Mutuality and state welfare: a historical comparison between Britain and Japan Minoru Takada (Kyushu International University) Introduction Welfare is an amorphous complex consisting of multiple principles and many different agencies; the relationships between the constituents have changed in accordance with historical context1. Family, community, charity organisation, company, local government and the state have provided various supports for their members through paternalism, philanthropy, commercial and public insurances, and tax-based assistance. Mutuality has been certainly one of the most important components as well. It was a fundamental principle for developing insurance and pensions in private and public sectors. Mutuality was crystallised in voluntary associations such as trade unions, friendly societies, and cooperative societies in the private sector2. The principle was As to the argument of ‘mixed economy of welfare’, see, P. Thane, ‘Histories of the welfare states’ in W. Lamont ed., Historical controversies and historians, UCL Press, 1998; M. Daunton, ed., Charity, Self-interest and Welfare in the English Past, UCL Press, 1996; M.B. Katz and C. Sachße eds., The Mixed Economy of Social Welfare: Public/ Private Relations in England, Germany, and the United State, the 1870’s to the 1930’s, Nomos Verlaggesellschaft, 1996. 2 As to the origins and continuity of association, see, M.F. Robinson, The Spirit of Association: Being some Account of the Gilds, Friendly Societies, Cooperative Movement, and Trade Unions of Great Britain, John Marry, 1913; P. Clark, British Clubs and Societies 1580-1800: the Origins of an Associational World, Oxford University Press, 2000. As to mutual aid associations, see, M. Gorsky, ‘The Growth and Distribution of English Friendly Societies in the Early Nineteenth Century’, Economic History Review, vol.51, 1998, pp. 489-511; do. ‘Mutual Aid and Civil Society: Friendly Soceities in Nineteenth-century Bristol’, Urban History, vol. 25, 1998; P. Johnson, Saving and Spending: The Working-Class Economy in Britain 1870-1939, Oxford University Press, 1985;E. Hopkins, Working-class Self-help in Nineteenth Century England: Responses to Industrialisation, UCL Press, 1995; P. Gurney, Cooperative Culture and the Politics of Consumption in England, c.1870-1930, Manchester University Press, 1996; K. Fukasawa, Voluntary Provision for Old Age by Trade Unions in Britain before the Coming of the Welfare State, unpublished Ph.D. thesis, University of London, 1996; do. ‘From Superannuation to State Old-Age Pensions: the Development of Trade Union’s View’ in Ad Knotter et al. eds, Labour, Social Policy, and the Welfare State, 1 1 transplanted in the public sector since the late nineteenth-century. National insurance system was a typical example of the transformation, in which all the players of society compulsorily participate under the state power. The welfare state after the Second World War might be partly interpreted as the historical result of institutionalising mutuality as a state system. In this sense the principle of mutuality has continuity than has been thought, although its forms underwent big changes. Nevertheless, the cardinal principle of mutuality as well as the institutions of the welfare state has been seriously damaged by the expanding market economy principle for the last quarter of century. Now, the total structure of welfare complex is changing drastically. This paper aims to examine the historical function of mutuality in the process of welfare state formation by comparing the British experience with the Japanese one in the nineteenth- and twentieth-centuries: that is a comparison between the early starter of the welfare state and the late comer. The examination was conducted mainly on the British case3, and then, by comparison, some characteristic features would be roughly suggested for the Japanese case4. The three questions are to be considered here. First, how did mutuality develop in the two countries in the terms of institutions and culture? Friendly society was not simple benefit society, but also cultural being. The culture was unique, and it constructed a peculiar identity of membership. The institutional function of mutual-help and socio-cultural implication of being the members of the societies cannot be separated. Stiching beheer IISG, pp. 111-124. As to charity, see, M. Gorsky., Patterns of Philanthropy: Charity and Society in Nineteenth Century Bristol, Boydell, 1999. 3 As to the British case, see, my papers, M. Takada, ‘The Ancient Order of Foresters Friendly Society and the Old Age Pensions in Early Twentieth-century Britain’, KIU Journal of Business Studies and Economics, vol.8, 2001、pp. 99-134; do, ‘The Administration of Old Age Pensions and the Intermediate Bodies in Britain, 1909-18’, KIU Journal of Business Studies and Economics, vol. 9, 2003, pp, 123-235. 4 As to international comparison of mutualism, see, Marcel van der Linden ed., Social Security Mutualism: the Comparative History of Mutual Benefit Societies, Peter Lang, 1996. 