Local Opportunity Structures and Intergenerational Neighborhood Income Mobility Jeremy Pais, Ph.D. Department of Sociology University of Connecticut 344 Mansfield Rd. Unit 2068 Storrs, CT 06269-2068 Phone: 860-486-0391 E-mail: j.pais@uconn.edu July 2014 Word count: 12,145 (excluding tables) Number of Figures:6 Number of tables: 4 Key words: income mobility; intergenerational elasticity; local labor markets; multigenerational; residential attainment; social mobility; spatial mobility Direct correspondence to Jeremy Pais, Department of Sociology, University of Connecticut, Storrs, CT 06269. E-mail: j.pais@uconn.edu. This research was supported by an internal faculty grant to the authors from the University of Connecticut. Local Opportunity Structures and Intergenerational Neighborhood Income Mobility Abstract: This study develops an analytical framework for understanding and evaluating the importance of the local opportunity structure for patterns of intergenerational spatial mobility. Of key interest are legacy effects: The effects of residential constraints to spatial mobility in one generation that manifest themselves in future generations. This framework helps us understand the multiple pathways through which past and current levels of racial residential segregation, racial and ethnic diversity, economic specialization, suburban sprawl, and urban development affect residential outcomes and stratification processes more generally. There is considerable metropolitan-area heterogeneity in the effect of parent’s neighborhood status (first generation) on their adult children’s neighborhood attainments (second generation). Focal metropolitan-area characteristics account for about a third of the intergenerational elasticity variation that exists across metropolitan areas. For black families, the effect of racial residential segregation on neighborhood income attainment operates almost entirely through the residential constraints placed on the first generation. 1 Introduction The connection between social mobility and spatial mobility is a pillar of social stratification theory (Park, Burgess, and McKenzie 1925; Massey 1985). A comprehensive understanding of one form of mobility is not complete without the other. Empirical research on intergenerational social mobility, however, outpaces intergenerational spatial mobility research by a considerable margin. Cases in point are the many recent studies on the intergenerational income elasticity—a common indicator intergenerational income mobility (e.g., Solon 1992; Graham and Sharkey 2013; Hertz 2005; Aaronson, and Mazumder. 200; also see http://www.equality-of-opportunity.org/). Only recently have researchers set out to quantify in a similar fashion the strength of the intergenerational elasticity with regard to residential location (Sharkey 2008; Vartanian, Buck and Gleason 2007). Current estimates using the same data source and methods have the intergenerational income elasticity in the United States as .534 (Hertz 2005), compared to a slightly more rigid intergenerational elasticity estimate of .640 for neighborhood income (Sharkey 2008). These estimates suggest that more than half of the respective income and neighborhood advantages/disadvantages are transmitted from one generation to the next. From a conceptual standpoint the lion’s share of recent interest with intergenerational income mobility is surprising given that the social mechanisms and processes that in large measure facilitate or hinder income mobility originate in neighborhood environments (discussed in more detail below). In fact, many of the factors that affect intergenerational spatial mobility should naturally supersede the causes of income mobility; and thus, intergenerational mobility research in general faces certain deadlock without a more rigorous understanding of the key 2 issues that affect intergenerational spatial mobility. This study develops an innovative framework that brings these key issues to light. The theoretical framework for this study relies on both macro-level conditions and microlevel social processes to explain why local opportunity structures are vital for understanding intergenerational mobility. The local opportunity structure is essential from both micro and macro perspectives because it is where residential aspirations and residential constraints are actualized. To better understand this process, a nuanced temporal approach is taken that (i) accounts for the way contemporary structural conditions shape the current residential mobility landscape, but (ii) also acknowledges the different ways historical-structural antecedents can influence the residential attainments of future generations. The latter possibility assumes the existence of legacy effects: These are the effects of residential constraints to mobility in one generation that manifest themselves in future generations primarily through human capital development or through the cultural conditioning of residential preferences and aspirations. This legacy perspective will help formulate more comprehensive explanations for why racial residential segregation, racial and ethnic diversity, economic specialization, suburban sprawl, and urban development affect neighborhood attainment and mobility outcomes. This perspective will also provide guidance for intergenerational mobility research more generally. There are four empirical objectives that will be used to evaluate this framework. First, I replicate prior estimates of the intergenerational elasticity of neighborhood income using updated data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). The replicated estimates are equivalent to those in the literature (Sharkey 2008). These estimates serve as a foundation from which to build. The second objective involves assessing the extent to which intergenerational neighborhood income mobility varies across different metropolitan areas. Metropolitan-areas are 3 proxy geographies for local opportunity structures. This objective establishes how much explanatory power local opportunity structures have for the intergenerational mobility process. The third and fourth objectives evaluate hypotheses involving specific metropolitan-area characteristics. The third objective assesses how these structural conditions are mediated by the intergenerational transmission process. This objective evaluates the legacy effects thesis. The fourth objective assesses the way intergenerational spatial mobility is moderated by various structural conditions. This objective provides novel insight into the dynamics that are shaping the residential outlooks of future generations. Conceptually and empirically this study is a step forward in the area of intergenerational spatial mobility research. Social Stratification and the Intergenerational Transmission of Neighborhood Status The importance of spatial mobility, or the lack of, for the geographic concentration of affluence and poverty in America widely recognized. The persistence of urban poverty, for example, is a perennial issue that is sustained in large measure by the perpetual exposure of children, generation after generation, to impoverished communities. This is because neighborhood poverty is associated with a dearth of positive role models, higher dropout rates, lower levels of educational