January 1999 Antitrust Remedies in High Technology Industries David A. Balto & James F. Mongoven INTRODUCTION Increasingly, the workload of the federal antitrust enforcement agencies has focused on high technology markets. This should not be surprising. Much of the growth in the U.S. economy during the last decade has been in high technology, from computers and software to biotechnology and pharmaceuticals. Beyond the importance of these industries, antitrust enforcers have recently given greater attention to the importance of high technology as an influence on growth and innovation, and how technological questions, such as the relationship between antitrust and intellectual property, should be evaluated. Some have questioned the application of the antitrust laws to high technology industries as inappropriate and ineffective. Some critics wonder whether laws initially enacted in 1890 can be effectively applied to industries that did not exist then and to patterns of trade and commerce that have evolved to serve a vastly different society. At times, this criticism is centered on the issue of remedies. The argument posed is that high tech industries are too fast moving to fashion effective antitrust remedies and that the abuse of market power will more readily be dissipated by market forces, especially ease of entry. The specific criticism concerning remedies is that the antitrust agencies will impose orders that are too broad in an attempt to sweep up all anticompetitive effects, resulting in a stifling of innovation incentives. This criticism has a grain of truth to it, but one that is used to spur a cautious approach to remedy. High technology industries do indeed exhibit some characteristics that make appropriate remedies more difficult to fashion, but that does not mean that the field should be abandoned to the play of private market forces that may be abused by anticompetitive behavior. The Federal Trade Commission takes account of the differences in high technology industries in crafting remedies that preserve competition without harming unilateral and collaborative efficiencies in research and development, manufacturing, distribution, or incentives to innovate. This article reviews the remedies used in several recent Federal Trade Commission and Department of Justice enforcement actions, including mergers and nonmergers. It considers the approach to remedy in innovation markets, networks, and vertical mergers, and addresses the use of several alternatives, including licensing, divestiture, firewalls, and trustees. It then addresses relief in several nonmerger cases. D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. THE COMMISSION’S REMEDIAL AUTHORITY The Federal Trade Commission’s remedies are designed to be equitable, not to punish.1 The relief is generally prospective, in order to stop unlawful conduct and deter future violations of the antitrust laws. One aspect of deterrence, of course, is removing any gain from illegal conduct. The Commission generally pursues three types of remedies in competition cases: structural (divestiture and licensing), conduct (cease and desist orders), and monetary (civil penalties, disgorgement, restitution). When addressing the competitive problems raised by a merger, the foremost objective of the Bureau of Competition (“Bureau”) is to provide relief that will return competition to the status quo ante. The Bureau recognizes, as do the courts, that relief from a Section 7 violation should be tailored to alleviate the likely anticompetitive effects in the relevant market. Thus, while it is true that the Commission has “wide discretion in its choice of a remedy,”2 it seeks to assure that its remedy is reasonably related to the unlawful practices. The Bureau is sensitive to the need not to upset transactions that may enhance efficiency if effective remedies may be achieved through settlement. Crafting an effective remedy depends, in part, on a careful analysis of market structure, especially entry barriers. It also depends on what kind of relief would be most effective in restoring competition. To be an acceptable alternative to litigation, a settlement must resolve the competitive concerns uncovered during the investigations. That may require, for example in the case of a merger, that the settlement provide that the divested assets will create a viable competitor with market share that can replace the competition lost by the merger, or, at least, facilitate entry (or expansion) of a successful competitor. Over the past decade the Bureau has faced several challenges in devising remedies in high technology cases. In the past, divestitures of physical assets in areas of competitive overlap have been the principal form of remedy. In high technology markets, that form of remedy sometimes appeared overinclusive and, on occasion, inadequate. Thus, the Bureau has sought a wide range of other remedies, including licensing arrangements.3 In some cases, these arrangements must be supplemented with a variety of assets and continuing relationships in order to assure that effective technology transfers take place. As in traditional industries, it is helpful to divide the remedy discussion in high technology industries into merger and nonmerger sections. January 1999 D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 23 ANTITRUST REPORT The merger remedies favored by the Commission in high technology acquisitions are as innovative as the markets they protect. MERGERS Since mergers are a structural event, the remedies to cure the anticompetitive part of an acquisition are typically, and preferably, structural. If the competitive overlap constitutes most or all of the acquisition or merger in question, the Commission will often seek a preliminary injunction to halt the transaction (and the likely harm to consumers) before it happens; if the competitive overlap is a smaller part of the overall deal, divestiture or licensing, if they can be drafted with sufficient protections, may suffice to remedy the competitive concern. When examining a merger that has both potential efficiencies and anticompetitive effects, the Commission will ordinarily attempt to find a structural solution that will preserve the former and eliminate the latter. As Justice Brennan recognized over thirty years ago, the “key to the whole question of antitrust remedy is of course the discovery of measures necessary to preserve competition.”4 That usually requires a remedy as substantial as divestiture. As the Supreme Court acknowledged in Du Pont, divestiture is the “most drastic” yet “most effective” form of remedy. The Court also advised that divestiture could not be denied the government “because economic hardship, however severe, may result.”5 Thus, the Court concluded that divestiture is a “natural remedy” for a violation of Section 7 and always should be “in the forefront of a court’s mind when a violation . . . has been found.”6 Divestiture of a manufacturing plant or other physical assets is something that the courts are familiar with and that the antitrust agencies are comfortable doing in order to preserve competition, particularly where the assets constitute an ongoing business.7 If the competing assets can be sold to a third party or spun off into a viable competitor, competition can be maintained with a one-time event. The Commission is most comfortable with an asset divestiture when it can identify an acceptable buyer in advance. If that cannot be done, the Commission order will maintain the status quo during the divestiture process by requiring a tight deadline for the sale, a trustee to oversee the assets to be divested, and the use of a crown jewel provision to ensure that the divestiture incentive is strong. Where much of the value of a firm resides in its intellectual property and the ability to innovate, however, divestiture may be somewhat more problematic. The complex interplay of human capital from which innovation springs is much more fragile than typical physical assets. In addition, intellectual property is often embodied in patents, and the patent system has its own complex system of legal protections. Thus, in some cases involving high technology markets the Commission will consider licensing as an alternative. Since the output of the innovation process can be consumed by more than one entity, the licensing of that output has the potential to replace lost competition without physically restructuring the merging firms. However, the Commission has always been concerned with licensing as a remedy.8 It is by nature more regulatory than divestiture, and may require ongoing oversight to ensure effectiveness.9 24 This section reviews merger remedies in innovation markets, computer markets, network mergers, and vertical mergers. It then discusses two special toots—firewalls and trustees—and closes with a practical road map to merger remedies. January 1999 Innovation Markets The Commission’s “innovation market” merger cases provide good examples of its thinking about remedies in high technology industries where only certain parts of a merger would have probable anticompetitive effects. In these cases, the Commission alleged that competition for the innovation of new products