2 The relationship will be made clear. Secondly, how was mutuality transplanted in the state welfare? What was the driving force for the change in cultural terms? Although the friendly societies were one of the most popular welfare agencies, since the late-nineteenth century they faced to the limitations in terms of membership and finance. This crisis was overcome with help of the state. But friendly society needed a new justification for accepting the state help which seemed to be hostile to its prime principle of ‘independence’. The society culturally constructed a new concept of the state. The process will be examined. Lastly, what impact did the perception of foreign welfare reforms have on the welfare state formation in Japan? Japan, as a late starter of modernisation, tried to catch up the Western society since the 1860s. Germany and Britain were great models in the field of welfare reform, although both states provided with different types of social services. German impact was bigger than British one before the Second World War, but after the War it was changed. The process will be analysed. In considering these questions, the attention was specially paid on the problem of inclusion and exclusion, and on the co-relationship between institution and discourse. The development of mutuality in the nineteenth century Firs of all, this paper starts with surveying the institutions of mutuality, and its cultural implication in the nineteenth century. Medieval community was dissolved in the process of industrialisation, and the vacuum of communality was fulfilled by voluntary associations, such as trade unions, friendly society, and cooperative society in Britain. In this paper the main focus is upon friendly society. The membership of the society was more than seven millions in its heyday, which was larger than that of trade union. The 3 friendly societies in the both countries provided sick and burial benefits for their members as of right on the condition of the regular contribution as of duty. But they were more than benefit societies; they were culturally constructed as well. The latter aspect was indispensable for cementing the mutual bond of the members in both countries. In Britain the members were asked to share a common quality of ‘respectability’: a sense of ‘intelligent and truer self-help’. The regular payment of contribution was praised as ‘self-denial’ practice. The active participation in administrating the society was encouraged as conduct of ‘good citizenship’. The society had strict rule decided by the general meeting; elected executive committee managed the society business; and breach of the rule was strictly fined. In other words, the friendly society was a kind of the state in miniature with the functions of legislation, administration, and justice. In fact, the executive committee encouraged their members to participate in the administration by using the analogy of the state and citizenship: ‘those associations [friendly societies or trade unions] which have sprung from the people themselves afford numerous opportunities for those capable of governing, of experiencing their opportunities, and educating themselves to fulfil to such situations in the State as may from time to time to be offered to them’5. The respectability must be visualised: the membership certificate beautifully decorated, the sashes and badges put on the cloths, and the procession with big flags in the city centre after the meeting. Ritual and ceremonies also played an important role6. Those cultural tools contributed to enhancing their comradeship as the first class citizens. Their identity distinguished the ‘voluntary’ and ‘mutual’ nature of their association 5 6 Foresters’ Miscellany, Jan., 1882, p. 8. S. Cordery, British Friendly Societies, 1750-1914, Palgrave, 2003, esp. ch. 2. 4 from the commercial insurance: ‘Commercialism means money and costs money. Given a purely mutual Friendly Society founded by the people, governed by the people, for the protection of the people, there can be no gainsaying the fact that the greatest help and economy prevail’ 7 . Moreover, ‘communal’ nature of the society was emphasised: ‘Friendly Society thrift differs from other forms of thrift, especially as compared with the deposits in saving banks, or membership of a comparative society or building society, these forms of thrift are purely personal, whereas Friendly Society thrift is communal’8. The friendly society was proud of this ‘communism’: ‘they were teaching a truer and nobler communism, a communism that would promote kindness, humanity and brotherly feeling, by obeying the great junction of bearing each other’s burdens’ 9. Nevertheless, friendly society could not be stable without state help. Many societies lacked actuarial soundness, and they were often thrown into bankruptcy. The government intervened to improve this aspect, and it imposed them the duty of registration. Protection and preferential treatment was given to the society in exchange of registration under the Friendly Societies Acts. Cheap government did not necessarily mean laissez-faire state; it actively intervened into the society to build and keep the framework within which the agencies of society sufficiently could carry out their functions. The state was ‘small’ and ‘minimal’, but it was also ‘regulatory’ and ‘strong’.10 Foresters’ Miscellany, Feb., 1900, p. 547. Foresters’ Miscellany, Sep., 1909, p. 396. 9 Foresters’ Miscellany, Dec., 1907. pp. 963-964. 