Housing Windfalls and Intergenerational Transfers in China1 Albert Park, HKUST Maria Porter, Michigan State University December 2013 Abstract In this paper, we study the impact of housing reform and the rapid development of the housing market in China on intergenerational transfers and elderly well-being. During the 1990s, the Chinese government gave property rights to many urban residents who had been allocated housing by their employers. These unexpected windfalls were substantial in size, and grew with the rapid increase in housing prices over time, significantly impacting the asset holdings and wealth of affected urban residents. We examine the effect of these exogenous changes in wealth on inter-vivos transfers and intergenerational transfer motives. 1 Maria Porter acknowledges financial support from the Oxford Martin School and the Oxford Institute of Population Ageing. Emails: albertpark@ust.hk, maria.porter@economics.ox.ac.uk. 1 1. Introduction A large literature starting with Becker (1974, 1981) describes and seeks to explain the motivations for intergenerational transfers. Understanding the responsiveness of private support to the needs of others has important implications for the design of public social assistance and social insurance programs. For this reason, it is of particular interest to know the extent to which private transfers are motivated by altruism. Transfers also may be motivated by exchange motives, either as part of mutual insurance or credit arrangements or in exchange for prior or future benefits (Bernheim, Shleifer, and Summers, 1985). For example, children might provide transfers to their parents in exchange for prior parental investments in their education, assistance in child care, or to influence future bequests. Previous studies of the motivations for intergenerational transfers have focused on testing how differences in the income of givers or recipients impact intergenerational transfers. The studies posit that altruism predicts that transfers are inversely related to recipients’ income levels while exchange motives predict that transfers increase with recipients’ income (Cox 1987). It is also possible for both motivations to exist at the same time, with different motives more prominent at different income levels. Unfortunately, these income-based tests suffer from conceptual, measurement, and identification problems. First, tests based on how recent transfers respond to contemporaneous income levels cannot distinguish between altruism and mutual insurance motivations, which both predict that current transfers increase with lower current income levels. Recent income may be low due to temporary negative income shocks, rather than reflecting lower permanent income. Second, income measurements are noisily measured, which can lead to attenuation bias. Third, if transfer recipients are elderly, their annual incomes may not well reflect their wealth or permanent income if they have stopped working. Finally, incomes 2 may reflect labor supply decisions of household members that respond to transfers, leading to simultaneity bias. The empirical evidence from such empirical studies shows mixed results.2 Previous authors have addressed some of these problems, for instance by testing how transfers respond to predicted incomes that are purged of transitory components and hold constant working hours. Studies using US data find that the probability of children receiving transfers from parents is positively associated with the children’s predicted age-adjusted earnings. In China, using predicted household incomes assuming full-time work by all household members Cai, Giles, and Meng (2006) find that transfers are altruistic for those below the poverty line, and Kazianga (2006) finds evidence of altruism in Burkina Faso when modeling permanent income as a function of livestock, farm, and other assets (Kazianga, 2006). However, this approach remains problematic for retired individuals whose wealth reflects income earned in the past when wage determination may have been quite different than in recent years. Moreover, exercises based on cross-sectional comparisons often still are unable to deal with omitted characteristics of recipients, such as an attractive personality, that may be correlated both with earnings’ ability and permanent income and the desire of others to provide transfers to them. If one tries to avoid the identification problems associated with unobserved heterogeneity by examining how transfers respond to changes in income, then the problem arises that the income changes may be anticipated or temporary, so that transfers may reflect insurance motives and liquidity constraints. Studies that test the responsiveness of transfers to recipients’ income that find evidence of altruism include McGarry and Schoeni (1995) and Schoeni (1997) in the US; Wolff, Spilerman, and Attias-Donfut (2007) in France; Raut and Tran (2005) in Indonesia; Cox and Jiminez (1992) and Cox, Eser, and Jiminez (1998) in Peru. Those finding evidence of exchange motives include Cox (1987) and Cox and Rank (1992) in the US. Cox, Jansen and Jimenez (2004) find that in the Philippines, transfers are altruistic at low income levels, while exchange motives dominate at higher income levels. 2 3 In this paper, we follow a unique approach to examine how a permanent change in one’s wealth influences transfers received from non-resident adult children. We identify the effect of a permanent wealth increase on intergenerational transfers by instrumenting household wealth with the market windfall many employees of work units received when they purchased housing from their employers. In urban China, housing reform resulted in rapid appreciation of undersupplied housing in the private sector. Prior to the housing reform, danwei employers allotted housing to their employees. During the period of housing reform, since this housing was allocated before a housing market existed; significant random variation resulted in the size of housing windfalls associated with the market value later placed on specific locations. In this paper, we use this variation in the appreciation of housing market values to identify the impact of an exogenous increase in household wealth on intergenerational transfers. Those who purchased subsidized housing from their work units received significant windfalls, resulting in an increase in household wealth and permanent income. If transfers from children to parents are motivated by altruism, we would expect children to reduce the amount transferred to their parents. On the other hand, if children increase the amount they transfer to parents when parents receive this housing windfall, then their transfer motives are more likely to be strategic rather than altruistic. Children may provide more to their parents in the hopes that parents will bequest their housing to them, or in exchange for living with them in better housing than they could afford at market rates. While children generally earn more than their parents, the housing windfall may also shift bargaining power within the family from adult children to elderly parents. They may be able to extract more time and care from their children as a result of this increased bargaining power. 4 In addition, wealth or asset holdings may be a better measure of elderly wellbeing than wage income, particularly in this context. In developing countries, income is hard to measure. Usually, expenditure proxies for income. In China, retired elderly receive little income. Some might receive pensions, but amounts are usually low. So they primarily rely on their wealth. In addition, wealth may reflect the occurrence of negative life events. For example, in the U.S., death and divorce slow down asset accumulation. Often assets are actually drawn down during such events. In the U.S., the evolution of assets is also very strongly related to health (Poterba, Venti, and Wise 2010). In urban China, the ability to draw down assets in times of need would be more difficult, since housing comprises nearly 80% of household wealth on average, and is an illiquid asset. Children might help their parents when they are in need so that they do not sell housing that would appreciate in value, allowing them to inherit this valuable asset or make use of it by living with parents. Other studies set in China find evidence of multiple transfer motives. As noted earlier, Cai, Giles, and Meng (2006) find that transfers by children to parents are altruistic when parents’ household income per capita is below the poverty line. Secondi (1997) finds that child care services may be one of the main services the elderly provide their adult children in exchange for money, and that altruism alone cannot explain transfers from children to elderly parents. In addition, Li, Rosenzweig and Zhang (2010) use twin data in China to exploit a "natural experiment" resulting from parents having been forced to send away one of their children for rustification during the Cultural Revolution, and use this experimental variation in parental time with children to identify its effect on transfers to children later in life, and whether transfers are motivated by altruism or guilt. The authors find that while transfers are motivated by altruism, 5 guilt also plays an important role, as children who had been sent away for a longer period of time receive more transfers from parents, even when they have higher earnings. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we present a theoretical model that allows for both altruism and exchange motives in order to derive predictions and clarify interpretation of the empirical specification. We provide background information on China’s housing reforms and housing market development in section 3; introduce the data from the China Health and Retirement Longitudinal Study and the empirical methodology in section 4; present the results in section 5, and conclude with section 6. 