would be harmed by the acquisitions. Remedies were needed that could replace the competition lost in the merger without blocking any procompetitive benefits. Both divestiture and licensing were used in appropriate circumstances. Although divestiture is the preferred remedy in all merger cases, as a remedy in innovation markets it requires special care because the success of research and development efforts often depends on a complex array of expertise and sustained knowledge. Sometimes, even in cases where divestiture is the appropriate remedy, it may be necessary to require ongoing obligations of the divesting party to assure that the purchaser has some probability of successful completion of the research effort. The appropriateness of divestiture as a remedy, and its case-by-case flexibility, are illustrated by the Glaxo case, where the merging parties were the two firms farthest along in developing non-injectable agonists, which are oral drugs used to treat migraine attacks.10 Although injectable drugs were already approved by the FDA, they were not sufficiently substitutable to be included in the relevant market. Both Glaxo and the acquired firm, Wellcome, competed to develop the new drugs, and barriers to entry, based on the necessity to acquire substantial specialized human capital resources, and the necessity of completing the FDA approval process, were high. No other firm besides the two merging firms was close to producing a non-injectable agonist. The Commission thus faced a highly concentrated market for the research and development of an important new drug where the merging parties were each other’s closest competitors. The complaint alleged that after the merger Glaxo could unilaterally reduce output in the relevant market by decreasing the number of research and development efforts to develop a non-injectable drug. It would have the incentive to do so because the remaining research effort would presumably produce a monopoly product until the third-best effort could complete the FDA approval process some years hence. Thus, divestiture of Wellcome’s non-injectable R&D assets was appropriate but not sufficient because of the difficulty of competing in this relevant market. In order to fully restore competition, the order had to make certain that the buyer of the divested assets could effectively use them to mount a strong research and development effort. The assets themselves might not have been sufficient, without the “complex array of expertise and sustained knowledge” embodied in D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 25 Although divestiture is the preferred remedy in all merger cases, as a remedy in innovation markets it requires special care . . . . human capital, to enable an acquirer to get to market 11 expeditiously. Thus, the order in this case required not only the divestiture of Wellcome’s non-injectable R&D assets, it also imposed significant obligations on Glaxo to assist the acquirer in its efforts to continue the research and development effort successfully. Glaxo had to provide information, technical assistance, and advice to the acquirer about the R&D efforts, including consultation with, and training by, Glaxo employees knowledgeable about the project.12 Additionally, under certain conditions Glaxo had to produce more of the experimental drug for the acquirer if it was unable to manufacture sufficient quantities on its own. A trustee was appointed and given the power to sell either the Wellcome or the Glaxo non-injectable assets if Glaxo had not divested the Wellcome assets within nine months. The divestiture in this case was a success: both Glaxo and the acquirer of its intellectual property now have oral migraine drugs on the market. With the required assistance from Glaxo, the acquiring firm, Zeneca, received complete FDA approval in only fifteen months. In the Ciba-Geigy/Sandoz case, the Commission alleged a market for the development of gene therapy products, despite the fact that there were no such current products licensed by the FDA.13 This $63 billion acquisition was the largest pharmaceutical merger in history, combining two Swiss firms that were the leading developers of gene therapy products. The technology at issue involved the treatment of disease through manipulation of genetic material and insertion or reinsertion into a patient’s cells. Although there were many firms doing pioneering research into gene therapies for various disease states, the merging firms were two of only a few entities with the intellectual property rights and other assets necessary for commercialization of such therapies. The firms’ combined position in gene therapy research was so dominant that other firms doing research in this area needed to enter into joint ventures or contract with either Ciba-Geigy or Sandoz in order to have any hope of commercializing their own research efforts. The remedy in the Ciba-Geigy/Sandoz case was designed to protect competition both in the particular products then being researched and the broader market for gene therapy research and development. For the identifiable products under development, the order required the licensing of certain key intellectual property rights held by the combined firm, and also required that an acceptable buyer be identified “up front.” Rhone Poulenc Rorer was identified as the licensee before the order was accepted by the Commission. For the broader gene therapy research and development market, the order required the companies to grant to all gene therapy researchers who applied non-exclusive licenses to all essential gene therapy technologies, along with access to drug master files and safety data filed with the FDA. Because adequate human capital was present in the identified buyer, as well as in other companies with R&D programs in gene therapy, ongoing technical assistance was unnecessary in this case. Although not usually ordered in merger cases, licensing was deemed necessary here to restore partnering prospects for other firms lost by the merger.14 Commissioner Azcuenaga dissented as to the licensing aspect of this order, noting ANTITRUST REPORT 26 that divestiture would cure the anticompetitive problem in a “simple, complete, and easily reviewable” manner.15 This is the crux of the decision to use licensing or divestiture to cure an anticompetitive merger. While divestiture is certainly an easier remedy to impose and monitor, it may not always be the most effective way of restoring competition. Because licensing is more flexible and can more easily be tailored to unusual fact situations, it may be the preferred remedy in innovation cases where divestiture could interrupt potentially successful research efforts. In this case, the majority of the Commission determined that the gene therapy research efforts, which contained a number of joint efforts with third parties, would be too difficult to disentangle from the merging firms, and would thus “not only . . . hamper efficiency but also could be less effective in restoring competition if it led to coordinated interaction or left the divested business at the mercy of the merged firm.”16 The Ciba-Geigy/Sandoz case and the settlement reached there highlight both the procompetitive and the anticompetitive potential of technology licensing. These agreements can increase competition if the licensing is used to create additional competitors. An older Commission case, however, shows the potential for competitive abuse when licensing agreements become too restrictive. Yamaha, a Japanese firm, and Brunswick, an American company, were two of the leading outboard motor manufacturers in the world.17 In the 1970s, the two firms formed a joint venture that effectively divided the world markets into exclusive territories so that they would not compete with each other. Yamaha held exclusive rights to sales in Japan, Brunswick in the United States and Australia, and the joint venture would sell in other countries under the joint venture trademark. Included in the joint venture agreements were technology licensing arrangements that led to the exchange of patents and other intellectual property regarding marine engines. The licensing agreements were restricted in that each company was forbidden to use the technology to make or sell products that would compete with the products of the other. Where, as here, the technology licensing agreements were nakedly anticompetitive, the only solution is to dissolve them. The Commission’s order dissolved both the joint venture and its attendant licensing agreements. January 1999 D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 27 Sometimes technology licensing cannot solve all of the competitive concerns in a merger. A joint venture between Shell Oil and Montedison, an Italian chemical company, to produce and market polypropylene was such a case.18 The relevant markets, in which both Shell and the joint venture participated, involved polypropylene technology and technology licensing. Both parties were willing to attempt to alleviate the Commission’s competitive concerns by excluding their technology licensing businesses from the joint venture. Based on the investigation, the Commission determined that exclusion