10 As to the relationship between the state and society, see, J. Brewer, The Sinews of Power: War, Money, and the English State, 1688-1783, Century Hutchinson, 1989; P. Harding and P. Mander, ‘From "Fiscal-military" State to Laissez-faire State, 1760-1850’, Journal of British Studies, vol. 32, 1993; J. Harris, Private Lives, Public Spirit: A Social History of Britain, 1870-1914, Oxford University Press, 1993P. Thane ‘Government and society in England and Wales, 1750-1914’, in F.M.L. Thompson ed. The Cambridge Social History of Britain, 1750-1950, vol.3, 1990; J. Harris, ‘Society and the State in Twentieth-century Britain’, in ibid.; M. Daunton, Trusting Leviathan: the 7 8 5 The friendly society, however, was not available to all. It has a definite borderline of inclusion and exclusion. Lower-waged workers could not join the society because of the difficulty of continuing to pay the subscription. Women were also excluded from the masculine world, except as the wife of male members; women were not expected to be active citizens in friendly society. Moreover, the members who could not observe the society’s moral code were often forcefully expelled. Their behaviour, particularly during the period of receiving the benefits, was kept under close surveillance. Sick visitors regularly visited ill members with dual purposes of caring and checking. If some member receiving sick pay was found in a pub, he was to be fined. If he repeated unrespectable behaviour, he was to be expelled from the society. In cultural terms, this was legitimatised by referring to the past: the memory of the Greek and Roman Clubs was mobilised. ‘The point I want to make clear is that in Greek and Roman societies there was not only an insurance at death, such as we have today, but that in the Roman Club an attempt was also made, as we are doing today, to exclude from membership any undesirable persons as members’11. The memorised, therefore constructed, antiquity played an important role of justifying the reality of exclusion in the modern friendly society. In the case of Japan, there were similar bodies as friendly societies. Yet, they were different from British ones in terms of coverage and historical character. There were two types of friendly societies. One is an old type of artisans confined in coal mining (Tomoko), which was similar as a guild in Europe. This type of society controlled labour Politics of Taxation in Britain, 1799-1914, Cambridge University Press, 2001; do., Just Taxes: The Politics of Taxation in Britain, 1914-1979,Cambridge University Press, 2002. As to the Friendly Societies Act, see P.H.J.H. Gosden, The Friendly Societeis in England 1815-75, Mancheser University Press, 1961. 11 Foresters’ Miscellany, Jan., 1900, p. 6. 6 supply to keep wage at a certain level, and prevented non-member from entering the labour market. It provided sick, burial, and unemployment benefits to the members; and some societies had a labour exchange function. As in British friendly society, it also had a strict rule, and if members breached it, they had to leave the society. Ritual was also essential to it. This type society had a long life than has been thought, and it survived the industrial revolution in Japan. It was eventually transformed into the trade union12. The other one is modern type (Kyosaikumiai) which was closely associated with company welfare. Around the turn of the last century, in facing the social problems of injury in factories and poverty caused by the industrial revolution, the company owners in both private and public sectors recognised the necessity of organising mutual-aid society in their companies in order to alleviate the problems. The idea was borrowed from Europe. The bureaucrats and company owners shared the organic theory of society and the state. Under their initiative, modern friendly societies were established to promote social solidarity in the organism. The members were limited to the middle- and upper classes of workers with permanent employment; and they contributed to 3 or 5 % of wage to the society’s fund. The societies were expected to provide benefits for death, sick, and factory injury. In this respect, they were similar with European societies. Yet, the culture was more tightly tied with work space and work ethic rather than civil society; ‘working diligently’ was the best values to be followed. It is because the society was organised in each company; it had, therefore, often an affinity with the ‘paternalism of company welfare’. Company itself, in fact, regularly contributed the considerable amount money to the fund of friendly society. Horizontal solidarity of workers, such as nationwide Orders in Britain, could not be seen in Japan. Rather, cooperation with the 12 N. Murakushi, Traditional Industrial Relationship in Japan (in Japanese), Tokyo, 1989 ; do, Coal miners in Japan: a history of Tomoko system (in Japanese), Tokyo, 1998. 7 specific company became the main feature of mutual help, which contributed to industrial efficiency of the company. In the end, the friendly societies in Japan were organised from the above by the industrial bosses and the state bureaucrats, and the ‘voluntary’ aspect of mutuality was extremely weak. Mutuality was prone to be utilised to enhance the royalty to the company, a sense of ‘for the sake of company’s interest’, which is a historical foundation of so called ‘Japanese companyism’13. In addition to that, the bureaucrats expected the mutual-help associations the role of supplementing minimal nature of public assistance. Public/private distinction was, unique in Japanese society. Public sphere organised from the top with imperial authority was far above and separated from the society of ordinary people. The mutual-aid society, in reality, played a role of substituting public help as an obligation of a member of organic society. It is interesting to pay attention to the similarity and difference of the parts the state played between the two countries. Both governments were ‘minimal’ and ‘regulatory’, but the primary motive behind was entirely opposite: the British one is to encourage civil society, and the Japanese one is to police the society. The material and cultural aspects were interwoven, and the mixture maintained the friendly societies as the associations of mutuality in the modern society. Yet the historical context differentiated the functions of the friendly societies between the two countries. The individuals were protected through the collective and ‘communal’, not ‘purely personal’, self-help. 13 As to the new type society, see, T. Saguchi, A History of Social Insurance Scheme in Japan(in Japanese), Tokyo, 1977, ch. 2; T, Ikeda, A History of Social Welfare in Japan (in Japanese), Tokyo, 1986, pp. 420-431. 