Lecture on Globalization and the Issue of Free Trade Recent arguments over the existence and effects of greater globalization have centered on (1) whether or not the world is more interconnected now than in the past; (2) whether increased free trade in goods and services can be harmful overall to certain countries; (3) whether groups or owners of factors of production within a country that are harmed by globalization can and will be properly compensated; (5) whether increased international capital flows and financial interconnectedness have made the world’s economy more unstable, and (6) whether technology has changed the structure of economies so much that all of the old arguments in favor of free trade (e.g. comparative advantage) no longer hold true. Nearly all arguments about the desirability of free trade, versus the advisedness of protection, can be sorted into one of these broad categories above. The basic question is an old one – are there lasting and equitable gains from free and open trade in goods and services. If so, then an open door policy should be pursued and perhaps even forced on countries. If not, then the open door should be at least partially closed either by laws, regulations, tariffs, or quotas. One problem with trying to systematically unpack these issues is that the losses and gains often cannot be adequately monetized and therefore remain highly subjective, value-laden, and abstract. Many of these losses include changes in traditional culture and the elimination of entire ways of life for large groups of people. They involve dislocations in livelihood and geography. The losses are often psychologically unsettling, at least for periods measured in decades. For example, the introduction of hypermarts (e.g., Carrefour) in Taiwan led to substantial changes in shoppers’ habits away from traditional markets and small stores. Taiwan has had to face its own form of Walmart-ization. The resentment has run strong and deep, but consumers have had little to complain about. Taiwan’s consumers have been given much greater choice. Instead of consumer welfare, it has been concern over small scale domestic producers which have been the focus of news stories and commentaries. These producers are much smaller in number than their consumers and are therefore more concentrated and unified in their opposition to free trade than their consumers are to opening trade. This is a common problem for free trade. The benefits are individually small and highly dispersed, whereas the costs are individually large and highly concentrated. This makes it difficult to generate strong political support for free trade, while opposition to free trade is easy to mobilize. This is true, even though the overall gains from trade can be manifestly larger than the collective costs. This short lecture will try to answer the six questions above. First we should answer whether or not the world is now more integrated than before. Consider the following graph The data is taken from the UN data website http://unstats.un.org/unsd/snaama/dnllist.asp and the graph shows the total world trade (exports + imports) as a percentage of total world GDP, with both numerator and denominator measured in current USD. Clearly there has been a steady increase in this measure of globalization beginning in 1985. As of 2005, the ratio stood at around 57%. This measure provides very strong evidence that globalization has been increasing and that the world is becoming increasing integrated economically. The spike in 1980 may have been due to the fact of the second oil crisis and the dramatic rise in the price of oil. The World Bank also makes estimates of trade to GDP ratios for the world and various groupings of countries. Here is a sample % Trade to GDP in current US Dollars World Low Income Low and Middle Income High Income 1990 32.3 23.6 32.5 32.3 2005 47.3 41.1 59.2 43.9 The World Bank has also estimated the percentage of services traded relative to GDP in a similar way. It found that world traded services to GDP rose from about 7% in 1990 to 11% in 2005. Obviously, trade in goods continues to dominate overall trade. In addition to trade flows, the world’s economies have become integrated financially through greater foreign investment – both foreign direct investment and foreign portfolio investment. Not only have private interests placed investments abroad, central banks have increasingly taken an important role in the holding of foreign assets. Here is a summary of their findings on investment as a percentage of GDP. Again it is clear that the overall trend in investment is towards greater internationalization. This is especially true of high income countries involving portfolio investment. FDI appears to be rising most quickly in low-middle income countries. The next question involves determining whether or not free trade is better than protectionism. This question goes all the way back to Adam Smith and the Wealth of Nations (1776). Smith believed that the only way to increase the wealth of a country was to increase productivity (he also recognized that if a greater percentage of the population were to engage in labor then wealth would rise.) To increase productivity, there must be a specialization of labor – something he called division of labor. He then asked how that a country could enjoy a greater degree of the division of labor. This he said depended on the size of the market. A larger market would allow greater specialization. In order to increase the size of the