attainment, higher rates of teenage pregnancy, poorer health outcomes, an increase of youthful involvement in crime and delinquency, and stunted cognitive development (for reviews see: Diez-Roux 2001; Ellen and Turner 2003; Jencks and Mayer 1990; Pickett and Pearl 2001; Robert 1999; Sampson, Morenoff, and Gannon-Rowley 2002; Small and Newman 2001). Often these associations persist apart from parental socioeconomic resources. Through processes of collective socialization, social and spatial isolation, and the unequal distribution of institutional resources, neighborhood and community environments come to facilitate or impede the acquisition of the types of attitudes, skills, and attributes that help 4 determine socioeconomic achievements later in life (Jencks and Mayer 1990). This is why the intergenerational transmission of neighborhood environment is considered a critical aspect of the stratification system (Sharkey 2008). There are several theories that are useful for understanding why childhood residential environments affect adult outcomes. Human capital theories, for instance, suggest that advantaged residential locations allow families to more easily transfer instrumental skills and knowledge from one generation to the next (Borjas 1995). Access to good schools, and to other children from affluent families, does not guarantee high levels of human capital acquisition in the next generation, but advantaged locations improve the chances above and beyond parental resources alone (Sharkey and Elwert 2011). Adult offspring with high levels of human capital are then able to afford housing in affluent neighborhoods that are of similar stature as their childhood neighborhoods. On the opposite end of the stratification hierarchy, families with poorly rewarded job skills and limited financial means are more likely to live in neighborhoods that subject their children to inferior educational institutions, few occupationally successful role models, and an informal street economy with lucrative short-run opportunities through criminal enterprises (Sampson, Raudenbush, and Earls 1997; Venkatesh 2006). These locational disadvantages make it more difficult, but not impossible, to acquire the types of skills and attributes that are needed to gain access to more affluent residential spaces. The overarching implication of this perspective is that the quality of child’s neighborhood growing up will impact the accumulation of human capital in ways that affect, to some degree, adult neighborhood outcomes. An equally pertinent theory comes from the residential satisfaction perspective (Landale and Guest 1985; Speare et al. 1975), which focuses on personal and lifecourse circumstances that 5 influence residential choices. A variant of the residential satisfaction perspective that is relevant for the intergenerational transmission process involves cultural conditioning. Cultural conditioning maintains that adult residential choice is a product of the preferences that are shaped by childhood neighborhood experiences (Vartanian et al. 2007). For instance, Sampson and Wilson (1995) maintain that people develop “cognitive landscapes” of the ecological structure of their communities, which are built on perceptions of racial, ethnic, and/or class based distinctions. These mental maps then tend to inform people’s residential preferences later in life. Children come to learn these mental maps, and in the process develop a sense of place in the larger ecological structure of the community. Wanting, or in some cases needing, to maintain spatial proximity to friendship networks and family ties also conditions residential preferences (Bell-McDonald and Richards 2008; Hedman 2013). From this perspective, a socioenvironmental disposition appears to develop in next generation through micro-level cultural and social processes that are constituted in a child’s milieu. Place stratification theory is the third useful theoretical perspective for understanding the intergenerational transmission of neighborhood status. Place stratification theory recognizes how the spatial-ecological structure of a community is controlled and manipulated by powerful group interests in an effort to maintain physical and social separation from populations they deem undesirable (Charles 2003; Logan and Molotch 1987). Power and race relations are at the center of place stratification theory because the residential preferences of the racial majority can avertedly or inadvertently impede the actualization of minority group residential aspirations. Although whites’ acceptance of minority neighbors has increased, whites still tend to prefer predominantly white neighborhoods over integrated neighborhoods, whereas black residents tend to prefer more ethnically integrated neighborhoods than do whites (Charles 2006; Krysan and 6 Bader 2007). These modest group differences in neighborhood preferences can create enduring levels of residential separation because the preferences of more powerful groups—powerful in terms of population size and economic resources—produce macro-level mobility constraints for less powerful groups (cf. Schelling 1971; Bruch and Mare 2006). From this perspective it is necessary to examine the effects of the local opportunity structure on the intergenerational neighborhood attainment separately for majority and minority groups. There is a longstanding tension in the residential mobility literature between the residential satisfaction perspective and place stratification theory. Whereas the residential satisfaction perspective tends emphasize individual preferences in shaping neighborhood outcomes, place stratification emphasizes structural constraints that limit neighborhood choices for less powerful groups. The tension in the literature stems from the inability of researchers to simultaneously account for the long-run effects of preferences and the long-run effects of constraints on neighborhood attainments (e.g., see Crowder et al. 2012; Sharkey 2008:941). Arguably, however, the distinction between preferences and constraints is too simple a dichotomy from an intergenerational vantage point: If neighborhood preferences are largely formed through cultural conditioning that takes place in spatial environments of racial and class bifurcation then the next generation’s residential preferences are likely affected by the preceding generation’s structural constraints. This is the premise behind W. J. Wilson’s (2010) recognition of how the local opportunity structure provides the context within which cultural responses are developed. This study evaluates and extends this premise by formulating hypotheses that speak to the historical and contemporary influences of key structural conditions on the intergenerational transmission of neighborhood status in the United States. 