8 The limitations of voluntary mutual-aid and the emergence of the state welfare in the early twentieth century The collective self-help in the forms of friendly association, however, had serious limitation. The limit became to be realised since the late nineteenth century, and movements for the new state welfare occurred. In terms of international comparison, it is interesting enough that the state welfare was introduced in the 1900s and the 1910s, in almost same years, although economic and political conditions were very different from country to country14. The lower wage workers, the ‘non-respectable’ people, and women were often left outside the mutuality as mentioned above; they were consciously excluded out of it. In addition to that, the friendly society itself faced the organisational crisis: the membership became stagnant, resulting in a financial instability since the late nineteenth century. Ageing of the members also worsened the financial situation by increasing the expenditure for sick pay as a real old age pension. The competition with other welfare agencies became severer as commercial insurance and dividing society became more popular. In terms of finance, the friendly society invented some relief fund systems to redistribute the burdens within the society, but it was not sufficient for coping with the difficulty. It is indispensable, therefore, to recruit new members for improving this serious situation. One of the expedients was to reform its exclusive structure. The friendly society loosened the condition for membership: the age was lowered to zero, juvenile section was built, and women were more positively welcomed by modifying the rule. The Friendly Societies Act also endorsed the revisions. The society tried to 14 P. Thane, The Foundations of the Welfare State, 2nd edn, London. 1996, ch. 6. 9 become more inclusive in terms of the institutional structure15. Nevertheless the problem of exclusion still remained. The necessity of continuous subscription remained a block to the lower waged workers, and moral barrier was also not applicable to all the member of the nation. The problems with the exclusive nature became to be gradually recognised by both the friendly societies, and the politicians and the state bureaucrats. Their eyes to the excluded people brought to the fore the new idea of mobilising the state power more positively in the late nineteenth-century. In the debates of the state pensions, the growing concern about the miserable condition of poor women was important. For example, leading politicians, like Asquith or Lloyd-George, talked against the contributory state pension scheme, on the ground that many of working class, particularly women, had been excluded from the friendly societies with contributory scheme. They also suggested the supplementary role of the friendly societies to fill the gap left after the introduction of the state pension16. Friendly society, however, could not accept the proposition initially because of a strong ethic of ‘independence’17. It seemed moral decay for the society to accept the state help, i.e., an external help. This spirit of ‘independent’ was even characterised as national identity: ‘the spirit of independence is stronger in Englishmen than in the habitants of other State’. Extremely enough it was alleged that, because of the very sprit, ‘a great number prefer to accept death early rather than seek to prolong life at the expense of other people’18. It was also insisted that ‘they [working men] know they are capable of managing’; that ‘our objection is to the working-class being singled out as 15 About the details, see my paper (AOF). The Parliamentary Debates, vol. 180, 1908, cols. 564-587 (16 June, 1908). 17 As to the debates in friendly society over the state pensions, see, J.H. Treble, ‘The Attitudes of Friendly Societies towards the Movement in Great Britain for State Pensions, 1878-1908’, International Review of Social History, vol. 15, 1970, pp. 266-99; 18 Foresters’ Miscellany, Jan. 1882, p.3. 