market, an increase in both exports and imports was needed. Therefore, to have a richer country, free trade would be the best policy. Free and balanced trade would always work to make both countries richer. Smith ran into trouble however in trying to decide what products countries should produce and trade. It seemed silly for a country to produce wheat and import wheat at the same time, since clearly wheat would be roughly the same regardless of where it was grown. If a country imported wheat, then it should not produce sizable amounts of wheat. In short, Smith lacked a correct way of describing the structure of trade – which products should be imported and which should be exported. David Ricardo and John Stuart Mill were given the task of explaining the structure of trade. Ricardo presented his theory of comparative advantage, which has now become a common place concept in international trade classes, and indeed is part of general economic theory (not only trade). However, Ricardo was rather blind to the aspects of demand. It was up to Mill to provide a clearer statement of the solution. Comparative advantage based on relative labor productivities would be the basis for geographic specialization, and respective demands would help to determine international relative prices, the actual quantities exported and imported, as well as the quantities consumed domestically. Would countries be unambiguously better off if there were free trade based on productivity-inspired comparative advantage and relative demands? Here it was clear that some people would be hurt after trade and some people would be helped. It was thought that those who were hurt would simply adjust to their new circumstances. The destruction of an industry due to cheap imports was to be accepted as part of the game. In the long run, all would be better. This was the accepted view for many years, although there was a suspicion that the pains of adjustment might be too great for a government to accept. Protection was always a welcome expedient. We can see how that trade is beneficial by considering two countries (A and B) and two goods (X and Y). Note the diagram on the next page. Country A is small compared to country B. One could think of Taiwan = Country A and US = Country B. If there is no trade, each country consumes at point C on its production possibilities frontier. If there is specialization and trade, the counties move to producing at points P and consuming at C’. A will export good Y and import good X, while B will export good X and import good Y. By trading both countries must be better off since they have more of each good. The only question here is one of distribution. Note that there is no discussion of how that enlarging the market causes greater wealth and prosperity. Smith’s original idea of linking free trade and the division of labor is not present in this analysis. This is Ricardo’s theory. By the way, the diagram shows that it is not necessary that both countries geographically specialize. Also, the diagram assumes that imports equal exports and therefore there is balanced trade. -------------------------------------------------We should point out here that recently, question number two above was considered again by none other than Paul Samuelson in an article in the Journal of Economic Perspectives 2004. The title of this article was “When Ricardo and Mill Rebut and Confirm Arguments of Mainstream Economists Supporting Globalization”. Let’s take a moment and consider this article closely…later we can look at his critics (e.g., G . Mankiw) and Samuelson’s own reply to his critics. Samuelson uses the method of a parable involving two countries which he calls the US and China. The paper is very simple and abstract. There is no capital flows and there are only two goods. Labor is homogeneous and is divided in both countries between the two industries. The parable is very much in the spirit of the above Ricardian analysis of two countries – two goods. Here are the assumptions and the analysis of Samuelson’s paper showing the movement from autarky to free trade. Autarky US: (here we use upper case letters) Assume Q1 2 L1 Q2 1 L2 2 L1 L 2 1 0 0 zero capital movements 1 W1L 1 W2 L 2 P1Q1 P2Q2 (2 P1 ) L 1 ( P2 ) L 2 2 which implies W1 2 P1 and W2 1 P2 2 Now, if there is competition in the product and factor markets, the real wages adjust in both sectors so that W1 W2 P* P* where we assume the aggregate price level P* is equal to some number we will discuss later. This combined with the two equations immediately preceding this yields P2 4 P1 Next, assume that the demands for good 1 and good 2 are such that P1Q1 1 (Nominal Income) 2 which implies P1Q1 P2Q2 and therefore L 1 L 2 50 Samuelson proceeds to measure real income by using the geometric mean of the consumptions of good 1 and 2. 1 Q1Q2 (2L1 )( L2 ) L1L2 L12 L1 50 2 Real Income = It follows that per capita real income in the US before trade is equal to Real Income / Population Note: We can write P2Q2 I / 2 . It follows that Thus, Q1Q2 P1Q1 I / 2 Q1Q2 = 50 0.50 100 where I = nominal income. 