from the joint venture of the parents’ respective technology licensing businesses did not solve antitrust concerns for two principal reasons: first, the shared interest created by the joint venture might temper competition between the parent companies in research and development and in technology licensing; second, meaningful innovation in polypropylene technology was dependent on, and inextricable from, firsthand experience in using the technology and the proprietary catalyst to produce and sell polypropylene resin and in working with customers to develop new resin formulations. The joint venture would in the future be the principal means by which Shell, and the only means by which Montedison, would produce and sell polypropylene resin. Under these circumstances, it was simply implausible that Shell and Montedison would continue to compete with each other, let alone with their joint venture, in innovation in polypropylene technology. The Commission’s staff rejected a licensing-only remedy in that case because the evidence showed that a viable and competitive technology business could not be maintained without production, sales, and distribution assets for both polypropylene resin and polypropylene catalyst. Thus, comprehensive structural relief was necessary in order to preserve continued competition between the two companies in innovation and in licensing of polypropylene technology and to assure the viability and competitiveness of the technology licensing businesses. Solutions short of divestiture that would leave the technology licensor and its licensees dependent on the Shell-Montedison joint venture for supply of suitable raw materials and for information regarding new product formulations were rejected.19 Accordingly, the Commission’s order required divestiture by Shell of an integrated polypropylene company sufficient to support continued research and development in polypropylene technology and to be a credible licensor of technology. ANTITRUST REPORT Computer Mergers The first industry most people think of when high tech is mentioned is the computer industry, and indeed, both the hardware and software components of the industry epitomize many of the characteristics that apply across the board to high tech industries. The technology of these products may change with unusual rapidity. Network effects are prevalent in both hardware and software because computers are essentially products designed to facilitate communication, and these effects can result in high barriers to entry. The Commission has recently 28 investigated a number of mergers in this industry that January 1999 have raised significant competitive concerns. One of the Commission’s more prominent merger investigations during the last year involved the settlement of Digital Equipment’s patent litigation with Intel, which resulted in cross-licensing of technology and the acquisition of a fabrication facility.20 Digital and Intel are aggressive rivals in the present and future development of microprocessors, and Digital’s Alpha microprocessor is a significant competitor both to Intel’s Pentium microprocessor and to Intel’s next generation IA-64 microprocessor. Digital sued Intel in May 1997, alleging that Intel’s Pentium microprocessors infringed some of Digital’s Alpha microprocessor patents. Intel countersued, claiming that Digital’s Alpha microprocessors infringed some of Intel’s patents. Digital and Intel settled their suit in October 1997 by agreeing to broad patent cross-licenses, the sale of Digital’s microprocessor production facilities to Intel, and an agreement that Intel would produce Alpha microprocessors for Digital. The sale of facilities to Intel did not include the intellectual property rights, design assets, or employees for the Alpha chip. Digital also agreed to design computer systems based on Intel’s IA-64 architecture and chips. The Commission’s complaint alleged that certain aspects of the settlement were likely to reduce competition in three relevant markets: (1) the manufacture and sale of high-performance, general purpose microprocessors capable of running Windows NT in native mode; (2) the manufacture and sale of all general purpose microprocessors; and (3) the design and development of future generations of high-performance, general purpose microprocessors.21 Antitrust concerns arose because in each of these markets Digital’s Alpha chips were the highest performance and most technologically advanced threat facing Intel’s own microprocessors. Barriers to entry were significant because any new microprocessor firm would need to convince computer manufacturers to design their systems around the new microprocessor, a daunting task given the network externalities embodied in current microprocessors. While recognizing that the settlement would free Digital from the enormous cost of owning and operating its own chip fabrication facilities, the Commission was nonetheless concerned that Alpha would not remain competitively viable under the original terms of the Digital-Intel agreement. Intel would have the ability to interfere with Digital’s supply of Alpha chips by withholding necessary cooperation at the manufacturing stage. Digital might also lack the ability and incentive to continue to actively develop and promote Alpha. To resolve these concerns, Digital entered into a consent agreement under which it would grant perpetual and generally non-terminable licenses of the Alpha architecture to Samsung and AMD or other suitable partners approved by the Commission so that they would be able to produce and develop Alpha chips. This is an “architectural” license under which the licensee will be free to create its own implementations and derivative works—that is, to design original chips around the architecture—with the caveat that the licensee maintain backward compatibility with the Alpha architecture. In that fashion, the licensees will have D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 29 the incentives to develop their own variations of the Alpha chip and thus restore innovation competition. An architectural license is important for two reasons. First, the licensee can become completely independent of the licensor by developing its own product line. Second, customers may be more willing to commit to the Alpha architecture knowing there are alternative sources of supply. The order also requires Digital to provide technical support to the licensees for a period of up to two years. Digital also agreed to begin the process of certifying IBM as a foundry for Alpha chips, thereby establishing a manufacturing alternative to Intel. Structural relief was not necessary in this case because the strength, experience, and market position of the licensees made them highly formidable potential competitors. Taken together, these provisions were intended to preserve Alpha as a viable product and competitor to Intel’s microprocessors. In Adobe, the Commission faced a merger to monopoly of two software firms.22 Both Adobe Systems and the acquired firm, Aldus, designed professional illustration software. These products are used by graphics professionals to efficiently and reliably create and print high-quality illustrations, a $60 million market. The Adobe product and the Aldus product were the only two professional illustration products available for use on Apple Macintosh and Power Macintosh computers, which are particularly favored by professional illustrators. Even if the market were expanded to include IBM-compatible computers, Adobe and Aldus would have 35 percent of the market and would be each other’s closest competitors. No new entry has occurred and barriers are high due to high developmental and reputational barriers, and a large installed base that makes penetration difficult and time consuming. In particular, the network externalities associated with both firms’ installed user base posed a particularly substantial barrier to entry. The consent agreement settling this case required Adobe to divest Aldus’s “Freehand” professional illustration software within six months. The parties presented and the Commission approved Altsys Corporation as an up-front buyer, which had developed the Freehand software. The divestiture package included customer names and addresses, as well as marketing, advertising, training, and technical support information and materials. The merged firm was also required to maintain Freehand’s viability and marketability in the interim. The Commission also required a ten-year prior approval agreement from the merged firm before acquiring any interest in any firm engaged in the development or sale of professional illustration software for the Macintosh or Power Macintosh, or before directly acquiring any such software if the purchase price was $2 million or more. As noted above, network effects can be a particularly thorny barrier to entry. If a new entrant’s product is not compatible with the dominant network, consumers will be unlikely to switch unless the new product offers a huge advantage in price or product attributes. Additionally, compatibility can be difficult to achieve due to intellectual property rights held by the incumbent network owner. The Commission recently had a merger