2. Model Consider the following model of intergenerational transfers that allows for both altruism and exchange motivations. In contrast to previous models designed to capture decisions of parents in the US and other developed countries on how much to transfer to children, our model makes the child the principal, which is consistent with the fact that unlike in the West in China transfers on average flow from children to parents. We model transfers from one child to one parent. The child maximizes his or her own utility defined as a function of three arguments: π = π(ππ , π΅, π(ππ , π, π΅)). (1) Utility is a function of the child’s own consumption Xc, bequests received from parents B, and the utility of the parent (defined by V), which itself is a function of parental consumption Xp, transfers from children T, and bequests. Transfers may be valued for emotional reasons that are independent of the consumption it facilitates. The inclusion of bequests in the parent’s utility function allows for the possibility that parents may value leaving large bequests to children 6 which is independent of the negative utility associated with foregone consumption. This could reflect a concern for the future welfare of their children, reflecting reciprocal altruism.3 Modeling B separately in the utility functions of parents and children enables us to distinguish exchange from altruism motives. We assume that consumption of parents and children are defined as follows: ππ = π 0 + ππ + π − π΅ (2) ππ = ππ − π. (3) Here, W0 is parental initial wealth, and Yp and Yc are the incomes of parent and child, respectively. We assume that bequests can be influenced by transfers to parents, so B is a function of T. Below we define the parent’s optimal bequest explicitly. Finally, there is a participation constraint for the parent. Parental utility must be greater than or equal to the utility of the parent absent the relationship with their children: π(ππ , π, π΅) ≥ π0 (π 0 + ππ , 0,0). (4) The model avoids time subscripts, reflecting our preference that the consumption, income, and transfer variables be interpreted as total outcomes spanning the life of the parent-child relationship. Such an interpretation is reasonable if children or parents have access to credit markets, in which case the optimal timing of income and transfers is irrelevant and consumption is perfectly smoothed over time (Cox, 1990). It is readily apparent that W 0 and Yp operate identically in the model. One can think of W0 as reflecting the wealth accumulated by parents before children become adults, earn income, and are in a position to make decisions affecting Parent’s could also feel pride in amassing large amounts of wealth which they prefer to leave to children, or in creating a legacy after their death through the wealth of their children. This formula makes the simplifying assumption that parents do not care about the consumption of their children; this could easily be added without affecting the main results. 3 7 their parents. Define W = W0 + Yp as permanent income of the parent during the life of the intergenerational relationship. To make the model more tractable, we assume that the utility functions are linearly separable. An important parameter α is introduced to capture the degree of altruism, with α=1 reflecting perfect altruism, meaning that children care as much about their parents as about themselves. We also substitute in for the definitions of Xc and Xp to arrive at the following: π = π’(ππ − π) + π(π΅ ∗ (π, π)) + πΌ[π£(π + π − π΅ ∗ (π, π)) + π(π΅ ∗ (π, π), π)]. (5) Here, B* denotes the optimal bequest decided upon by parents, which is the solution to the parent’s utility maximization problem defined as follows: max π£(π + π − π΅) + π(π΅, π). π΅ (6) Note that the utility from bequests is likely to be positively related to the amount of transfers received from children, if this is the case then the cross-partial with respect to B and T is ππ2 positive, or ππ΅π = ππ΅ππ > 0. If T were not included as an argument in g, then transfers would not affect bequests any differently than the parent’s own income. We focus on the case in which the participation constraint of the parent is non-binding. If the constraint binds, the child does not wish to make the parent better off despite their altruistic feelings. This is most likely to occur when the parent’s lifetime income is much greater than that of the child, which is relatively uncommon in a rapidly growing country such as China. Thus, we can simply take the first order condition (FOC) for equation (5) with respect to T. This yields: −π’′ + π ′ π΅ π + πΌ(π£ ′ (1 − π΅ π ) + ππ΅ π΅ π + ππ ) = 0. 8 (7) We then totally differentiate the FOC with respect to W and T to derive the comparative static result: π (π’′′ + π ′ π΅ ππ + π ′′π΅ + πΌ(π£ ′′ (1 − π΅ π )2 + (ππ΅ − π£ ′ )π΅ ππ + ππ΅π΅ π΅ π + πππ )) π + (π ′ π΅ ππ + πΌ(π£ ′′ (1 − π΅ π )(1 − π΅ π ) + (ππ΅ − π£ ′ )π΅ ππ ))ππ = 0 (8) Rearranging terms, and noting that The first order condition for optimal bequests requires that gB – v’ = 0, we derive the following expression for the effect of parental wealth on transfers: ππ π ′ π΅ππ +πΌπ£ ′′ (1−π΅π )(1−π΅π ) = − π’′′ +π′π΅ππ +π′′π΅π +πΌ(π£′′ (1−π΅π )2 +ππ΅π΅ π΅π +πππ ) ππ (9) The denominator of this expression is unambiguously negative given decreasing marginal utility in all arguments, which means that the sign of dT/dW is the same as the sign of the numerator. The first term in the numerator is positive because parental wealth increases the influence of transfers on bequests. This is intuitive since there is more wealth for the parent to bequeath, and it can be easily derived from the optimal bequest problem solved by parents. It captures the exchange motive of children to increase transfers in order to receive larger bequests when more is at stake. The second effect is negative as long as transfers increase parental consumption (1BT>0), reflecting the altruism motive.4 With greater wealth, the marginal utility gain to parents from transfers falls, which reduces transfers if children are altruistic (α>0). This leads to an overall ambiguous prediction on the effect of parental wealth on transfers. From (9) it is also possible to predict how the relative importance of altruism and exchange motives varies with the permanent income, or wealth, of the recipient. At low levels of wealth, the marginal utility of consumption is high so that greater wealth will mostly be consumed. This implies that the impact of wealth on the responsiveness of bequests to 4 If transfers increase bequests by more than the amount of transfers (B T>1), then more transfers reduce parental consumption, in which case there is an unambiguous prediction that greater parental wealth will increase transfers to parents. 9 transfers(π΅ ππ ) will be smaller, reducing the first term of the numerator in (5). At lower consumption (and wealth) levels, if the utility function is sufficiently concave (v’’’>0)5 then v’’ will be more negative, and the impact of both transfers and wealth on bequests is likely to be reduced. For these reasons, the second term in the numerator of (9) is also likely to be more negative at lower wealth levels. Thus, altruism is more likely to dominate at lower wealth levels while exchange motives are likely to dominate at higher wealth levels. 3. Housing Reform in China Initial housing sales gave owners the right to use their property and pass it on through inheritance, but not the right to sell. Initial experiments began between 1979 and 1981, with the sale of new housing to urban residents at construction costs. In the early 1980s, all housing was purchased from work units. In Gansu, this was true until the 1990s, and a private market for housing did not seem to really develop until 1998 (see Figure 1b). However, throughout much of the country, from 1982 to 1985, there were experiments with subsidized sales of new housing. The buyer paid one-third of the cost, while the remainder was subsidized equally by the employer and the city government. Such costs included the cost of land acquisition as well as the provision of local public facilities. Experiments with comprehensive housing reform began between 1986 and 1988. At this time, public sector rents were raised; a housing subsidy for all public sector employees was introduced; and sales of public sector housing were promoted. In November 1991, a conference resolution “On Comprehensive Reform of the Urban Housing System,” resulted in large scale 5 This is the necessary condition for utility functions to exhibit prudence, which provides a motive for precautionary saving. 10 sale of public housing at very low prices, particularly to current occupiers. But in 1993, the government suspended this housing reform because of concern about very low prices of sales. In 1994, a significant wave of housing reforms was put into place as a result of “The Decision on Deepening the Urban Housing Reform.” Under this system, employers and employees contributed to house savings funds. Rents were increased, especially for new tenants. However, low-income households received lower rents for old or unsellable public housing. Three price mechanisms were put into place for public housing sales: (1) high-income families paid market prices and received full property rights, including the right to resell on the open market; (2) low- and middle-income families paid below market prices, which covered all costs, including land acquisition, construction, and local public facilities; (3) for those who could not afford these costs, a transitional pricing scheme was offered, taking into account both cost and affordability. The latter two types of subsidized purchases only gave home-owners use rights. In order to resell, the owner would have to repay the housing subsidy that had been originally provided. During this time, few cities had any secondary housing market. In July 1998, a new policy was developed in order to stop the material distribution of public housing to employees and to introduce a cash subsidy for housing issued by public sector employers. Specific policies varied across regions and details were determined by local bodies. In general however, affordable housing was built with government support for low- and middleincome families, which constituted 70-80 percent of urban residents). High-income families (1015 percent urban residents) purchased higher quality housing in the market. Poor families were given subsidized rental housing by their employers or the city government. But local authorities and state enterprises often had insufficient resources to pay such subsidies.6 6 For additional details on the history of housing reform policies in China, please see Wang and Murie (2000). 