Corporate Governance as a Mechanism to Mitigate Financing Constraints on Investment Anna Grosman1 This version: 16 May 2013 Abstract This paper addresses whether adopting good governance standards alleviates constraints on financing investment via improved internal efficiency or access to external capital. The Russian context serves as an appropriate setting for studying the longitudinal effect of governance. I use transparency and disclosure score computed by Standard and Poor’s (S&P) as the primary proxy for corporate governance, supported by shareholder ownership structure and shareholder characteristics. I find that corporate governance has a positive and significant impact on capital investment. I find also that state owned enterprises (SOEs) are more sensitive than oligarch-owned enterprises to improved governance, but less sensitive to the changes in internal funds (cash-flows). SOEs are poorly governed judging by their S&P transparency and disclosure scores, therefore, any improvements to their governance might have a significant effect on the level of their capital expenditures. On the other hand, it might be that SOEs are subject to soft budget constraints. I find also that governance of financially constrained firms positively and significantly affects investment. Governance, therefore, is a valid mechanism for reducing financing constraints on investment. The empirical analysis is conducted on a 10-year panel dataset containing observations on the largest Russian companies, publicly listed in Russia or abroad. Robustness checks and controls for endogeneity include dynamic panel generalized method of moments (GMM) and vector autoregression (VAR) techniques. Keywords Corporate governance, transparency and disclosure, investment, SOEs, oligarchs 1 Imperial College Business School. Email: a.grosman09@imperial.ac.uk. I thank Mario Amore, Erkko Autio, Bat Batjargal, Gilles Chemla, Ciaran Driver, Maria Guedes, Sergei Guriev, Philip Hanson, Jonathan Haskel, Bersant Hodbari, Alan Hughes, Anna Kochanova, Aija Leiponen, Ekaterina Lyahovetskaya, Janus Lim, Anita McGahan, Nigel Meade, Andrea Mina, Bruce Tether, Stefano Rossi, Ammon Salter, Alex Settles, Bruce Tether, Mike Wright and Todd Zenger for helpful comments and discussions. Participants at SOAS, the European School of New Institutional Economics (ESNIE), Druid Academy, London Business School Trans-Atlantic Doctoral Conference, Royal Economic Society (RES) job market, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Academy of Natalya Nesterova (Moscow), BASEES (the British Association for Slavonic and East European Studies), CEELBAS, Techniques in Management Research Workshop and Imperial College Research Festival also provided useful comments. I also thank Standard and Poor’s for providing the transparency and disclosure scores. This research is supported by EPSRC. All views expressed and errors are my own. 1 1. Introduction This paper researches the influence of corporate governance, measured by transparency and disclosure practices, on investment behaviour. I address two primary and distinct questions. First, does good corporate governance help internal capital markets to channel the right amounts of capital to each project within the firm? In other words, can corporate governance improve firm transparency and the efficiency of internal capital budgeting so that the funds are allocated appropriately among investment projects? And second, does good corporate governance help external capital markets to channel the right amount of capital to each firm? In other words, by being better governed, are firms able to attract adequate amounts of external capital to lift financing constraints on investment projects? Although these two questions are logically distinct - in the sense that the workings of the external and internal capital markets appear to be quite different - an overarching goal of this research is to emphasize how governance regulates capital allocations across and within firms. Corporate governance is one of the curative mechanisms that arise endogenously to mitigate the effect of financing constraints on investment outcomes. Both research questions addressed in this paper have been subject to prior empirical and conceptual study although the first question, on the impact of governance through internal capital markets, has been less well studied relative to the second question. The theoretical and empirical literature focuses on explaining capital budgeting practices on the basis of information and agency problems within the firm. This literature identifies cases where certain governance structures, through their impact on internal capital markets, can lead to either increases or reductions in the efficiency of capital allocation. This literature includes works by Rajan et al. (2000), Williamson (1975), Scharfstein and Stein (2000), to name a few (for a more extensive review, see Stein, 2003). Research on the impact of governance through external capital markets is more mature and includes seminal works by Hubbard (1998), Schleifer and Vishny (1997) and Johnson et al. (2000). Corporate governance, through firm transparency, plays a crucial role in giving firms access to external capital and, thus, mitigating financing constraints on investment. Arguably, the 2 importance of governance is underestimated by managers of funds-rich state-owned firms, but adopting high governance standards might still improve their firms’ internal efficiency and financing structure. I test the effect of corporate governance on financing constraints through investment, a factor that has not been tested extensively in the Russian context; most of the literature examines the effect of governance on firm value, profitability and performance, which are very widely used indicators of shareholder value. In summary, the research gap addressed by this paper is the relationship between transparency and disclosure practices, financing constraints, and investment behaviour in an emerging economy context. Related studies on corporate governance in Russia include Black et al. (2006, 2001), Goetzmann, Spiegel and Ukhov (2003), and Kuznecovs and Pal (2012); and Durnev and Kim (2005), and Klapper and Love (2004) (cross-country). These studies tend to focus on one year (in case of surveys) or a relatively short time period. Thus the access to the unique data computed by Standard and Poor’s (S&P) on transparency and disclosure (TD) rules in the period comprising reforms of governance code in 2002-2004 2 allows me to update the effect of governance on investment in Russia. I go beyond this literature in that my analysis highlights the different investment behaviours of the state and oligarchs. The present paper contributes also to the literature on financing constraints (Hubbard, 1998; Moyen, 2004; Raith et al., 2007; Brown and Petersen, 2009). Countries vary substantially in their predominant mode of firm governance. For simplicity, I compare two models: an external, diffuse shareholder model, and an internal concentrated blockholder model. In the presence of weak protection of shareholder rights, weak law enforcement, as well as less efficient capital markets, the predominant ownership structure is concentrated. The main risks that beset emerging economies, including Russia, are principal-principal conflicts, that is, conflicts between the ‘controlling’ and the minority shareholders. These conflicts centre on transparency and disclosure, dilution (through share issuance, mergers, etc.), asset stripping and transfer pricing, bankruptcy, limits on foreign 2 A new Code of Conduct was issued by the Federal Securities Commission (FSC) in February 2002, effective in 2003, reflected in firms’ accounts from 2004.The code’s major objective was to provide a framework for corporate governance in Russian firms (Puffer and McCarthy, 2003). 3 ownership, management attitude to shareholders, registrar risk, dividend policy and dividend payout. I contribute to the literature on concentrated blockholder models (Grossman and Hart, 1980; Shleifer and Vishny, 1986; Leland and Pyle, 1977; Aghion and Tirole, 1997; Claessens et al., 2000) and, more specifically, to work on politically connected firms, since state controls between 50 and 70% of Russian listed firms (Fisman, 2001; Faccio, 2006; Frye and Iwasaki, 2011; Okhmatovskiy, 2010). Russia’s unique institutional context allows longitudinal study of the effects of corporate governance on investment behaviour. In developed countries, governance is stable over time. The improvements to Russian governance over the last 10-20 years provide enough variation to test the relationship between corporate governance and investments, in fixed effects and instrumental variable frameworks. Only a few studies examine governance in the Russian context over an extended period. The findings in this paper suggest that governance impacts on investment through internal capital markets and also that private ownership concentration could replace good governance. Specifically, I find that governance does not impact significantly on investments in the case of oligarch firms. This reinforces the theoretical and empirical findings of a curvilinear relationship between governance and concentration of ownership (Guriev et al., 2003). Up to a certain limit, ownership concentration has a positive effect on corporate governance. Above that threshold, the relationship becomes negative. Empirical findings suggest that the threshold is at about 50%, which reinforces the importance of corporate control market. I find also that governance matters most for fixed investment by SOEs. State companies make up 80% of the value of stock market in China, 62% in Russia, and 38% in Brazil.3 Another important finding is related to the zero sensitivity of cash flow to investment for SOEs. In emerging economies context, zero sensitivity of cash flow to investment is interpreted as evidence of a weak form of soft budget constraints (Lizal and Svejnar, 2002). Firms face soft budget constraints if there is willingness of government or some other institution to provide additional resources or to otherwise bail them out.4 A positive 3 Sources: Deutsche Bank, Fortune and The Economist 4 See Kornai (1979, 1986, 1998) for an introduction to and discussion of the concept of a soft budget constraint. 4 sensitivity of cash flow to investment can be interpreted as evidence of financing constraints (Fazzari et al., 1988). When estimating the impact of governance on capital investment through external capital markets, I find that corporate governance matters for investment in firms that are a priori financially constrained. While corporate governance influences investments, the opposite could be argued that capital-intensive firms might decide to improve transparency and disclosure levels in order to obtain more investment (reverse causality). More importantly, the relations between governance and investment are likely to be dynamic (unobserved heterogeneity and simultaneity). For example, current investment will affect future governance choices and these, in turn, may affect future firm investment. I address endogeneity using dynamic panel data (Arellano-Bond Generalized Method of Moments – GMM - version) and vector autoregression (VAR) techniques. The dynamic panel GMM estimator incorporates the dynamic nature of governance relationships to provide a valid and powerful instrument that controls for unobserved heterogeneity and simultaneity (Wintoki et al, 2012). The use of GMM estimator is also strictly required where the lagged dependent variable introduces Nickell’s bias (Arellano, 2003). The dynamic modelling approach has been used in other areas of finance and economics where the structure of the problem suggests a dynamic relation between the dependent and independent variables. Examples include governance and research and development (R&D) (Driver and Guedes, 2012), external finance constraints and investment (Whited and Wu, 2006), internal finance and investment (Bond and Meghir, 1994), economic growth convergence (Caselli et al., 1996), labour demand estimation (Blundell and Bond, 1998), and economic growth (Beck et al., 2000). The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the theoretical framework; Section 3 describes the data and the empirical proxies for corporate governance. Section 4 demonstrates the empirical relationships between governance, financing constraints and investment; Section 5 reports robustness checks. Section 6 concludes. 2. Theoretical Framework Financing constraints affect all publicly listed companies and particularly in emerging markets where debt and equity capital markets are underdeveloped or illiquid (La Porta et 5 al., 1997, 2000). Modigliani and Miller’s seminal work on the irrelevance of the financing structure has given rise to various models generally without reference to the possible influence of financing factors. However, by relaxing Modigliani and Miller’s assumptions, especially those related to the symmetry of information, firms experience financing constraints in the presence of imperfect and inefficient markets. The higher the asymmetry of information or the lower the standards of governance, the higher is the effect of governance on financing constraints (Hubbard, 1998) where such constraints exist. This effect of governance on financing constraints is illustrated in Figure 1. For constrained firms, good governance extends the horizontal part of the supply curve or flattens the angle of the slope as shown in Figure 1. Unconstrained firms will still benefit from good governance since it improves their operational transparency and efficiency. Figure 1: Financing constraints Rate of return Demand Demand (unconstraine (constrained d firm) firm) Supply of financing Good governance demand shift Supply of financing (good governance discount ) R1 R0 (=cost of internal funds) C0 Internal funds up to C0 C1 C1’ with good governance Capital By improving governance or reducing the asymmetry of information between agent and principal (external shareholder or debtholder), I hypothesize that the firm could mitigate financing constraints in the following (non-exhaustive) ways: 6 Hypothesis One. Internal capital market channel: Good TD may improve the firm’s internal efficiency making cash-flows more visible and controllable, and promoting more efficient allocation of internal funds stimulating investment expenditure; and Hypothesis Two. External capital market channel: the firm’s greater transparency will attract external investors and provide greater access to local and global financial markets, enabling the firm to raise more funds externally via capital markets mitigating financing constraints on capital investments. Since the influential work of Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen (1988), researchers have used the sensitivity of capital investment to cash-flow as a metric for gauging the severity of financing constraints. The intuition behind this test is straightforward. If a firm cannot obtain outside finance, then its investment should respond strongly to movements in internal funds. Implementing this idea requires controlling for investment opportunities; otherwise cash flow might capture movements in investment opportunities rather than movements in internal funds. Investment opportunities or demand are most often proxied by Tobin’s Q, although some studies suggested Tobin’s Q contains measurement error (Ericksson and Whited, 2000; Hennessy et al., 2007). The standard approach to measuring financing constraints continues to be based on fixed effects regression of capital investment on cash-flow and Tobin’s Q. Most studies find that firms that are a priori more likely to face binding financing constraints exhibit