16 10 the class which require nursing from the cradle to the grave’; and that ‘their history of the past thirty years, as written in their own organizations, proves indisputably that they are competent, and will ultimately “work out their own redemption”’ 19 This was another important reason against the state intervention. It should be borne in mind that independence was consistently the first imperative for their argument, and that any measures to injure this basic sprit would never acceptable for them at all. Moreover, they disliked the National Insurance because participation and self-government was lacked in the system. They said, ‘if National Insurance were established it would injure those organizations of the people, for it would lack this one essential element--- the contributors would have no voice in the management of the fund.’20 The notion of ratepayers’ democracy accompanying participation and self-government played a crucial role for opposing the state insurance. This would also have continuity. The spirit of associational culture was the important basis for criticising state welfare at least at this initial stage of state pension debates in the 1880s. Yet, in the 1890s and 1900s the tone of argument changed. The factors promoting the change were the worsening financial situation, and the increasing concern to the excluded person from the help of voluntary associations. How did the friendly societies change their attitudes to the state welfare? Their justification was quite interesting. They constructed the new image of the state as the extended entity of their cardinal principle of mutual-help. The state was no longer to be the other; it was to be the expanded themselves. One leader said: By all means let us preach self-help, applying it to the trade and friendly associations, but not to stop there. The same spirit must lead people more and 19 20 Foresters’ Miscellany, Jan. 1882, p.9. Foresters’ Miscellany, Jan. 1882, p.8. 11 more to recognise that the State is themselves, and learning their power in this direction will use their collective capacity for dealing with these problems that affect our national life, and in doing so they will be exercising the principle of self-help in its truer sense.21 Another leader also pointed out the same thing: It seems desirable to promote the idea that the Government is ourselves, organised for collective purpose regarding the State as a great benefit society of which the whole body of citizens are member. The provision of Pensions for the aged appears me an obvious expansion of the democratic idea22. Significantly the state intervention was legitimatized as an extended mutuality. In this way stubborn friendly society eventually became a supporter of the state welfare in the case of state pension. They found a new proper space of supplementing the state welfare in the mixed economy of welfare. In the case of the National Insurance Act of 1911, the clash between friendly societies and the state was severer, because they battled over the limited resources for subscription of the people. But in this case, the successful adjustment was made again; the friendly societies were given a privileged position of ‘approved society’, and they underpinned the administration of the state insurance. Their principle was transplanted in the state insurance, within which their organisation played a practical role. The fresh and close relationship with the state was built up. This brought a satisfactory result, at least in terms of membership. After the introduction of the National Insurance Act the membership rapidly increased, and in the 1920s and 30s, the friendly society entered ‘the new Golden Age’ underpinned by the network of the state insurance, although a 21 22 Foresters’ Miscellany, Oct. 1897. Foresters’ Miscellany, Jan. 1898. 12 conflict between voluntary and state sectors in the society became severer, leading to a kind of identity crisis: what was ‘voluntary’ association?. The above notion of ‘the government is ourselves’ was embodied in this context to the greater extent. The voluntary association of mutuality could not be separated from the state welfare; rather it was an important historical and practical foundation for expanding the state welfare in Britain, at least before the Second World War. On the other hand, in Japan, associations of mutuality gave little impact on the introduction and the expansion of state welfare. The perception of public relief as of right, in general, was weak. If the relief was provided, it should be appreciated as a ‘mercy of the emperor’ in modern Japan. In contrast, obligation was imposed on the subjects of the emperor. The Relief Ordinance was issued in 1874: it provided that ‘it is the obligation of the subjects to help the destitute and the disabled with a feeling of compassion’. The obligation was met in the forms of ‘mutual-aid of neighbourhood’ (Rinposoufu) as well as ‘family’ or ‘self-help’. The fundamental ideology was an extreme version of paternalism. The emperor with absolute power was to be merciful father as well as holy and authentic ruler. The state was taken as an enlarged ‘family’ with the patriarchal authority of the emperor. The mixture of the obligation of self-help, family, and the local community was the basis of modern welfare in Japan. The limitation of the system became clearer and new measures were needed around the turn of the century. Since then the labour problem and the poverty had attracted special attention from politicians, social reformers, and academics. After the Rice Riot of 1918, the movement toward introducing the national insurance was facilitated. The national insurance was first introduced in 1927, and it was enlarged as a measure to grow up ‘sound soldiers’ in the 1930s and the 1940s. The surface of the insurance 13 system was modern, but it was ‘paternalistic’. It might be interpreted as institutionalising the extended mutuality, but the character of the mutuality was different from that in Britain. The duty of contribution to support the poverty stricken comrade as ‘the subject’ was much more emphasised: the notion of the right to benefit was very weak. The ‘family’ image of the state was emphasised, so the obligation of the family member to the state. Although there was a debate over participation of the trade unions, or