case in which the owner ANTITRUST REPORT 30 of a product with dominant network effects attempted to purchase a firm that was on the verge of entry with a competitive and compatible product, Autodesk’s acquisition of Softdesk.23 Autodesk had 70 percent of the market and 70 percent of the installed base for computer-aided designThe antitrust enforcement agencies have been (“CAD”) software engines forincreasingly vigilant in investigating and seeking Windows-based computers. Theserelief when appropriate in network mergers. products are used in the architecture, engineering, and construction industries to automate the design process, and are used by over 1.4 million consumers. The large installed base of Autodesk users necessitates that any new CAD engine developed and offered in the market offer file compatibility and transferability with Autodesk’s product in order to be an effective competitor. Users of the Autodesk product have a large number of drawings in the Autodesk format, and many users must share files they create with others who must be able to read and edit those files using the CAD software. This situation creates barriers to entry to CAD engines that cannot read the Autodesk files without losing data or information. A smaller firm, Softdesk was about to introduce its own CAD engine, IntelliCADD, that would have provided substantial direct competition to Autodesk because it offered compatibility and transferability with Autodesk-generated files and application software. In this case, when apprised by the Commission staff of the competitive implications of the merger, Softdesk divested its product to a third party, Boomerang Technology. The order settling the case barred Autodesk or Softdesk from reacquiring IntelliCADD or any entity that owns or controls the IntelliCADD technology for a period of ten years without prior notification to the Commission. In addition, Autodesk and Softdesk were prohibited from interfering with the ability of Boomerang to recruit or hire employees of Softdesk who worked on the development of IntelliCADD. Both the Adobe/Aldus and the Autodesk/Softdesk acquisitions suggest the importance of structural relief where network externalities are present. In those cases, even though technology may have been evolving, network effects created such a formidable barrier that remedy short of divestiture may have been inadequate. January 1999 Network Mergers The antitrust enforcement agencies have been increasingly vigilant in investigating and seeking relief when appropriate in network mergers. Perhaps a decade ago, most such mergers received little attention, in part because it was difficult to perceive significant barriers to entry. Now as the understanding of network effects, including network externalities, installed base, and switching costs, has become more sophisticated, network mergers are receiving more careful scrutiny.24 For example, in 1995 the FTC challenged the acquisition of the Western D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 31 Union consumer money transfer system (owned by First Financial Management Corp.) by First Data Corp., the owner of the MoneyGram system.25 Consumer wire money transfer systems involve one-way money transfers, typically between two consumers. Wire transfer agents include a wide variety of retail outlets, including grocery stores and check cashing outlets. Historically, entry into the consumer wire transfer service market was difficult for two reasons: (1) the need to develop a minimum viable scale nationwide network of money transfer agents; and (2) the need to establish name recognition and customer acceptance through large-scale advertising and promotion. Long-term agent contracts utilized by Western Union made acquiring a sufficient agent network difficult, and building brand name recognition required a substantial investment over a number of years. First Data (MoneyGram) was the only firm that had succeeded in overcoming those barriers and had begun to offer significant competition to Western Union, until then a monopolist. No other firm was likely to enter. To address these concerns the consent order required First Data to divest the MoneyGram network, including its trademark and relationships with a sufficient number of geographically dispersed agents (over 10,000) to create a viable network. Since the agent base and trademark were critical factors, the order had two novel provisions. First, First Data could not solicit any MoneyGram agents until the term of their contract expired. Second, during the divestiture period, an interim trustee was appointed to ensure the network did not deteriorate in value. Specifically, the trustee had the ability to increase the level of MoneyGram advertising by 20 percent, and there were financial incentives to sign up additional MoneyGram agents to build the agent base. Another recent network merger involved the acquisition of most of the assets of AutoInfo by Automated Data Processing (“ADP”) in the market for a used auto parts exchange network.26 Auto exchange networks facilitate the trade and purchase of auto parts between salvage yards. They consist of several components, including (1) a yard management system, a computerized inventory-control and management system for salvage yards; (2) an interchange, a numeric system for identifying interchangeable used automobile parts that is included in electronic form within the AutoInfo yard management system; and (3) a communications network, an electronic, satellite, or land-based communications system to effectuate trading of parts between salvage yards. The ADP/AutoInfo transaction resulted in a monopoly in the relevant market. The merger was challenged after its consummation, in part because of withholding of relevant Hart-Scott-Rodino information by ADP.27 The antitrust case was ultimately settled after administrative litigation had begun. The consent order required the divestiture of the AutoInfo assets, including the communications network and the yard management system. There was a problem with a simple divestiture, however, because ADP had switched all AutoInfo customers to use the ADP interchange after the acquisition and failed to update the AutoInfo interchange, which quickly became obsolete. In effect the ADP interchange had become the industry standard since ADP’s conversion of all ANTITRUST REPORT 32 users to its own interchange rendered impracticable any attempt to ask users of the assets to be divested to change back to the AutoInfo Interchange. Thus, the Commission faced a problem: how to provide access to the ADP interchange to the acquirer of the AutoInfo assets while providing incentives for them to develop their own interchange? The answer was a requirement that ADP provide a paid-up, perpetual, non-exclusive license (with no continuing royalties and with unlimited rights to sub-license) to ADP’s interchange. This license arrangement required no post-divestiture royalties and did not limit the licensee’s right to sublicense. The order also required ADP to license all interchange updates. Moreover, the order provided that ADP had to give the acquirer a copy and non-exclusive license to all computer programs, databases, and information sources that ADP has used to update its interchange. As in the First Data case, the Commission recognized that the divesting network could take actions to drive customers from the new network, and therefore implemented provisions to protect the customer base. ADP could have prevented customers from dealing with the new network or create barriers to interoperability between networks. To address that issue the order contained an open access provision that prevented ADP from reinforcing its installed base advantage by preventing its customers from accepting or transmitting inventory data by way of other vendors’ services. The order also provided that ADP could not use any contracts or other means to hinder its customers’ attempts to interconnect with the acquirer’s products or services. This provision ensured that ADP’s customers could freely choose to send inventory data generated from ADP systems or sent over ADP communications networks to other vendors’ systems or networks. Moreover, to facilitate the transition of ADP customers to the new network the order provided that, for one year following divestiture, ADP facilitate conversion of any customers (acquired post-acquisition) to the acquirer’s system by foregoing any penalties otherwise available and by permitting customers to exit existing contracts. January 1999 Vertical Mergers Vertical merger cases can also have anticompetitive effects, although they may raise different issues from the horizontal cases already mentioned.28 The main potential anticompetitive effect from vertical mergers is that market opportunities may be foreclosed and barriers to entry may be raised by the necessity of entering at more than one level in order to complete effectively. The Commission recently settled two vertical merger cases in high technology industries. In both of these cases, the acquisitions exhibited potential efficiencies along with the probable anticompetitive effects from potential foreclosure. Thus, the challenge in each