Emergency wards raise maternity fee for non-locals Summary of the news Public hospitals agreed to almost double the fees for non-local women giving birth in emergency wards, to HK$90,000. Pregnant mainland women will have to show their marriage certificate and their husband’s Hong Kong identity card to book a bed at private obstetrics departments after The Hospital Authority confirmed that no mainland woman not married to a local man would be allowed to give birth in Hong Kong next year. Introduction The number of mainland mothers giving birth in Hong Kong is increasing rapidly, because of the right of abode in Hong Kong and higher quality medical services offered. This led to a fierce competition for birth places. There is an excess demand of obstetric services in public hospitals. In order to protect the rights of Hong Kong pregnant women, Chief executive-elect Leung Chun-ying said that there would be a quota of ‘zero’ for mainland births next year. Public hospitals agreed to raise maternity fees for non-local women giving birth in emergency wards, to HK$90,000 so as to prevent the abuse of emergency childbirth services. Scarcity, Opportunity cost and excess demand can be applied in this case. P. 1 Economic Analysis Firstly, we look into the current market of obstetric services in public hospital. Since the beds in public hospitals are limited, the supply curve of obstetric services is vertical. The HKSAR government has to fulfill its function on income redistribution; it runs the public hospitals and provides lowly-charged medical services. The government controlled price (P1) is set below the equilibrium price (P*). At the current price (P1), the quantity demanded is larger than the quantity supplied; there is an excess demand for the obstetric services in public hospital. As the price of public hospital service is much lower than the private one and the obstetric services in public hospitals are scarce goods, therefore both the Hong Kong and mainland mothers compete vigorously for the beds in public hospitals. Many Hong Kong mothers are discriminated against in the competition, and this results in many complaints about the exploitation of Hong Kong people’s welfare. Moreover, private hospitals found that obstetric services are in shortage and they can earn high profits by offering them. They recruit doctors and nurses from public hospitals with high income. This leads to a shortage of labour in public hospitals. This creates another problem, which is the deteriorating quality in services provided by public hospitals. In order to solve the problem of exploitation of Hong Kong mothers’ welfare by non-local mothers, the HKSAR government plans to prohibit non-locals from giving birth in Hong Kong. P. 2 Secondly, we can look into the demand curve for obstetric services in public hospitals in the future. Since the non-locals are not allowed to give birth in Hong Kong, with the change in government policy, the demand curve for obstetric services in public hospitals shifts to the left. There is a decrease in demand from D1 to D2 (see diagram2). However, we should aware that emergency delivery services are still available. Some non-local mothers may take the chance to give birth in Hong Kong by going to the emergency wards in public hospitals. As emergency delivery services are a substitute to appointed obstetric services, a decrease in the demand of appointed obstetric services will lead to an increase in the demand of emergency delivery services in public hospitals. Its demand curve shifts rightward from D1 to D2 (see diagram3). In order to prevent the overload on P. 3 emergency wards, all the public hospitals agreed to raise maternity fees for non-local women giving birth in emergency wards, to HK$90,000. Thirdly, we can look into the market of emergency delivery services in public hospitals, to see whether the above measure can help. The supply of emergency delivery services in public hospitals is fixed, therefore its supply curve is vertical. The current maternity fee in public hospitals is around $45,000. At the price of $45,000, there is an excess demand (a). After raising the price to $HK90,000, excess demand (b) may still occur. From diagram 4, we can see that the length of b is shorter than a. Therefore, the problem of shortage will be less serious after the price is increased. In addition, we can see that if the price is raised to the equilibrium price (P*), there will be no excess demand. Therefore we can conclude that raising the price can help tackle the problem of excess demand on emergency delivery services and prevent the abuses of emergency wards. However, the price should not be set too high. Otherwise, those who are really in need cannot afford these services. There will also be an excess supply when the price is set above the equilibrium price. Although the HKSAR government prohibits non-local women from giving birth in Hong Kong and raises the maternity fees in public emergency wards, some of the non-locals try hard to give birth in Hong Kong through illegal ways. They acquire fake marriage certificates and men’s identity cards through some agencies in Shenzhen at a low price. Their action can be explained by opportunity cost. P. 4 The benefits of giving birth in Hong Kong are that the quality of obstetric services in Hong Kong is high and the risk is relatively lower than that of the mainland. The most important is that children born in Hong Kong can have the right of abode in Hong Kong. They can enjoy the benefits of free education, social welfare programs, legal protection and a higher living standard in Hong Kong. In addition, mainland women are no longer bound by the ‘One-child policy’ in China; they can give birth to more than one baby in Hong Kong. However, there are also costs. First, giving birth in emergency wards is not safe and the risk of death to babies and mothers are higher. Second, using false documents is a criminal act and can result in imprisonment. Despite a higher cost, the mainland mothers will still give birth in Hong Kong if they think that marginal benefits are higher than the marginal costs. They will opt for an illegal way to come to Hong Kong. Conclusion The conflicts between mainland and Hong Kong mothers upon ‘beds’ can be solved after the announcement of a ‘zero’ quota for mainland births in the future. Though this increases the chance of emergency deliveries, raising the fee for non-local women giving birth in emergency wards will be effective in maintaining the quality of emergency services provided by public hospitals. I believe that the workload of medical personnel can be lowered under this policy; hopefully the quality of medical services, especially the obstetric area, provided by public hospitals can be improved. However, private hospitals will suffer from this policy in the short term. They will lose their high earnings from obstetric services. They should develop other profitable services in order to maintain their operations. Government intervention brings both pros and cons to different interest groups in this issue. It protects the rights of Hong Kong mothers successfully; however, it also hinders the development of some private hospitals. I agree that this time the government should speak out and protect the rights of Hong Kong mothers. Nevertheless, the government should be aware not to abuse its power. Otherwise, the market cannot be run efficiently. This will bring negative impacts to the Hong Kong economy. In addition, to solve the problem of mainland women giving birth in Hong Kong entirely, I think the issue of whether to give the new-born babies the right of abode in Hong Kong or not should be a major concern. P. 5