agricultural unions into the administration of the state insurance, it was denied on the ground the ‘democratic participation’ of the ‘voluntary’ association might be disturbing the monolithic nature of the state solidarity. The strong state was underpinned by the notion of ‘family’ image of the state and the ‘family members’ obligation’ to the state. The local community, another important intermediate body, was also compulsorily charged the obligation to look after neighbours, because it was a part of ‘organic’ entity, although we do not have enough space to discuss this aspect here. In any way, the metaphor of family had the effect of creating a strong sense of nation identity, which resulted in forging the unique welfare regime in Japan23. The process of establishing state welfare in Japan was very different from the British case. In the former, the limitation of voluntary associations of mutuality did not give any impact on introducing the state welfare at all; the reverse is the fact. Minimal state welfare was introduced bureaucratically from the above for the purpose of keeping social order. Little attention was paid to the role of the existing mutual aid society,. Takashi Saguchi insisted: ‘we cannot trace the roots of Japanese social insurance into friendly societies and trade unions’24. In this way the paternalistic and nationalistic state 23 M.Takahashi, The Emergence of Welfare Society in Japan, Aldershot, 1997, pp. 33-54; Y. Aizawa, The Making of Social Insurance in Japan (in Japanese), Tokyo, 2003. 24 Saguchi, op. cit, p. 126. 14 welfare was introduced in Japan. Yet, we should not overlook the common features that the role of the state should remain ‘minimal’ even under the entirely different political regimes; the more space was to be left for the other welfare agencies. It is true that the state welfare was more inclusive than any other welfare measures, but it did not necessarily solve the problem of inclusion and exclusion. Rather the state welfare drew a new boundary between the nation and the non-nation25. The nation within the boundary was treated better than before, but the non-nation was excluded with more mighty power of the state. Significantly ‘the nation’ to be relieved has been constructed in accordance with the norms defined in a series of the welfare laws. Especially, nationality was crucial for becoming the recipients of the new state welfare measures. Moreover, the notion of nationality usually entailed a stronger bias to some peoples than before; the bias was associated with literacy. As the result, the state welfare was harsher for some groups, especially the ethnic minority. For example, in Britain, in the debates of the Alien Act of 1905, Prime Minister, A. Balfour had said: ‘We have the right to keep out everybody who does not add to the strength of community—the industrial, social, and intellectual strength of the community’26. After the introduction of the National Insurance Act, a Home Office circular of 1912 explained: ‘a person who can have no claim to be invested with the full rights of British nationality in the United Kingdom if he has not identified with the life and habits of the country to the extent of P. Thane, ‘The British Imperial State and the Construction of National Identities’, in B. Melman ed., Borderlines: Genders and Identities in War and Peace, 1870-1930, Routledge, pp. 29-46. As to the problem of inclusion and exclusion in the pension administration, see, my paper (the Administration), and M. Jones, ‘The 1908 Old Age Pensions Act; the Poor Law in New Disguise’, K. Laybourn ed., Social Conditions, Satus and Community, Sutton Press, 1997. 26 D. Feldman, Englishmen and Jews: Social Relations and Political Culture, 1840-1914, Yale University Press, 1994, p. 287. 25 15 becoming reasonably proficient in the language’. 27 Jewish people without being naturalised were sometimes out of the state pensions. In Japan as a late-comer imperial state, the more cruel racial discrimination occurred against the Asian immigrants, in particular the Korean and the Chinese, many of whom were often enforced to move from their native country against their will. There were many cases that those ethnic groups in both counties were protected better in voluntary provisions or by the Poor Law 28 : one of the pension officers said ‘The Poor Law makes no distinction of nationality, and an alien who becomes destitute is just as much entitled to relief as a natural-born English citizen’29. The residual role of the Poor Law was the characteristic feature of British welfare system.30 The development of welfare was neither linear nor progressive in a simple way. Inclusion and exclusion in welfare were overlapped in such a complicated way. Each social group had its own cultural identity, and it drew a social boundary between self and the others. In the field of welfare, the excluded persons outside the border were cared by the other agencies which had often wider coverage and were more inclusive in the nature. A new system was introduced, and the new identity, in turn, was constructed. The cultural identity again strengthened the institutional framework of the new welfare system. The state had more mighty power than the other welfare agencies; it resulted in more protection and more constraint, or more inclusion and stronger exclusion. 27 Ibid, p. 376. R. Kalman, ‘The Jewish Friendly Societies of London, 1793-1993’, Jewish Historical Studies, vol. 33, 1995, pp. 141-161; V. Lipman, A Century of Social Service, 1859-1959: the History of Jewish Board of Guardians, Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1959; D. Feldman, op. cit., ch. 11, 12, and 13. 