case was to tailor the relief to restore pre-acquisition competition while allowing the efficiencies to be realized. In Silicon Graphics, the acquiring firm had 90 percent of the market for workstations that run entertainment graphics software and the acquired firms, D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 33 Alias Research and Wavefront Technologies, were two of the three leading entertainment graphic software firms in the world.29 The software is used to produce high-resolution two- and three-dimensional digital images for movies and other media. The two interdependent acquisitions totaled nearly $500 million. The complaint alleged that the acquisitions would foreclose access by other workstation producers to the relevant software as well as give Silicon Graphics nonpublic information about its competitors’ products. In addition, the acquisition could foreclose, or increase costs to, potential entertainment software firms, raising barriers to entry by making it necessary to enter on two levels. The complaint also alleged a reduction in innovation in both hardware and software markets. The consent order required Silicon Graphics to enter into a “porting agreement” with a Commission-approved partner that would allow the partner to run the two most important software programs of Alias. This porting requirement would ensure that at least one other workstation manufacturer would have access to the important Alias graphics packages being acquired by Silicon Graphics. The settlement identified Digital Equipment, Hewlett-Packard, IBM, or Sun Microsystems as possible porting agreement partners, as long as the agreement itself was approved by the Commission. The Commission also required Silicon Graphics to maintain an open architecture and to publish its application programming interfaces so that other software developers could write entertainment graphics software for Silicon Graphics workstations. Silicon Graphics was also required to offer independent entertainment graphics software companies participation in its software development programs on terms no less favorable than it offers other types of software companies. To address the potential for disclosure of competitors’ information, the order prohibited the release of non-public information from the platform partner porting the Alias software to those Silicon Graphics or Alias employees not participating in the porting process. ANTITRUST REPORT 34 In the other merger, the Commission alleged that Cadence Design System’s acquisition of Cooper & Chyan Technology would reduce competition for software used to automate the design of integrated circuits.30 Cadence is the leading supplier of microchip layout environments, and Cooper & Chyan was the only firm with a commercially viable constraint-driven, shape-based router, which is used to automate the solution of unique engineering problems associated with the increasingly smaller scale of microchip design. Cadence thus stood in a vertical relationship with Cooper & Chyan as a purchaser of its products, and the merger could lead to efficiencies due to tighter integration between Cooper & Chyan’s integrated circuit design tools and Cadence’s product line, which would allow the tighter coupling of physical design software with logical design tools that is necessary to design integrated circuits at the submicron level. The complaint alleged that the acquisition would reduce the incentives of Cadence to permit competing suppliers of routing tools to obtain access to Cadence’s layout environments, thereby increasing barriers to entry for routing tool developers because they would have to simultaneously enter at the router and layout environment levels. Innovation would suffer as a result. The evidence indicated that Cadence was no stranger to attempts to block access to its layout environments in order to raise costs to potential competitors. In the past, Cadence had thwarted attempts by firms with potentially competitive technology to develop interfaces. The consent order required Cadence to allow developers of commercial integrated circuit routing tools to participate in the Cadence “Connections Program” and any other Cadence independent software interface programs that enable independent software developers to develop and sell interfaces to Cadence layout tools and environments. Cadence was required to offer participation to independent software developers on terms no less favorable than those applicable to any other participants in the program. Cadence’s Connections Program had over 100 participants, and thus the nondiscrimination requirement was easy to enforce and it allowed actual and potential competitors of Cooper & Chyan products to have equal access to Cadence’s layout environment. The key aspect of the relief in both of these cases was the use of nondiscrimination provisions aimed at preventing self-favoritism. These provisions are typically not easy to draft or monitor. However, in both the Silicon Graphics and Cadence cases, there were available benchmarks that could be used to judge how the companies would have treated rivals if the market were more competitive. Thus, in Silicon Graphics, the respondent must treat independent entertainment graphics software developers in the same way it treats independent developers of industrial and scientific software applications doing business in more competitive markets. Similarly, in Cadence, the respondent must allow router developers to participate in existing software development interface programs available to developers of other software tools. As Howard Morse has observed, in both cases “the application of an existing benchmark resulted in an order that is easier to monitor compared to other nondiscrimination provisions.”31 In other cases, where these benchmarks are unavailable, stronger remedy alternatives may January 1999 D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 35 ANTITRUST be necessary. REPORT Vertical merger cases with both potential efficiencies and anticompetitive problems may present an additional remedial difficulty. Firewalls Vertical merger cases with both potential efficiencies and anticompetitive problems may present an additional remedial difficulty. If the merger is allowed to proceed, the combined firm may be in a position to gain access to proprietary information of a competitor through a supply relationship with that company. One form of relief to obviate this problem is the so-called “firewall,” an order provision requiring some segregation of information within the merged entity. The Commission has taken this approach in several vertical merger cases in defense industries32 and pharmaceuticals.33 Firewalls may be appropriate when, because of its position in two levels of the market, a newly vertically integrated firm may be both a competitor and a customer or supplier of a particular firm or group of firms. In its activities as customer or supplier, the merged firm may, in the nature of things, acquire access to competitively sensitive information about these competitors. If this information flows freely from the customer/supplier segment of the integrated firm to the competitor segment, the non-integrated competitor may be harmed in several ways. The integrated firm may be able to appropriate the fruits of the competitor’s research and development and decipher product road maps. If the integrated competitor gets access to a non-integrated competitor’s technical information, the latter’s incentives to innovate or engage in research and development may be sharply reduced because the rewards for such investment may be appropriated by the integrated firm. Further, in a market where firms bid for business, the integrated firm also may be able to forecast, or at least approximate, the competitor’s bids, and itself bid less aggressively than it would have in a state of greater uncertainty. One example of a firewall in a defense-industry case is found in Martin Marietta/General Dynamics, a 1994 consent order. That case involved the acquisition by Martin—now Lockheed Martin—of General Dynamics’ Space Systems Division. The Commission’s complaint alleged that as a result of the acquisition, Martin’s launch-vehicle division would have access to detailed, non-public information from competitors in the satellite industry, which it could then pass on to its satellite division. That is because launch vehicle designers must have a lot of information about the satellites their vehicles are to carry. This information could be misappropriated by Martin to make better bids for satellite business or even to build better satellites. The consent permitted the acquisition, but prohibits Martin’s launch division from disclosing to its satellite division any non-public information it receives from a satellite manufacturer. The first use of a firewall provision in the pharmaceuticals industry was a consent in Eli Lilly and Company/PCS Health Systems, in 1995. That case involved Lilly’s acquisition of McKesson Corporation’s PCS Health Systems, a pharmacy benefit 36 management (“PBM”) business. PCS, in carrying out its PBM activities, maintains a “drug formulary,” a list of drugs it gives to pharmacies, physicians, and