Peter Bakvis 02.10.2012 01:02

advertisement
>>> Peter Bakvis <Pbakvis@globalunions-us.org> 02.10.2012 01:02 >>>
1 October 2012
Remarks on World Bank's WDR 2013
The World Bank has released the 2013 edition of its "flagship" annual policy research publication,
the World Development Report, which this year is on the theme of jobs. For the Bank to do a report
on this topic is in itself a sign of progress considering that it is an institution where, for a long time,
the dominant thinking was that as long as policies support economic growth, job creation would
automatically follow (not that, by any means, the Bank had a sure-fire growth formula).
The fact that the Bank has decided to focus on the jobs crisis, even if it is well after most other
international institutions have begun paying at least rhetorical attention to the issue, reflects the
impact of global demonstrations of concern about the persistent employment deficit and growing
inequality.
Debunking the Doing Business myth
The WDR 2013 contains several positive aspects but also some negative ones. Perhaps the most
important contribution is the WDR's useful review of economic literature (in Chapter 8) that corrects
a myth propagated by the World Bank's highest-circulation publication over several years, namely
that economies with completely deregulated labour market have substantially higher employment
growth than those that regulate minimum wages, hours of work, use of short-term contracts, etc.
That publication, Doing Business, suspended its "employing workers indicator" (earlier called "hiring
and firing indicator") in 2009 after pressure from the ILO, ITUC and some governments, but it
continues to collect the raw data for calculating the indicator and the Doing Business team not
hidden its desire to reincorporate it. The WDR's finding that the claimed robust relationship between
level of regulation and rate of employment is unfounded will hopefully put an end, once and for all,
to the Bank's campaign for across-the-board labour market deregulation. (It must be added,
however, that the balanced review of economic literature in Chapter 8 is tempered somewhat by a
one-sided view of labour regulation, centred largely on India, in an annex to Chapter 9 on "How to
accelerate labor reallocation?".)
The WDR presents useful material on the jobs crisis and its different manifestations in developing
and industrialized countries and pokes holes in some of the World Bank's favourite development
fads, pointing out that their employment impact is marginal or worse (that is, they may hinder job
creation in other sectors). These include support for micro-finance and for highly capital-intensive
extractive industry projects in developing countries. On the other hand, the report agrees that
support for health care, education, infrastructures and rule of law are all important ingredients for
steady high-quality job creation.
On the issue of rule of law, the WDR 2013 provides a substantial defence, for the first time in a highprofile World Bank publication, of the need to support compliance with the ILO's core labour
standards (Chapter 5). It also minimizes the contribution that voluntary corporate social
responsibility initiatives, which the Bank has played some role in supporting, can have in assuring
that workers' rights are protected: "Voluntary labor initiatives cannot substitute for domestic efforts
to set up adequate legal protections and put in place institutions to support compliance and provide
avenues for redress" (p. 306-307).
"Good jobs" instead of decent work
On the negative side, one of the most problematic elements is the WDR's decision to put aside the
ILO's Decent Work concept and substitute one of its own, which it calls "`good jobs for
development". The report offers this summary definition: "Good jobs for development are those
that make the greatest contribution to society, taking into account the value they have to the people
who hold them, but also their potential spillovers on others" (p. 154).
The WDR does not make it easy to understand what this vague concept means in practice, especially
when it adds that "jobs agendas are … inherently country specific" (p. 153). It does specify that jobs
that do not respect CLS "are unequivocally bad [and] should not be considered jobs" (p. 153). But
when it states that good jobs can include informal economy jobs where such rights are not enforced,
one wonders how deep the "unequivocal" commitment to CLS is. As for jobs that are not good for
development, the report makes abundantly clear that they include employment in "bloated" public
sector entities by using the term not once but three times (on pp. 17, 154 and 163).
This unjustified denigration of public sector employment is not the only instance in the WDR 2013
where some of the World Bank's deeply ingrained biases show through. Another is in the section
that repeats the decades-old Bank credo in support of further unconditional trade liberalization,
including of services, a theme to which it devotes three pages (Chapter 9). By contrast, the report
expresses no support for measures to prevent a recurrence of the financial sector's self-inflicted
meltdown that led to the greatest collapse of employment in 80 years, other than to mention that
the "financial crisis of 2008 has reopened heated debates about the appropriate level of regulation
of the financial sector" (p. 294).
Another problematic approach is that on "social insurance". The WDR seems to have decided that
the more common term of "social protection" is a bad word, which it may have done in order to
avoid mentioning the now widely-supported concept and objective of the Social Protection Floor.
First developed by the ILO, the entire UN system endorsed the SPF in 2011, as did the G20 at its
Cannes Summit last November. Even the IMF supports the concept to the extent of working with the
ILO in designing country-specific SPF financing mechanisms.
Social insurance is a narrower concept than social protection; in many countries social services and
income support schemes are not all established on an insurance basis, which is a market-based
notion of purchasing protection in case of a possible contingency and involving pooling of risk. The
WDR's insistence that all social protection is insurance leads to occasional nonsensical statements,
such as the following: "Concerns about job search disincentives and hidden redistribution have led
to some interest in unemployment insurance savings accounts [which are in fact not insurance] …
Some countries have adopted these savings accounts as an alternative approach to insurance-based
programs" (p. 273).
For a report on jobs, the WDR does not contain a great deal of information about the trade union
movement, although what it does include is mostly positive, such as observing its role in reducing
income inequality through collective bargaining and in achieving broader social goals. Strangely, a
passage on improving working conditions and workers’ rights in developing countries mentions the
role of multinationals and civil society organizations but not trade unions (p. 241).
Detailed boxes that focus on specific roles of trade unions are provided on the following topics: Self
Employed Women's Association of India; efforts of domestic workers' unions to obtain an ILO
convention; Cambodia's Better Factories programme; South Africa's collective bargaining councils;
new forms of collective bargaining in China; and Germany's reduced working time programme.
Peter Bakvis
ITUC/Global Unions - Washington Office
888 16th Street NW, suite 400
Washington, DC 20006
Phone: 202-974-8120
Fax: 202-974-8122
E-mail: pbakvis@globalunions-us.org
Download