29 London County Council, Minutes of Evidence, 1909, p. 628. 30 J.Harris, ‘From Poor Law to Welfare State?: a European Perspective’, in D. Winch and P.K. O’Brien eds, The Political Economy of British Historical Experience 1688-1914, Oxford University Press, 2002. 28 16 The perception of the British model and the welfare state formation in Japan Lastly, the foreign experience was important for the ‘welfare state formation’ in Japan: above all the perception of the European welfare reforms was crucial. A reform movement for modernisation (the Meiji Restoration) took place in the 1860. The reformers sought to introduce a series of the Western culture to modernise the ancient regime of Japanese society: constitution, laws, political institutions, military organisation, and economic system were introduced from Prussia, France, and Britain. The ‘advanced’ and ‘progressive’ image of ‘the Western’ culture, in general, played a decisive role. Around the turn of the twentieth century, politicians, social reformers, and academics paid urgent attention to the labour problem and poverty. Although their stances were different to each others, they were common in seeking the resolutions in the experiences of Europe, particularly Germany and Britain. They were obsessed with the ‘backwardness’ of Japanese ‘social policy’, although the word meant rather ‘labour policy’ at the moment. They studied the British labour policy as ‘pioneering attempt’ to ‘preserve the value of labour forces’, i.e. the Factory Acts, and the German social policy as the successful example of social insurance. They learned the Poor Law and the Elberfelt system as a local public assistance as well. In the late-nineteenth century, Japanese scholars and bureaucrats learned social researches of Charles Booth and Seebohm Rowntree, and they embarked on the similar researches by themselves in the big cities, which made clear of the extent of social problem in Japan. Settlement movement was also organised by intellectuals and students as a result of study on Toynbee Hall, although the movement was converted into enhancing obligatory community help rather than social reform. 17 Yet, they admired the German model in particular, because the political regime of empire was acceptable to them: in fact, the constitution had been introduced from Germany. Bismarck Social Insurance, and the welfare reforms based on the social right ideas in the Weimar Republic were also studied well. In the late 1930s, Nazi Germany gave a big impact on Japanese public health reform: Wohlfahrtswesen or Wholfahrtsphlege were imported and utilised to in Japan. The ruling class preferred a hierarchical and ordered society to a liberal society. As the Japan’s state sought to be stronger, so became its ideological link with German welfare idea; diplomatic and military strategy promoted the linkage. From the 1930s warfare and welfare went hand-in-hand; welfare was taken an necessary investment into ‘human capital’ useful to the war effort. Welfare was entirely incorporated into wartime mobilising strategy of the state. The aim of welfare became monolithic. In the end, both countries forcefully brought the neighbour nations into misery under totalitarian regime. It was after the war that the effort of reorganising welfare started, which was closely associated with the political imperatives of democratising the Japanese regime. At this moment, the British model was crucial. It was perceived as ‘advanced’, ‘pioneering’ and ‘ideal’ accompanying the image of ‘democratic’ political regime. The bureaucrats and social scientists uncritically praised the Bveridge Report, and tried to imitate the proposals in the Report almost intact. The Report was represented as one of the symbols of building democratic regime after the war. The ‘national minimum’ became fashionable among them; the state responsibility was emphasised. The words of ‘social solidarity’ and ‘mutuality’ were admired. But, paradoxically enough, these words tended to be interpreted as stressing the duty of the nation to the society, but not vice versa.31 31 K.Tamai, Inventing the Prevention of Poverty: a Study of Modern Social Policy (in Japanese), 18 In the formation of Japanese ‘welfare state’, the perception of British model was much more influential than the past experience of mutuality in its own society. In that sense, civil society was separated from the state in the Japanese welfare reform. Vitalising the civil society in the ‘welfare state’ has been and still remains a most important issue in Japan. The brief survey shows that the perception of foreign welfare reform played a crucial role in Japan. But the state never pursued any specific type of welfare regime. The primal concerns of social reformers, bureaucrats, and intellectuals waved in accordance with historical conditions, from British to German, from German to British, and the middle way between them. Moreover, the perception itself was constructed by the necessity of reform in reality. Above all, political stability was the primary interest for reformers, and foreign welfare measures, institutions, and agencies were depicted in the forms adaptable to the primary interest. Friendly society was the good example; it was one of the typical voluntary associations in Britain, but the character was transformed in Japan. Conclusion Mutuality was reality and construction in history. Although mutuality in civil society has been often idealised, the historical reality was different from the ideal. It is sometimes described that independent individuals voluntarily assembled in the association to help each others, and played a great role of mutual-aid with little support from the state in modern world. The associations would be the origins of NGO or NPO organisations, which were expected to be re-vitalised in the contemporary welfare Kyoto, 1992, esp. ch. 7. 