greater sensitivity of investment to cash-flow, for example, Fazzari et al. (1988, 2000), Hubbard (1998), Whited and Wu (2006) and Bond and Van Reenen (2007), but Kaplan and Zingales (1997, 2000) criticize this view. Referring back to Figure 1, the steeper the upward-sloping portion of the supply curve, the higher the cost of capital. Whether governance has the effect of making this slope shallower or steeper can be investigated by testing its interaction effect with a measure of access to external capital. In the extreme case, where there are no costs associated with the asymmetry of information between lender and borrower, the slope would be horizontal, and there would be no financing constraints on investment. Further analysis of the interaction effects is conducted in the section 4 ’Empirical Specification’. Conceptually, the claim that governance will positively affect investment cannot be straightforwardly justified. Jensen (1986) argues that managerial opportunism leads 7 managers to overinvest in ‘pet’ projects that do not create shareholder value; therefore, good governance might stop managers from investing and ultimately reduce investment. Jensen’s argument is based on events in the late 1970s and early 1980s related to US oil companies, which wasted a lot of money on pet projects and diversification. These acquisitions were unsuccessful partly because of the absence of managerial expertise outside the oil sector. The oil industry had large increases in free cash flow. However, the evidence shows that the oil firms continued to invest in exploration and development even though the rate of return probably had a negative net present value (NPV) (McConnell and Muscarella, 1985), rather than paying out the excess cash to shareholders. The overinvestment problem is likely to be more pronounced in stable, cash-rich companies in mature industries with few growth opportunities. The Russian institutional context allows me to hypothesize that there are no reasons to expect Russian managers to overinvest. Most Russian firms already have old and fully amortised assets, due to the legacy of the soviet regime and heavy use of outsourcers rather than reliance on own production. The current average longevity of equipment in Russia is twice its desired levels. In spite of the prolonged recovery in 1999-2008, capital investment by Russian firms is still low and of poor quality. Russian firms are characterized by inseparability of management and control due mainly to the influence of large shareholders over management. This influence over management is not unusual for firms with concentrated ownership (R. Murdoch, R. Branson and C. Koch preside respectively over News Corp, Virgin Group and Koch Industries and control their management entirely). But unlike in Europe and the US, there are legal loopholes in Russia allowing the majority shareholders (with the consent of managers) to funnel funds out of firms rather than to invest in long term assets and infrastructure. They seek to maximize short-term rents because of the uncertain legacy of their assets acquired in the 1990s’ privatisations, often through crime and bribes, which undermines investment and leads also to conflicts between majority and minority shareholders. The majority of Russian firms consider their productive assets to be underinvested and obsolete in the face of growing competition and market demand (Aganbegyan, 2008, Dzarasov, 2011). This institutional impediment to investment growth supports my hypothesis of good governance improving investment. 8 3. Data The mechanisms of governance can be assessed according to board and management structures, to shareholder rights, to transparency and disclosure of information, etc. Table Table 8 on page 55 in the appendices compares the methodologies of different institutions used to measure levels of corporate governance. All are based on more or less similar criteria. The TD score is the most frequent measure of governance standards and appears in the methodologies of four out of five institutions. I use unique corporate governance variables from the TD rankings of S&P. Black et al. (2006) analyse the various measures of corporate governance in Russia and conclude that sophisticated governance indices are not necessarily better predictors. They found the S&P TD scores to be more useful measures of governance, in that they predicted Tobin’s Q and, therefore, may correspond to the elements of governance that matter to investors. Black et al. (2006) state that, in this respect, TD scores outperform the more complex S&P governance indices. Based on previous research findings, I decided to use S&P TD scores as my proxies for corporate governance. The TD scores produced by S&P for 90 companies consist of three components: ownership structure and shareholder rights; financial and operational information; and board and management structure and process. These three sub-scores are positively correlated with one another. The checklist methodology consists of searching for 110 TD attributes relating to the three components (for the full list of attributes see Table 12 in the appendices). Each attribute is scored on a binary basis to ensure objectivity, and the scores for the three components are based on the scores for individual attributes. Scoring accounts for information included in three major sources of public information annual reports, web-based disclosures, and public regulatory reporting (such as publicly available statutory documents filed with the Federal Financial Markets Service (FFMS), the Russian financial markets regulator, the Frankfurt Stock Exchange, UK Listing Authority (UKLA), the UK Financial Services Authority (FSA), and the US Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), available on the web sites of companies and stock exchanges or the respective regulatory authority). According to the weighting system, public disclosure regardless of its source - yields 80% of the maximum score for each item in the check list used for data compilation. The remaining 20% of points (10% each) are awarded if this 9 information is also available from the other two sources. This methodology reflects the notion that replication of information in various sources represents value for investors since it makes the information more easily accessible. The value of replication, however, is incremental relative to the fact of disclosure. The S&P methodology is constructed from the perspective of an international investor, which is reflected in the list of attributes. Table 1: Example questions, survey of transparency and disclosure The strengths of the TD score lie in its usage and applicability. First, there is enough interfirm and temporal variation among scores to make the TD score an interesting variable for a longitudinal study. 2009 scores range from 20% for the lowest scored company to 80% for the highest one. There is room for improvement in future Russian TD scores. In 2009, the transparency index, calculated as the average score for the 90 Russian companies, was only 56%; in 2003, the last year that this survey was conducted in the UK, France and US the scores for these countries were respectively 71%, 68% and 70%. Second, TD scores matter for investors, especially foreign ones, since they are willing to pay the highest premium for Russian firms with the best governance practices relative to firms from other countries (McKinsey, 2002 - Global Investor Opinion Survey). Examples of these 10 firms include MTS, Vimpelcom and Wimm-Bill-Dann, which have higher trading multiples relative to their counterparts (Shekshnia, 2004). Third, transparency and disclosure are integral to corporate governance (Patel et al., 2002). TD practices are an important component of the corporate governance framework (OECD, 1999) and a leading indicator of corporate governance quality. Beekes and Brown (2006) find that firms with higher corporate governance standards make more informative disclosures. Transparency and full disclosure of information is important for emerging markets and particularly Russia, where external capital is necessary to sustain the high growth rate and the biggest agency problem centres on asymmetric information and expropriation by majority shareholders (Aksu and Kosedag, 2006). However, the TD scores produced by S&P used in this paper have not been analysed previously in connection with financing constraints on investment in Russia or other emerging markets. Most research that uses TD scores focuses on their interaction with firm value. Patel et al. (2002) provides a series of bi-variate correlations of price-to-book ratios to TD scores for six emerging countries,5 and finds that for five markets, this correlation is positive. Aksu and Kosedag (2006) provide evidence that firm size, financial performance and market-to-book equity best explain the variation in TD scores of the firms listed on the Istanbul Stock Exchange. Doidge et al. (2007) test a model of how country characteristics, such as legal protections for minority investors and the level of economic and financial development, influence firms’ implementation of measures to improve the transparency of their Profit and Loss Statement (P&L). The authors find that country characteristics explain much more of the variance in TD ratings (39%-73%) than observable firm characteristics (4%-22%). Patel and Dallas (2002), in one of the first studies on TD, highlight that firms with good TD practices have lower costs of capital. In their seminal research, Gompers et al. (2003) included TD as one of the components of corporate governance index and found that stronger rights in the US have led to better firm performance. Similarly, Klapper and Love (2004) and Black et al. (2006) considered TD parameters along with other corporate governance practices. Black et al. (2006) have used alternative governance indices provided by other agencies and investment banks and shown that governance positively influences firm’s value. 5 Kuznecovs and Pal (2012) find that TD scores significantly boosted the Does not include Russia. 11 performance of firms, particularly for utility firms. The general consensus in this literature is that better TD practices tend to lower the cost of capital, boost performance and increase firm value. The TD score gives a ranking for a firm based on publicly disclosed information. It is an objective measure in the sense that the information is either disclosed or not. The accuracy of the information, however, is not entirely assessed. To an extent, the disclosure of audited accounts, especially if they accord with IFRS or US GAAP standards and/or are conducted by a top-tier auditor, is some measure of the accuracy of the information disclosed. However, for more ’subjective’ governance measures, Russian companies tend to engage in ‘window dressing’, and good governance practices are limited to a box ticking paper exercise. Is an independent director really independent? Or, vice versa, is he so remote from the firm’s operations as to be purely a public relations figure? Nevertheless, TD scores by S&P are more reliable and complete than other measures of governance for Russian listed firms (for methodology on other governance measures, see Table 8 on page 55 in the appendices). TD and governance standards in Russia are improving gradually as more and more Russian firms participate in international capital markets. In 2009 over 60 Russian companies were listed abroad. S&P TD scores show that companies listed on the main markets of the London Stock Exchange (LSE) and the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) were substantially more transparent than those not listed.6 The data also show that companies electing independent directors to their supervisory boards have higher levels of transparency. Table 2 on page 13 lists number of observations, mean, median, standard deviation from mean, minimum and maximum observations for the raw variables used in empirical specifications. The TD total score is broken down into three sub-scores: financial and operational disclosure, ownership and shareholders rights, and board and management structure. The total score is an algebraic sum of the three sub-scores. Financial data are from the Compustat Global database for all Russian firms listed in Russia or abroad in the period 2000-2010. Investment is defined as annual capital spending on tangible assets. 6 Companies traded only in Russia had an average transparency index of 50%, whereas the transparency index for companies listed on the LSE was 63% and 74% for NYSE-listed firms. 12 Ownership data were collected from annual reports, web-based disclosures and business publications. Average annual sales for the sample are 2.1 billion euros7 which is quite high due to some large outliers and high standard deviation. Median annual sales are 486 million euros. Average capital investment amounts to 347 million euros and median investment to 57 million euros. The averages for the three sub-scores over the entire period are 51, 49 and 44 percent respectively. Table 2: Summary statistics There is significant correlation between firm size (proxied by sales) and its corporate governance (Table 3). Larger publicly listed firms tend to be more attentive to appropriate governance levels. Investment is strongly correlated with gross cash-flow, which is in line with mainstream finance theory. New debt is strongly correlated with governance; the higher the governance standards, the lower the cost of capital due to reduced moral hazard and, therefore, more access to external financing. 7 Exchange rate EUR/RUR of 40.8 over 01/01/2000-31/12/2010 period. 13 Table 3: Correlations 4. Empirical Specification Let us define the empirical specification. Investment equations can be run as ‘Q’, Euler or accelerator models. Q models use Tobin’s Q based on the idea that if Q is greater than 1, then a firm has an incentive to invest. Euler models are dynamic disequilibrium models that are estimated indirectly. Accelerator models can take many forms and relate to sales on the assumption of some constancy of the investment to sales ratio (which can be modified by including other variables). Both Q and accelerator models can be run in error correction form because they are both based on the idea of a target that may not be in equilibrium so disturbances from the target can be modelled. I start with an accelerator model of investment in error correction form. Most research shows that investment is non-stationary so the error correction model is preferred. Error correction models have been used for capital investment and R&D investment in a number of papers, such as Becker and Hall (2009), Bond et al. (2003), Mairesse et al. (1999), Bond et al. (1997), Blundell et al. (1992) and Bean (1981). βπππ‘ = π½0 + π½1 βππ,π‘−1 + π½2 (ππ,π‘−2 − π π,π‘−2 ) + π½3 βπππ‘ + π½4 βππππ,π‘−1 +π½5 πππ‘ + ππ‘ + πππ‘ (1), 14 where βπππ‘ is the first difference of the logarithm of investment. An alternative proxy for investment used in the literature is the ratio πΌππ‘ , where πΌππ‘ is investment and πΎπ,π‘−1 is ⁄πΎ π,π‘−1 the capital stock (fixed assets) at the end of the period t-1.8 However, by using βπππ‘ , I avoid reliance on πΎππ‘ which contains biased fixed assets valuation. In other words, πΎππ‘ is based on the assumption of depreciation of fixed assets and, hence, is less accurate than πΌππ‘ . πππ‘ represents a vector of the variables which have been emphasized as determinants of investment from a variety of theoretical perspectives. It includes first difference of sales in logarithms βπ ππ‘ . It also includes a debt term to control for possible omitted variable biases and to evaluate the changing role of external finance on investment (Bond and Meghir, 1994; Brown and Petersen, 2009). The rationale for the inclusion of lagged investment term, based on formal models of investment behaviour, is the presence of adjustment costs of investment (Brown and Petersen, 2009). βππππ,π‘−1 which is the first difference of the logarithms of the firm’s gross cash flow at the end of period t-1 is defined as the sum of net income and depreciation and amortisation charges. The coefficient of βππππ,π‘−1 represents the potential sensitivity of investment to fluctuations in available internal finance and could reflect the presence of financing constraints on investment. The term (ππ,π‘−2 − π π,π‘−2 ) is the error correction term, where ππ,π‘−2 is natural logarithm of capital investment and π π,π‘−2 is natural logarithm of sales at the end of period t-2. The error correction term represents the long-run properties of this model. ‘Error correcting’ behaviour requires that π½1 < 0, so that investment above the desired level is associated with lower future investment, and vice versa. βπππ‘ is the first difference of governance (natural logarithm), proxied by the TD score. ππ‘ controls for year fixed effects, and πππ‘ is a random error term. The unit of analysis is firm i at time t. Firm fixed effects are removed by first-differencing. 