 416-424. 3