11 In both Gansu and Zhejiang, we can see the major housing reform policies in 1991 and 1996, when the number of housing purchases increased considerably from previous years (see Figures 1a and 1b). Work unit housing purchases began to decline in 1999 when housing reform policies were for the most part coming to an end. While there was virtually no private housing market in Gansu until 1998, in Zhejiang, the number of houses purchased in the private market seems to be closely related to housing reforms. For example, market-bought housing purchases peaked in 1991, one year before work unit purchases peaked during the first major wave of reforms. Market-bought housing also declined when work-unit housing purchases peaked. In addition, the number of housing purchases in the private market rose significantly in 1998, two years after the peak in work-unit purchases in 1996, during the second wave of major reforms. These fluctuations suggest that as work-unit housing became increasingly available for purchase, the private market for housing developed rapidly in response. By 1999, few houses could be purchased from employers. Private housing markets began to dominate the scene, with rapidly rising prices because of insufficient supply. Shing-Yi Wang (2010) examines the equilibrium price effects of the privatization of housing assets that were allocated by the state. Findings suggest that the removal of price distortions raised housing demand and equilibrium prices. Using variation in the timing of housing reform across cities, Iyer, Meng, and Qian (2010) find that housing reform increases the proportion of households living in private housing and lowers the proportion in public rental housing. Wang and Murie (2000) and Wang (2000) examine differences across different social groups and land-use zones (central vs. peripheral), focusing on Beijing. In Figures 2a and 2b, we can see the rapid response of the market to the availability of work-unit housing on the private market, as the 2008 market value of housing purchased from 12 work units increased considerably. In Zhejiang, the market value of housing purchased from work units during the two major reform periods in 1992 and 1996 was relatively high. Gansu being a much poorer province, has seen lower housing windfalls. But all of the windfalls in Gansu have come from work-unit purchases. In Zheijiang, the average current market value of housing purchased from the market increased substantially in 1996. This may have to do with the resale of housing obtained during the earlier period of housing reform in the early 1990s. These differences in market values also reflect the fact that the quality of housing purchased from work unit was considerably higher than privately owned housing. The degree to which households gained from the housing reform of the 1990s can also be seen vividly when the 2008 market values are compared to the average prices for housing at the time of purchase. In Figures 3a, we can see that work-unit purchases in Zhejiang were sold at considerably lower prices than housing sold in the private market. In the early 1990s, prices were extremely low and close to zero. In the second wave of housing form beginning in 1996, prices for work-unit housing rose. This may reflect differences in the quality of housing made available, or in the fact that by 1993, the Chinese government became concerned about the extremely low prices at which danwei housing had been sold. Nonetheless, the purchase price for work-unit bought housing was around half the price of market-bought housing. In addition, market prices for housing rose considerably after the second wave of housing reforms in the mid to late 1990s. In comparison, in Gansu where most houses purchased were purchased from work units, there was not much change in purchase prices (see Figure 3b). Both work unit and market prices remained extremely low. In comparing these figures with Figures 2a and 2b, it is clear that households have benefited considerably from a rise in housing prices in recent years. In Zhejiang, a private market for housing seems to have developed as a result. This is an important 13 point, since it indicates that housing assets were not completely illiquid assets. While in more developed countries, housing assets tend to be relatively illiquid, it seems there were considerable gains to selling a home that had been purchased from one’s work unit and may have been located in a choice location of the city. The primary constraint in selling one’s home may be due to a lack of affordable housing to find in its place. Further research is needed to understand the extent to which such constraints have played a role. In terms of our analysis, such constraints would underestimate our results, since we may overestimating windfall gains to household wealth. 4. Data and Empirical Analysis CHARLS Survey Data We use data from a pilot study for the China Health and Retirement Longitudinal Survey (CHARLS), which was conducted in 2008. Surveyed households were restricted to those with members ages 45 and above. Much of the questionnaire was based on survey questions from the Health and Retirement Study in the U.S. (HRS), the English Longitudinal Study of Ageing (ELSA), and the Survey of Health, Ageing, and Retirement in Europe (SHARE). Two provinces were chosen for the pilot study. Zhejiang is a relatively wealthy and highly urbanized coastal province. In contrast, Gansu is the poorest province in China. It is located in the interior of the country, and is populated by many non-Han minorities. In the two provinces, 48 communities or villages were surveyed, belonging to 16 counties or districts. The overall sample was comprised of 2,685 individuals living in 1,570 households. In this study, since only official urban residents were affected by the housing reform, we restricted our sample to those households in which the respondent or spouse held an urban hukou 14 or official urban registration, and the household was in an officially designated urban area. An urban area was defined as an area with a designated community office rather than a village office. Housing reforms were largely implemented by community offices, since work units or danwei employers were located in these areas. This restricted our potential sample to 258 respondents. We restricted our sample of children of these respondents to those who were the biological children of either the respondent or spouse, resulting in 588 children. Of these children, 575 of them were adults (age 16 and above). The sample was further restricted to nonresident adult children, resulting in a sample of 475 children of 196 respondents. The present value of all currently owned housing was summed to determine total household wealth. Respondents were asked specifically about their housing assets and how they were impacted by housing reform policies. The main respondent was asked detailed questions regarding purchase of the house of residence. In addition, the main respondent and spouse were asked about any housing they had purchased from a work unit. Questions included: who purchased the house, who owned the house at the time of the survey, the year of purchase, the purchase price, the market price at the time of purchase, and the current market price (at the time of the survey). The latter price was available so long as the housing unit was the respondent’s residence. If the unit had been sold prior to the time of the survey, then the current market price was replaced with the price at which the housing unit had been sold. If the unit had not been sold, and it was not listed as a residence (as was the case for 28 male and 7 female respondents), then these values were imputed using the local community average market value for urban housing bought from a danwei. For one respondent, there was no other such housing in the local community; the county average market value for urban housing bought from a danwei was used in this case. For one additional respondent, there was no such housing in the county, so the 15 current market value was imputed from the province average market value for urban housing bought from a danwei. Of the 475 children in our sample, the present market value of all housing currently owned by their parents was available for 468 children, and the year housing was purchased by their parents was provided for 457 children. The latter was needed to deflate the nominal value of housing purchase prices to real terms. Thus, there were 7 children for whom we were missing information on the present market value of their parents’ household wealth, resulting in a sample size of 450 children. Five of these children were born to two respondents in Gansu whose current residence was valued significantly higher than that of any other respondents. These extreme outliers were excluded from our sample, as they more than doubled the average current market value of a residence in urban Gansu. In addition, there were 16 respondents in urban Zhejiang whose household wealth was more than five times greater than the average housing value for the province. These respondents were also excluded from our sample. In addition to questions regarding housing, respondents and spouses were asked detailed questions regarding the value of household assets such as: a car, bike, refrigerator, washing machine, TV, computer, and mobile phone. They were also asked about household and individually-held financial assets such as cash, savings, stocks, and funds. In order to compute total household wealth, we summed up all of these assets and deducted the household's outstanding and unpaid loans and mortgage payments, and added it to our measure of household wealth. Available data on this amalgamated measure of total household wealth resulted in a sample of 395 observations. This measure of total household wealth was instrumented by the total housing windfall, which is the sum of: the difference between the current market price of all currently owned 16 housing and the original purchase price in real terms; and the difference between the price at which housing was sold and the original purchase price in real terms. Thus, while differences in household wealth may reflect some differences in lifetime earnings, the housing windfall is independent of such differences because it varies depending on the price at which the housing was originally purchased, which was exogenously determined by state policy. For three current residences owned by the respondent, the original purchase price was missing. As these residences had originally been purchased from a danwei, these prices were imputed by the local community average purchase price in real terms for urban housing bought from a danwei. Similarly, missing purchase price data for any danwei-bought housing that was not a current residence was imputed in the same manner for 27 male respondents and 7 female respondents. For one male respondent, there were no such prices in the local community, so the county average purchase price for urban housing bought from a danwei was used instead. Finally, in addition to these questions on asset-holdings, respondents were asked a number of detailed questions about financial transfers. The first question in this section of the survey was quite detailed, in order to remind the respondent of all of the different possible sources of help they may have received or provided to others in the past year: “Did you or your spouse receive more than 100 Yuan in financial help last year from any others? By financial help we mean giving money; helping pay bills; covering specific costs, such as those for medical care or insurance, schooling, and down payment for a home or rent; and providing non-monetary goods.” The respondent was then asked: “What