8 πΌππ‘ πΌ βπΎππ‘ . Proof: ππ‘⁄πΎ ≈ ≈ ⁄πΎ ⁄πΎ π,π‘−1 π,π‘−1 π,π‘−1 πΎ = log ( ππ‘⁄πΎ − 1) = βπππ‘ = βπππ‘ , where πππ‘ is the (natural) log of π,π‘−1 βπππ‘ can be approximated by the ratio βππππΎππ‘ = log πΎππ‘ − ππππΎπ,π‘−1 the desired capital stock for firm i in the period t. 15 Hypothesis One: Good TD can improve the internal efficiency or transparency of the firm, cash-flows become more visible and controllable, and there is more efficient allocation of internal funds stimulating investment expenditure. I believe that transparency and disclosure facilitates accountability of boards and managers, and, in a broader economic context, stimulates economic competitiveness and capital investment. In Table 4 Model (1) I test for the direct effect of governance on investments. Table 4: Investment and direct impact of governance, fixed effects Governance is statistically significant in Model (1). The t-test on the error correction term ect shows that ect’s coefficient is different from 0 and significant in all three models, which means that cointegration exists. In other words, the error correction model is a representation of the short-run dynamic relationship between sales and investment, in which the error correction term incorporates in the model long-run information on sales and investment. I test for heteroscedasticity in the error terms with White’s test (White, 1980) by reporting White’s robust standard errors. 16 If I control for firm size with first difference in total assets, in addition to controlling with first and second differences in sales, the results of model (1) are unchanged. If I split the panel into two parts - according to the existence of controlling majority shareholder (50% plus 1 share) or not, governance remains a significant and positive factor for investment in the presence of a majority shareholder, whether this is a state entity or a private investor. The results for a dispersed ownership sub-panel are inconclusive partly due to its smaller size. I then analyse the companies owned by majority shareholders and look at the sub-panel with an oligarch as the controlling shareholder, and at the sub-panel with the state as the controlling shareholder (SOEs). I find that governance significantly and positively influences investment in the latter case (cf. Table 4 Model (3)). This might be interpreted as greater transparency and disclosure being a positive factor for investment in SOEs. SOEs are poorly governed; their TD scores are much lower than the average score or scores of non-SOEs, therefore, any improvement to their governance might have a significant impact on the level of their capital expenditure. The coefficient of governance in the state-sub panel (0.35) is double that for the full panel (0.18). While governance is important for SOEs, I notice that the coefficient of gross cash flow is insignificant. The absence of sensitivity of investment to internal funds in the case of SOEs could be evidence of soft budget constraints, which means that cash-rich Russian SOEs are not financially constrained. Another explanation of non-sensitivity of investment to cash flow would be that SOEs operate in frictionless markets, i.e., it is cheaper to issue external than internal funds. Asymmetrically, oligarch-owned firms are more sensitive to the levels of internal funds (significance in the βgcfi,t−1 coefficient), while governance matters less to them than to SOEs. I lag the difference in gross cash-flow by one year to avoid reverse causality since once the firm has invested, it might become financially constrained. The state is involved in many Russian firms whether through direct shareholdings, board membership or other shareholders being members of the Parliament (Duma), etc. To account for any state involvement, I split my panel into two sub-panels: with (any share ownership, board directorship, etc.) and without any kind of state involvement. The results for the sub-panel of firms with state involvement are less significant (coefficient range of 17 0.185-0.250) than for those firms with a strictly controlling state ownership stake (table not reported). Companies with some state involvement as opposed to state control might be better governed so that investment reacts less strongly to changes in governance. To validate my results with panel fixed effects, I run ordinary least squares (OLS) on the means of the explanatory variables (cf. Table 13 on page 69 in the appendices) and control for fixed effects (industry, listing, foreign shareholder). I confirm that governance has a significant and positive impact on investment. I find that firms in the metals and mining, oil and gas and diversified telecommunications sectors have a higher propensity to invest than in other sectors. I find significance in neither the ownership nor listing variables. Hypothesis Two: By being more transparent, the firm attracts external investors, has greater access to local and global financial markets, and is able to raise more external funding via capital markets, which in turn mitigates financing constraints on investment. I argue here that transparency towards investors and the general public is essential for accessing local and international capital markets and, thus, diversifying sources of funding, which mitigates financing constraints on investment. A recent stream in the finance literature (see Brown and Petersen (2009) for a comprehensive review) argues for the inclusion of external finance in investment studies. Including debt issues would control for possible omitted variables bias and evaluate the role of external finance on investment. Carpenter (1995) argues that, in the investment equation, the focus is not only on cash-flow but also on the fundamental difference in the role of debt finance in the firm’s financing decision. For constrained firms, debt is a source of external finance used to fund profitable investment projects. When these firms issue new debt, it represents a relaxation of the constraint and there should be a large and positive change in investment. Goergen and Renneboog (2001) justify the inclusion of debt by saying that debt captures potential bankruptcy costs and the tax advantages of debt. They find that a high level of leverage leads to a reduction in investment as the bond market and banks require high premiums to compensate for the bankruptcy risk if internally generated funds do not suffice for investment spending. 18 Moyen (2004) constructs two models: an unconstrained model in which firms have access to external financial markets, and a constrained model in which firms have no access. She does not include debt in the regression and finds that it magnifies cash flow sensitivity of unconstrained firms, i.e., she implies that omitting debt from ICF regressions may lead to upward biased cash flow coefficients. Raith et al. (2007) model investment and internal funds and show that the relationship between the two variables is a convex U-shape: in particular, for sufficiently low levels of internal funds, a further decrease leads to an increase in the firm’s investment. If internal funds are sufficiently negative, a further decrease in internal funds might make it optimal to increase borrowing to such a degree that there may be a negative correlation between investment and cash flow. Brown and Petersen (2009) control for external finance and instrument cash flow to eliminate the contemporaneous correlation between external finance and the cash flow variable. For the reasons stated above, I control for the use of debt finance in the investment equation. Table 5: Investment and external finance, fixed effects 19 Here, I only analyse long term debt, while about 50% of debt on the sampled firms’ balance sheets is short term debt. The firms are still not highly leveraged; on average, they have 1.5x Debt/EBITDA multiple. There is a broad range of firms contracting new long term debt, from firms controlled by the state to firms controlled by private shareholders. Governance is significant in models (1) and (2) in Table 5. New long term debt positively and significantly affects capital investment. A common approach in the financing constraints literature is to separate firms into groups according to a priori criteria related to the presence of financing constraints. Researchers have used a variety of criteria to categorize firms (see Hubbard, 1998). Some split the sample by firm size (Carpenter et al., 1998, Chevalier and Scharfstein, 1995), some by dividend payouts, both are proxies for net worth. Other a priori groupings are based on more direct proxies for information costs, e.g., firm’s underwriting costs (Calomiris and Himmelberg, 1995). Another popular approach that I use in Table 5 Models (2) and (3) is to measure financing constraints directly and interact them with the variables of interest (cash-flow, governance, etc.). Goergen and Renneboog (2001) construct financing constraints as a dummy variable that is set to 1 if a company issues new equity, reduces dividend payments, omits dividends, or is financially distressed (files for bankruptcy). Gertler and Hubbard (1989) interact cash flow with a dummy for periods of recession showing that, between 1970 and 1984, US manufacturing firms exhibited a higher sensitivity of investment to cash flow during recessions. Amore et al. (2012) defines as financially constrained those firms that are either young or credit dependent (have an S&P credit rating). My sample is rather small to separate the firms into groups. Instead, I create a variable for financing constraints that categorizes firms as constrained and unconstrained and interact this variable with governance. Financing constraints is a dummy variable, taking the value 0 for unconstrained firms, i.e., firms that paid common or preferred dividends (following Fazzari et al., 1988; Bond and Meghir, 1994) and did not issue common equity (Angelopoulou and Gibson, 2007) and 1 for constrained firms, i.e., those firms that issued new common equity. Seifert and Gonenc (2010) found that firms in emerging economies 20 finance their investment needs mainly with equity, the opposite of what would be expected under the pecking order theory. Statistically, Russian firms have low leverage and in this situation, I could argue that external equity is raised before debt to finance their deficits. If firms want to raise equity, being transparent is more important to them since they are facing public investors hence the improvement in TD scores will give them better chances in raising equity and drive investment. While for the banks, TD scores are less important: they know the information already (whether through secondary issue or not), since they monitor the firms through covenants. I lag financing constraints by one year to avoid reverse causality since once the firm has invested, it might become financially constrained. In model (3) of Table 5, the interaction term between financing constraints and governance is significant and positive. This is evidence that companies with financing needs suffer from underinvestment, and it provides support for Hypothesis 2 when I control for constrained firms. Corporate governance matters and has positive impact on investment for firms that are a priori financially constrained. 5. Robustness Checks In this section, I address some potential concerns about the data and econometric methodology. One such is endogeneity. Endogeneity problems are frequent in studies that analyse corporate governance practices at firm level (Klapper and Love, 2004). This is because it is generally difficult to find exogenous factors or natural experiments with which to identify the relations being examined (Wintoki et al., 2012). First, there is the problem of reverse causality. A fast growing firm, for example, may adopt better governance practices in order to ensure access to external financing at lower cost. These growth opportunities will be reflected in the market valuation of the firm, inducing a positive correlation between governance and Tobin’s Q. It is more questionable whether, after controlling for growth opportunities with Tobin’s Q, I would still find reverse causality between investment and corporate governance. If I assume that firms and investors care about governance, and TD scores in particular, then a positive change in investment or cash flows might improve the TD score. Would firms try to influence S&P in order to get a higher TD score through the increase in investment or 21 cash flow? This seems rather cumbersome, since there are other direct ways of improving the score, such as publicly disclosing more information. So if reverse causality between investment and TD scores exists, it is not very intuitive. If I use another proxy for corporate governance, such as board structure, reverse causality is more obvious because the board structure is the firm’s decision ultimately and not that of an external institution. Dynamic panel data (Arellano and Bond version) are often used to address the issues of causality, unobserved heterogeneity and simultaneity (Wintoki et al, 2012). Investment data are not as fat-tailed as high frequency share data for example, so GMM is unlikely to be spurious. Here, I use difference GMM and system GMM with collapsed instruments (Roodman, 2009). I make a small sample adjustment and report t-statistics and the Wald π 2 test. I also report robust standard errors which are consistent with panel-specific autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity. I produce a Hansen test for over-identification. The dynamic panel GMM estimator uses multiple lags as instruments. This means that the system is over-identified, and provides me with the opportunity to carry out the over-identification test. Table 6 and Table 7 show the results of the Hansen test for the GMM estimates, difference and system respectively. The Hansen test yields a J-statistic which is π 2 distributed under the null hypothesis of the validity of my instruments. The results in Tables 6 and 7 reveal a J-statistic with a p-value in the range of 0.1-0.3, meaning I cannot reject the hypothesis that my instruments are valid. I tested also for exogeneity of a subset of my instruments using difference-in-Hansen test of exogeneity (not reported). The results also showed that I cannot reject the hypothesis that the additional subset of instruments used in the GMM estimates is indeed exogenous. Taken together, the specification tests provide empirical verification for my argument that my instruments for governance are exogenous