third-party payors to guide them in prescribing and dispensing prescriptions to health plan beneficiaries, and it negotiates with drug manufacturers about rebates, discounts, and prices to be paid for drugs. Obviously, this involves obtaining a great deal of proprietary information from manufacturers that compete with Lilly, and the concern was that, in the absence of a firewall provision, such information could be shared with Lilly. The consent order prohibited such information-sharing.34 The Commission’s experience with these cases indicates that, if the troublesome information flow can be prevented, the problems of misappropriation of competitively sensitive information can be avoided.35 In this regard, competitors serve as an extra set of eyes for the Commission, and can alert it if there has been a breach of the firewalls. These firewalls are rather straightforward and they are a “clean” solution, in the sense that they should not have any negative impact on legitimate potential efficiencies. Firewalls appear to be effective and seem not to be creating unplanned negative effects. Nonetheless, firewalls are not appropriate to every situation in which disclosure of competitively sensitive information is potentially anticompetitive. A firewall provision may be adequate where there is some neutral third-party oversight, for instance the Department of Defense or third-party payors like insurance companies. In other cases, a firewall will be far less than sufficient. One might suggest that firewalls are unnecessary because private parties can negotiate for similar agreements. But private parties might not be able to accomplish the same level of protection with private non-disclosure agreements. There also may be some instances in which the incentives of parties to negotiate private confidentiality agreements would not be fully aligned with the Commission’s concerns about the health of competition. January 1999 Trustees One important element in some of the remedies in high technology markets is the use of a trustee. Trustees have been used for a number of purposes. For example, in First Data,36 an interim trustee was used to ensure that the value of the MoneyGram network did not dissipate during the divestiture period. The trustee was responsible for monitoring advertising expenditures and solicitation of agents. In Glaxo,37 a trustee was used to ensure that an adequate package of intellectual property was divested, that the research and development continued to be pursued in an appropriate fashion, and that the acquiring party could manage the regulatory drug approval process. In Digital,38 a trustee was used to monitor both the process of finalizing the implementing agreements for the licenses and the continuing relationships between Digital and the licensees. The Commission’s increasing use of trustees in recent high technology mergers is based on several recurring complexities in high technology industries. Where the Commission does not possess the technical expertise to draft and D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 37 monitor effective licenses, an experienced trustee may be able to do so. Many trustees are experts with hands-on experience in certain industries and technologies and can effectively determine whether a particular remedy is adequate to restore competition. Ongoing relationships between the respondent and the acquirer may provide the opportunity for strategic behavior by the respondent to thwart the acquirer’s ability to compete effectively. The trustee can monitor the transfer of know-how and other agreements to deter strategic behavior. Also, the constant presence of a trustee may be necessary in order to ensure that research and development continues to be pursued and to facilitate the seamless exchange of information necessary to contract for a license. Finally, Commission orders that contain licensing provisions usually contain “crown jewel” provisions requiring the divestiture of a more valuable set of assets if problems arise with the license. Trustees are available to enforce these provisions and activate the crown jewel clause, if necessary. ANTITRUST REPORT A Practical Road Map to Merger Remedies The merger remedies favored by the Commission in high technology acquisitions are as innovative as the markets they protect.39 While each remedy is different, molded to the precise competitive situation in the affected markets, there are certain key factors that are considered: Divestiture of an Ongoing Business Divestiture of an ongoing business with customer and supplier relationships with an up-front buyer or under a strict timetable remains the preferred remedy; it is quick and has a high probability of success. Divestiture of Selected Assets Where it can be determined that a divestiture of selected assets is adequate, with the right acquirer, to facilitate entry, the Bureau will consider this as a possibly less burdensome requirement. In high technology markets, such selected assets may include patents and technology portfolios, and research and development assets. Licensing If divestiture appears to be inappropriate for whatever reason, licensing will be considered. Generally, the Bureau prefers exclusive licenses, so that the licensee has the greatest economic stake in the technology being transferred. In addition, the Bureau will generally prefer that the licensee obtain the right to use any improvements to the technology that the licensee develops, including uses of the technology in fields outside the alleged innovation product market. Often, licensing must be supplemented with other assets such as supply agreements for an interim period, critical personnel, facilities, or customer relationships. 38 Use of an Up-Front Buyer January 1999 Presentation of an up-front buyer is always useful, regardless of the form of remedy. Where the divestiture is less than an ongoing business or where licensing is considered, it is critical for the respondent to present an up-front buyer or licensee during consent negotiations. An up-front buyer or licensee will help to assure that the remedy is adequate to restore competition. The Bureau will always attempt to determine if the up-front buyer will be able to effectively utilize the divested assets or the proffered license. This gives the Bureau more confidence that competition will be restored for the long run. Crown Jewel Provision Also, the Bureau will often insist on a “crown jewel” provision, with enforcement power in the trustee, to assure that the respondent will make every effort to resolve the remedy issue in a timely and effective fashion. A crown jewel provision requires a company to sell a different, more valuable group of assets if the assets to be divested are not sold in a given time period. Such provisions increase the incentive for the respondent to sell the initial package during the initial period and provide a more attractive package for the trustee to divest if the respondent is unsuccessful. A crown jewel will be particularly important where licensing is used; it creates incentives for the respondent to cooperate fully in technology transfers and supply agreements and may dampen the incentives to engage in strategic behavior. Interim Trustees Very often, the Bureau will require the appointment of an auditor-trustee to oversee the respondent’s efforts in transferring technology and performing under any supply agreement. The orders will also frequently contain a hold-separate and an interim maintenance requirement, to make certain that the active research and development continues on schedule and that the assets are not dissipated during transfer. In such instances, an auditor-trustee can prevent the dissipation of assets and information-exchange problems that might occur. D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 39 ANTITRUST NONMERGERS REPORT When the Commission considers the need for effective remedies for anticompetitive conduct in high technology industries, it faces a broad set of issues. In part, this merely reflects the greater number of merger cases, but it also highlights the wider range of conduct under review in nonmerger cases. While all mergers are alike in that they are a melding of separately owned assets at a particular point in time, potentially anticompetitive nonmerger conduct is more diverse, ranging from per se horizontal division of markets to monopolization to vertical distribution agreements analyzed under the rule of reason. In addition, divestiture and other structural remedies may be more difficult to fashion in a situation where assets are not already being combined or spun-off. To be sure, conduct remedies such as injunctive relief and cease and desist orders are also important remedies in nonmerger cases, but even these are more difficult to analyze and put in place than a simple prohibition of an acquisition. Finally, nonmerger conduct might call for a third type of remedy that is not often appropriate in mergers, that is, monetary relief. Monetary remedies might include civil penalties, restitution, or perhaps even disgorgement.40 Several of the perceived differences in high technology competition may have an impact on the type of remedies sought