7 A Framework for Examining the Legacy of the Local Opportunity Structure The main objective of this study is to examine how the local opportunity structure affects neighborhood attainment from one generation to the next. The premise guiding this study is of an essential interplay between the larger opportunity structure and the social processes that occur within residential settings. Two conceptual dimensions of the intergenerational transmission process highlight the importance of this interplay. The first dimension is temporal. The focus is on when exposure to different structural conditions occurs. For instance, the current metropolitan structure can affect a new generation of home seekers directly through the immediate opportunities and structural constraints emerging from local housing markets and local labor markets. This direct pathway is established in the neighborhood attainment literature, and it is best characterized by the “housing availability model” of residential mobility (e.g., South and Crowder 1997; Pais et al. 2012; South et al. 2011). However, a second pathway may also exist through the exposure of the first generation to the constraints of the local opportunity structure when the parents sought appropriate housing for raising families. A parent’s exposure to the opportunity structure will indirectly affect the status outcomes of their adult children by determining the social environments in which human capital is developed and cultural conditioning occurs. It is through these indirect pathways, or legacy effects, that historical-structural antecedents can have long-term implications for stratification outcomes. Despite the clear conceptual significance of both the direct and indirect pathways, there is little explicit acknowledgement in the neighborhood attainment literature of their co-existence, and the empirical nature of this co-existence is entirely unexplored. It seems a comparison of direct and indirect contextual pathways to neighborhood attainment is warranted, as it will 8 provide a window into the relative explanatory power attributed to long-term historical-structural antecedents versus contemporaneous structural opportunities in affecting neighborhood outcomes. The second key distinction stems from a longstanding recognition in the social stratification literature between status attainment and status mobility (Blau and Duncan 1967). This distinction is germane here for several reasons. Conceptually, different patterns of mobility and attainment will likely impart on the next generation different neighborhood aspirations and preferences. Ideally, the opportunity structure should produce a higher average degree of neighborhood attainment and a higher rate of intergenerational spatial mobility. This is ideal because later generations, especially from poorer strata, are more inclined to develop advantageous aspirations and preferences in areas with these characteristics (cf. Wilson 1959). Theoretically, however, four different patterns are plausible: (1) High attainment/high mobility; (2) low attainment/low mobility; (3) high attainment/low mobility; and (4) low attainment/ high mobility, and specific structural characteristics may affect the average level of neighborhood attainment as well as the average rate intergenerational neighborhood mobility in different ways. Racial group heterogeneity can further complicate these patterns. These two dimensions can now be used to help develop specific hypotheses. Figure 1 is useful for identifying the different kinds of research hypotheses addressed in this study. It illustrates the key pathways and effects identified by the proposed framework for understanding the effects of the local opportunity structure. These key effects include: (a) the intergenerational elasticity between parent’s and adult child’s neighborhood attainments (i.e., status mobility between generations); (c) the direct effect of the local opportunity structure on the average level neighborhood attainment among the second generation; (a * b) the indirect effect of the local 9 opportunity structure on the average level neighborhood attainment among the second generation that operates through the residential constraints on the parent’s neighborhood attainment; and (d) the cross-level interactions involving the effects of the local opportunity structure on the strength of the intergenerational elasticity. Hypotheses concerning each of these pathways and effects are developed for specific structural conditions (e.g., H1; H1a; H1b; H2). For this study there are several metropolitan-area characteristics in the spatial stratification literature that capture key aspects of this larger opportunity environment. Broadly, these metropolitan-area characteristics include residential segregation, racial and ethnic population composition, economic specialization, urban development, and suburban sprawl (e.g., Farley and Frey 1994; Jargowsky 1996; Logan et al. 2004; Pais et al. 2012; Sassen 2006; South et al. 2011a). [Figure 1 about here] Racial residential segregation is a critical feature of the local opportunity structure (Galster 1991; Massey and Denton 1993), but it operates differently for majority and minority groups. In highly segregated metropolitan areas, minorities tend to live in more disadvantaged neighborhoods (Krivo et al. 2009), while whites tend to live in whiter and wealthier neighborhoods in these highly segregated areas (Pais et al. 2012). Two intergenerational transmission pathways can account for these residential patterns. These two pathways are not mutually exclusive and both are supported by place stratification theory. First, current levels segregation being highly correlated with past levels of segregation can directly affect an adult child’s chances of upward/downward spatial mobility in the same fashion it hindered/advanced the parent’s residential opportunities. That is, the level of residential segregation can impose an ecological rigidity on the residential geography of U.S. cities in ways that directly recreate each succeeding generation’s residential opportunities. However, segregation may also operate 10 indirectly by affecting the residential attainments of the parents, which then in turn exposes young children to areas of varying levels of concentrated disadvantage where micro-level social and cultural processes condition future generations in ways that make social and spatial mobility more or less likely. By using first generation’s neighborhood attainment as a mediator of residential segregation (and other structural characteristics), it is possible to empirically disentangle the direct and indirect role of residential segregation in shaping neighborhood outcomes, generation after generation. Accordingly, we should expect (H1) higher levels of racial segregation to decrease the neighborhood attainments of black families and increase the neighborhood attainments of white families, and this should occur because (H1a & H1b) the effects of racial segregation will operate in an indirect fashion (H1a) and a direct fashion (H1b). We should also expect, racial residential segregation to (H2) decrease intergenerational spatial mobility for black families (i.e., increase the intergenerational elasticity) but increase intergenerational spatial mobility for white families (i.e., decrease the intergenerational elasticity). Expectations concerning the relative strength of the indirect and direct effects stemming from residential segregation cannot currently be developed from the extant literature. It must instead be treated as an empirical question. A metropolitan area’s racial and ethnic population composition is another structural characteristic that may affect the intergenerational transmission process of neighborhood attainment. There are two primary perspectives