with respect to investment. Models (1) in Table 6 and Table 7 show that governance is significant and positive for investment. However, when controlling for gross cash-flows and Tobin’s Q in Model (3) in Table 6, neither governance, nor gross cash-flow are significant for investment. Could it be that improved governance coupled with growing cash-flows is still not enough to reverse the trend of allocation of funds to short term projects, due to risks related to uncertain property rights? This might be one explanation for why Russian firms have underinvested in 22 assets while not always being financially constrained. According to the pecking order theory9, this could be interpreted as an absence of financing constraints. In other words, it could be that demand for investment funds by managers is so low that it does not intersect the upward-sloping portion of the supply curve ( Figure 1, page 6). This might indicate that managers are colluding with major shareholders to hold investment low irrespective of cash flow, because of the risk of asset extraction by the state. A manager-controlling shareholder tandem might decide to spend the extra cash on short term projects or dividends, rather than to invest in capital assets. An alternative empirical explanation could be that the number of GMM instruments is getting large relative to the number of groups of observations and as a result standard errors provide an inefficient estimation. The absence of significance in TD might then reflect the data limitations and further robustness checks are needed. Model 5 in Table 6 provides support for Hypothesis 2 - the interaction term between financing constraints and governance is positive and significant, meaning that firms classified as financially constrained benefit from better governance. Table 7 presents the results for the system GMM. Both gross cash flow and Tobin’s Q are positive and significant for investment, providing support for the findings in the classical investment literature. Again, for firms that are a priori financially constrained, greater transparency and disclosure mean greater investment (Model 5). In addition to GMM, I also apply VAR to my panel data (for full details on the methodology, see Love and Zicchino, 2006) to address endogeneity. By analysing orthogonalized impulseresponse functions I can separate the response of investment to shocks coming from governance or other variables. My results (cf. Figure 7 on page 70 in the appendices) indicate that the impulse response of investment to a one standard deviation shock in governance has a positive impact. A second problem might arise due to omitted variables which serve as pre-determinants for differences in sales, assets, or gross cash-flows, which, in turn, are shown to be correlated with investment. I use panel data techniques with fixed effects, which partially addresses 9 Pecking order theory states that firms prefer to finance investments with internal funds first, then debt and finally, equity. 23 omitted variables bias for variables such as industry, region, legal framework, etc. I also use lagged dependent variables. A third potential concern is selection bias. The companies in the sample were selected according to their size and liquidity. In 2009, they amounted to 90, 76 of which were included in a 2008 study. The liquidity of stocks is generally positively correlated with firm size, but there are exceptions, especially in cases of minor free-float. There are more than 300 public companies in Russia, and the S&P sample may not be representative of all Russian public companies. As larger companies tend to be more transparent than smaller ones, the sampling method is likely to cause an upward bias in assessments of the transparency of the entire population of public Russian companies. On the other hand, since the companies included in the sample account for some 80% of the cumulative market capitalization of the Russian stock market, they represent a majority of the Russian economy in terms of assets and operations. Russian small and medium-sized enterprises (SME) have different priorities. They are operating in situations where there is less need for transparency, similar to other SMEs in the rest of the world. The costs of transparency and disclosure are quite high, including accounting and information technology (IT) expenses, and they can be an obstacle to pursuing good governance standards. 24 Table 6: Investment and corporate governance, difference GMM 25 Table 7: Investment and corporate governance, system GMM 26 6. Conclusion I conclude this paper with a brief summary of my main findings and a discussion of the main implications. I tested the significance of capital investment sensitivity to governance through internal capital markets. I found governance to be a significant and positive factor for investment, using both fixed effects and GMM estimators. I analysed the companies owned by majority shareholders, and looked at the sub-panel with an oligarch as the controlling shareholder and at the sub-panel with the state as the controlling shareholder. I found that governance significantly and positively influences investment in the latter case. This might be interpreted as greater transparency and disclosure being a positive factor for investment in SOEs. Private ownership concentration might replace good governance. Specifically, I found that governance does not significantly affect investments when looking at firms controlled by oligarchs. When estimating the impact of governance on capital investment through external capital markets, I found that corporate governance matters and has a positive impact on investments for firms that are a priori constrained. External capital has a significant and positive influence on investment. Firms that raised additional debt were (are) subject to more scrutiny from banks and were (are) applying better governance rules to maximize the use of additional cash flows in investment projects. An unexpected result consisted of finding gross cash flow to be not always significantly related to investment. This might indicate that managers are colluding with major shareholders to hold investment low irrespective of cash flow because of the risk of expropriation. Another reason for gross cash flow-investment insensitivity might be the presence of soft budget constraints. In an emerging economies context, zero sensitivity of cash flow to investment is interpreted as evidence of a weak form of soft budget constraints. 27 References Adachi, Y. 2009. Building big business in Russia: The impact of informal corporate governance practices. London: Routledge. Aganbegyan, A. 2008. Investitsii v Strategii Sotsialno-Economitcheskogo Razvitiya. In Sulakshin, S. (Eds.), Problemy Modernizatsii Ekonomiky I Economitcheskoi Politiky Rossii: 124–145. Economitcheskaya Doctrina Rossiyskoi Federatsii, Moscow: Nauchni Expert. Aghion, P. and Blanchard, O. J. 1998. On privatization methods in Eastern Europe and their implications. Economics of Transition, 6(1): 87-99. Aghion, P. and Tirole, J. 1997. Formal and real authority in organizations. Journal of Political Economy, 1-29. Aguilera, R. V. and Jackson, G. 2003. The cross-national diversity of corporate governance: Dimensions and determinants. The Academy of Management Review, 28(3): 447-465. Aguilera, R. V., Filatotchev, I., Gospel, H. and Jackson, G. 2008. An organizational approach to comparative corporate governance: Costs, contingencies, and complementarities. Organization Science, 19(3): 475-492. Aharoni, Y. 2000. The performance of state-owned enterprises. In P. A. Toninelli (Ed.).The rise and fall of state-owned enterprise in the western world, 1: 49-72. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ahuja, G. 2011. Explaining influence rents: The case for an institutions-based view of strategy. Organization Science, 22(6): 1631-52. Ahuja, G., 2000. Collaboration networks, structural holes, and innovation: A longitudinal study. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45: 425-455. Aksu, M. and Kosedag, A. 2006. Transparency and disclosure scores and their determinants in the Istanbul Stock Exchange, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 14(4): 277-296. Amore, M., Schneider, C. and Zaldokas, A. 2013. Credit supply and corporate innovations. Journal of Financial Economics (forthcoming). Available at SSRN 2026824. Anderson, R. C., and Reeb, D. M. 2003. FoundingβFamily Ownership, Corporate Diversification, and Firm Leverage. Journal of Law and Economics, 46(2): 653684. 28 Angelopoulou, E., and Gibson, H. D. 2009. The balance sheet channel of monetary policy transmission: evidence from the United Kingdom. Economica, 76(304): 675-703. Arellano, M. 2003. Panel data econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Arellano, M. and Bond, S. 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58: 277-97. Arellano, M. and Bover, O. 1995. Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-component models. Journal of Econometrics 68: 29-51. Arthurs, J. D., Hoskisson, R. E., Busenitz, L. W. and Johnson, R. A. 2008. Managerial agents watching other agents: Multiple agency conflicts regarding underpricing in IPO firms. Academy of Management Journal, 51(2): 277-294. Bae, K. H., Kang, J. K., and Kim, J. M. 2002. Tunneling or value added? Evidence from mergers by Korean business groups. The Journal of Finance, 57(6): 2695-2740. Baum, J. A., and Oliver, C. 1991. Institutional linkages and organizational mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36: 187-218. Baum, J.A.C., Calabrese, T. and Silverman, B.S. 2000. Don’t go it alone: Alliance network composition and start-ups performance in Canadian biotechnology. Strategic Management Journal, 21: 267-94. Baysinger, B. D., and Butler, H. N. 1985. Corporate governance and the board of directors: Performance effects of changes in board composition. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1(1): 101-124. Baysinger, B., and Hoskisson, R. E. 1990. The composition of boards of directors and strategic control: Effects on corporate strategy. Academy of Management Review, 15(1): 72-87. Bazzoli, G. J., Casey, E., Alexander, J. A., Conrad, D., Shortell, S., Sofaer, S., Hasnain-Wynia, R. and Zukoski, A. 2003. Collaborative initiatives: Where the rubber meets the road in community partnerships. Medical Care Research and Review, 60(4): 63-94. Bean, C. R. 1981. An econometric model of manufacturing investment in the UK. The Economic Journal, 91(361): 106-121. Becht, M., Bolton, P. and Röell, A. 2003. In G. M. Constantinides, M. Harris and R. M. Stultz (Eds.). Corporate governance and control. Handbook of the Economics of Finance, 1A: 1-109. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science BV. 29 Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Laeven, L. and Maksimovic, V. 2006. The determinants of financing obstacles. Journal of International Money and Finance, 28: 932-52. Beck, T., Levine, R. and Loayza, N. 2000. Finance and the sources of growth. Journal of Financial Economics, 58: 261–300. Becker, B., and Hall, S. G. 2009. Foreign Direct Investment in R&D and Exchange Rate Uncertainty. Open Economies Review, 20(2): 207-223. Beekes, W., and Brown, P. 2006. Do BetterβGoverned Australian Firms Make More Informative Disclosures? Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 33(3β4): 422-450. Beiner, S., Drobetz, W., Schmid, F. and Zimmermann, H. 2004. Is board size an independent corporate governance mechanism? Kyklos, 57(3): 327-356. Bennedsen, M. and Wolfenzon, D. 2000. The balance of power in closely held corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1): 113-39. Berglöf, E. and Pajuste, A. 2005. What do firms disclose and why? Enforcing corporate governance and transparency in Central and Eastern Europe. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 21(2): 1-20. Berle, A.A. and Means, G C. 1932. The modern corporation and private property. New York: Harcourt, Brace and World. Bertrand, M., Mehta, P. and Mullainathan, S. 2002. Ferreting out tunneling: An application to Indian business groups. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1): 121-148. Bhagat, S., Bolton, B. and Romano, R. 2007. The promise and peril of corporate governance indices, ECGI Working Paper Series in Law, N89/2007, Brussels: European Corporate Governance Institute. Billett, M. T., Garfinkel, J. A. and Jiang, Y. 2011. The influence of governance on investment: Evidence from a hazard model. Journal of Financial Economics, 102(3): 643-70. Black, B. 2001. The corporate governance behavior and market value of Russian firms. Emerging Markets Review, 2(2): 89-108. Black, B., Love, I. and Rachinsky, A. 2006. Corporate governance indices and firms' market values: Time series evidence from Russia. Emerging Markets Review, 7(4): 36179. Blair, M.M. 1995. Ownership and control, rethinking corporate governance for the twentyfirst century. Washington DC: The Brookings Institution. 30 Blundell, R. and Bond, S. 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87: 115-43. Blundell, R., Bond, S., Devereux, M., and Schiantarelli, F. 1992. Investment and Tobin's Q: Evidence from company panel data. Journal of Econometrics, 51(1): 233-257. Bond S., Elston, J., Mairesse, J. and Mulkay, B. 1997. Financial factors and investment in Belgium, France, Germany and the UK: A comparison using company panel data, NBER Working Paper no. 5900, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Bond, S. and Meghir, C. 1994. Dynamic investment models and the firm’s financial policy. Review of Economic Studies, 61: 197–222. Bond, S., and Van Reenen, J. 2007. In J. J. Heckman and E. Leamer (Eds.), Microeconometric models of investment and employment. Handbook of econometrics, 6: 44174498. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science BV Bond, S., Elston, J. A., Mairesse, J., and Mulkay, B. 2003. Financial factors and investment in Belgium, France, Germany, and the United Kingdom: a comparison using company panel data. Review of economics and statistics, 85(1): 153-165. Boone, P. and Rodionov, D. 2002. Rent seeking in Russia and the CIS. Moscow: Brunswick UBS Warburg. Borgatti, S.P., Everett, M.G. and Freeman, L.C. 2002. Ucinet for Windows: Software for social network analysis. Harvard, MA: Analytic Technologies. Boycko, M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. 1994. Voucher privatization. Journal of Financial Economics, 35(2): 249-266. Boyd, B. 1990. Corporate linkages and organizational environment: A test of the resource dependence model. Strategic Management Journal, 11(6): 419-30. Boyd, B. and Hoskisson, R. 2010. Corporate governance of business groups. In A. M. Colpan, T. Hikino and J. R. Lincoln (Eds.). The Oxford Handbook of Business Groups. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Braguinsky, S. 2009. Postcommunist oligarchs in Russia: Quantitative analysis. Journal of Law and Economics, 52(2): 307-49. Braguinsky, S. and Mityakov, S. 2013. Foreign corporations and the culture of transparency: Evidence from Russian administrative data. Journal of Financial Economics, accessed from http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.02.016, on 15 May 2013. 31 Braguinsky, S. and Myerson, R. 2007. A macroeconomic model of Russian transition: The role of oligarchic property rights. Economics of Transition, 15:77-107. Braguinsky, S., and Myerson, R. B. 2007. Capital and growth with oligarchic property rights. Review of Economic Dynamics, 10(4): 676-704. Brass, D. J. and Burkhardt, M.E. 1993. Potential power and power use: An investigation of structure and behavior. Academy of Management Journal, 36(3): 441-70. Brass, D. J., Galaskiewicz, J., Greve, H.R. and Tsai,W. 2004. Taking stock of networks and organizations: A multilevel perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 47(6): 795-815. Brennan, N., and McDermott, M. 2004. Alternative perspectives on independence of directors. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 12(3): 325-336. Brown, J. and Petersen, B. 2009. Why has the investment-cash flow sensitivity declined so sharply? Rising R&D and equity market developments. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33: 971-84. Brown, J., Fazzari, S.M. and Petersen, B.C. 2009. Financing innovation and growth: Cash flow, external equity and the 1990s RD boom. The Journal of Finance, 64(1): 151-185. Bruton, G. D., Ahlstrom, D., and Wan, J. C. 2003. Turnaround in East Asian firms: Evidence from ethnic overseas Chinese communities. Strategic Management Journal, 24(6): 519-540. Bruton, G. D., Filatotchev, I., Chahine, S., and Wright, M. 2010. Governance, ownership structure, and performance of IPO firms: the impact of different types of private equity investors and institutional environments. Strategic Management Journal, 31(5): 491-509. Buckley, P. J., and Strange, R. 2011. The governance of the multinational enterprise: insights from internalization theory. Journal of Management Studies, 48(2): 460-470. Burt, R. S. 1980. Autonomy in a social topology. American Journal of Sociology, 85(4): 892925. Bushee, B. 2004. Identifying and attracting the “right” investors: Evidence on the behavior of institutional investors. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 16(4): 28-35. Bushman, R.M., Piotroski, J.D. and Smith A.J. 2003. What determines corporate transparency? Journal of Accounting Research, 42(2): 207-52. 32 Byrd, J. W., and Hickman, K. A. 1992. Do outside directors monitor managers?: Evidence from tender offer bids. Journal of Financial Economics, 32(2): 195-221. Cadbury, Adrian. 2002. Corporate Governance and Chairmanship: A Personal View. New York: Oxford University Press Inc. Calomiris C.W. and Himmelberg, C. P. 1995. Investment banking costs as a measure of the cost of access to external finance. Columbia University Working Paper, Columbia University, Cambridge, MA Campos, N. and Giovannoni, F. 2006. The determinants of asset stripping: Theory and evidence from transitional economies. Journal of Law and Economics 69: 681– 706. Carpenter, R.E. 1995. Finance constraints or free cash flow? Empirica, 22(3): 185-209. Carpenter, R.E., Fazarri, S.M. and Petersen, B.C. 1998. Financing constraints and inventory investment: A comparative study with high-frequency panel data. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(4): 513-19. Casciaro, T. and Piskorski, M.J. 2005. Power imbalance, mutual dependence, and constraint absorption: A closer look at resource dependence theory. Administrative Science Quarterly, 50: 167-99. Caselli, F., Esquivel, G. and Lefort, F. 1996. Reopening the convergence debate: a new look at cross-country growth empirics. Journal of Economic Growth, 1: 363-89. Chahine, S., Filatotchev. I. 2008. Do venture capitalists certify and monitor new issues? Global Finance Journal, 18(3): 351-372. Chahine, S., Filatotchev. I. and Wright, M. 2007. Venture capitalists, business angels, and performance of entrepreneurial IPOs in the UK and France. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 34(3)&(4): 505-28. Chang, E. C. and Wong, S. M. L. 2004. Political control and performance in China’s listed firms. Journal of Comparative Economics, 32(4): 617–636. Chen, G., Firth, M., Gao, D. and Rui, O. 2006. Ownership structure, corporate governance and fraud: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 12: 424-48. Chernykh, L. 2008. Ultimate ownership and control in Russia. Journal of Financial Economics, 88(1): 169-192. Chevalier, J. A. and Scharfstein, D. S. 1995. Liquidity constraints and the cyclical behavior of markups. The American Economic Review, 85(2): 390-396. 33 Claessens, S. 2003. Corporate governance and development. Global Corporate Governance Forum, Focus 1. The World Bank Working Paper. Available at SSRN 642721. Washington DC: The World Bank. Accessed from http://www1.ifc.org/wps/wcm/connect/7fc17c0048a7e6dda8b7ef6060ad5911/ Focus_1_Corp_Governance_and_Development.pdf?MOD=AJPERES on 15 May 2013. Claessens, S., Djankov, S. and Lang, L.H.P. 2000. The separation of ownership and control in East Asian corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 58: 81-112. Claessens, S., Djankov, S., and Lang, L. H. 2000. The separation of ownership and control in East Asian corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1): 81-112. Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J. P. and Lang, L. H. 2002. Disentangling the incentive and entrenchment effects of large shareholdings. The Journal of Finance, 57(6): 2741-2771. Clarke, T. 2004. The stakeholder corporation: A business philosophy for the information age. In T. Clarke (Ed.) Theories of Corporate Governance, 189-202. London: Routledge. Cleary, S. 1999. The Relationship between Firm Investment and Financial Status. Journal of Finance, 54(2): 673-692. Connelly, B. L., Hoskisson, R. E., Tihanyi, L., and Certo, S. T. 2010. Ownership as a form of corporate governance. Journal of Management Studies, 47(8): 1561-1589. Cosh, A., Cumming, D., and Hughes, A. 2009. Outside Enterpreneurial Capital. The Economic Journal, 119(540) : 1494-1533. Dahya, J., Dimitrov, O., and McConnell, J. J. 2008. Dominant shareholders, corporate boards, and corporate value: A cross-country analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 87(1): 73-100. Daily, C. M., and Dalton, D. R. 1992. The relationship between governance structure and corporate performance in entrepreneurial firms. Journal of Business Venturing, 7(5): 375-386. Daily, C. M., and Dalton, D. R. 1994. Bankruptcy and corporate governance: the Impact of board composition and structure. Academy of Management Journal, 37(6): 1603-1617. 34 Daily, C. M., and Schwenk, C. 1996. Chief executive officers, top management teams, and boards of directors: congruent or countervailing forces? Journal of Management, 22(2): 185-208. Dalton, D.R., Daily, C.M., Johnson, J.L. and Ellstrand A.E. 1999. Number of directors and financial performance: A meta-analysis. Academy of Management Journal, 42(6): 674-86. Degryse, H., and de Jong, A. 2006. Investment and internal finance: Asymmetric information or managerial discretion? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24(1): 125-147. Demsetz, H., and Villalonga, B. 2001. Ownership structure and corporate performance. Journal of Corporate Finance, 7(3): 209-233. Desender, K., Aguilera, R. V., Crespi-Cladera, R. and Garcia Cestona, M.A. 2013. When does ownership matter? Board characteristics and behavior. Strategic Management Journal. Forthcoming, doi: 10.1002/smj.2046. Dharwadkar, R., George, G, and Brandes, P. 2000. Privatization in emerging economies: An agency theory perspective. Academy of Management Review, 25(3): 650-69. DiMaggio, P. J., and Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 147-160. Djankov, S., and Murrell, P. 2002. Enterprise restructuring in transition: A quantitative survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(3): 739-792. Doidge, C., Karolyi, A. and Stulz, R. 2007. Why do countries matter so much for corporate governance? Journal of Financial Economics, 86: 1-39. Doidge, C., Karolyi, G.A. and Stulz, R.M. 2004. Why are foreign firms listed in the US worth more? Journal of Financial Economics, 71(2): 205-38. Douma, S., George, R., and Kabir, R. 2006. Foreign and domestic ownership, business groups, and firm performance: Evidence from a large emerging market. Strategic Management Journal, 27(7): 637-657. Driffield, N. L., Mickiewicz, T., and Temouri, Y. 2012. Institutional Reforms, Productivity and Profitability: from Rents to Competition? Journal of Comparative Economics, 41(2): 583-600. 35 Driver, C. and Guedes, M.J.C. 2012. Research and development, cash flow, agency and governance: UK large companies. Research Policy, 41(9): 1565-77. Driver, C. and Temple, P. 2012. The Unbalanced Economy: A policy appraisal. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Drori, G.S. 2006. Governed by governance: The new prism of organizational change. In G.S Drori, J.W. Meyer, and H. Hwang (Eds), Globalization and Organization: World Society and Organizational Change, 91-118. Oxford: Oxford University Press. D'souza, J., and Megginson, W. L. 1999. The financial and operating performance of privatized firms during the 1990s. The Journal of Finance, 54(4): 1397-1438. Durnev, A., and Kim, E. 2005. To steal or not to steal: Firm attributes, legal environment, and valuation. The Journal of Finance, 60(3): 1461-1493. Dyck, A. 2003. The Hermitage fund: Media and corporate governance in Russia. Harvard Business School Case, 703-010. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School. Dyer, J. H., and Singh, H. 1998. The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23(4): 660-679. Dzarasov, R. 2011. Eichnerian megacorp and investment behaviour of Russian corporations. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 35(1): 199–217. Earle, J. S., and Estrin, S. 2003. Privatization, competition, and budget constraints: disciplining enterprises in Russia. Economics of Planning, 36(1): 1-22. Eisenhardt, K. 1989. Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14: 57-74. Eisenhardt, K. and Schoonhoven, C. 1996. Resource-based view of strategic alliance formation: strategic and social effects in entrepreneurial firms. Organization Science, 7: 136-50. Erickson, T., and Whited, T. M. 2000. Measurement error and the relationship between investment and q. Journal of Political Economy, 108(5): 1027-1057. Estrin, S. and Wright, M. 1999. Corporate governance in the former Soviet Union: An overview. Journal of Comparative Economics, 27(3): 398-421. Estrin, S., Hanousek, J., Kocenda, E. and Svejnar, J. 2009. The effects of privatization and ownership in transition economies. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(3): 699728. 36 Estrin, S., Poukliakova, S. and Shapiro, D. 2009. The performance effects of business groups in Russia. Journal of Management Studies, 46(3): 393-419. Faccio, M. 2006. Politically connected firms. American Economic Review, 96(1): 369-86. Faccio, M. and Lang, L. 2002. The ultimate ownership of Western European corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 65: 365-95. Faccio, M., Lang, L. H., and Young, L. 2001. Dividends and expropriation. American Economic Review, 91(1): 54-78. Fama, E. 1980. Agency problems and the theory of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88: 288-307. Fama, E. and Jensen, M. 1983. Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 301-25. Fazzari, S. M., Hubbard, R. G., and Petersen, B. C. 2000. Investment-cash flow sensitivities are useful: A comment on Kaplan and Zingales. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(2): 695-705. Fazzari, S., Ferri, P., and Greenberg, E. 2008. Cash flow, investment, and Keynes–Minsky cycles. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 65(3): 555-572. Fazzari, S., Hubbard, R.G. and Petersen, B.C. 1988. Financing constraints and corporate investment. NBER Working Paper No. 2387. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Ferris, S. P., Kim, K. A., and Kitsabunnarat, P. 2003. The costs (and benefits?) of diversified business groups: The case of Korean chaebols. Journal of Banking and Finance, 27(2): 251-273. Filatotchev, I., Buck, T. and Zhukov, V. 2000. Downsizing In Privatized Firms in Russia, Ukraine, and Belarus. Academy of Management Journal, 43(3): 286-304. Filatotchev, I., Kapelyushnikov, R., Dyomina, N. and Aukutsionek, S. 2001. The effects of ownership concentration on investment and performance in privatized firms in Russia. Managerial and Decision Economics, 22(6): 299-313. Filatotchev, I., Lien, Y.C. and Piesse, J. 2005. Corporate governance and performance in publicly listed, family-controlled firms: Evidence from Taiwan. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 22(3): 257-83. 37 Filatotchev, I., Strange, R., Piesse, J. and Lien, Y. C. 2007. FDI by firms from newly industrialised economies in emerging markets: corporate governance, entry mode and location. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(4): 556-572. Filatotchev, I., Toms, S., and Wright, M. 2006. The firm's strategic dynamics and corporate governance life-cycle. International Journal of Managerial Finance, 2(4): 256279. Filatotchev, I., Wright, M., Uhlenbruck, K., Tihanyi, L., and Hoskisson, R. E. 2003. Governance, organizational capabilities, and restructuring in transition economies. Journal of World Business, 38(4): 331-347. Filatotchev, I., Zhang, X. and Piesse, J. 2011. Multiple agency perspective, family control and private information risk in emerging markets. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 28(1): 69-93. Fisman, R. 2001. Estimating the value of political connections. The American Economic Review, 91(4): 1095-1102. Fracassi, C. and Tate, G. 2012. External networking and internal firm governance. The Journal of Finance, 67(1): 153-94. Friedman, E., Johnson, S. and Mitton, T. 2003. Propping and tunnelling. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31: 732-50. Fox, M. B., and Heller, M. A. 2000. Corporate governance lessons from Russian enterprise fiascoes. NYUL Rev., 75, 1720. Frye, T. 2002. Capture or exchange? Business lobbying in Russia. Europe-Asia Studies, 54(7): 1017-36. Frye, T.M. and Iwasaki, I. 2011. Government directors and business–state relations in Russia. European Journal of Political Economy, 27: 642-58. Galen, M. 1989. A seat on the board is getting hotter. Business Week, 3113, 72-73. Gales, L. M., & Kesner, I. F. 1994. An analysis of board of director size and composition in bankrupt organizations. Journal of Business Research, 30(3): 271-282. Gertler, M., and Hubbard, R. G. 1989. Financial factors in business fluctuations. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper, No. 2758. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Goergen, M., and Renneboog, L. 2001. Investment policy, internal financing and ownership concentration in the UK. Journal of Corporate Finance, 7(3): 257-84. 38 Goetzmann, W.N., Spiegel, M. and Ukhov, A. 2003. Modeling and measuring Russian corporate governance: The case of Russian preferred and common shares. NBER Working Paper, No. 9469. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Gomes, A. 2000. Going public without governance: Managerial reputation effects. The Journal of Finance, 55(2): 615-46. Gomez-Mejia, L. R., Larraza-Kintana, M., and Makri, M. 2003. The determinants of executive compensation in family-controlled public corporations. Academy of Management Journal, 46(2): 226-237. Gompers, P., Ishii, J., and Metrick, A. 2003. Corporate governance and equity prices. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1): 107-156. Gorodnichenko, Y. and Grygorenko, Y. 2008. Are oligarchs productive? Theory and evidence. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36: 17-42. Gorodnichenko, Y., Martinez-Vazquez, J. and Peter, K.S. 2008. Myth and reality of flat tax reform: Micro estimates of tax evasion and productivity response in Russia. Journal of Political Economy, 117: 504-54. Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91(3): 481-510. Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. The Journal of Political Economy, 94(4): 691-719. Grossman, S. J., and Hart, O. D. 1980. Takeover bids, the free-rider problem, and the theory of the corporation. The Bell Journal of Economics, 42-64. Grossman, S. J., and Hart, O. D. 1988. One share-one vote and the market for corporate control. Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 175-202. Gugler, K. 2003. Corporate governance and investment, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 10: 261–89. Gugler, K. and Yurtoglu, B. B. 2003. Average Q, marginal Q, and the relation between ownership and performance, Economics Letters, 78: 379–84. Gul, F.A. and Tsui, J.S. 2001. Free cash flow, debt monitoring, and audit pricing: Further evidence on the role of director equity ownership. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, 20(2): 71-84. 39 Gulati, R. 1999. Network location and learning: the influence of network resources and firm capabilities on alliance formation. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 397-420. Guriev, S. and Rachinsky, A. 2005. The Role of Oligarchs in Russian Capitalism. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1): 131-50. Guriev, S., Lazareva, O., Rachinsky, A., and Tsouhlo, S. 2003. Concentrated ownership, market for corporate control, and corporate governance. CEFIR working paper, 23, Moscow: New Economic School. Guthrie, D., Okhmatovskiy, I., Schoenman, R. and Xiao, Z. 2012. Ownership networks and new institutional forms in the transition from communism to capitalism. In B. Kogut (Ed.) The Small Worlds of Corporate Governance, 117-150. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Hadlock, C. J. 1998. Ownership, liquidity and investment, RAND Journal of Economics, 29: 487–508. Haid, A., and Weigand, J. 2009. R&D, liquidity constraints, and corporate governance. Journal of Economics and Statistics (Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik), 221(2): 145-167. Hall, B. and Lerner, J. 2010. The financing of R&D and innovation. In B. Hall and N. Rosenberg (Eds), Handbook of Economics of Innovation. Amsterdam: ElsevierNorth Holland. Hambrick, D. C., and D'Aveni, R. A. 1992. Top team deterioration as part of the downward spiral of large corporate bankruptcies. Management Science, 38(10): 1445-1466. Hansen, L. P. 1982. Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 50(4): 1029-1054. Hanson, P. and Teague, E. 2005. Big business and the state in Russia. Europe-Asia Studies, 57(5): 657-80. Hart, O. 2009. Hold-up, asset ownership and reference points. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(1): 267-300. Hart, O. and Moore, J. 1994. A theory of debt based on inalienability of human capital. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109: 841-79. Hart, O. and Moore, J. 1998. Default and renegotiation; a dynamic model of debt. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113: 1-41. 40 Heaton, J.B. 2002. Managerial optimism and corporate finance. Financial Management, 31(2): 33-45. Henisz, W.J. and B.A. Zelner, 2001. The institutional environment for telecommunications investment. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 10(1): 123-48. Hennessy, C. A., Levy, A., and Whited, T. M. 2007. Testing Q theory with financing frictions. Journal of Financial Economics, 83(3): 691-717. Hermalin, B and Weisbach, M.S. 2007. Transparency and corporate governance. NBER Working Paper, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Hermalin, B. E. and M. S. Weisbach. 2003. Boards of directors as an endogenously determined institution: A survey of the economic literature. Economic Policy Review 9 (1): 7-26. Hermalin, B. E., and Weisbach, M. S. 1991. The effects of board composition and direct incentives on firm performance. Financial Management, 20(4): 101-112. Hillman A., Keim, G. and Schuler, D. 2004. Corporate political activity: A review and research agenda. Journal of Management, 30(6): 837-57. Hillman, A. Cannella, A.A. and Paetzold, R. L. 2004. The resource dependence role of corporate directors: Strategic adaptation of board composition in response to environmental change. In T. Clarke (Ed.) Theories of Corporate Governance, 138-148. London: Routledge. Hillman, A. J., Cannella, A. A., and Paetzold, R. L. 2000. The resource dependence role of corporate directors: Strategic adaptation of board composition in response to environmental change. Journal of Management Studies, 37(2): 235-256. Hillman, A., Withers, M and Collins B.J., 2009. Resource dependence theory: A review. Journal of Management, 35(6): 1404-27. Hillman, A.J. and Dalziel, T. 2003. Boards of directors and firm performance: Integrating agency and resource dependence perspectives. Academy of Management Review, 28(3): 383-96. Himmelberg, C., Hubbard, G. and Love, I. 2002. Investor protection, ownership and the cost of capital. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 2834. New York: World Bank. 41 Hitt, M. A., Ireland, R. D., Camp, S. M., and Sexton, D. L. 2001. Strategic entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial strategies for wealth creation. Strategic Management Journal, 22(6β7): 479-491. Hobdari, B. 2008. Insider ownership and capital constraints: An empirical investigation of the credit rationing hypothesis in Estonia. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 16(6): 536-549. Holmström, B. and Milgröm, P. 1991. Multitask principal agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7: 24-52. Holtz-Eakin, D., Newey, W., and Rosen, H. 1988. Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica, 56: 1371–1395. Hope, O. K. 2003. Firmβlevel disclosures and the relative roles of culture and legal origin, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting, 14(3): 218248. Hoshi, T., Kashyap, A., and Scharfstein, D. 1990. The role of banks in reducing the costs of financial distress in Japan. Journal of Financial Economics, 27(1) : 67-88. Hoskisson, R. E., Eden, L., Lau, C. M., and Wright, M. 2000. Strategy in emerging economies. Academy of Management Journal, 43(3): 249-267. Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Johnson, R. A., and Grossman, W. 2002. Conflicting voices: The effects of institutional ownership heterogeneity and internal governance on corporate innovation strategies. Academy of Management Journal, 45(4): 697716. Hoskisson, R. E., Johnson, R. A., and Moesel, D. D. 1994. Corporate divestiture intensity in restructuring firms: Effects of governance, strategy, and performance. Academy of Management Journal, 37(5): 1207-1251. Hoskisson, R., Wright, M., Filatotchev, I. and Peng, M.W. 2013. Emerging multinationals from mid-range economies: The influence of institutions and factor markets. Journal of Management Studies, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2012.01085.x Hsiao, C. 1986. Analysis of Panel Data, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, MA. Hubbard, G. 1998. Capital-market imperfections and investment. Journal of Economic Literature, 36: 193-225. 42 Huse, M. 2005. Accountability and creating accountability: A framework for exploring behavioural perspectives of corporate governance. British Journal of Management, 16(1): 65-79. International Finance Corporation. 2004. The Russia Corporate Governance Manual. International Monetary Fund. 2012. Russian Federation, 2012 Article IV Consultation. IMF Country Report No. 12/217 Iwasaki, I. 2008. The determinants of board composition in a transforming economy: Evidence from Russia. RRC Working Paper Series No. 9. Tokyo: Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University. Jensen, C. and Meckling, H. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305-60. Jensen, M. 1986. Agency cost of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. American Economic Review, 76(2). John, K., and Senbet, L. W. 1998. Corporate governance and board effectiveness. Journal of Banking and Finance, 22(4): 371-403. Johnson, J. L., Daily, C. M., and Ellstrand, A. E. 1996. Boards of directors: A review and research agenda. Journal of Management, 22(3): 409-438. Johnson, R. A., Hoskisson, R. E., and Hitt, M. A. 1993. Board of director involvement in restructuring: The effects of board versus managerial controls and characteristics. Strategic Management Journal, 14(1): 33-50. Johnson, S., and Mitton, T. 2003. Cronyism and capital controls: Evidence from Malaysia. Journal of Financial Economics, 67(2): 351-82. Johnson, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A. 2000. Tunneling. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 90 (2): 22-27. Johnson, Simon, La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, Shleifer, Andrei, 2000. Tunneling. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings) 90 (2): 22–27. Jones, D. 1998. The economic effects of privatization: Evidence from a Russian panel. Comparative Economic Studies, 40(2): 75-102. Jorgenson, D. W. 1971. Econometric studies of investment behavior: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 9(4): 1111-1147. 43 Judge, W. Q., Naoumova, I., and Koutzevol, N. 2003. Corporate governance and firm performance in Russia: an empirical study. Journal of World Business, 38(4): 385-396. Kaplan, S. N., and Zingales, L. 1997. Do investment-cash flow sensitivities provide useful measures of financing constraints? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1): 169-215. Kaplan, S.N. and Zingales, L. 2000. Investment-cash flow sensitivities are not valid measures of financing constraints. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(2): 707-12. Kathuria, R. and Mueller, D. C. 1995. Investment and cash flow: asymmetric information or managerial discretion, Empirica, Vol. 22, 1995, pp. 211–34. Khanna, T. and Yafeh, Y. 2007. Business groups in emerging markets: Paragons or parasites? Journal of Economic Literature, XLV: 331-72. Khanna, T., and Palepu, K. 2000. Is group affiliation profitable in emerging markets? An analysis of diversified Indian business groups. The Journal of Finance, 55(2): 867891. Klapper, L.F. and Love, I. 2004. Corporate governance, investor protection and performance in emerging markets. Journal of Corporate Finance, 10(5): 703-28. Kornai, J. 1979. Resource-constrained versus demand-constrained systems. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 47(4): 801-819. Kornai, J. 1986. The soft budget constraint. Kyklos, 39(1): 3-30. Kornai, J. 1998. The place of the soft budget constraint syndrome in economic theory. Journal of Comparative Economics, 26(1): 11-17. Kornai, J., Maskin, E., and Roland, G. 2003. Understanding the soft budget constraint. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(4): 1095-1136. Kuznecovs, M. and Pal, S. 2012. Does corporate governance reform necessarily boost firm performance? Recent evidence from Russia. Discussion Paper series, Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit, No. 6519, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn, Germany. La Porta, R., LopezβdeβSilanes, F., and Shleifer, A. 2002. Government ownership of banks. The Journal of Finance, 57(1): 265-301. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer A. and Vishny, R.W. 1997. Legal determinants of external finance. Journal of Finance, 52: 1131-55. 44 La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer A. and Vishny, R.W. 1999. Corporate ownership around the world. Journal of Finance, 54: 471-517. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. 2000. Investor protection and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 1-2: 3-27. Lazonick, W. and O’Sullivan, M. 2004. Maximising shareholder value: A new ideology for corporate governance. In T. Clarke (Ed.) Theories of Corporate Governance, 290303. London: Routledge. Le, T. V., and O'Brien, J. P. 2010. Can Two wrongs make a right? State ownership and debt in a transition economy. Journal of Management Studies, 47(7): 1297-1316. Ledeneva, A. V. 2013. Can Russia Modernise? Sistema, Power Networks and Informal Governance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lei, A.C. and Song, F.M. 2012. Board structure, corporate governance and firm value: Evidence from Hong Kong. Applied Financial Economics, 22(15): 1289-1303. Leiponen, A.E. 2008. Competing through cooperation. Management Science, 54: 1920-34. Leland, H. E. and Pyle, D. H. 1977. Information asymmetries, financial structure, and financial intermediation, Journal of Finance, 32: 371-387. Lester, R. H., Hillman, A., Zardkoohi, A. and Cannella, A. A. 2008. Former government officials as outside directors: The role of human and social capital. Academy of Management Journal, 51: 999–1013. Levine, R. and Zervos, S. 1998. Stock markets, banks and economic growth. American Economic Review, 88: 537-58. Levitt, B., and March, J. G. 1988. Organizational learning. Annual Review of Sociology, 14: 319-340. Lin, C., Ma, Y. and Xuan, Y. 2011. Ownership structure and financial constraints: Evidence from a structural estimation. Journal of Financial Economics, 102(2): 416-31. Linz, S., and Krueger, G. 1998. Enterprise restructuring in Russia's transition economy: formal and informal mechanisms. Comparative Economic Studies, 40(2): 5-52. Lipparini, A. and Lomi, A. 1999. Interorganizational relations in the Modena biomedical industry: A case study in local economic development. In A. Grandori (Ed.), Interfirm networks: Organization and industrial competitiveness: 120-50. London: Routledge. 45 Lizal, L., and Svejnar, J. 2002. Investment, credit rationing, and the soft budget constraint: evidence from Czech panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2): 353370. Love, I. and Zicchino, L. 2006. Financial development and dynamic investment behavior: Evidence from panel VAR. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 46: 190-210. Luo, Y. 2003. Industrial dynamics and managerial networking in an emerging market: The case of China. Strategic Management Journal, 24: 1315-1327. Luo, Y., and Chen, M. 1997. Does guanxi influence firm performance? Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 14: 1-16. Mairesse, J., Hall. H.B., Mulkay, B. 1999. Firm-Level Investment in France and the United States: An exploration of what we have learned in twenty years. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 55-56: 27-67. Masulis, R. W., Wang, C., and Xie, F. 2009. Agency problems at dualβclass companies. The Journal of Finance, 64(4): 1697-1727. Maury, B. and Pajuste, A. 2005. Multiple large shareholders and firm value. Journal of Banking and Finance. 29(7): 1813-34. McConnell, J. J., and Muscarella, C. J. 1985. Corporate capital expenditure decisions and the market value of the firm. Journal of Financial Economics, 14(3): 399-422. McDonald, M.L. and Westphal, J.D. 2003. Getting by with the advice of their friends: CEO’s advice networks and firms’ strategic responses to poor performance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48: 1-32. McFaul, M. 1993. Russian centrism and revolutionary transitions. Post-Soviet Affairs, 9(3): 196-222. McKinsey and Company. 2002. Global Investor Opinion Survey: Key Findings. Accessed from http://ww1.mckinsey.com/clientservice/organizationleadership/service/corpgov ernance/PDF/GlobalInvestorOpinionSurvey2002.pdf Megginson, W. L., and Netter, J. M. 2001. From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(2): 321-389. Mehran, H. 1995. Executive compensation structure, ownership, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 38(2): 163-184. 46 Mickiewicz, T. 2010. Hard budget constraint. In Mickiewicz, T. (Eds.), Economics of institutional change: Central and Eastern Europe revisited: 76-86.Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Mickiewicz, T., Bishop, K., and Varblane, U. 2004. Financial constraints in investment. Panel data results from Estonia, 1995-1999. Acta Oeconomica, 54(4): 425-449. Millar, C. C., Eldomiaty, T. I., Choi, C. J., and Hilton, B. 2005. Corporate governance and institutional transparency in emerging markets. Journal of Business Ethics, 59(12): 163-174. Mironov, M. 2013. Taxes, theft, and firm performance. The Journal of Finance. DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12026. Access on 15 May 2013 from http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jofi.12026/pdf Modigliani, F. and Perotti, E. 1997. Protection of minority interest and the development of security markets. Managerial and Decision Economics, 18(7β8): 519-528. Modigliani, F., and Miller, M. H. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. The American Economic Review, 48(3): 261-297. Morck, R., Wolfenzon, D. and Yeung, B. 2005. Corporate governance, economic entrenchment and growth, Journal of Economic Literature, 43: 657-722. Moyen, N. 2004. Investment–cash flow sensitivities: constrained versus unconstrained firms. The Journal of Finance, 59(5): 2061-2092. Mueller, D. C., and Peev, E. 2007. Corporate governance and investment in Central and Eastern Europe. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(2): 414-437. Myers, S. C., and Majluf, N. S. 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics, 13(2): 187-221. Myers, S.C. 1984. The capital structure puzzle. Journal of Finance, 39: 575-92. Myers, S.C. 2000. Outside equity. Journal of Finance, 55: 1005-37. Myers, S.C. 2003. Financing of corporations. In G. M. Constantinides, M. Harris and R. M. Stultz (Eds.). Corporate governance and control. Handbook of the Economics of Finance, 1A: 215-254. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science BV. Mykhayliv, D. and Zauner, K.G. 2012. Investment behavior and ownership structures in Ukraine: Soft budget constraints, government ownership and private benefits of control. Journal of Comparative Economics, 41(1): 265-278. 47 Nguyen, B. D., and Nielsen, K. M. 2010. The value of independent directors: Evidence from sudden deaths. Journal of Financial Economics, 98(3): 550-567. Nickell, S. 1981. Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 1417-26. Nickell, S. J. 1996. Competition and corporate performance. Journal of Political Economy, 104(4): 724-46. Nolan, P. 2001. China and the Global Business Revolution. New York: Palgrave. OECD, 1999 Okhmatovskiy, I. 2010. Performance implications of ties to the government and SOEs: A political embeddedness perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 47(6): 1020-47. Okhmatovskiy, I., and David, R. J. 2012. Setting your own standards: Internal corporate governance codes as a response to institutional pressure. Organization Science, 23(1): 155-176. Pagano, M. and Roëll, A. 1998. The choice of stock ownership structure: Agency costs, monitoring, and the decision to go public. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113: 187-226. Patel, S. A., Balic, A., and Bwakira, L. 2002. Measuring transparency and disclosure at firmlevel in emerging markets. Emerging Markets Review, 3(4): 325-337. Patel, S., and Dallas, G. 2002. Transparency and disclosure: Overview of methodology and study results-United States. Working Paper. Available at SSRN 422800, accessed from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=422800 on 15 May 2013 Patel, S.A., Balic, A. and Bwakira, L. 2002. Measuring transparency and disclosure at firmlevel in emerging markets. Emerging Markets Review, 3: 325-37. Pawlina, G., and Renneboog, L. 2005. Is Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivity Caused by Agency Costs or Asymmetric Information? Evidence from the UK. European Financial Management, 11(4): 483-513. Pearce, J. A., and Zahra, S. A. 1992. Board composition from a strategic contingency perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 29(4): 411-438. Peasnell, K. V., Pope, P. F., and Young, S. 2005. Board monitoring and earnings management: do outside directors influence abnormal accruals? Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 32(7β8): 1311-1346. 48 Peng, M. W., and Jiang, Y. 2010. Institutions behind family ownership and control in large firms. Journal of Management Studies, 47(2): 253-273. Peng, M. W., Buck, T., and Filatotchev, I. 2003. Do outside directors and new managers help improve firm performance? An exploratory study in Russian privatization. Journal of World Business, 38(4): 348-360. Peng, M.W. 2004. Outside directors and firm performance during institutional transitions. Strategic Management Journal, 25(5): 453-71. Perotti, E. C. and Gelfer, S. 2001. Red barons or robber barons? Governance and investment in Russian financial–industrial groups. European Economic Review, 45(9): 16011617. Perotti, E. C. and Vesnaver, L. 2004. Enterprise finance and investment in listed Hungarian firms. Journal of Comparative Economics, 32(1): 73-87. Pfeffer, J. and Salancik, G.R. 1978. The external control of organizations: A resource dependence perspective. New York: Harper and Row. Pfeffer, J. and Salancik, G.R. 2003. The external control of organizations: a resource dependence perspective. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Phelps, C. C. 2010. A longitudinal study of the influence of alliance network structure and composition on firm exploratory innovation. Academy of Management Journal, 53(4): 890-913. Pindado, J., and De La Torre, C. 2009. Effect of ownership structure on underinvestment and overinvestment: empirical evidence from Spain. Accounting and Finance, 49(2): 363-383. Pound, J. 1988. Proxy contests and the efficiency of shareholder oversight. Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 237-265. Power, C. 1987. Shareholders aren’t rolling over anymore. Business Week, April 27: 32-33. Pöyry, S., and Maury, B. 2010. Influential ownership and capital structure. Managerial and Decision Economics, 31(5): 311-324. Provan, K.G., Beyer, J. M. and Kruytbosch, C. 1980. Environmental linkages and power in resource-dependence relations between organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly, 25: 200-25. 49 Provan, K.G., Fish, A. and Sydow, J. 2007. Interorganizational networks at the network level: A review of the empirical literature on whole networks. Journal of Management, 33(3): 479-516. Puffer, S.M. and McCarthy, D.J. 2003. The emergence of corporate governance in Russia. Journal of World Business, 38(4): 284-98. Pyle, W. 2011. Organized Business, Political Competition, and Property Rights: Evidence from the Russian Federation. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 27(1): 2-31. Raith, M., Povel, P., and Cleary, S. 2007. The U-shaped investment curve: Theory and evidence. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 42: 1-39. Rajan, R. and Zingales, L. 1998. Financial dependence and growth. American Economic Review, 88: 559-86. Rajan, R., Cervaes, H. and Zingales, L. 2000. The cost of diversity: The diversification discount and inefficient investment. Journal of Finance, 55: 35-80. Rediker, K. J., and Seth, A. 1995. Boards of directors and substitution effects of alternative governance mechanisms. Strategic Management Journal, 16(2): 85-99. Rigi, J. 2005. State and big capital in Russia. In B. Kapferer (Ed.) Oligarchs and Oligopolies: New Formations Of Global Power: 57-69. New York: Berghahn Books. Roll, R. 1986. The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. Journal of Business, 59: 197216. Romano, R. 1996. Corporate law and corporate governance. Industrial and Corporate Change, 5(2): 277-340. Roodman, D.M. 2009. How to do xtabond2: An introduction to Difference and System GMM in Stata. The Stata Journal, 9: 86-136. Roohani, S., Furusho, Y. and Koizumi, M. 2009. XBRL: Improving transparency and monitoring functions of corporate governance. International Journal of Disclosure and Governance, 6: 355-69. Roosenboom, P. 2005. Bargaining on board structure at the initial public offering. Journal of Management and Governance, 9(2): 171-198. Rosenstein, S., and Wyatt, J. G. 1990. Outside directors, board independence, and shareholder wealth. Journal of Financial Economics, 26(2): 175-191. 50 Rowley, T., Behrens, D. and Krackhardt, D. 2000. Redundant governance structures: An analysis of structural and relational embeddedness in the steel and semiconductor industries. Strategic Management Journal, 21: 369-86. RuedaβSabater, E. 2000. Corporate Governance: And the Bargaining Power of Developing Countries to Attract Foreign Investment. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 8(2): 117-124. Rutherford, M. A., Buchholtz, A. K., and Brown, J. A. 2007. Examining the Relationships Between Monitoring and Incentives in Corporate Governance. Journal of Management Studies, 44(3): 414-430. Scharfstein, D. S., and Stein, J. C. 2000. The dark side of internal capital markets: Divisional rentβseeking and inefficient investment. The Journal of Finance, 55(6): 25372564. Schiantarelli, F. 1996. Financial constraints and investment: methodological issues and international evidence. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 12(2): 70-89. Seifert, B., and Gonenc, H. 2010. Pecking order behavior in emerging markets. Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting, 21(1): 1-31. Settles, A. 2010. Corporate governance and IPOs: Comparison of Russian companies crosslisting on the London Stock Exchange. Unpublished working paper, Higher School of Economics, Moscow. Shekshnia, S. V. 2004. Roles, responsibilities, and independence of boards of directors. In D. J. McCarthy, S. M. Puffer and S. V. Shekshnia (Eds.), Corporate Governance in Russia: 201-221. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Shilling, M.A. and Phelps, C.C. 2007. Interfirm collaboration networks: The impact of largescale network structure on firm innovation. Management Science, 53(7): 111326. Shirley, M.M. and Walsh, P. 2001. Public vs. private ownership: The current state of the debate. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, Washington DC: The World Bank. Shleifer, A. 1998. State versus private ownership, NBER Working Paper Series, No. w6665. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. 1986. Large shareholders and corporate control. The Journal of Political Economy, 94(3): 461-488. 51 Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. 1997. A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52(2): 737-83. Siegel, J. 2007. Contingent political capital and international alliances: Evidence from South Korea. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52(4): 621-666. Sprenger, C. 2011. The choice of ownership structure: evidence from Russian mass privatization. Journal of Comparative Economics, 39(2): 260-277. Standard and Poor’s and the Centre for Economic and Financial Research (CEFIR) at the New Economic School. 2009. Transparency and disclosure by Russian companies 2009: The gap between the highest scoring companies and the lowest scoring companies widens. Moscow: Standard and Poor’s. Accessed from http://www.standardandpoors.com/home/en/us on October 21, 2009. Stein, J.C. 2003. Agency, information and corporate investment. In G.M. Constantinides, M. Harris, and R. Stulz. (Eds) Handbook of the economics of finance, 1A: 111-166. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science BV. Sun, P., Mellahi, K. and Wright, M. 2012. The contingent value of corporate political ties. Academy of Management Perspectives, 26(3): 68-82. Sundaramurthy, C., Mahoney, J. M., and Mahoney, J. T. 1997. Board structure, antitakeover provisions, and stockholder wealth. Strategic Management Journal, 18(3): 231245. Taggart, R. 1983. Capital allocation in multi-division firms: Hurdle rates vs. budgets, NBER Working Paper Series. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Tian, L. and Estrin, S. 2007. Retained state shareholding in Chinese PLCs: Does government ownership reduce corporate value? Journal of Comparative Economics, 36: 7489. Tihanyi, L., and Hegarty, W. H. 2007. Political Interests and the Emergence of Commercial Banking in Transition Economies. Journal of Management Studies, 44(5): 788813. Tihanyi, L., Johnson, R., Hoskisson, R. and Hitt, M. 2003. Institutional ownership differences and international diversification: The effects of boards of directors and technological opportunity. Academy of Management Journal, 48(2): 195-211. Tirole, J.2005. The theory of corporate finance. Princeton, NG: Princeton University Press 52 Toms, S. 2006. Accounting for entrepreneurship: a knowledge-based view of the firm. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 17(2): 336-357. Toms, S., and Filatotchev, I. 2004. Corporate governance, business strategy, and the dynamics of networks: A theoretical model and application to the British cotton industry, 1830–1980. Organization Studies, 25(4): 629-651. Toms, S., and Wright, M. 2002. Corporate governance, strategy and structure in British business history, 1950-2000. Business History, 44(3): 91-124. Toninelli, P. A, 2000. The rise and fall of state owned enterprise in the Western world. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Tosi, H. L., Katz, J. P., and Gomez-Mejia, L. R. 1997. Disaggregating the agency contract: The effects of monitoring, incentive alignment, and term in office on agent decision making. Academy of Management Journal, 40(3): 584-602. Uhlaner, L., Wright, M., and Huse, M. 2007. Private firms and corporate governance: An integrated economic and management perspective. Small Business Economics, 29(3): 225-241. Von Hirschhausen, C. 1998. Industrial restructuring in Ukraine seven years after independence: From socialism to a planning economy? Communist Economies and Economic Transformation, 10(4): 451-465. Ward, A., Brown, J. and Rodriguez, D. 2009. Governance bundles, firm performance, and the substitutability and complementarity of governance mechanisms. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17(5): 646-60. Weidenbaum, M. 1985. The best defense against the raiders. Business Week, 2913, 2-3. White, H. 1980. A heteroscedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroscedasticity, Econometrica, 48: 817-838. Whited, T.M. and Wu, G. 2006. Financial constraints risk. Review of Financial Studies, 19(2): 531-59. Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies. New York: Free Press Williamson, O. E., 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York and London: Free Press. Williamson, O.E. 1988. The logic of economic organisation. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4(1): 65-93. 53 Williamson, O.E. 1998. Transaction cost economics: How it works; where it is headed. The Economist, 146(1): 23-58. Wintoki, M. B., Linck, J. S., and Netter, J. M. 2012. Endogeneity and the dynamics of internal corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 105: 581-606. Wright, M., Buck, T. and Filatotchev, I. 1998. Bank and Investment Fund Monitoring of Privatized Firms in Russia. Economics of Transition 6(2): 361–387 Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R. E. and Peng, M. W. 2005. Strategy Research in Emerging Economies: Challenging the Conventional Wisdom. Journal of Management Studies, 42: 1–33. Wright, M., Siegel, D. S., Keasey, K., and Filatotchev, I. 2013. Introduction. In M. Wright, D. S. Siegel, K. Keasey and I. Filatotchev (Eds.) The Oxford Handbook of Corporate Governance, 1-22. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Wulf, J. 1999. Influence and inefficiency in the internal capital market: Theory and evidence, Working Paper, Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania. Xin, K. K., and Pearce, J. L. 1996. Guanxi: Connections as substitutes for formal institutional support. Academy of Management Journal, 39(6): 1641-1658. Young, M. N., Peng, M. W., Ahlstrom, D., and Bruton, G. D. 2002. Governing the corporation in emerging economies: a principal-principal perspective. In Academy of Management Proceedings, No. 1, E1-E6. Academy of Management. Young, M.N., Peng, M.W., Ahlstrom, D., Bruton, G.D., and Jiang, Y. 2008. Corporate governance in emerging economies: A review of the principal–principal perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 45(1): 196-220. Zahra, S. A. 1996. Governance, ownership, and corporate entrepreneurship: The moderating impact of industry technological opportunities. Academy of Management Journal, 39(6): 1713-1735. Zajac, E. J., and Westphal, J. D. 1994. The costs and benefits of managerial incentives and monitoring in large US corporations: when is more not better? Strategic Management Journal, 15(1): 121-142. Zingales, L. 2000. In search of new foundations. Journal of Finance, 55: 1623-53. 