kind of help did you receive: regular or nonregular allowance? What is the total value of regular financial help you received? How much non-regular financial help, such as an allowance, a living stipend, or money for school expenses, did you receive in the past year?” Respondents also noted any transfers received during special 17 occasions such as festivals, holidays, birthdays, or marriages. The focus of our analysis was on all of these received transfers combined, net of transfers provided to adult non-resident children. We dropped six outliers on the variable for net transfers, which were above the 98th percentile for this measure. With these outliers, average non-negative net transfers were 1307 RMB and without these outliers, the average was 1048 RMB. The resulting regression sample consisted of 389 respondents. For six of these children, we did not know whether or not they were living in the same city as their parents. Of the remaining 383 children, 343 children gave at least as much to their parents as they received from them (non-negative net transfers from children), and 224 children gave more to their parents than the amount they received from them (positive net transfers from children). Summary statistics on all variables included in the analysis for our resulting sample are presented in Table 1. Means and standard errors were estimated using household sampling weights. Nominal values were deflated by the urban province-specific Brandt-Holtz deflator where possible (years 1986-2004). For other years, nominal values were deflated by the urban province-specific consumer price index (CPI) provided by the China National Bureau of Statistics in annual Statistical Yearbooks, where the 2008 Zhejiang CPI was set to 100. Linear Regression Analysis We are interested in measuring the extent to which the value of total household assets influences transfers received from non-resident adult children. To begin with, we estimate the following OLS regression: Transfersij = b0 + b1(Household Wealth)i + b2Xij + b3Xi + µc + εij (10) where Xij are child level controls, Xi are characteristics of the main respondent and spouse, and µc are community fixed effects. Child characteristics include: age, birth order, gender, highest 18 education level attained, whether the child is currently working, whether the child is married, whether the child lives in the same community or neighborhood as the parent, the number of adult siblings, the average education level of adult siblings, and the average age of adult siblings. The latter two variables are interacted with whether the child has any adult siblings. Characteristics of the main respondent include: marital status, number of non-adult children, household size, whether the CHARLS respondent lives with an adult child, age of household head,7 age of household head squared, whether the household head was employed in the public sector, dummies for the highest education level of the household head, and dummies for five year intervals of the year of the first housing purchase interacted with whether a housing purchase was made. Estimates of b1 are likely to be biased since households owning a greater amount of wealth may also behave differently than poorer households when it comes to decisions regarding intergenerational transfers. For example, wealthier individuals may have better educated or higher ability children who provide them with greater financial assistance, or alternatively, who require less financial assistance from parents. In addition, reverse causality may be at play here. Respondents who receive more transfers from children on a regular basis may save this source of income and would have larger holdings of financial assets as a result. For these reasons, we employ an instrumental variables approach, using estimates of the housing market windfall as instruments for household wealth. The following two-stage leastsquares regressions are estimated using equations (11) and (12): (Household Wealth)i = b0 + b1Hi + b2Xij + b3Xi + µc + εij (11) Transfersij = b0 + b1(Estimated Household Wealth)i + b2Xij+ b3Xi + µc + εij (12) 7 By household head, we mean the husband if the respondent is married and living with a spouse, and the respondent otherwise (whether male or female). 19 where Hi is our instrument for household wealth. The instrumental variable used here is the housing market windfall, which is the difference between the current housing market value and the price at which the house was originally purchased if it is still currently owned, combined with the difference between the price at which any work unit housing was sold and its purchase price. There are a number of potential endogeneity issues here. Housing with higher markups over time is likely to be better than average quality. Since housing wealth is included in our measure of household wealth, the source of identification in instrumenting with housing windfall is the housing purchase price. Another potential bias is that the type of person who is allocated this type of housing and can afford to purchase it (perhaps even with a subsidy) may be different from the average person. Some may choose to work in a work unit in order to receive subsidized housing in a good location. For this reason, we control for characteristics of the household head, such as education and whether he/she worked in the public sector. We also estimate regressions where the housing windfall is the dependent variable and the unit of observation is the CHARLS respondent or parent and transfer recipient. These estimates indicate that a significant determinant of the windfall is the year of the initial housing purchase (see Table 4). In particular, housing purchased in the early 1990s has a higher windfall. This reflects the relatively low price for housing purchases during this early period of the reform. In addition, the number of adult children is a statistically significant predictor of housing windfalls. We include it as a control variable in all regressions. Relatedly, one might consider that living arrangement decisions of children may be impacted directly by these changes in the housing market, which would also impact intergenerational transfers. In fact, we find that living arrangement decisions of adult children are not impacted by household wealth when instrumented by the housing windfall (see 20 Table 5). We also examine whether a child’s characteristics are affected by household wealth when instrumented by the housing market windfall. We find that while education is not influenced by parent’s wealth, a child’s age is negatively related to wealth and positively related to the probability that an adult non-resident child is working. These characteristics are included among the covariates in all regressions. Non-Linearities and the Conditional Least Squares Model In order to determine transfer motives, recent studies in developing countries examining the relationship between transfers and recipient pre-transfer income have emphasized the nonlinearity of the relationship. While linear estimations do not necessarily point towards a strong relationship between recipient income and transfers, authors do find evidence of a non-linear relationship between recipient income and transfers (Cox et al. 2004, Cai et al. 2006). We also find evidence of such non-linearity in our case. Using our main regression sample for non-negative transfers, and controlling for the other covariates in equation (12), we plot net transfer receipts as a function of recipient wealth instrumented by housing windfalls to transfer recipients. More specifically, we regress net transfer receipts on Xij, Xi, and µc, and plot the residuals from this regression on the y-axis. We then estimate our first stage equation (11) to calculate predicted household wealth. We regress this predicted wealth on our covariates Xij, Xi, and µc, and plot the residuals from this regression on the x-axis. We graph a lowess estimator for the relationship between these residuals with a 0.99 bandwidth. Figure 4 displays the resulting Ushaped relationship between net transfer receipts and wealth levels. For relatively low wealth levels, predicted wealth and transfer receipts are negatively related, pointing towards altruistic motives. But as recipients’ predicted wealth increases, transfers flatten and then begin to 21 increase.8 Most of our observations are clustered around the first half on the initial U-shaped curve. Nonetheless, the curvature follows the model proposed by Cox et al. 2004 (see their Figure 1), where here we replace recipient income with recipient wealth. For relatively low wealth levels, transfer receipts decline with wealth, as children provide less support to parents who are less in need of it. These children are altruistically motivated to provide financial support to their parents. But at a certain wealth level, transfer motives switch to an exchange motive, where children provide more transfers as wealth levels increase. For these parents, children may provide financial transfers in exchange for services such as care of grandchildren (Secondi 1997). As parent wealth increases, parents may want more reimbursement for their time until parents become so wealthy that they want to devote less of their time to grandchild care, and therefore receive fewer transfers from children. In order to examine this potential relationship further, we follow the approach used by Cox et al. 2004 and Cai et al. 2004. The latter authors showed that this method yields similar results to those derived from a partial linear model (described in greater detail by Yatchew 1998, 2003). As the latter method requires a considerably large sample size, we implement the conditional least squares model. In this model, Transfersij = b0 + b1min(Wi, K) + b2max(0, Wi-K) + b3Xij + b4Xi + µc + εij (13) where Wi is recipient household wealth and K is the point at which transfer motives switch from altruistic to exchange motives. If transfers are altruistically motivated, then the derivative between transfers and wealth would be negative, since children would provide fewer transfers to parents who are in less need of them. The other variables are defined as before. Similarly to Cai 8 The positive slope at higher wealth levels is identified from relatively few observations; it disappears if the largest 16 wealth residual observations are excluded. However, the kink in the downward slope remains (steep decline followed by lesser decline) . 