that guide expectations. One perspective highlights the longstanding ecological ramifications posited by group-threat theory, which predicts stronger white avoidance of black neighborhoods, and greater black preference for black neighborhoods, in highly concentrated black areas (Charles 2000). The housing availability model, on the other hand, recognizes the demographic reality that affects the probability of 11 having greater or fewer neighborhoods of the opposite race. For example, prior research finds that large relative shares of black population increases both black and whites exposure to black neighborhoods (South et al. 2011b). Yet, despite the strong correlation between neighborhood poverty levels and neighborhood racial composition (Quillian and Pager 2001), racial population composition at the metropolitan level has little net effect on average neighborhood income for either white or black households (Pais et al. 2012). In support of the group-threat perspective, we should expect (H1) higher levels of racial population concentration to decrease the neighborhood attainments of black families and increase the neighborhood attainments of white families, and this should primarily occur by (H1a) the indirect effects of racial concentration on the second generation’s neighborhoods attainments and (H2) the decreasing of black’s and the increasing of white’s intergenerational spatial mobility. Conversely, and in support of the housing availability model, we should also expect (H1) higher levels of racial population concentration to decrease the neighborhood attainments of black and white families, but this should primarily occur by (H1b) the direct effect of racial concentration on the second generation’s neighborhoods attainments and (H2) the decreasing of black’s and white’s intergenerational spatial mobility. For similar reasons, the relative size of the foreign-born population in the metropolitan area may influence the intergenerational transmission process. A large local presence of foreignborn population may foster, or conversely weaken, neighborhood class divisions by increasing residential exposure to racial and ethnic diversity (Fischer and Tienda 2006; Logan and Zhang 2010). This could have three consequences. First, according to the housing availability model, increasing numbers of foreign-born residents will facilitate greater class integration among whites and blacks, which will be reflected in greater levels of intergenerational spatial mobility, 12 but a general decline in neighborhood income status for all groups. Place stratification, on the other hand, posits that levels of immigrant population concentration may further precipitate white flight and white avoidance of minority neighborhoods (e.g., Crowder, Hall, and Tolnay 2011; Wilson and Taub 2007), thereby exposing black households to declining neighborhood incomes but having the opposite effect for white households. A third possibility suggests that the new residential opportunities for class integration created by high levels of immigration will primarily benefit black households as the residential dichotomies between white and black neighborhoods weakens through added diversity. This is often referred to as the buffering hypothesis (Frey and Farley 1996). In support of the housing availability model, we should expect (H1) higher levels of foreign-born population concentration to decrease the neighborhood attainments of black and white families, and this should primarily occur by (H1b) the direct effect of foreign-born concentration on the second generation’s neighborhoods attainments (given the rapid increase in immigration beginning in the late 1980s) and (H2) the increasing of black’s and white’s intergenerational spatial mobility (i.e., lower attainments/higher mobility). According to the place stratification perspective, we should expect (H1) higher levels of foreign-born population concentration to decrease the neighborhood attainments of black families and increase the neighborhood attainments of white families, and this should primarily occur by (H1b) the direct effects of foreign-born concentration on the second generation’s neighborhoods attainments, and (H2) the decreasing of black’s and the increasing of white’s intergenerational spatial mobility. Finally, the buffering perspective anticipates (H1) higher levels of foreign-born population concentration to increase the neighborhood attainments of black families and decrease the neighborhood attainments of white families, and this should primarily occur by (H1b) the direct 13 effect of foreign-born concentration on the second generation’s neighborhoods attainments, and (H2) the increasing of black’s and the decreasing of white’s intergenerational spatial mobility. A metropolitan area’s employment specialization is another factor that can shape the residential landscape (e.g., Farley and Frey 1994; Logan et al. 2004). From the housing availability perspective, areas with many highly educated workers and many high paying jobs will produce better kinds of residential opportunities than areas with many low paying jobs. Major industrial shifts towards high finance and information technology, on the one end, and poor paying service jobs, on the other end, coupled with deindustrialization and the hollowing out of the manufacturing core in many U.S. cities have helped to spatially bifurcated the rich and poor (Jargowsky 1996; Sassen 2006). The emergence of the public sector as a source of stable mid-tier employment, especially among urban blacks (Waldinger 1996), seems to have provided at least a partial stopgap against these macro-level trends. Thus, economic transformations over the last half a century involving shifting employment concentrations in key industries, such as, high finance, insurance and real estate (FIRE), government, manufacturing, and the low-skilled service sector have helped to create today’s residential hierarchies. Accordingly, we should expect (H1) higher paying industries (e.g., FIRE) to be associated with higher levels of neighborhood status attainment for black and white families than mid-tier paying industries (e.g., government and manufacturing) and low paying industries (low skilled service sector). However, it is difficult to anticipate a priori (H1a & H1b) the relative strength of the indirect and direct effects stemming from these labor market characteristics. Therefore, the expectation is that the sub-hypotheses should operate in the same direction as H1, all else equal. However, there is sound reason to anticipate (H2) industry effects on intergenerational spatial mobility: Employment specializations associated with increasing 14 income inequality and residential bifurcation (e.g., higher levels of FIRE and low-wage serve) are expected to reduce prospects for intergenerational spatial mobility; whereas industries that provide stable mid-tier employment (e.g., higher levels of manufacturing and government employment) should facilitate greater levels of intergenerational spatial mobility. Urban development and suburbanization may affect the intergenerational transmission process as well. Large supplies of new housing could create improved opportunities for neighborhood attainment, but this could largely depend on what kinds of units are being built (single family vs. multiunit rental properties), and where the new units are being built. New units are often built as a result of affordable housing initiatives, suburban expansion, and urban renewal, and these development projects generate new units in poor and nonpoor areas alike (cf. Dwyer 2007; Galster et al. 2001; Massey et al. 2013). Of course, this will have different structural implications for neighborhood attainment. For instance, South (et al. 2011a) finds new housing built in nonpoor census tracts increases the probability of moving into nonpoor neighborhoods for whites and blacks. Yet, there is little indication that new housing in general improves neighborhood income status (Pais et al. 2012). On the other hand, large supplies of new housing could create opportunities for more spatial mobility regardless of where the housing is built. New housing creates short-term vacancies in other parts of the city, and this spurs increased opportunities for residential migration. Accordingly, it is difficult to expect in advance whether (H1) higher levels of new housing will increase or decrease neighborhood income status, and more difficult still to anticipate the legacy of new housing on the second generation’s neighborhoods attainments (H1a & H1b). But, there is adequate reason to expect (H2) new housing to the increase intergenerational spatial mobility for black and white families. 15 The level of suburbanization in a metropolitan area might also affect neighborhood attainment and spatial mobility across generations. In metropolitan areas with large suburban areas there could be greater neighborhood heterogeneity, and therefore, more opportunity for upward and/or downward spatial mobility. On the other hand, highly suburbanized metropolitan areas tend to contain numerous independent municipalities, which can use zoning policies and other strategies to prevent the in-migration of poor populations (cf. Yang and Jargowsky 2006). Place stratification perspectives maintain that these barriers to suburban entry are particularly pronounced for minority households (Alba and Logan 1991). Current research suggests, however, that urban renewal and suburban sprawl are linked to significant increases in suburban poverty; as better-off households vacate housing in older inner-ring suburban areas—either to return to gentrifying neighborhoods or to attain greater housing amenities in exurban areas (Knox 2008)—the resulting effect is has been to increase affordable housing in large suburban areas (Howell and Timberlake 2013). These contemporary patterns suggest that large suburban areas may actually lack the type exclusivity found in smaller suburban areas. Therefore, there is relatively weak reason to expect (H1) higher levels of suburbanization to simply increase average neighborhood attainments, as smaller suburban areas are likely more exclusive, particularly for white households. However, given the fairly recent novelty of suburban poverty, it is reasonable to expect the direct and indirect effects of suburbanization to operate differently. More specifically, (H1b) whites should be more affected by current direct levels of suburbanization, possibility in a more negative direction; whereas given the legacy of suburban exclusion of minorities, we should expect (H1a) the indirect effect of suburbanization to be stronger and negative for black families. Lastly, we should expect (H2) large suburban areas to increase intergenerational spatial mobility for both whites and blacks. 16 Data and Methods Following Sharkey (2008), this study estimates intergenerational neighborhood income elasticities using four additional waves of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). The PSID started in 1968 with an initial panel of approximately 4,800 families that were interviewed annually until 1995 and biennially up to the latest round in 2011. The PSID follows the progression of multiple generations over time because new families are added to the panel as children in the original panel split-off to form their own households. With the PSID-Geocode Match File, researchers can merge geographic information (e.g., census-tract and metropolitanlevel census data) to individual PSID records. The PSID is the only multigenerational data source in the U.S. with enough geographic coverage to study the structural determinants of intergenerational spatial mobility.1 Sample Selection and Neighborhood Status: The sample selection and core variable construction follows the same design as Sharkey (2008:945). Two PSID files are created: a parent file (aka first generation), including all PSID respondents that are ever parents (adoptive parents included); and a child file (aka second generation), including all PSID respondents that were ever children of a PSID parent. Pairs of parents and children are then matched using family IDs provided by the PSID. Matched family pairs are included in the sample if they meet the following criteria: (1) the “parent” is observed as the head of household at age 26 or older in at least one year where the “child” was under 18 years old; (2) the “child” is later observed as an adult head of household or a spouse/partner of a head of household at age 26 or older. Data 1 The PSID, and the specific use of the data here and in Sharkey, are not without limitation and complication. Of specific concern here is the geographic representativeness of the PSID sample for estimating MSA-level effects, and the sampling weight adjustments using a multilevel estimator. Sensitivity checks that address these issues are provided below. For further discussion and sensitively checks dealing with general issues of PSID representativeness, attrition bias, and sampling weight adjustments see Sharkey (2008, footnotes 5, 8, 16). The combined information here, and in Sharkey (2008), should minimize (not eliminate) concern about biased estimates and type-one error. The geographic limitations of the data do likely produce higher (i.e., more conservative) typetwo error rates at the MSA-level. 17 constraints limit our sample to only black and white families. This procedure produces 4,633 parent-child pairs with valid geo-identifiers, which is slightly more than Sharkey’s 4,464 family pairs because of the additional four waves of PSID data used here. The key measure of neighborhood status is average neighborhood income. Data for this measure comes from the Neighborhood Change Data Base (NCDB), which provides decennial U.S. Census data from 1970 to 2010 normalized to the census tract boundaries in 2010 (GeoLytics 2013). Linear interpolation and extrapolation is used to estimate average neighborhood income for non-census years (1968, 1971-1979 1981-1989, 1991-1999, 20012009, 2011). Average neighborhood income is converted into real 2000 dollars using the Consumer Price Index. The census tract data are then merged with the parent’s file and the child’s file in long format (i.e., person-year). The next step is to adjust neighborhood income by using four auxiliary regressions, where neighborhood income is regressed on age, age-squared, and family-level fixed effects. That is, one regression model for (1) white first generation; (2) black first generation; (3) white second generation; and (4) black second generation. The predicted values of neighborhood