54 Appendices Table 8: Measuring corporate governance risks in Russia 55 Figure 2: Distribution of companies by total TD score, 2008-2009 Distribution of companies by transparency score, 2008-09 Share of companies in the sample 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 2008 15% 2009 10% 5% 0% <30% 30%-40% 40%-50% 50%-60% 60%-70% >70% T&D Score Note: The gap in transparency between the highest and the lowest scorers in the ranking remains considerable and even increased over 2008-2009. In 2009, the scores ranged from a high of 80% (78% in 2008) for the top ranked company to a low of 20% (28% in 2008) for the lowest ranked company. Some companies in the middle tier of 2008 dataset have improved their performance, while for some other companies from the middle tier and some outsiders transparency has worsened significantly. As a result, the score dispersion within the rank has increased. The average gap between the neighbouring companies amounts to almost 0.68 percentage points which is higher than in 2008 (0.56 percentage points) but almost the same as in the 2007 dataset. The average TD index for the top 10 companies remained virtually unchanged from 2008 to 2009 at 75.6%. 56 Figure 3: TD sub-scores distributions graphs ο· ο· Histogram Fin. and operational information score Frequency 30 0 0 10 20 20 Frequency 40 40 50 60 Histogram Ownership Structure and Shareholder rights score 0 ο· .2 .4 .6 .8 Ownership structure and shareholder rights score 1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 Financial and Operational Information score 1 0 20 Frequency 40 60 Histogram Board and Management structure score 0 .2 .4 .6 Board and management structure and process score .8 Note: Ownership and Shareholder rights score and Board and Management score show a normal distribution shape with highest frequency of 50% score. A number of firms have high Financial and Operational information score in the range of 60%-80%. 57 Figure 4: TD sub-scores correlations graphs Board management structure score to fin. and operational information score 0 1 .8 .6 .4 .2 0 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Financial and operational information score Ownership str. & s/holder rights score to financial and operational information score .2 .4 .6 .8 Ownership structure and shareholder rights score Fitted values 1 0 .2 .4 .6 Board and management structure and process score 95% CI Fitted values 95% CI Correlation between log of capex and total T&D score 0 0 .2 5 .4 .6 10 .8 1 15 Board management structure score to ownership and s/holder rights score .8 0 .2 .4 .6 Board and management structure and process score (%) Fitted values 95% CI .8 0 .2 .4 Total TD Score (%) Log of capex in RUB Fitted values .6 .8 95% CI Note: The 3 sub scores are correlated. If a firm has high reporting of financial and operational information, it will likely report sufficient information on board, management and ownership structures. The log of capital expenditure (investment) is correlated with Total TD score. 58 Sahre of the aggregate MCap Figure 5: Distribution of aggregate market capitalization by transparency, 2008-2009 10 60% 50% 40% 30% 2008 20% 2009 10% 0% <30% 30%-40% 40%-50% 50%-60% 60%-70% >70% TD Score Figure 6 : Relationship between firm market capitalization and transparency, 2009 70% 60% TD Score 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% <200 200-400 400-1000 1000-5000 >5000 MCap, USDmln Note: The 2009 TD dataset shows that, similar to previous years, a major portion of total market capitalization is represented by companies with high levels of transparency. In 2009 (see Figure 5) this relationship was especially pronounced. Companies with TD scores higher than 60% represent about 78% of aggregate market capitalization. This effect can be explained both by the generally greater transparency of big companies (Figure 6) compared to smaller ones, and by the positive impact of greater transparency on the company’s market value. 10 Market capitalization numbers were computed based on the market capitalization of companies averaged for the period 1.1.2009 to 18.5.2009 (Source: S&P) 59 Disclosure to investors of some important elements remains low, especially in relation to information on the terms of employment contracts with CEOs, details of directors’ and executives’ remuneration and information on auditors’ provision of non-audit services (Table 9: Weakest areas of disclosure by the largest Russian companies, 2007-2009). Table 9: Weakest areas of disclosure by the largest Russian companies, 2007-2009 Component 2007 2008 2009 23 43 29 42 26 48 24 29 34 22 15 42 27 36 44 4 16 11 15 26 14 19 7 8 19 19 12 23 39 11 8 7 3 23 23 2 24 32 1 29 37 33 6 30 6 20 6 1. Ownership Structure ο· ο· Number and indemnity of all the shareholders holding more than 10% Disclosure of share of beneficiary owners more than 75% 2. Shareholder rights ο· ο· ο· Evidence of existence of code of business conduct and ethics Announcement of recommended dividends before the record date Calendar of important future shareholder dates 3. Financial Information ο· ο· ο· ο· Detailed earnings forecast Disclosure of whether auditor renders non-audit services Non-audit fees paid to the auditor Indication that related-party transactions are made on market or non-market terms 4. Operational information ο· Social reporting 5. Board and management information ο· ο· ο· Details of CEO’s contract Record of attendance at board meetings Information on ratio of in person and in absentia board meetings 6. Board and management remuneration ο· ο· Specifics of directors’ pay Specifics of managers’ pay 60 Table 10: TD Scores of 10 Most Transparent Russian Companies 61 Table 11: List of 90 Russian companies with S&P TD scores (in 2009) (Arranged alphabetically) Acron OGK-1 Aeroflot OGK-2 AFI Development OGK-3 (WGC-3) AvtoVAZ OGK-4 Baltika OGK-6 Bank Saint Petersburg Open Investments Bashneft Pharmstandard C.A.T. oil PIK Central Telecommunications Co. Polymetal Cherkizovo Polyus Gold Comstar-UTS Raspadskaya Π‘Π’Π‘ Media RAZGULAY Group Dixy Group RBC Information Systems Enel OGK-5 Rosneft Eurasia Drilling Rostelecom Evraz Group Sberbank FGC UES Seventh Continent Fortum (formerly TGC-10) Severstal Gazprom Sibir Energy Gazprom Neft Sibirtelecom GlobalTrans Sistema IDGC Holding Sistema-Hals IDGC of Centre Slavneft-Megionneftegaz IDGC of North-West SOLLERS (formerly Severstal-Avto) IDGC of Urals Surgutneftegas IDGC of Volga Tatneft IDGC of Centre and Volga Region TGC-1 INTER RAO UES TGC-4 62 Irkutskenergo TGC-5 RusHydro TGC-6 KAMAZ TGC-9 LSR Group TGC-14 LUKOIL TMK M.Video TNK-BP Holding Magnit Uralkali Mechel Uralsvyazinform MMK Veropharm Mobile TeleSystems Vimpelcom Mosenergo Volga TGC (TGC-7) MOESK VolgaTelecom Norilsk Nickel VSMPO-AVISMA North-West Telecom Bank Vozrozhdenie NOVATEK VTB Novolipetsk Steel Wimm-Bill-Dann Foods Novorossiysk Commercial Sea Port X5 Retail Group 63 Table 12: Criteria for TD survey Block 1: ownership structure and shareholder rights Component 1. Ownership structure Disclosure of: 1. The number and par value of issued ordinary shares. 2. The number and par value of issued other types of shares disclosed. 3. The number and par value of authorized but unissued shares of all types. 4. The identity of the largest shareholder. 5. The identity of holders of all large stakes (blocking: > 25%; controlling: > 50%). 6. The identity of shareholders holding at least 25% of voting shares in total. 7. The identity of shareholders holding at least 50% of voting shares in total. 8. The identity of shareholders holding at least 75% of voting shares in total. 9. The number and identity of each shareholder holding more than 10%. 10. Indication that management is not aware of the existence of any stake exceeding 5% other than those reported. 11. An update on shareholder structure after the record date. 12. Shareholding in the company by individual senior managers. 13. Shareholding in the company of individual directors. 14. Description of share classes. 15. Shareholders by type. 16. Percentage of cross-ownership. 17. Information on exchange listings. 18. Information on indirect ownership (e.g., convertible instruments). Component 2. Shareholder rights Disclosure of: 19. Corporate governance charter or corporate governance guidelines. 20. Evidence of existence of a code of business conduct and ethics. 21. Content of code of business conduct and ethics. 22. Articles of association (including changes). 23. Voting rights for each voting or non-voting share. 24. How shareholders nominate board members. 64 25. How shareholders convene an extraordinary general meeting (EGM). 26. Procedure for initiating inquiries with the board. 27. Procedure for putting forward proposals at shareholders meetings. 28. Formalized dividend policy. 29. Announcement of recommended dividends before the record date. 30. Review of last shareholders meeting. 31. Full minutes of general shareholder meeting (GSM). 32. Calendar of important shareholder future dates. 33. GSM materials published on the web site. 34. Detailed press releases covering last corporate events. 35. Policy on information disclosure. Block 2: Financial and Operational Information Component 3. Financial information Disclosure of: 36. The company’s accounting policy. 37. The accounting standards it uses for its accounts. 38. Accounts according to local standards. 39. Annual financial statements according to an internationally recognized accounting standard (IFRS/U.S. GAAP). 40. Notes to annual financial statements according to IFRS/U.S. GAAP. 41. Independent auditor’s report on annual financial statements according to IFRS/U.S. GAAP. 42. Unqualified (clean) audit opinion on annual financial statements according to IFRS/U.S. GAAP. 43. Audited IFRS/U.S. GAAP financial statements published before 30 April. 44. Unaudited IFRS/U.S. GAAP financial statements published before 30 April. 45. Audited IFRS/U.S. GAAP financial statements published before annual general meeting. 46. Unaudited IFRS/U.S. GAAP financial statements published before 30 June. 47. Disclosure of related-party transactions (RPTs): sales to/purchases from, payables to/receivables from related parties. 48. Indication that RPTs are made on market or non-market terms. 49. Exact RPT terms. 65 50. Interim (quarterly or half yearly) financial statements according to an internationally recognized accounting standard (IFRS/U.S. GAAP). 51. Notes to these financial statements. 52. Whether these financial statements are audited or at least reviewed. 53. Consolidated financial statements according to local standards. 54. Methods of asset valuation. 55. List of affiliates in which company holds a minority stake. 56. Ownership structure of affiliates. 57. A basic earnings forecast of any kind. 58. A detailed earnings forecast. 59. Segment analysis (results broken down by business line). 60. Revenue structure (detailed breakdown). 61. Cost structure (high degree of detail). 62. Name of auditing firm. 63. Whether audit firm is a top-tier auditor. 64. Auditor rotation policy. 65. How much the company pays in audit fees to the auditor. 66. Whether auditor renders non-audit services. 67. Non-audit fees paid to the auditor. Component 4. Operational information Disclosure of: 68. Details of the firm’s type of business. 69. Details of products or services company produces or provides. 70. Output in physical terms. 71. Description of functional relationships between key operating units within the group. 72. Industry indicators that allow comparison with peers. 73. Other financial indicators. 74. Characteristics of fixed assets employed (including licences). 75. Efficiency indicators. 76. Discussion of corporate strategy. 77. Plans for investment in future years. 78. Detailed information about investment plans in the coming year. 66 79. Output forecast of any kind. 80. Overview of trends in the relevant industry; regulatory environment with regard to industry. 81. Market share for any or all of the company’s businesses. 82. Social reporting (e.g., Global Reporting Initiative). 83. Overview of compliance with ecology law. 84. Principles of corporate citizenship. Block 3: Board and Management Structure and Process Component 5. Board and management information Disclosure of: 85. List of board members (names). 86. Details of directors’ current employment and position. 87. Other details: previous employment and positions, education, etc. 88. Date of appointment to the board. 89. Name of chairman. 90. Details on role of company board of directors. 91. List of matters reserved to the board. 92. List of board committees. 93. Names of all members of current committees. 94. Bylaws relating to other internal audit functions than the audit committee. 95. Information on ratio of in absentia and in person board meetings. 96. Record of attendance at board meetings. 97. List of senior managers not on board of directors. 98. Senior managers backgrounds. 99. The non-financial details of CEO’s contract. 100. The number of shares held by managers, in other affiliated companies. 101. Policy on assessment of board of directors and training provided to them. Component 6. Board and management remuneration Disclosure of: 102. Decision-making process related to directors’ pay. 103. Specifics of directors’ remuneration, including salary levels. 104. Form of directors’ salaries, such as in cash or in shares. 67 105. Specifics of directors’ performance-related pay. 106. Decision-making process to determine managerial (not directors’) pay. 107. Specifics of managers’ (not directors’) emuneration, such as salary levels and bonuses. 108. Form of managers’ (not directors’) pay. 109. Specifics of managers’ performance-related pay. 110. Level and composition of CEO’s remuneration. 68 Table 13: Investment and direct impact of governance, cross section Ordinary Least Squares 69 Figure 7: Impulse responses - VAR model Note: Errors are 5% on each side generated by Monte-Carlo with 1000 reps. VAR model with three variables: Log of investments (lncapxr), log of sales (lnsaler) and log of total TD score (lntotal) 70 Acronyms CEE Central and Eastern Europe CIS Commonwealth of Independent States EBIT Earnings before Interest and Tax EUR Euro FDI Foreign Direct Investments FE Fixed effects FFMS Federal Financial Markets Service FSA Financial Services Authority FSC Federal Securities Commission GDP Gross Domestic Product GAAP Generally Accepted Accounting Principles GMM Generalized Method of Moments IFC International Finance Corporation IFRS International Financial Reporting Standards IMF International Monetary Fund IT Information Technology LSE London Stock Exchange MBA Master of Business Administration MSc Master of Science NPV Net Present Value 71 NYSE New York Stock Exchange OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development OLS Ordinary Least Squares P&L Profit and Loss Statement PhD Doctor of Philosophy PPA Principal-Principal Agent PPP Purchasing Power Parity RDT Resource Dependence Theory RPT Related Party Transactions RUIE Russian Union of Industrialists and Entrepreneurs RUR Russian Rouble S&P Standard and Poor’s SCA Securities and Exchange Commission SME Small and Medium Enterprises SOAS School of Oriental and African Studies SOE State Owned Enterprise TD Transparency and Disclosure TFP Total Factor Productivity UK United Kingdom UKLA UK Listing Authority US United States VAR Vector Auto-Regression 72