Annex 1 Political Economy of Public Sector Institutional Reform in Philippines Background 1. By definition, public sector reforms imply a change in the distribution of benefits and, more critically, the institutionalization of such change. As such, reforms in the public sector may attract intense opposition or other means of limiting their effect by those who would lose. Because public sector reforms involve large scale institutional change, affect various constituencies and often unfold over an extended period, interests, actors and their strength, and whole governing regimes may shift resulting in a decidedly different environment than when initially conceived or adopted. Often, this results in reform programs that fail in spite of seemingly strong technical foundations. 2. In order to better understand how reformers can ensure reforms are adopted, implemented, and institutionalized, it is critical to understand the political economy within which a particular reform program operates. In particular, it is important to gain a better understanding of what and how economic, social and political variants affect the adoption, content, and implementation of reforms in a number of critical public sector areas. From such an understanding, practitioners may identify politically-informed strategies that could be used to manage reform processes in order to achieve optimal results. 3. This note outlines a conceptual framework for the study of the political economy of reform around five major public sector areas in the Philippines. It is based on a brief review of the theoretical and case study literature of the political economy of reforms in various service and economic sectors. The five substantive areas of public sector reform for which this framework is developed are: decentralization, public expenditure management, tax administration, civil service, and procurement. It is expected that this conceptual framework will be elaborated and adapted for each reform area in order to draw relevant lessons grounded in the specifics of each case. Literature Review 4. The literature on the political economy of public sector reform, typically drawing lessons from case studies of reform experiences gone awry, falls into two schools. One, focused on the institutions and history of a particular entity, offers a path-dependent explanation for why certain reforms are adopted and implemented, or fail. In this view, reforms adopted are reflective of a particular way of doing things that is historically and institutionally mandated; deviations (such as those externally mandated) will likely fail. A second view focuses on proximate political, administrative and social structures – and thus the arenas and actors in play – to explain policy adoption and implementation, or failure. Both perspectives accept as a given, as we do, that the reforms proposed are both technically feasible and desirable. 5. Neither of these perspectives has an analytical superiority (inherent or otherwise) and each is a foundation for several articulate studies that offer significant insights into policy and reform processes. The adoption of either seems to largely correlate with the analysts’ prior theoretical biases (i.e. new institutionalism vs. historical institutionalism, or rational choice vs. ethnographic biases). For our purposes, however, it is worthwhile to consider the strength a combined perspective can offer by drawing on the streamlined analytical precision of rational choice analysis and the deeper interrogative analysis essential to an ethnographic review of actors and institutions and their interests, histories and strengths. 1 6. A theoretical framing drawing from the two perspectives is appropriate in the case of Philippines’s public sector reforms for a number of reasons. An historical and institutional review is essential to understanding how the macro political economy – in particular the heritage, eventual collapse, and aftermath of an authoritarian neo-patrimonial regime – affected reform processes at a lower level. It would be difficult to understand the actors, their range of interests, and their strength (or lack of) in policy reform without understanding how this macro environment conditioned their emergence and operation. Moreover, it would be essential to correlate the changing fortunes of each reform program (and presumably of the relevant actors/interests/institutions) with the different phases of the macro reform and post-Marcos state elaboration. On the other hand, an historical-institutional review would be of limited utility without a thorough understanding of the dynamics of the actors, interests, coalitions and institutions around each particular reform area. Indeed, while the history and macro institutions may constrain choice and action, it is the proximate actors and interests that make the choices that affect policy. Main Research Questions 7. In general, a review of the political economy of reform in the public sector should address four essential questions. The case studies of reform in five public sector areas in Philippines, for which this analytical framework is developed, should focus in particular on answering these questions. 8. The content of the reform program: What was the specific reform program pursued; what were its specific goals; what reforms were actually implemented; who implemented; how did the reform program relate to other reforms/non-reform; what other reforms were considered/rejected? 