income at age 40 are derived from these regressions including family-fixed effects. These predicted values are then averaged over the duration of the study period for each respondent according to the same criteria above: (a) the parent was older than 26 with children under age 18 and (b) the child was out of the parent’s home and older than 26. These average exposure measures are then logged. Hertz (2005) explains how these adjustments help minimize measurement error and provide equal footing for first and second generation comparisons at age 40. Local Opportunity Structure: The focal independent variables for this study are a series of metropolitan-area characteristics. Metropolitan areas are typically used as geographic 18 delineators of local labor markets. Metropolitan-level data come from the U.S. Census of Population and Housing Summary Files (U.S. Department of Commerce) unless noted otherwise. Crosswalks are used to convert historic MSA codes to current Office of Management and Budget CBSA codes(see https://www.census.gov/population/metro/; and http://www.nber.org/data/cbsamsa-fips-ssa-county-crosswalk.html). The construction of these MSA variables follows the same averaging procedure as the neighborhood income variables: MSA-level values are interpolated and extrapolated for non-census years; these values are then merged via the PSID retro-coded CBSA geo-identifiers to the parent file and child file in long format; then the metropolitan area characteristics are averaged over the duration the respondents met the sample criteria set above. No auxiliary regressions are used. These values are then linked to the match parent-child data file to provide distinct MSA-level exposures for the first generation and the second generation. Metropolitan-area characteristics include: Black-white residential segregation measured using the dissimilarity index (Logan and Stults, Project US2010); the percentage of the population that is non-Hispanic black; the percentage of the population that is foreign-born; the percentage of the civilian labor force that is employed in either finance; insurance or real estate industries; the percentage employed in public sector jobs (i.e., either federal, state, or local government); the percentage in manufacturing industries; and the percentage of the civilian labor force that is employed in the low-wage service sector (i.e., entertainment and recreation services, hotels and lodging places, private household services, and other miscellaneous personal services). MSA-development characteristics include the percentage of new housing units built in the last ten years, and the percentage of the population living outside central cities constitutes the relative size of the suburban population. In addition to these key explanatory variables, this study also controls for MSA median income and population size, both in natural log form. 19 Control Variables: All the statistically significant independent variables predicting intergenerational neighborhood income elasticity in Sharkey’s regression model (Table 6, 2008:956) are selected as control variables at the child-parent level. These variables include the first generation’s family income constructed in the same fashion as neighborhood income above. The race of the first generation’s head of household (1=black; 0=white). The gender of both the first and second generation respondents (1=men; 0=women). The educational attainment of both the first and second generation, which is coded categorically as less than a high school degree; high school degree; some college; college degree or more (less than high school degree is the reference group). Home ownership, measured as the proportion of years the first generation is observed owning their home. And finally, a measure of parental aspiration, a scale that captures how ambitions the respondent is with regard to improving their economic wellbeing. Analytic Approach: This study has four primary empirical objectives. The first objective is to replicate Sharkey’s (2008) previous analysis with more recent waves of PSID data using OLS regression with robust standard errors and with, and without, sampling weights. Construction of the sampling weights follows Sharkey (2008:943, footnote #6). This step simply establishes baseline validity, and arguably improves the reliability of the intergenerational elasticities given the increased amount of data on the second generation. The second objective is to assess the amount of metropolitan-area variability in the intergenerational transmission process. A series of null multilevel regression models provide the estimates of variance that are needed to make these assessments. There are a two null regression models that allow a random intercept for the second generation’s neighborhood income status and a random slope for the intergenerational elasticity (i.e., the effect of the first generation’s neighborhood status attainment on the second generation’s neighborhood status attainment). 20 Version one includes the full sample. Version two includes only those families that remained in the same metropolitan area for the study period and that live in a metropolitan area that had at least ten other PSID families. The more restrictive sample provides a sensitivity check of two data issues. One issue is the potential bias caused by intermetropolitan migration. The second issue involves geographically sparse PSID data coverage across a full range of metropolitan areas (Clarke 2008). In the full sample, the PSID families’ modal metropolitan- area is used as the geoID needed to calculate the metropolitan-level variance components. Relying on a modal geoID will to some degree bias the metropolitan variance estimates because families may have moved to different areas over the course of the study. By restricting the sample to non-movers, we can evaluate the extent of this bias. Restricting the sample of metropolitan areas to only those MSAs with ten or more PSID families provides robustness check against (a) the potentially unduly influence of shrinkage in the multilevel estimator, and against (b) the fact that measures of metropolitan characteristics are less precise in smaller areas (e.g., the dissimilarity index). The restriction to ten or more families means that the analysis only includes the largest metropolitan areas. These same sensitivity checks are implemented on the full cross-level interaction model discussed below. The third objective is to estimate the total, direct, and indirect metropolitan influences on the second generation’s neighborhood attainment. This is accomplished via a 2-1-1 multilevel mediation analysis (Krull and MacKinnon 2001) with one modification. Ordinary the total effect should equal the direct effect plus the indirect effect when doing path analysis [i.e., cT = c + a*b (see Figure 1)]. In this study, the additive combination of direct and indirect effects are not exactly equal to the total effect because MSA exposure is different for first and second 21 generation respondents (although highly correlated).2 The direct effects of the second generation’s MSA exposure reported here reflect current structural constraints on the second generation’s residential choices, which includes whatever structural consistency that persists from the first generation