1 I I ( ( P1Q1 )( P2Q2 ) ) * P1P2 2 P1P2 2P is a good measure of real income where index to deflate nominal income. It is also true that P* . is the appropriate price The only argument I have with what Samuelson has done is that the measure appears to be only half the exact measure of real income. to be the correct measure of real income. That is, 2 Q1Q2 looks This is not important to the main thrust of Samuelson’s paper. China: (here we use lower case letters) Assume q1 1 l1 20 q2 1 l2 5 l 1 l 2 1 0 0 0 zero capital movements w1l 1 w2l 2 p1q1 p2 q2 ( 1 1 p1 )l 1 ( p2 )l 2 20 5 which implies w1 1 p1 20 w2 1 p2 5 and Likewise, competition forces p2 1 p1 4 Assume that the demands for good 1 and good 2 are such that p1q1 1 (Nominal Income) 2 which implies p1q1 p2q2 and therefore l 1 l 2 500 Again, Samuelson measures real income using the geometric mean of the consumptions of good 1 and 2. Real Income = q1q2 ( 1 1 1 1 2 1 l1 )( l2 ) l1l2 l1 l1 50 20 5 10 10 10 It follows that per capita real income in China before trade is equal to Real Income / Population = 50 0.05 1000 Free Trade Now suppose that these two countries trade together freely. For the US, a unit of good 1 requires a 1/2 unit of labor -- whereas a unit of good 2 requires 2 units of labor. In the US, good 1 is relatively cheaper. By contrast, China’s technology is such that a unit of good 1 requires 20 units of labor – whereas a unit of good 2 only requires 5 units of labor. In China, good 2 is relatively cheaper. This means that the US has a comparative advantage in good 1 and China has a comparative advantage in good 2. The US should specialize in the production of good 1 and China should specialize in the production of good 2. The countries should then trade. If the US produces only good 1 it can produce a total of 200 units of good 1. Similarly, if China produces only good 2, it can produce a total of 200 units of good 2. The international terms of trade is therefore given by P2 p2 1 P1 p1 Real per capita income in the US and in China (after free trade) is now given by Real per capita income US = Q1Q2 1002 / 100 1.0 Real per capita income China = q1q2 1002 / 1000 0.10 Clearly, both the US and China are better off than when they were in autarky. This is the typical analysis of free trade found in most textbooks. No real argument here, except some questions about the distribution of real income. Now Samuelson asks a simple question. Suppose that China’s technology q 1 changes so that the productivity in the good 1 industry rises from 1 to l1 20 q1 8 q 1 while 2 . l1 10 l2 5 What this means for China is that q1 4q2 , which is exactly the same in the US. Thus, the US no longer has a comparative advantage and there is no reason for trade. The technological advance has eliminated the gains that can be obtained through trade. Samuelson’s point is simply that technology can eliminate trade and that differences in productivity and technology makes trade desirable. The view he is espousing is that China’s growing skilled labor force and its rich technical advances may result in a loss of comparative advantage for the US in the future. An open China may result in a future diminished role for trade if China begins to resemble the US. As he writes “..it is free trade’s own spontaneous killing off of all trade that does harm to the United States.” We will discuss Mankiw’s response to this. We now turn to the third question which is whether winners will compensate losers in free trade. The great English economist Alfred Marshall weighed in on this question. Instead of pursuing the welfare question and the gains from trade from the point of view of Pareto (something that was not very practical), Marshall chose a different tack. He claimed that even if there were those who might be hurt by free trade, the rest of society who were helped by free trade could compensate those who were hurt and still be better off than with no trade (called autarky). The issue then became not whether gains offset losses, but whether those who won at free trade would significantly compensate those who lost at free trade. This compensation would be used to buy time for the economy to adjust to a new structure of trade and industry. The US has had a program of compensation for trade dislocation since 1974. Here is what the US Department of Labor says about trade adjustment: The Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) Program is a federal program established under the Trade Act of 1974 that provides aid to workers who lose their jobs or whose hours of work and wages are reduced as a result of increased imports. The TAA program offers a variety of benefits and reemployment services to help unemployed workers prepare for and obtain suitable employment. Workers may be eligible for training, job search and relocation allowances, income support, and other reemployment services. A petition for TAA may be filed by a group of three or more workers, their union, or other duly authorized representative. The Trade Adjustment Assistance Reform Act of 2002 (TAA Reform Act) reauthorized the TAA program through fiscal year 2007 and amended and added provisions to the program. I will be discussing some of the other questions and G . Mankiw’s paper in class next time. By the way, here are some basic arguments for and against free trade. wish to read these. There is nothing technical here. You may ARGUMENTS FOR AND AGAINST FREE TRADE I. WHY IS FREE TRADE ADVANTAGEOUS ? There is an increasing trend towards greater economic interdependence among countries of the world. The US has concluded agreements with Canada and Mexico to institute a free trade area known as NAFTA (the North American Free Trade Area). Europe is similarly working to promote the EC (the European Community) in which trade between its member countries will be much freer. Finally, there is a clear shift towards cooperation in Asia with APEC (the Association of Pacific Rim Economic