19 debates32. But those organisations had a definite borderline of inclusion and exclusion. The line was made stronger by the cultural discourse of their identity. The sense of belonging was underpinned by the sense of moral superiority, and it was always visualised through the cultural tools, such as membership certificates, badges, sashes, and parades. The visualised image of the membership contributed to clarify the borderline more vividly. It resulted in the stronger solidarity and stability of the society, which contributed to creating reliability of mutual-aid society. The cultural power was indispensable to institutionalise mutuality. However, the excluded became problematic in terms of making stronger ‘imperial race’; the eyes to those excluded was the driving force of the welfare reform in early twentieth century Britain. The state power was mobilised to reform total structure of welfare. At this moment, the most important was how to justify the state intervention. The answer is the analogy between the friendly society and the state. The key word was that ‘the government is ourselves’; the state was the extended entity of mutuality. The identities of voluntary associations and the state synchronised in this way. Society and the state were not separable in the cultural term, but rather identical; a strong identity could create a strong solidarity of the nation. The power of culture was important in this way. But the structure of inclusion and exclusion was also transplanted in the state welfare in the same time, and it was reproduced in the wider extent with the mightier power of the state. More people came under the umbrella of state welfare, but more strongly non-nation was excluded from the state welfare. Paradoxically enough, the last resort for them were voluntary associations. The institution and the discourse of 32 P. Hirst, Associative Democracy, Polity Press, 1994; R.D. Putnam, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Princeton University Press, 1993; do., Bowling Alone: the Collapse and Revival of American Community, Simon Shuster, 2000. 20 mutuality interacted in a complex way to make the welfare state. The welfare state could not be interpreted in the simple progressive model. Although the comparison between Britain and Japan was insufficient, some points might be suggested even from the brief observation. There were mutual-aid associations in Japan, but their mutuality was entirely different from British one. It was more circumscribed by the character of civil society, although recent studies critically warned us not to idealise the British civil society33. Work ethic and royalty to the company was signified, and the coordination with those was taken into account to establish the ‘voluntary’ associations. The transplantation of mutuality into state welfare was also circumscribed by the unique notion of the state. The state was taken as ‘family’, and the nation’s obligation to the state was emphasised. Therefore, stress was put on policing rather than active participation in the field of welfare. The comparative study of the relationship between mutuality and state welfare could suggest the characteristic feature of the relationship between society and the state in each country. Moreover, this examination suggested the complex relationship between the reality and perception of the foreign experience. In the case of Japanese welfare state formation, the perception of the British model played a crucial role. Yet the perception was constructed; the idealised image of British experience as the symbol of modernity or democracy was grafted with the reality of unreformed society. This brought the contradiction in the welfare system: the minimal and paternalistic state combined with thin layer of voluntary associations, which charged the welfare burden upon family and company. Although high rate of economic growth could conceal the contradictions, the 33 F. Trentmann, Paradoxes of Civil Society: New Perspectives on Modern German and British Society, Bergahn, 2000; J. Harris, Civil Society in British History: Ideas, Identities, and Institutions, Oxford University Press, 2003. 21 existence of a big hole in the Japanese welfare system was recognised after the economic prosperity has gone away. Now new perception of welfare proper for the Japanese society was needed, and a rich cultural image of our future society is indispensable. The historical relationship between mutuality and state welfare raised the new question: how much mutuality will be perpetual after dissolving the institutions of the welfare state. 22 Minoru Takada is affiliated to Kyushu International University. Research field: the making of British welfare state. Publications: 'The Administration of Old Age Pensions and the Intermediate Bodies in Britain, 1909-18', KIU Journal of Economics and Business Studies, vol. 9, no. 3, pp. 123-235. 'The Ancient Order of Foresters Friendly Society and the Old Age Pensions in Early Twentieth-century Britain', KIU Journal of Economic and Business Studies, vol. 8, no. 1, pp. 99-134. 23