22 et al. (2006), we use net transfers received as the main dependent variable, and gross transfers received as a robustness check (the latter results are available upon request from the authors). As household wealth is potentially endogenous, we instrument this variable with housing windfall (Hi). Thus, we estimate the following set of regressions using a two-step instrumental variables tobit estimator: Wi = b0 + b1Hi + b2Xij + b3Xi + µc + εij (14) Transfersij = b0 + b1 est. min(Wi, K) + b2 est. max(0, Wi-K) + b3Xij + b4Xi + µc + εij (15) In this model, K is the value of instrumented household wealth at which point transfer motives change from altruism to exchange. IV. Empirical Results Relationship between Household Wealth and Net Transfer Receipts Table 2 summarizes results from OLS and Tobit estimations where the net transfer amount received from adult non-resident children is the dependent variable and household wealth is the main independent variable. Where wealth is entered linearly into the regression, or in those regressions where a squared wealth term is added, coefficient estimates on household wealth are not statistically significant and are quite small. However, in the Conditional Least Squares Model (CLM), coefficient estimates on wealth below the kink point are negative, very high, and statistically significant. Also, the estimated kink point is at the sixth or second percentile, which indicates that altruistic motivations would only be relevant here for the very poorest households. Such estimates on household wealth may be overestimating the effect of wealth on transfers if the poorest households have children who are also very poor. If this is the case, then children may respond 23 very strongly to a marginal increase in parental wealth because they are less willing and able to provide additional resources to parents whose need for support declines at the margin. In all of these regressions, we also include controls for sibling characteristics to examine the extent to which competition among siblings might also play a role in determining transfer motives. Those who have an adult sibling provide significantly less transfers, indicating that perhaps siblings share in the responsibility of providing support to their parents. On the other hand, there is also some evidence of possible competition among siblings, as transfers are positively related to the average education level attained by adult siblings. This positive relationship may also be explained by the fact that those with better educated siblings may themselves earn more as a result, and are therefore more willing and able to provide financial support to their parents. Delineating between these two hypotheses would be an interesting research question for future work in this area. Adult siblings may play another role in determining financial transfers provided to parents. If an adult sibling lives with the parent, then a non-resident child may provide fewer transfers to the parent. Since money is generally fungible among household residents, at least some of the support provided by a non-resident child to a parent may be shared with co-residing children. In addition, this child may provide additional income to the household, so that parents would be in less need of support from their non-resident children. While we have shown that adult children are not more likely to live with parents who have received greater windfalls, the presence of an adult child in the household reduces transfers from non-resident children, particularly for the sample of non-negative net transfers. Coefficient estimates on this variable are strongly negative and statistically significant for non-negative net transfers. Estimating the effect of household wealth on net transfer receipts 24 By instrumenting for wealth with windfalls arising from housing reform, we can identify the effects of an increase in wealth on transfers (see Table 3). In the first stage of the two-stage least-squares regressions, coefficient estimates on housing windfall are statistically significant and very close to one, indicating that the housing windfall is a strong predictor of household wealth. In the second stage of the two-stage least squares results, where household wealth is instrumented by housing windfall and enters linearly into regressions on transfer receipts, coefficient estimates are negative, but relatively small in magnitude and statistically insignificant. However, when a squared term on predicted wealth is added to the regression, coefficient estimates are higher, and for the subsample of positive net transfers, estimates are statistically significant at the 1% level. An increase of 10,000 RMB in household wealth results in a reduction in non-negative net transfers of approximately 17 RMB and a reduction in positive net transfers of roughly 27 RMB. With average household wealth at 250,000 RMB and net transfer receipts at 1031 RMB including zeros and1580 excluding zeros, these results imply that a 4% average increase in household wealth reduces transfer receipts on average by roughly 1.7%. Next, we apply the conditional least squares model with instrumental variables as outlined above to examine whether the linear relationship between predicted household wealth and net transfer receipts may be underestimating the degree to which transfer motives are altruistic. Transfers at higher wealth levels may not be as greatly affected by marginal increases in wealth, with altruism being strongest for lower levels of wealth. Results of these regressions indicate there is a non-linear relationship between instrumented household wealth and net transfer receipts. These non-linear estimates also indicate that linear regressions underestimate the relationship between transfers and household wealth for those parents with wealth levels at or 25 below the 32nd or 43rd percentile (a predicted household wealth level of around 100,000-146,000 RMB). Beyond this kink point, the relationship between wealth and transfers becomes relatively flat and coefficient estimates are not statistically significant. Thus, household wealth and transfer receipts are more strongly negatively related at lower wealth levels, with altruism playing a stronger role at these lower levels. An increase in household wealth of 10,000 RMB (4% increase on average) results in a decline of 46 to 57 RMB in transfers, a decline of roughly 4.5% or 3.6% on average, with the lower estimates resulting from the smaller subsample of positive net transfers. These estimates also indicate that non-instrumented estimates significantly overestimate the effect of household wealth on transfer receipts. The poorest respondents may have poor children who are less able to provide support to their parents, particularly when the parents receive a marginal increase in wealth. In contrast, an exogenous increase in household wealth indicates that parents do indeed receive fewer transfers from their children, particularly for those with predicted wealth levels below the 32nd percentile. These results point towards evidence of altruistic motivations for transfers from children for the lowest wealth households. In addition, as in prior regressions, these results point to some potentially interesting dynamics in the role of sibling characteristics in determining net transfer receipts. As before, those who have an adult sibling provide significantly fewer transfers to parents, though coefficient estimates are only statistically significant for the sample of non-negative net transfer receipts. When zero transfers are excluded from the sample, coefficient estimates are imprecise. Similarly, the average education level of adult siblings is positively related to net transfers, though again, estimates are statistically significant for only the sample of non-negative net transfers. As previously mentioned, these results may point towards some sharing of the 26 responsibility for caring for elderly parents, and also perhaps some competition among siblings for currying favor with parents. But on the other hand, those with more educated siblings may be wealthier as a result, and therefore may be better able to provide financial support to their parents. Understanding these dynamics across siblings is an important question for future research. Finally, we include a dummy variable for living with an adult child in these regressions. Coefficient estimates on this variable are strongly negative and statistically significant for nonnegative net transfers. Thus, the presence of an adult child in the household may deter some nonresident children from providing financial transfers to their parents. Determinants of Household Wealth and Housing Windfall In order to examine potential sources of selection bias in our instrument and instrumented variable, we estimate regressions on household wealth and the housing windfall on a number of covariates, with the unit of observation being the parent who receives the transfers and potentially received a windfall in housing assets. The results summarized in Table 4 show that one statistically significant predictor of household wealth is the number of adult children of the parent. A respondent with one additional adult child has a greater wealth level of roughly 94,000 RMB, and received an additional windfall amount of roughly 184,000 RMB. However, the number of adult children does not have a significant impact on wealth or windfalls for our smaller sample of positive net transfers. Coefficient estimates are relatively low in magnitude and statistically insignificant. For all other characteristics of the parent, coefficient estimates on the windfall are relatively low in magnitude. One significant factor in determining housing windfalls is the timing of the housing purchase. Purchases made in the 1990s, particularly between 1990 and 1994, resulted in 27 significantly higher windfalls than purchases made in other years. In particular, a housing purchase made between 1990 and 1994 resulted in an increase in the housing windfall of 180,000 to 390,000 RMB. With an average housing windfall of 109,000 RMB for our sample, this implies that housing purchased in the early 1990s resulted in a windfall that was 65% greater than the average windfall, and over 250% higher than average for the smaller sample of positive net transfer recipients. This indicates the importance of the timing of housing purchases, as government policies varied sale prices over the years of the reforms. As the timing is so important, we control for the year of housing purchase in all our regressions. Living arrangements and characteristics of adult children While the empirical results above indicate that transfer motives are altruistic in this context, the relationship between transfers and household wealth may be confounded by the fact that parents with higher household wealth live in nicer and larger accommodations which may be more attractive places for adult children to live in with their parents. The first column of Table 5 shows results of IV probit estimates of instrumented household wealth on the likelihood a child lives with the parents. While previous regressions