9. The actors/interests affected by reforms: Who advocated, opposed, or was neutral to reforms; how involved were they, and at what stages; what relative strength did each have, and at what stages; how did different actors/interests interact and to what effect? 10. The process of reform evolution: How was the reform initiated (agenda-setting), elaborated (instrumentation), and implemented; in what arenas was reform initiated, formulated, implemented; how did this affect the content and actors in reform? 11. The impact of reform: Beyond the installation of new rules and norms, what primary effects of reform are evident (e.g. transparent accounting rules); what secondary effects (e.g. actual public comment on accounts); what post-reform events/reactions are evident? Attention should be paid to both service delivery and institutional/accountability issues. Principal Variables to be Examined 12. In order to answer the above four questions, it is necessary to examine a number of variables necessary to understand how the political economy conditions public sector reform in Philippines. These variables are not meant to be exclusive but to provide a sufficient number of data points (narratives) to allow for both an in-depth explication and a comparison across the five reform areas. 13. In very brief sketches, the following are the critical variables: 2 I. The type of regime: constitutional issues, macro politics and especially the nature of state power. (This variable will not be investigated in each case. Rather, a separate analysis will be provided as a background and context for the variables II-IV). Part of the theoretical literature on policy reform underscores the relevance of state structures to the adoption of particular policy reforms. Such studies link how well such reforms fare to the broader historical and institutional postures of the state. While this variable is most enlightening when one is comparing policy reforms across countries, in the case of policy reforms across different areas in a single country some ‘unpacking’ is necessary. For the proposed study, an examination of the political context of the Philippines public sector, in particular, an exposition of the political-administrative traditions, the discourse of development, the impact of authoritarianism, cronyism, and centralization on state-society relations will be examined. For the specific case studies, this preface should be disaggregated to examine how it is manifest in each policy area. For example, how did cronyism and corruption affect/promote particular rules and expectations on tax administration or on the role and performance of civil servants. Thus, the utility of the macro-political background must be distilled from the evident ways it structured performance – and ultimately reform. On public sector reform, each reform policy area should be examined in terms of how its reform reflected or inverted the predominant regime profile and especially the local-center relations. Similarly, any significant breaks with the status quo (e.g. the 1986 people’s revolution) should be examined in terms of its impact on policy reforms and implementation. II. Actors and their relative strength: What actors were involved in the reform identification, elaboration and implementation. The analysis will focus on the incentives that motivate the actors to undertake public sector institutional reform in the Philippines. The analysis will identify the key political and other actors and their incentives to support or oppose key institutional reforms. The analysis will also examine the process of coalition building. Key actors may include the executive (including the president, key presidential advisors, ministers, heads of key executive agencies, executive departments, armed forces, police, key government owned or controlled corporations, government financial institutions), the legislature (including congressional committees), the Church, the media, political parties, trade unions/employees’ federations, other religious interests, ethnic/linguistic and other interest groups. The theoretical and case study literature points to the role played by actors inside and outside institutions in shaping reform dynamics. In particular, the literature identifies three sets of actors that are important to examine. First, ‘veto’ actors have sufficient power and opportunity to derail the adoption or implementation of reform. These may include politicians, administrative officials, or international actors. Second, ‘proposal’ actors – often the same as above but often including civil society and others outside the system – have essentially an agenda setting role although they may not be part of the formulation. While they may not stop reform, they can frustrate it, make it costly and reformulate agendas that detract from its implementation. While these two groups are usually focused on the large reform program, a third group of actors, interest groups, may have more narrow interests that wax and wane depending on the policy’s impact on their narrow interests (e.g. street vendors in tax administration issues). Their relative weight and access 3 are minimal but not insignificant for they can be enlisted by other actors or simply cumulate their displeasure or support into proposal or veto levels. The presence, weight, and effect of each of these categories of actors should be examined within each policy area. III. Phases