in nonmerger cases. For instance, the prevalence of network effects may raise issues of access to the network by competitors or by producers of complementary goods. In such a case, the owner of a proprietary system who committed anticompetitive or exclusionary acts could be forced to open the system in order to restore competitive conditions. The abuse of intellectual property licensing in order to maintain monopoly power can also give rise to an antitrust violation. In the Pilkington case, the Department of Justice alleged that the British firm, the world’s largest producer of float glass, violated Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act by maintaining agreements and understandings that unreasonably restrained interstate and foreign trade in the construction and operation of float glass plants and in float glass process technology, and by monopolizing the world market for the design and construction of float glass plants.41 The agreements in question were put in place in the 1960s, but the patents and trade secrets they were initially based-on had long since expired and had moved into the public domain. Despite the erosion of the intellectual property protections, over 90 percent of float glass worldwide continued to be manufactured under a Pilkington license agreement. The complaint specifically alleged that, without sufficiently valuable intellectual property rights, Pilkington and other float glass manufacturers allocated territories for, and limited the use of, float glass technology worldwide, required competitors to prove that all of the licensed technology had become publicly known before being relieved of the territorial and use restrictions, and imposed limitations on the sublicensing of float glass technology. As a result of the restrictions, existing licensees, including those in the United States, could not design and build new float plants without Pilkington’s permission. 40 The consent decree entered in Pilkington enjoined defendants from enforcing license provisions that restrain their U.S.-based licensees’ freedom to use float glass technology anywhere in the world, and from enforcing license restrictions against their other licensees that restrain the licensees’ freedom to use float glass technology in the United States. It also enjoined defendants from asserting any proprietary know-how rights in such technology against individuals or firms in the United States who are not licensees. The settlement freed competitors worldwide to pursue the best technology and to innovate to produce new technology. The Department estimated that thirty to fifty float glass plants were planned or projected worldwide out to the year 2000, amounting to expenditures of as much as $5 billion. Once defendants were enjoined from imposing the licensing restrictions, firms in the United States could compete for contracts to design and manufacture these plants. The judgment also enjoined conduct that had the effect of restricting exports of float glass and float glass technology into the United States. Three recent high technology nonmerger cases brought by the FTC show the diversity of remedies being sought. In the Intel case, which is currently in administrative litigation, the Commission alleges that Intel refused to provide to three companies technical information necessary to make products that would work with Intel microprocessors, in an attempt to force those companies to license their own technology to Intel.42 The relief sought by the Commission would order Intel to cease and desist from discriminating, or threatening to discriminate, between customers that compete with it or who threaten to assert intellectual property rights concerning computer technology against it, and those that do not, unless Intel can demonstrate legitimate business reasons for such discrimination. Discrimination would be forbidden in the areas of the sale of microprocessors, terms of nondisclosure agreements concerning microprocessors, providing information concerning Intel’s computer technology, providing prototypes of Intel’s products in development, and providing technical assistance concerning Intel’s existing dominant products or products in development. The VISX case also involved abuse of market power based on intellectual property.43 In that case, Summit Technology and VISX, the only two FDA-approved manufacturers of lasers used in photo refractive keratectomy (“PRK”) to treat vision disorders, formed a patent pool whereby the two firms agreed to charge a $250 licensing fee that was paid into the pool each time laser eye surgery was performed using either firm’s equipment. The proceeds of the pool were split according to a formula. The result was that prices were far higher than they would have been if the two firms had been competing with each other, in markets for the sale or lease of PRK equipment, and the licensing of technology related to PRK. Both companies possessed patents that would have allowed them to be horizontal competitors, and they had planned to so act before the pool was formed. The pool effectively fixed the minimum price for the technology licenses under which doctors perform PRK. The pool also had the power to exclude competitors. Any manufacturer that wanted to market a laser for PRK needed a January 1999 D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 41 license from the pool for one of the patented laser aiming mechanisms. The pool eliminated the option of receiving bids from two competing firms to license the technology and it also permitted either Summit or VISX to veto any potential licensee. The veto power was exercised and third-party entry was prevented. In this case, a cease and desist order and licensing of the intellectual property of both companies were sufficient to restore competitive conditions. Under the terms of the settlement of the patent pool charge, the two firms are prohibited from fixing prices or agreeing in any way to restrict each other’s sales or licensing of their patents or lasers, including prohibition of the “per-procedure fee” charged to doctors for use of the lasers. Since the companies had already agreed to dissolve the patent pool, the order requires them to take no action inconsistent with the dissolution, and also requires them to license each other, on a royalty-free and non-exclusive basis, the patents that each contributed to the pool. This settlement embodies the principle found in the Intellectual Property Guidelines that a patent pool that evidences anticompetitive effects may be defended if it is reasonably necessary to achieve procompetitive efficiencies.44 Here, the Commission found that the pool was anticompetitive and not necessary to achieve efficiencies. The Dell Computer case involved an anticompetitive acquisition of market power through abuse of a standard-setting procedure.45 At issue was a standard designed for the Video Electronics Standards Association for a local bus to transfer instructions between a computer’s CPU and peripherals. There would be considerable efficiency-enhancing potential in a product that would let computer and peripheral manufacturers know how to make products compatible with one another. The agreement on the standard was premised on representations by the participants that no firm would assert intellectual property rights that might block others from developing towards the standard. The anticompetitive potential of the standard-setting activity surfaced when Dell alleged that the new standard infringed on its patent, despite twice certifying, along with other members of the Association, that it would not assert intellectual property rights. Dell made its claim only after the bus was highly successful, and its claim for royalties gave it effective control of the standard. Dell’s belated assertion of patent ownership in this case enabled it to exercise market power that went beyond power that it could have obtained in the absence of its misrepresentation. The Commission’s complaint specifically alleged that industry acceptance of the new standard was delayed and that uncertainty about the acceptance of the design standard raised the cost of implementing the new design. Other firms avoided using the new bus because they were concerned that the patent dispute would reduce its acceptance as an industry standard. In addition, willingness to participate in industry standard-setting efforts was chilled. When Dell asserted ownership of a blocking patent, this anticompetitive use of intellectual property was sufficient to cause harm through suppression of innovation and delay of introduction of the products that the standard was designed to implement. ANTITRUST REPORT 42 NOTES Dell Computer was a January 1999 relatively straightforward case, and the Effective antitrust enforcement depends on a resulting remedy was also simple and thoughtful and determined approach to remedies. easy to effectuate. The consent order requires that Dell refrain from enforcing its patent against any computer manufacturer using the new design in its products. In addition, Dell is prohibited from enforcing any of its patent rights that it intentionally fails to disclose upon request of any standard-setting organization during a standard-setting process. Other competitors are thus free to innovate and produce products to the specifications of the standard, and Dell is precluded from duplicating its anticompetitive behavior in the future. CONCLUSION Effective antitrust enforcement depends on a thoughtful and determined approach to remedies. The unique innovation incentives and intellectual property aspects of high technology industries have challenged the Commission to craft remedies that work effectively in difficult and unfamiliar situations. The same remedies of divestiture and licensing that are used in traditional “smokestack” industries are also used in high technology industries, but they must be applied with unusual precision in order not to adversely affect the innovation and new product development that are the hallmarks of competition for these rapidly evolving industries. The Commission’s efforts to apply intelligent and flexible remedies in high technology industries have helped protect competitive markets and ensure open access to those markets for new entrants, and thus have the ultimate effect of increasing innovation incentives across all industries. 