to the second generation (e.g., highly segregated areas tend to remain highly segregated). The mediation estimates are based on three regression models. The first model estimates the total effect (cT) which regresses second generation neighborhood status on first generation MSA measures and all family level control variables. The total effects models omit the first generations neighborhood status and the second generation’s MSA measures. The total effects incorporate the indirect effects that are transmitted via intergenerational elasticity and the direct effects that influence the second generation’s exposure to MSA characteristics. The second model estimates the proxy direct effects (c’) by regressing the second generation’s neighborhood income status on the first generation’s neighborhood income status, family controls, and the first generation’s MSA measures. The proxy direct effect is use to calculate the indirect effect, which is the difference in the first generation MSA effects between model 1 and model 2 (a*b = cT – c’). Model 3 regresses the second generation’s neighborhood status on the first generations neighborhood status, family controls, and the second generation’s MSA measures. The direct effects (c) come from this model. The null hypotheses are whether these effects (cT, a*b, and c) are statistically significant from zero. The standard errors are estimated from a 1000 bootstrap replications. Mediation analyses are done separately for white and black families. The fourth objective seeks to explain why rates of intergenerational spatial mobility vary across metropolitan areas. This analysis relies on a pooled multilevel model with cross-level 2 If we base the analysis only on first generation MSA exposure then the total effect does equal the direct effect plus the indirect effect. This approach, however, would give imprecise estimates of the direct effect we are interested in because it would not fully capture the second generation’s level of MSA exposure. 22 interactions between the intergenerational elasticity and the second generation’s MSA measures. The pooled multilevel model also assesses the black-white difference in MSA-level effects. The cross-level interactions are estimates for whether a metropolitan-area characteristic facilitates or hinders intergenerational spatial mobility. Cross-level interactions also tell us, to a greater or lesser extent, why rates of intergenerational spatial mobility vary across metropolitan areas. The following composite equation is the pooled cross-level interaction model: y 2ij = β 0 + β1 (y1ij ) + β 2 (black ij ) + β3 (y1ij* black ij ) + β 4 (Xij ) + fixed effects, level one β6 (Wj ) + β7 (Wj * black ij ) + β 7 (y1ij*Wj ) + β8 (y1ij *Wj * black ij ) + fixed effects, level two v0j + v1j (y1ij ) + ε ij random effects Formally, y2ij is the average neighborhood income among second generation respondents, y1ij is the average neighborhood income among first generation respondents, blackij is a dummy variable for the race of the PSID family, Xij is a matrix of family-level covariates, Wj is a matrix of second generation MSA-level exposure variables, β0 is the average level of neighborhood income among the second generation (holding all family and MSA-level covariates at their grand means), which varies across metropolitan areas by v0j. β1 is the average intergenerational elasticity which varies across metropolitan areas by v1j. (v0j and v1j are allowed co-vary). εij is the level-one idiosyncratic error. The main effects for this model [β4(Xij), β6(Wj), β7(y1ij*Wj)] are the main effects for white families, and the black interactions captures the racial difference in the effects from whites [β7(Wj*blackij), β8(y1ij*Wj*blackij)] . The focus in on the β7s and β8s in the cross-level interaction models because the main effects by race are provided in the mediation analysis. 23 Results Replication: Table 1 provides the descriptive statistics for white and black PSID families using aggregate sampling weights. This sample is representative of the families created in the post-civil rights era by black and white individuals alive in the United States in 1968. The family-level descriptive statistics are very similar to those reported by Sharkey (2008: Table 1). For example, the mean first generation age-adjusted log neighborhood income is 10.78 for Sharkey and 10.79 here. The mean second generation age-adjusted log neighborhood income is 10.97 for Sharkey and 11.11 here. The slightly higher average reflects the fact that the second generation has had more time to mature financially. The same pattern holds for education where 31 percent of the second generation had college degrees by 2003 compared to 38 percent of the second generation with college degrees by 2011. The descriptive statistics in Table 1 also provide insight into how metropolitan areas have changed between first and second generation respondents. There has been a modest decline in residential segregation exposure between generations going from an average of .69 to .60; a substantial decline in manufacturing employment from 21% to 14%; a 7 percentage point decline in new housing but an offsetting increase in suburbanization between generations. There has also been a 3 percentage point increase in foreign-born population concentration and more than a doubling of employment in the low-wage service sector. These generational differences largely mirror the population trends over the last several decades. [Table 1 about here] Table 2 presents the replication analysis of Sharkey (2008: Table 6). The actual point estimates are very similar between the two studies and the pattern of effects across model specifications is nearly identical. First, the average intergenerational neighborhood elasticity is 24 .609, meaning a one percent change in parent’s neighborhood income status is associated with a .61 percent change in the second generations neighborhood status (slightly less than the Sharkey estimate of .641). Parent’s neighborhood income status exerts a large effect that accounts for 74 percent of neighborhood income variation in the second generation (R2 = .74). The remaining 26 percent variation of the second generation’s neighborhood income status stems from spatial mobility and neighborhood change (and perhaps idiosyncratic error). Model 2 presents the unadjusted racial disparity among second generation households, which is slightly larger here (.411) than the Sharkey estimate (-.369). Comparing these unconditional effects across studies suggests that as more data is collected over time (i.e., as the second generation matures), the amount of intergenerational spatial mobility increases slightly and the racial neighborhood income gap increases slightly. Estimates here suggest the neighborhood income status among black families in the second generation in the post civil-rights era is approximately 33 percent less than that of second generation white families [(e-.411-1)*100 = 33%]. Neighborhood status of the first generation in Model 3 accounts for nearly half (-.411 vs. -.215) of this racial neighborhood income gap among the second generation. [Table 2 about here] Model 4 (with PSID sample weights) and Model 5 (without PSID sample weights) introduce family-level covariates. The PSID sampling weights have little