included only non-resident adult children, these estimates also include co-resident adult children. Results indicate that children are not more likely to live with parents whose household wealth is greater. Regression results also indicate that household wealth as predicted by one’s housing windfall does not impact a child’s educational attainment. To the extent that the highest education level achieved is a reasonable proxy for income, these regressions indicate that respondents with higher household wealth do not generally have better off children. However, parent wealth does increase the likelihood that a child is currently working. When the dependent variable is birth order, coefficient estimates on household wealth are also not statistically 28 significant, and magnitudes are relatively low. However, parents’ wealth is negatively related to a child’s age. As wealthier parents have younger children who are also more likely to be working, we control for these characteristics among others in all our regressions. Sensitivity Analysis The above results have shown the importance of examining the non-linear relationship between recipient wealth and net transfer receipts. These results have also shown that children are likely to be altruistically motivated in making transfers to their parents, particularly when recipients have wealth levels below the 32nd percentile. In this section, we examine how robust these findings are to variations in our model specification and sample. In the above results, we had eliminated the top 2% in net transfer receipts as these were outliers in our sample. In Appendix Table A1, we summarize the results of regression estimates when these outliers are included in the sample. Coefficient estimates on total assets remain negative for all regressions, and results of the second stage of CLM with IV are also robust to including these outliers. While coefficient estimates on wealth levels below the kink point are higher in magnitude for this sample, average net transfers are also considerably higher when these outliers are included. For the sample of non-negative net transfers, the coefficient estimate is statistically significant at the 10% level, and the wealth level at which point transfer motives switch is similar to the previous sample (33rd percentile). For the smaller sample of positive net transfers, the wealth level for a switch in transfer motives remains close to the 34th percentile, and the coefficient estimate is statistically significant at the 1% level. Finally, coefficient estimates on sibling variables are fairly similar to those in our main regressions, though magnitudes differ somewhat in some cases. 29 In order to examine the role of adult siblings further, we estimate our regressions on the subsample of children who have adult siblings. Our results are robust to using this subsample. When a squared wealth term is included in the regression, coefficient estimates on total wealth are negative and statistically significant at the 5% and 1% levels. For the second stage of CLM with IV, coefficient estimates on wealth levels below the kink point are very similar to those in our main regressions and they are statistically significant at the 1% level. The wealth level at which point transfer motives switch from being altruistic to an exchange motive is at the 83rd percentile for non-negative net transfers, and the 69th percentile for positive net transfers. Thus, the kink point is considerably different when the sample is restricted to those with adult siblings and zero net transfers are included in the sample. Finally, the number of adult siblings and their average education level remain positively related to net transfer receipts. Thus, while sibling competition may be at play here, these regressions primarily point towards strong evidence of altruistic motivations behind transfers to parents when children have adult siblings. Yet, the presence of an adult child living with the parent seems to have a strongly negative effect on transfers from non-resident children. We examine this issue further by restricting our sample to those children whose parents do not live with any adult children (see Table A3). For this smaller sample, altruistic motivations are more pronounced than in prior regressions, with considerably higher magnitudes in our coefficient estimates, which are statistically significant at the 1% level. In addition, the wealth level at which point transfer motives switch from altruism to exchange is much higher than in previous regressions. Thus, for a majority of the sample of CHARLS respondents who do not live with an adult child, nonresident children are altruistically motivated in providing transfers to their parents. This further points to the importance of other household members in determining transfers. Non-resident 30 children may be less altruistically motivated in providing support to parents who may share transfers with co-resident siblings. Alternatively, parents may be less reliant on non-resident children because of the support they receive from co-residing children. Since co-residing adult children are an important factor in determining financial transfers to parents, more broadly, proximity to parents may also be important here. In the second set of regressions in Table A3, we restrict our sample to those children who live in the same city as their parents. If parents received a significant housing windfall, housing costs in the city they live in may be relatively high. For non-resident children living in the same city, such high housing costs may counteract altruistic motivations for providing transfers. In fact, results of CLM with IV are robust to this subsample. Coefficient estimates on wealth levels below the kink point are similar in magnitude to those of prior regressions, and they are statistically significant at the 1% level. In addition, coefficient estimates for wealth levels above the kink point are positive and statistically significant. For this sub-sample, the switch in transfer motives is most apparent. However, transfers are altruistically motivated for the majority of the subsample. Non-resident children may be more altruistically linked to parents when they live closer to them. We also examine this issue by including an interaction term between recipient wealth and a dummy variable for the child living in the same city as the parent. Here, the wealth kink point is quite high, at around the 95th percentile. In addition, coefficients on wealth for the wider sample of non-negative net transfers are much smaller in magnitude and are not statistically significant. There does not seem to be much of a relationship between non-negative net transfers and wealth when it is interacted with a dummy for living in the same city as parents. But for our subsample of positive net transfers, coefficient estimates are very similar in magnitude to those in our main regressions, and they are statistically significant. These differences may reflect 31 differences between those children who are net givers to parents and those who do not provide any support. Finally, as previously mentioned, we imputed a number of missing values on market values and purchase prices for housing. Our results are robust to excluding these imputed values. Coefficient estimates on the wealth level below the kink point are statistically significant at the 1% level. For our wider sample of non-negative net transfers, the coefficient on wealth below the kink point is higher in magnitude than in our main regressions, and for the smaller sample of positive net transfers, the coefficient is smaller in magnitude. For the sample of non-negative net transfers, the wealth kink point is fairly similar to that of previous regressions, but for the smaller sample of positive net transfers, it is much higher (84th percentile). Thus, there is some sensitivity in our estimates to these variations and it is important to keep this in mind when we consider how strong of a role altruism plays; the extent to which altruism is important may vary somewhat for different populations within our sample. Nonetheless, our general finding that transfer motives are primarily altruistic is robust to numerous modifications to our model specification and sample. It is apparent that the relationship between transfers and recipient wealth is non-linear. Particularly for the bottom third of our sample in terms of recipient wealth, transfers from non-resident children appear to be altruistically motivated. 6. Conclusion We have shown that housing reform policies have significantly raised housing market values. Employees of work units were allocated housing by their employers, were then given the right to buy this housing at subsidized rates, and benefited considerably as private housing 32 markets developed and housing prices rose considerably. We have shown that such windfalls have had a considerable impact on household wealth, and that family members take this into consideration when providing financial help to windfall recipients. Those who benefited from such windfalls receive considerably less financial help from children, indicating that transfers from children are likely to be altruistically motivated. 33 References Altonji, Hayashi, and Kotlikoff. 1997. “Parental Altruism and Inter Vivos Transfers: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Political Economy 105(6): 1121-66. Becker, Gary S. 1974. “A Theory of Social Interactions.” Journal of Political Economy 82: 1063-94. Becker, Gary S. 1981. A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Bernheim, Shleifer and Summers. 1985. “The Strategic Bequest Motive.” Journal of Political Economy 93(6): 1045-1076. Cai, F., J. Giles, and X. Meng. 2006. "How Well Do Children Insure Parents Against Low Retirement Income? An Analysis Using Survey Data from Urban China." Journal of Public Economics 90(12): 2229-2255. Cox. 1987. “Motives for Private Income Transfers.” Journal of Political Economy 95(3): 508546. Cox. 1990. “Intergenerational transfers and liquidity constraints.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 105(1): 187-217. Cox, Eser, and Jimenez. 1998. “Motives for Private Transfers over the Life Cycle: An Analytical Framework and Evidence for Peru.” Journal of Development Economics 55: 57-80. Cox, Jansen, and Jimenez. 2004. “How responsive are transfers to income? Evidence from a laissez-faire economy.” Journal of Public Economics 88(9-10): 2193-2219. Cox and Jappelli. 1990. “Credit rationing and private transfers: evidence from survey data.” Review of Economics and Statistics 72(3): 445-454. 34 Cox and Jimenez. 1992. “Social Security and Private Transfers in Developing Countries: The Case of Peru.” World Bank Economic Review 6(1): 155-169. Cox, Jimenez, and Okrasa. 