1. The Commission’s remedial authority is derived from the Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 41-58, the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § § 12-21, and more than 30 more specialized statutes, e.g., Magnuson-Moss Warranty Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2301, Fair Packaging and Labeling Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1451-61. 5. Id. at 327. 6. Id. at 331. See Ford Motor Co. v. United States, 405 U.S. 562, 573 (1972) (divestiture is “particularly appropriate” in merger cases); Olin Corp. v. FTC, 986 F.2d 1295 (9th Cir. 1993), cert. denied, 510 U.S. 1110 (1994); RSR Corp v. FTC, 602 F.2d 1317, 1325-26 (9th Cir. 1979), cert. denied, 445 U.S. 927 (1980); Ash Grove Cement Co. v. FTC, 577 F.2d 1368, 1379-80 (9th Cir. 1978). 2. FTC v. Rubberoid Co., 343 U.S. 470, 473 (1952). 3. By requiring licensing, the Commission can create a new competitor or enhance the probable success of an existing competitor without weakening the respondent by removing assets or intellectual property that may be necessary to successfully compete in the relevant market. 7. See, e.g., RSR Corp. v. FTC, 602 F.2d 1317 (9th Cir. 1979), cert. denied, 445 U.S. 927 (1980) (partial divestiture sufficient to restore competitive entity); OKC Corp. v. FTC, 455 F.2d 1159, 1161 (10th Cir. 1972) (total divestiture of acquired assets necessary to restore “viable, independent, local competitive entity”). 4. United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 366 U.S. 316, 326 (1960). 8. Although it may present difficulties, sometimes the divestiture of intellectual D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 43 ANTITRUST 19. Potential future input supply problems will not always necessitate divestiture. In the recent Exxon/Shell case, the Commission determined that a long-term supply contract would solve the competitive problems. Exxon Corp., FTC File No. 971-0007 (Aug. 20, 1998) (proposed consent order). REPORT property or innovation efforts is necessary to fully restore competition. In these cases, the Commission will not hesitate to order divestiture. See, for example, the discussion of Glaxo and Montedison, infra. 9. Some commentators have criticized the adequacy of licensing as an antitrust remedy. See Richard T. Rapp, The Misapplication of the Innovation Market Approach to Merger Analysis, 64 Antitrust L.J. 19 (1995). For a response, see Thomas N. Dahdouh & James F. Mongoven, The Shape of Things to Come: Innovation Markets in Merger Cases, 64 Antitrust L.J. 405, 438 (1996) (“Licensing is usually found to be an appropriate remedy when market participants and innovators agree that access to intellectual property is key”). 20. Digital Equip. Corp., No. C-3818 (FTC July 14, 1998) (consent order). 21. Digital Equip. Corp., Complaint at ¶¶ 11-13. 22. Adobe Sys., Inc., No. C-3536 (FTC Nov. 8, 1994) (consent order) (Commissioner Owen dissenting). 23. Autodesk, Inc., No. C-3756 (FTC June 18, 1997) (consent order). 24. For a discussion of the evolution of government enforcement in this area, see David Balto, The Murky World of Network Mergers: Searching for the Opportunities for Network Competition, 42 Antitrust Bull. 793 (1997). 10. Glaxo plc, No. C-3586 (FTC June 14, 1995) (consent order). 11. Dahdouh & Mongoven, supra note 9, at 439. 25. First Data Corp., No. C-3635 (FTC Jan. 16, 1996) (consent order). 12. See III P. Areeda & H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 707i, at 184 (1996) (advocating “divestiture of sufficient assets to create viable new firms with free access to the monopolist’s then-existing technology . . . where an acquisition, or a series of acquisitions, has probably made a substantial contribution to monopoly power”). 26. Automatic Data Processing, Inc., FTC Dkt. No. 9282 (June 18, 1997) (consent order). 27. Automatic Data Processing, Inc., FTC File No. 951-0113 (Mar. 27, 1996) (consent order). ADP agreed to pay a $2.97 million civil penalty, the third largest ever obtained for an HSR violation and the largest ever involving the failure to submit documents. United States v. Automatic Data Processing, Inc., No. 96-0606, 1996 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 21160 (D.D.C. Apr. 10, 1996). 13. Novartis A.G., No. C-3725 (FTC Apr. 8, 1997) (consent order) (Commissioner Azcuenaga concurring in part and dissenting in part). 14. For a discussion of the Commission’s use of licensing as a remedy, see Mary Lou Steptoe & David A. Balto, Finding the Right Prescription: The FTC’s Use of Innovative Merger Remedies, Antitrust, Fall 1995, at 16. 28. For a description of recent government enforcement in this area, see M. Howard Morse, Vertical Mergers: Recent Learning, 53 Bus. Law. 1217 (1998). For a more elaborate analysis of vertical merger remedies, see Richard Parker & David Balto, The Merger Wave: Trends in Enforcement and Litigation (forthcoming). 15. Separate Statement of Commissioner Azcuenaga at 1. 16. Statement of Chairman Pitofsky & Commissioners Steiger, Starek & Varney at 2. 17. Brunswick Corp., 96 F.T.C. 151 (1980), aff’d as modified, Brunswick Corp. v. FTC, 657 F.2d 971 (8th Cir. 1981), cert. denied, 456 U.S. 915 (1982). 29. Silicon Graphics, Inc., No. C-3626 (FTC Nov. 16, 1995) (consent order) (Commissioners Azcuenaga & Starek dissenting). 18. Montedison S.p.A., No. C-3580 (FTC June 15, 1995) (consent order). 30. Cadence Design Sys., Inc., No. C-3761 (FTC Sept. 2, 1997) (consent order) 44 1998) (complaint). January 1999 43. VISX, Inc. and Summit Technology, Inc., FTC Dkt. No. 9286 (Aug. 21, 1998) (proposed consent order). (Commissioner Azcuenaga concurring in part and dissenting in part; Commissioner Starek dissenting). 44. U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Federal Trade Comm’n, Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (1995), reprinted in Antitrust Laws and Trade Regulation: Primary Source Pamphlet (Matthew Bender 1998). 31. Morse, supra note 28. 32. See, e.g., Martin Marietta/General Dynamics, No. C-3500 (FTC June 1994) (consent order). 33. See, e.g., Eli Lilly & Co./PCS Health Sys., No. C-3594 (FTC July 1995) (consent order). 45. Dell Computer Co., No. C-3658 (FTC May 20, 1996) (consent order) (Commissioner Azcuenaga dissenting). 34. A similar prohibition of sharing non-public information is contained in the order in Merck & Co., Inc., FTC File No. 971-0097 (Aug. 27, 1998) (proposed consent order), which arose from the vertical merger between Merck and Medco Containment Services, a pharmacy benefit manager. 35. The use of firewalls has raised questions in the past. Commissioner Mary L. Azcuenaga issued a separate statement questioning the extent to which the firewall adds to private contracts and the FTC’s ability to effectively monitor compliance in one of the first cases using a firewall. Alliant Techsystems, Inc., 5 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 23,714, at 23,474 (FTC Apr. 7, 1995). 36. First Data Corp., No. C-3635 (FTC Jan. 16, 1996) (consent order). 37. Glaxo plc, No. C-3586 (FTC June 14, 1995) (consent order). 38. Digital Equip. Corp., No. C-3818 (FTC July 14, 1998) (consent order). 39. See Mary Lou Steptoe & David A. Balto, Finding the Right Prescription: The FTC’s Use of Innovative Merger Remedies, Antitrust, Fall 1995, at 16, 18. 40. See Andrew J. Strenio, Jr., FTC Commissioner, Why Thirteen Should Be a Lucky Number for Victims of Price Fixing, Speech before the Section of Antitrust Law, American Bar Association, 36th Annual Spring Meeting, Washington, D.C. (Mar. 23, 1988) (advocating disgorgement in antitrust cases in appropriate circumstances). 41. United States v. Pilkington plc, No. 94-345 (D. Ariz. May 25, 1994) (consent decree). 42. Intel Corp., FTC Dkt. No. 9288 (June 8, D AVID A. B ALTO is Assistant Director, Office of Policy and Evaluation, Federal Trade Commission. JAMES F. MONGOVEN is an attorney in the Office of Policy and Evaluation. The opinions expressed herein are the authors and not necessarily those of the Commission or of any individual Commissioner. 45