of reform: discrete reform moments. In analyzing progress in reform it is useful to recognize distinct phases of reform and how the peculiar configuration of institutions, actors and interests impinge on events and outcomes at each phase. Several studies suggest reform has at least three phases, with each having different opportunities and vulnerabilities, which would be useful to examine. Case studies for public sector reform may consider any of three (not exclusive) models: (political decision instrumentation implementation) (initiation formulation implementation) (commitment building coalition building implementation) As much as possible, the case studies should provide analysis of events within these discrete stages. Although analytically distinct these stages are inter-connected arenas on which actors, interests and institutions compete and each outcome often frames the next contest (eliminating competition or escalating the competition) in the next arena. Moreover, the discussion on the phases of reform should consider an important principle from the theoretical and case study literature that proposes that the extent and possibility of reform is greatest at times of crisis and/or honeymoon for regimes. The coincidence of reform phases with the opportunity structure in the macro as well as the proximate policy/political environment is worth examining. IV. Other Variables to Consider The theoretical and case study literature also suggests several other variables as having potentially significant explanatory power for public sector reform success or failure. Several of these variables may fruitfully be explored within the context of the broader variables discussed above. If they carry overriding significance by themselves in a particular reform arena, they ought to be investigated and discussed separately. Among these, the most prominent are: leadership at various levels, bureaucratic arrangements behind reform implementation (PIUs), the pace of reform (gradual vs. swift), effects of international pressure and/or comparative experiences, other related and unrelated reforms, compensation mechanisms for ‘losers’, etc. 14. Within the overall framework outlined above, the case studies will: Identify potential winners and losers of policy reforms; Show how to influence and/or manage coalition development to enhance chances of reform success; Estimate the effect of different stakeholder positions on likelihood of reform consensus; Show how stakeholders move over time in response to one another; and Predict the extent of reform and level of support. 15. Each case study would identify the key incentives for and against reform faced by the relevant decision-makers, how coalitions are built and sustained, and show how decisions taken are a function of the values that key variables assume (likely variables for analysis are decision makers' discount rates, control over resource allocation, control over patronage positions, popularity of reform measures, etc.). In sum, each case study would identify the costs and 4 benefits of reform to decision-makers and constituencies in order to explain why some reforms are supported and others are not. The case studies would also investigate how decision-makers' incentives impact the quality and nature of reforms (for example, why some governments tend to opt for ad hoc measures over more comprehensive ones, and under what conditions more comprehensive reforms are preferred). 16. The case studies would present their findings as generalized hypotheses to be confirmed in other circumstances and countries, while also identifying the particularities of the Philippines case. 5 PART TWO Structure of the Case Studies 17. This conceptual framework will be elaborated to guide the five case studies on public sector reform in Philippines in order to provide a common basis for comparison. Specifically, the framework will be adapted by adding variables peculiar to each reform area. The case studies should endeavor to meet two equally important objectives: first, to provide a theoretically informed and rigorous analysis of progress in each reform area; and second, to provide analysis responsive to a common framework that allows comparison and the drawing of transferable lessons about the political economy of public sector reform 18. The five case studies will cover the following public sector reform areas: Decentralization reform; Civil service reform; Tax administration reform; Public expenditure management reforms; and Procurement reforms. 19. Specifically, each case study is expected to have the following components: a) Executive Summary Summarizing the main findings and lessons of the research, including highlights of data, trends, and possible lessons; [2 pages] b) Introduction and Conceptual Framework An elaboration of the variables in framework and additional ones drawn from the theoretical and case study literature on each reform area. [2 pages] c) Detailed Analysis Detailed reporting of the main findings on the reform dynamics the particular area of public sector reform in Philippines. This analysis should follow the framework proposed with deviations and additions as warranted by the evidence examined and the author’s best judgment. [15 pages] d) Conclusion e) Bibliography f) Annexes [2 pages] 6 Amitabha Mukherjee N:\Amit\Philippines\Decentralization Study (P078066)\PEFA\030318_Philippines PEFA Study Framework_Draft.doc March 18, 2003 11:19 PM 7