Cooperation) and other similar organizations. The first thing to note about free trade is that it is between two groups who willingly undertake the exchange. If the trade did not benefit both of these groups, it would not take place. Both the buyers and the sellers must be satisfied. This is always true of voluntary exchange, and it is very different from when the government purchases things. We should always keep it in mind that free exchange must make both parties in the exchange better off. Second, free trade promotes competition and efficiency. When a domestic firm faces only domestic competition, it may not utilize its resources in the least costly manner. It may decide to use its profits to pay dividends to stockholders, rather than using the profits to modernize its factories and upgrade its research. Greater competition places greater pressure on firms to find the least costly way to produce their products. This will free resources which can then be used to manufacture other products in the economy. Third, free trade can promote development of the economy. Many countries must borrow vast sums of foreign exchange or foreign money to purchase needed goods such as food, medicine, and capital equipment. To get this foreign exchange, such countries must have access to open markets which will allow them to export and earn the foreign exchange. South Korea is a good example of a country which has used foreign loans and a free US consumer market to build their economy into a competitive force. Moreover, free trade allows the expansion of markets and the specialization of industry. This increases the division of labor and increases productivity. Fourth, free trade can promote the diffusion of new technologies and ideas. Both Japan and China suffered greatly when they closed their economies to foreign trade. China is largely behind the world technologically because it refused to engage the rest of the world in trade. It is now making impressive progress because of the opening of its markets. Finally, free trade promotes international harmony and peace. History is replete with examples of countries going to war principally because they refused to trade freely with each other. The US has recently decided to use free trade as a means to encourage better relations with China. It has learned that nothing is accomplished by forcing China to withdraw into itself. And, even when relations between the US and Japan were at their post-war low in 1988, the two countries knew that trade was too important to allow a serious break to develop between their two economies. Taiwan is also learning that cooperating economically with Mainland China has its rewards. II. WHY IS FREE TRADE DISADVANTAGEOUS ? While we have listed some of the good points in favor of free trade, we must acknowledge that no country in world practices pure free trade. Every country in the world engages in some sort of protectionism, although there is less pressure today than before for these policies. But, why do countries seek to protect themselves from foreign trade? First, some industries are important for the national defense. Generally, most economists agree that agriculture is a necessary industry for every country, since importing food during war might not be feasible. The same argument might be made for certain basic industries such as steel and chemicals. But, unfortunately, it is difficult to classify industries in this way. Each industry believes that it is necessary to the national defense. Second, free trade can cause social dislocations and adverse structural changes in the economy. For example, free trade in steel in the US nearly resulted in a destruction of the steel industry. It was only when the US government provided protection to US steel producers that the industry was saved. Today, the US steel industry is doing much better. It is using a smaller workforce, producing more output, and exporting more than before. However, many steelworkers lost their jobs and had to move to other areas of the country. This caused a long period of readjustment and social hardship. Third, some people feel that free trade can only help resource and technology rich countries. They feel that the US is championing free trade because it has the greatest economic strength, and will therefore benefit the most. Countries which are underdeveloped and do not possess the resources and technology of the US will not be able to compete. Their economies will not be able to grow if US, European, and Japanese products are allowed to be imported freely. Protection is necessary in order to level the playing field. Fourth, some people feel that traditional culture suffers when there is free trade. If US pop culture can be imported freely into a country, it might disrupt the value system of the young in that country. A generation gap might even appear between the young and old. This is of great concern in Mainland China where the term "spiritual pollution" has been used to describe this effect. In other countries it has been called "cultural imperialism". Finally, some people feel that free trade is a wonderful idea theoretically, but it is impossible to enforce. There are simply too many subtle ways that a country can restrict trade. Even if trade is free for a while, if a country feels that its national interests are at stake, it will simply impose protection. In this sense, free trade can never be a law, but can only be a principle -- and as we all know, principles can be subjectively interpreted.