1997. “Family Safety Nets and Economic Transition: A Study of Worker Households in Poland.” Review of Income and Wealth 43(2): 191-209. Cox and Rank. 1992. “Inter-vivos Transfers and Intergenerational Exchange.” Review of Economics and Statistics 74(2): 305-314. Guiso and Jappelli. 1991. “Intergenerational transfers and capital market imperfections: Evidence from a cross-section of Italian households.” European Economic Review 35(1): 103-120. Hoddinott, J. 1992. “Rotten Kids or Manipulative Parents: Are Children Old Age Security in Western Kenya?” Economic Development and Cultural Change 40: 545-566. Iyer, Meng, and Qian. “Estimating the value of individual property rights: evidence from China’s urban housing reforms.” Working Paper. Jensen, R.T. 2004. "Do Private Transfers Displace the Benefits of Public Transfers? Evidence from South Africa." Journal of Public Economics 88: 89-112. Kazianga, H. 2006. “Motives for household private transfers in Burkina Faso.” Journal of Development Economics 79(1): 73-117. La Ferrara, Eliana. 2007. “Descent rules and strategic transfers. Evidence from matrilineal groups in Ghana.” Journal of Development Economics 83: 280-301. McGarry. 1999. “Inter vivos transfers and intended bequests.” Journal of Public Economics 73: 321-351. McGarry and Schoeni. 1995. "Transfer behavior: Measurement, and the redistribution of resources within the family." Journal of Human Resources 30: S184—S226. 35 Raut, Lakshmi K. and Lien H. Tran. 2005. “Parental human capital investment and old-age transfers from children: Is it a loan contract or reciprocity for Indonesian families?” Journal of Development Economics 77: 389-414. Schoeni, Robert. 1997. “Private Interhousehold Transfers of Money and Time: New Empirical Evidence.” Review of Income and Wealth 43(4): 423-448. Secondi, G. 1997. “Private Monetary Transfers in Rural China: Are Families Altruistic?” Journal of Development Studies 33(4): 487-511. Sloan, Zhang, and Wang. 2002. “Upstream intergenerational transfers.” Southern Economic Journal 69(2): 363-380. Wang, Shing-Yi. “State Misallocation and Housing Prices: Theory and Evidence from China.” New York University Unpublished Manuscript. Wang, Ya Ping. 2000. “Housing reform and its impacts on the urban poor in China.” Housing Studies 15(6): 845-864. Wang, Ya Ping and Alan Murie. 2000. “Social and spatial implications of housing reform in China.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 24(2): 397-417. Wolff, Spilerman, and Attias-Donfut. 2007. “Transfers from migrants to their children: evidence that altruism and cultural factors matter.” Review of Income and Wealth 53(4): 619-644. Yatchew. 1998. “Non-parametric regression techniques in economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 36: 669-721. Yatchew. 2003. Semiparametric Regression for the Applied Econometrician. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge. 36 Figure 1a. Number of Housing Purchases in urban Zhejiang 30 Number of Houses Purchased Number of houses bought in the private market 25 Number of houses bought from danwei 20 15 10 5 0 1980 to 1984 1985 to 1989 1990 to 1994 1995 to 1999 2000 to 2004 2004 to 2008 Year of Purchase Figure 1b. Number of Housing Purchases in urban Gansu 30 Number of Houses Purchased Number of houses bought in the private market 25 Number of houses bought from danwei 20 15 10 5 0 1980 to 1984 1985 to 1989 1990 to 1994 1995 to 1999 Year of Purchase 37 2000 to 2004 2004 to 2008 Average Current Market Value per Square Meter (1000 RMB per square meter) Figure 2a. Current Market Value of Housing in urban Zhejiang 0.07 0.06 Current Market Value of Privately Bought Housing Current Market Value of danwei bought housing 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 1980 to 1984 1985 to 1989 1990 to 1994 1995 to 1999 2000 to 2004 2004 to 2008 Year of Purchase All values are deflated by the urban province-specificCPI, where the 2008 Zhejiang CPI=100. The Brandt-Holtz delfator is used for 1986-2004. For all other years, the urban province-specific CPI is from the China Statistical Yearbooks. 38 Average Current Market Value per Square Meter (1000 RMB per square meter) Figure 2b. Current Market Value of Housing in urban Gansu 0.014 0.012 Current Market Value of Privately Bought Housing Current Market Value of danwei bought housing 0.01 0.008 0.006 0.004 0.002 0 1980 to 1984 1985 to 1989 1990 to 1994 1995 to 1999 2000 to 2004 2004 to 2008 Year of Purchase All values are deflated by the urban province-specificCPI, where the 2008 Zhejiang CPI=100. The Brandt-Holtz delfator is used for 1986-2004. For all other years, the urban province-specific CPI is from the China Statistical Yearbooks. 39 Average Purchase Price per Square Meter (1000 RMB per square meter) Figure 3a. Purchase Prices of Housing in urban Zhejiang 0.07 Purchase Price in Private Market 0.06 Purchase Price of danwei bought housing 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 1980 to 1984 1985 to 1989 1990 to 1994 1995 to 1999 Year of Purchase 2000 to 2004 2004 to 2008 All values are deflated by the urban province-specificCPI, where the 2008 Zhejiang CPI=100. The Brandt-Holtz delfator is used for 1986-2004. For all other years, the urban provincespecific CPI is from the China Statistical Yearbooks. 40 Average Purchase Price per Square Meter (1000 RMB per square meter) Figure 3b. Purchase Prices of Housing in urban Gansu 0.014 Purchase Price in Private Market Purchase Price of danwei bought housing 0.012 0.01 0.008 0.006 0.004 0.002 0 1980 to 1984 1985 to 1989 1990 to 1994 1995 to 1999 Year of Purchase 2000 to 2004 2004 to 2008 All values are deflated by the urban province-specificCPI, where the 2008 Zhejiang CPI=100. The Brandt-Holtz delfator is used for 1986-2004. For all other years, the urban provincespecific CPI is from the China Statistical Yearbooks. 41 800 -200 0 200 400 600 Figure 4a. Non-Negative Net Transfers and Recipient Wealth -50 0 Recipient Wealth Residuals 50 Note: 3 out of 343 Observations taken out (wealth residuals greater than 100 taken out). 42 Table 1. Summary Statistics Variable Obs Weight Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Net transfers received (RMB) 343 130 1031.21 1757.12 0.0 10794.9 Total household wealth (10,000 RMB) 343 130 25.84 42.53 -3.6 309.3 Housing windfall (10,000 RMB) 343 130 10.86 23.41 -4.1 200.0 Gender of child 343 130 1.50 0.50 1.0 2.0 Household head is married = 1 343 130 0.70 0.46 0.0 1.0 Household size 343 130 2.49 1.19 1.0 6.0 Child lives outside local area = 1 343 130 0.77 0.42 0.0 1.0 Housing purchase was made = 1 343 130 0.02 0.15 0.0 1.0 Year of first housing purchase 198 82 1994.45 7.56 1970.0 2008.0 Male head of household = 1 343 130 0.75 0.43 0.0 1.0 Age of household head 343 130 66.64 9.57 47.0 86.0 Education level of child 343 130 5.38 1.69 1.0 10.0 Child is married = 1 343 130 0.83 0.37 0.0 1.0 Child is currently working = 1 343 130 0.77 0.42 0.0 1.0 Age of child 343 130 38.34 10.05 16.0 77.0 Birth order of child 343 130 1.95 1.20 1.0 8.0 Number of adult siblings of child 343 130 2.06 1.55 0.0 7.0 Child has adult sibling(s) = 1 343 130 0.87 0.34 0.0 1.0 Mean education of adult siblings 343 130 4.48 2.20 0.0 9.0 Mean age of adult siblings 343 130 33.78 15.43 0.0 58.5 Number of non-adult children 343 130 0.02 0.15 0.0 1.0 Household head employed in public sector = 1 343 130 0.34 0.47 0.0 1.0 Education level of household head 343 130 3.90 2.32 1.0 12.0 Child lives in same city as parent = 1 343 130 0.74 0.44 0.0 1.0 Respondent lives with an adult child = 1 343 130 0.33 0.47 0.0 1.0 Sample used in main regression results (non-resident adult children, non-negative net transfers). 43 Table 2. Relationship between Household Wealth and Net Transfers Received from Children (Tobit and OLS) Linear wealth term only Total Assets (10,000 RMB) Squared wealth term included Non-Negative Net Positive Net Transfers (Tobit) Transfers (OLS) 3.202 3.763 (3.374) (5.126) Total Assets Squared Non-Negative Net Transfers (Tobit) 1.28 (8.526) 0.007 (0.030) Positive Net Transfers (OLS) -5.682 (10.833) 0.038 (0.040) Wealth Levels Below Kink Point Conditional Least Squares Model Non-Negative Net Transfers (Tobit) Observations R-squared or Pseduo R-squared 150.206 (144.558) -4,981.140* (2629.362) 466.092*** (152.449) 7.225 (59.625) -1,307.010** (586.617) 343 0.0382 17.004 (158.696) -3316.372 (2771.378) 143.205 (146.998) 11.504 (65.260) -827.778 (635.268) 224 0.4298 146.391 (145.460) -4,960.787* (2655.077) 463.972*** (154.528) 7.084 (59.823) -1,311.775** (594.419) 343 0.0382 0.342 (163.746) -3272.240 (2818.450) 130.661 (151.727) 10.236 (65.969) -809.423 (654.451) 224 0.435 -1,534.420** (609.507) 3.529 (3.408) 149.345 (140.503) -5,706.099** (2639.266) 485.178*** (152.326) 18.718 (59.624) -1,340.276** (580.071) 343 0.0398 Total Wealth Kink Point Percentile for Wealth Kink Point n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 0.0524 5.52% Wealth Levels Above Kink Point Number of adult siblings Have adult sibling = 1 Avg education of adult siblings Avg age of adult siblings Parents lives with adult child = 1 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by CHARLS respondent. Sample exclues outliers on housing windfall, housing wealth, and net transfers. Sample includes all non-resident adult children. 44 Positive Net Transfers (OLS) -13,095.065*** (2213.226) 6.856 (5.731) -28.493 (165.367) -4,126.210* (2407.259) 175.437 (136.385) 27.491 (58.735) -295.378 (527.437) 224 0.4789 0.0398 2.10% Table 3. Effect of Household Wealth on Net Transfers Received from Children (2SLS) First Stage of 2SLS Windfall (10,000 RMB) NonPositive Negative Net Net Transfers Transfers 1.220*** 1.181*** (0.140) (0.080) Total Assets (10,000 RMB) 2nd Stage of 2SLS NonNegative Net Positive Net Transfers Transfers (IV T-Tobit) (IV) 2nd Stage of 2SLS NonNegative Net Positive Net Transfers (IV Transfers T-Tobit) (IV) -2.806 (3.090) -17.375* (10.236) 0.053 (0.034) -4.445 (3.699) Total Assets Squared 2nd Stage of CLM NonNegative Net Positive Net Transfers (IV Transfers T-Tobit) (IV) -27.454*** (7.505) 0.090*** (0.029) Wealth Levels Below Kink Point Number of adult siblings 7.393*** (2.555) Have adult sibling = 1 -32.857 (21.917) Avg education of adult siblings 0.667 (1.988) Avg age of adult siblings 0.577 (0.491) Parents lives with adult child = 1 14.877 (10.034) Observations 343 R-squared or Pseduo R-squared 0.8877 11.444*** (2.742) -24.506 (30.326) 2.509 (2.366) 0.124 (0.773) 5.222 (10.737) 224 0.9426 224.851 (136.535) -4,988.219* (2636.004) 469.797*** (155.877) 5.704 (59.820) -1,176.304** (566.129) 343 0.0381 152.376 (148.152) -3,100.86 (2776.119) 134.364 (150.801) 9.556 (64.726) -717.397 (633.355) 224 0.4299 247.807* (138.244) -5,079.887* (2612.729) 464.951*** (154.523) 7.857 (59.111) -1,087.840* (553.794) 343 0.0387 190.701 (157.023) -3,333.22 (2775.759) 138.44 (150.472) 8.574 (64.562) -625.538 (615.997) 224 0.4594 -45.584** (20.292) -1.814 (3.120) 318.878** (149.363) -5,537.062** (2602.398) 517.103*** (151.400) 12.511 (59.307) -1,020.683* (544.716) 343 0.039 Total Wealth Kink Point n/a Percentile for Wealth Kink Point n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 9.96 32.36% Wealth Levels Above Kink Point -56.984*** (17.668) -2.618 (3.776) 326.133** (157.579) -4,284.371 (2617.934) 214.301 (143.682) 21.237 (61.889) -553.249 (569.049) 224 0.461 14.59 43.30% Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by CHARLS respondent. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Sample excludes outliers on housing windfall, housing wealth, and net transfers. Sample includes all non-resident adult children. 45 Table 4. Determinants of Household Wealth and Housing Windfall Total Household Wealth Housing Windfall Non-Negative Positive Net Non-Negative Positive Net Net Transfers Transfers Net Transfers Transfers Made housing puchase = 1 -13.572 8.808 1.588 13.946 (25.320) (17.650) (34.402) (23.868) Housing purchase in 1980-84 -16.847 9.251 -2.08 -2.264 (27.122) (18.906) (47.876) (33.217) Housing purchase in 1985-89 2.541 12.653 -2.169 11.056 (21.848) (15.230) (48.536) (33.675) Housing purchase in 1990-94 11.893 33.925*** 18.052 39.151* (16.039) (11.180) (29.494) (20.463) Housing purchase in 1995-99 2.741 16.544* -2.331 10.276 (14.178) (9.883) (21.937) (15.220) Housing purchase in 2000-04 -12.377 10.579 -24.302 4.319 (18.839) (13.132) (27.960) (19.399) Housing purchase in 2005-09 5.547 19.623 26.829 24.753 (30.273) (21.102) (40.800) (28.308) Number of adult children 9.400** 2.67 18.358*** 6.927 (4.003) (2.790) (6.441) (4.469) Number of adult sons 4.393 -1.526 -4.798 -6.767 (5.740) (4.001) (9.248) (6.416) Live with adult child = 1 20.975 9.269 10.935 11.208 (20.534) (14.314) (31.225) (21.664) Married Respondent -9.188 2.749 48.745 5.504 (24.122) (16.815) (75.705) (52.525) Household Size 1.083 -0.521 0.204 -0.389 (5.965) (4.158) (9.698) (6.729) % children living outside area -0.036 -0.053 -0.053 -0.198 (0.165) (0.115) (0.309) (0.214) Household head Is male = 1 18.73 -2.449 -34.241 -3.908 (25.030) (17.448) (72.707) (50.445) Age of household head -4.972 0.689 2.432 6.64 (9.199) (6.412) (16.095) (11.167) Age of household head squared 0.024 -0.005 -0.039 -0.048 (0.067) (0.046) (0.117) (0.081) Household head works in public sector 9.292 12.063 22.99 18.368 (11.468) (7.994) (21.491) (14.911) Mean children's education 0.867 -2.401 3.665 -2.574 (4.870) (3.395) (8.357) (5.798) Percent married children 0.046 0.029 -0.056 0.026 (0.254) (0.177) (0.417) (0.289) Percent working children 0.17 0.126 0.101 0.334 (0.206) (0.144) (0.401) (0.278) Mean age of children 0.265 -0.75 1.329 -0.964 (1.357) (0.946) (2.472) (1.715) Observations 105 105 75 75 R-squared 0.6822 0.5014 0.7273 0.5646 Standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Unit of observation is the CHARLS respondent, or parent recipient. Additional controls include number of non-adult children, household head education dummies and community fixed effects. 46 Table 5. Effect of Household Wealth on Child Characteristics All Adult Children Likelihood child lives with parent1 IV Probit Household Wealth (10,000 RMB) -0.003 (0.004) Observations 388 Wald Chi-squared or R-squared 308.6 x Likelihood child is Age of Child x working 2SLS IV Probit -0.010** 0.013* (0.005) (0.007) 431 325 0.9251 1323 Adult Non-Resident Children Education of Child 2SLS 0.000 (0.002) 343 0.5371 Age of Child 2SLS -0.010* (0.005) 343 0.9166 Birth Order of Child 2SLS -0.001 (0.001) 343 0.8085 Sample includes non-negative net transfers. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by CHARLS respondent. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 First stage results are not shown here as they are qualitatively similar to the first stage results when the dependent variable is transfers. 1 Dummy for parent living with adult child is excluded here. All other controls are the same as those in the main regressions. For this reason, there is a smaller sample size than one might expect in the regressions on the likelihood that the child lives with the parent; community fixed effects are included in these regressions. 47 Appendix Table A1. Effect of Household Wealth on Net Transfers Received from Children (Including Outliers) Windfall (10,000 RMB) First Stage of 2SLS NonNegative Positive Net Net Transfers Transfers 1.227*** 1.184*** (0.140) (0.080) Total Assets (10,000 RMB) 2nd Stage of 2SLS NonPositive Negative Net Net Transfers (IV Transfers T-Tobit) (IV) 2nd Stage of 2SLS NonPositive Negative Net Net Transfers (IV Transfers T-Tobit) (IV) -9.665 (6.453) -18.988 (15.612) 0.034 (0.046) -7.607 (5.797) Total Assets Squared 10.958*** (2.759) -29.308 (29.127) 2.972 (2.325) 0.178 (0.818) 4.641 (10.856) 230 0.9408 541.155** (242.944) -10,013.562** (4163.056) 761.231*** (265.642) 26.707 (87.499) -2,018.268*** (770.482) 349 0.0365 571.843* (318.886) -8,354.36 (5075.329) 318.308 (301.241) 54.174 (122.824) -1,409.120* (737.118) 230 0.4283 556.494** (247.381) -10,151.706** (4128.610) 761.048*** (265.431) 29.07 (86.572) -1,958.773** (767.603) 349 0.0366 593.543* (333.398) -8,792.972* (5221.429) 336.946 (303.804) 57.151 (126.430) -1,368.099* (736.230) 230 0.4329 -57.776* (29.868) -8.38 (6.962) 650.250** (260.331) -10,765.211*** (4085.064) 821.588*** (257.673) 36.29 (85.739) -1,824.287** (760.926) 349 0.0369 n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 10.53 32.95% Wealth Levels Above Kink Point Have adult sibling = 1 Avg education of adult siblings Avg age of adult siblings Parent lives with adult child = 1 Observations R-squared or Pseduo R-squared 7.489*** (2.495) -37.266* (20.881) 0.809 (1.997) 0.632 (0.493) 14.873 (10.121) 349 0.8867 Total Wealth Kink Point n/a Percentile for Wealth Kink Point n/a Non-Negative Net Transfers Positive Net (IV T-Tobit) Transfers (IV) -23.796* (13.300) 0.063 (0.045) Wealth Levels Below Kink Point Number of adult siblings 2nd Stage of CLM -79.445*** (29.286) -5.373 (6.630) 764.781** (356.378) -10,096.232** (4936.051) 423.995 (292.575) 78.273 (122.640) -1,193.487* (685.082) 230 0.4432 11.78 33.91% Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by CHARLS respondent. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Sample excludes outliers on housing windfall and housing wealth. Sample includes all non-resident adult children. 48 Appendix Table A2. Effect of Household Wealth on Net Transfers Received from Children (Sample with adult siblings) Windfall (10,000 RMB) First Stage of 2SLS NonNegative Positive Net Net Transfers Transfers 1.186*** 1.136*** (0.130) (0.073) Total Assets (10,000 RMB) 2nd Stage of 2SLS Positive Non-Negative Net Net Transfers Transfers (IV T-Tobit) (IV) 2nd Stage of 2SLS NonNegative Positive Net Net Transfers Transfers (IV T-Tobit) (IV) 0.138 (3.521) -26.626** (12.174) 0.099** (0.045) -1.106 (3.654) Total Assets Squared -36.984*** (6.121) 0.145*** (0.021) Wealth Levels Below Kink Point Wealth Levels Above Kink Point Number of adult siblings Avg education of adult siblings Avg age of adult siblings Parent lives with an adult child = 1 Observations R-squared or Pseduo R-squared 7.354** (2.835) 0.799 (2.003) 0.496 (0.469) 12.941 (10.159) 326 0.8961 10.091*** (3.308) 0.957 (2.236) -0.838 (0.602) 4.171 (10.808) 215 0.9529 312.620* (180.147) 446.562*** (155.930) -15.158 (60.965) -1,063.768** (521.044) 326 0.0339 220.469 (208.800) 69.436 (154.418) -23.626 (65.477) -457.577 (572.220) 215 0.4407 372.910** (179.908) 444.393*** (152.611) -11.553 (59.303) -923.086* (516.981) 326 0.0358 2nd Stage of CLM Positive Non-Negative Net Net Transfers Transfers (IV T-Tobit) (IV) 358.038** (174.271) 62.108 (146.698) -12.637 (60.004) -231.018 (512.134) 215 0.502 -47.473*** (17.966) 6.318 (3.948) 489.449** (196.066) 488.729*** (151.275) -12.717 (58.842) -605.454 (487.879) 326 0.0367 -73.949*** (10.561) 5.141** (2.520) 633.461*** (149.967) 174.512 (136.832) -34.69 (59.197) 112.675 (435.153) 215 0.5180 Total Wealth Kink Point n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 38.9093 27.49 Percentile for Wealth Kink Point n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 82.82% 69.30% Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by CHARLS respondent. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Sample excludes outliers on housing windfall, housing wealth, and net transfers. 49 Appendix Table A3. Sensitivity Analysis: Conditional Least Squares Model Non-Negative Net Transfers Positive Net Transfers T-Tobit IV T-Tobit OLS 2SLS Sample includes only those children whose parents do not live with any adult children Wealth Kink Point (10,000 RMB) 0.02 36.59 0.15 28.84 Wealth Kink Point Percentile 2.56% 81.18% 7.18% 74.59% Total Wealth Below Kink -12,641.022*** -91.462*** -9,201.793*** -88.457*** (15.535) (2.834) (2688.223) (19.989) Total Wealth Above Kink -1.359 4.013*** -1.327 -0.085 (1.096) (0.941) (5.081) (3.524) Observations 255 255 181 181 R-squared or Pseduo R-squared 0.0546 0.0551 0.5245 0.5526 Sample includes only those children who live in the same city as parents Wealth Kink Point (10,000 RMB) 0.016 37.77 201.12 27.11 Wealth Kink Point Percentile 1.83% 79.09% 97.33% 68.16% Total Wealth Below Kink -19,159.059*** -46.398*** 3.705 -60.613*** (2710.663) (13.497) (4.893) (10.691) Total Wealth Above Kink 8.295** 10.393*** 47.017*** 8.441** (3.525) (3.904) (12.783) (3.340) Observations 263 263 179 179 R-squared or Pseduo R-squared 0.0523 0.0485 0.5868 0.6091 Regressions include interaction between total wealth & living in same city as parents Wealth Kink Point (10,000 RMB) 10.12 116.11 0.04 110.55 Wealth Kink Point Percentile 48.90% 95.34% 2.10% 95.54% Total Wealth Below Kink 59.968 -15.868 -13,312.734*** -41.160*** (98.986) (12.541) (2722.885) (12.059) Total Wealth Above Kink 0.427 0.775 5.203 15.067** (4.589) (7.469) (5.640) (7.111) Live in same city = 1 1,003.335* -91.089 -442.005 -576.491 (510.725) (353.582) (366.134) (476.948) Interaction w/wealth below kink 5.157* 5.837 2.342 -5.076 (2.666) (6.821) (2.225) (6.307) Interaction w/wealth above kink -189.925** -1.177 -151.818 17.539 (75.497) (9.828) (1443.952) (11.593) Observations 343 343 224 224 R-squared or Pseduo R-squared 0.0405 0.0391 0.4834 0.4678 No imputed values for total wealth or windfall Wealth Kink Point (10,000 RMB) 0.040 6.58 0.04 43.57 Wealth Kink Point Percentile 3.75% 29.64% 2.19% 83.56% Total Wealth Below Kink -1,590.295*** -75.674*** -11,841.599*** -38.998*** (53.469) (5.197) (2193.608) (9.186) Total Wealth Above Kink 6.795*** 1.616** 8.957* 7.596** (0.660) (0.661) (5.279) (3.469) Observations 334 334 219 219 R-squared or Pseduo R-squared 0.0409 0.0408 0.5217 0.5143 Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by CHARLS respondent. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 50