effect on the results and virtually no effect on the substantive conclusions: A substantial intergenerational elasticity and a substantial racial neighborhood income gap remain after controlling for relevant family-level characteristics. The family covariate point-estimates are similar between studies as well, with the exception of parental aspiration being non-significant, and a positive effect for homeownership instead of a negative effect (see Sharkey 2008:957, footnote #19). The regression model without 25 weights tends to produce more efficient standard errors, generally larger family-level point estimates, and correspondingly, a larger R-square (.83 vs. .88). The sensitivity check for PSID weights is important here because the sampling weights as constructed produce nonsensical variance estimates in the multilevel models. For these reasons the multilevel models omit the PSID sampling weights (cf. Lee and Forthofer 2006:21). Metropolitan Heterogeneity: The next empirical objective uses a multilevel estimator to examine the degree of metropolitan-area heterogeneity in the intergenerational neighborhood attainment process. This analysis answers two basic but important questions: (1) How different are rates of intergenerational neighborhood mobility across U.S. metropolitan areas; and (2) Is there more or less intergenerational mobility in richer or poorer metropolitan areas? The multilevel specification for this analysis includes a random intercept capturing the difference across metropolitan-areas in the average neighborhood income attainment of second generation respondents; a random slope capturing the difference in the average effect of the first generation’s neighborhood status on the second generation’s neighborhood status (i.e., intergenerational elasticity); and a covariance between the random intercept and the random slope. This covariance accounts for the relationship between the average level of neighborhood income in an MSA and the strength of the intergenerational elasticity in that MSA. Based on the full sample, the metropolitan-area estimates for the intergenerational neighborhood income elasticity is as low as .449 at the 5th percentile and as high as .758 at the 95th percentile. The correlation between the random intercept and the random slope is -.170. Based on the restricted sample, the corresponding estimates are very comparable: .447 and .749, respectively, and the correlation is -.127 (results not shown). The negative correlation means that metropolitan areas 26 with higher average neighbored income levels experience greater rates of intergenerational neighborhood mobility (i.e., a flatter slope for the intergenerational elasticity).3 To contextualize the varying degree of these intergenerational elasticity estimates, it is revealing to forecast how long of an influence the first generation’s neighborhood income status will have on future generations. Assuming a constant level intergenerational change between generations (e.g., no exogenous shocks)4, and ignoring metropolitan heterogeneity for the moment, the first generation will still exert approximately an 8 percent influence on neighborhood attainment five generations later (.6095 = .08; also see Sharkey 2008:951). Stated differently, among families that began 60 percent (above or below) the mean neighborhood income level, it will be 5 generations before the neighborhood income of the descendents is within 10 percent of the long-run mean. Accounting for metropolitan heterogeneity gives us a much broader perspective of this process. For example, among metropolitan areas with the highest intergenerational elasticity estimates (e.g., New York, NY; Baltimore, MD; Philadelphia, PA; Cleveland, OH; Chicago, IL), the influence may still be felt in 9 generations (e.g., .7589 =.08). Among metropolitan areas with the lowest intergenerational elasticity estimates (e.g., Phoenix, AZ; Jackson MS; Nashville, TN), the first generation’s influence will be felt 3 generations out (e.g., .4493 = .09). The range between 3 to 9 generations of long-term influence clearly highlights the importance of geographic location in understanding rates of intergenerational neighborhood mobility. Multilevel Mediation Analysis: The next step in the analysis is to evaluate the hypotheses involving specific metropolitan area characteristics. Together, Table 3 and Table 4 provide the 3 This negative intercept-slope correlation is not driven by the log transformation as supplemental models without log transformed neighborhood income also produce negative correlations. 4 This is a strong and perhaps unreasonable assumption. The estimates of MSA heterogeneity are for expressing the effect size; not for prediction. The assumption of no exogenous change over nine generations is too strong for us to reasonably use these estimates for prediction. 27 results that are needed to evaluate these hypotheses. A 2-1-1 multilevel mediation analysis evaluates the legacy effects of metropolitan-area characteristics on the neighborhood attainment of the second generation. The results of this analysis are presented in Table 3 and discussed in this section. The effects of racial residential segregation on the intergenerational transmission of neighborhood status are expected to operate differently for white and black families. As expected, the total effect for black families is negative and statistically significant: A unit increase in segregation exposure among the first generation decreases the neighborhood income attainment of the second generation by .3 percent (Table 3). Importantly, this total effect for black families is then almost entirely mediated (87 % mediated = -.271/-.312) once the first generation’s neighborhood income status is controlled. The indirect effect is 7.7 times larger than the direct effect (7.7 = -.271/.035). This key finding suggests that the effects of residential segregation on neighborhood income attainment operates primarily through a transgenerational process that conditions young black children’s experiences in ways that make upward mobility more difficult. For white families, the pattern of effects is different. The total effect is nonsignificant but this is because a small negative indirect effect is offset by a small positive direct effect. There is little theoretical guidance to anticipate these divergent effects.5 [Table 3 about here] According to the housing availability perspective, place stratification theory and the buffering hypothesis, neighborhood attainment is also influenced by the racial and ethnic population concentration of an area. However, the effects from the mediation analysis in Table 3 provide little support for any one perspective. There are no significant effects total, direct, 5 As conjecture, I suspect that highly segregated areas have negative implications of varying degrees for the development of all children. However, as adults, whites may work harder to spatially segregate themselves from blacks in highly segregated areas and this produces a positive direct effect for white families. 28 indirect or otherwise for share of black population in a metropolitan-area (net of other MSA characteristics).6 For foreign-born population concentration, there are positive total and direct effects for blacks and whites, and a positive indirect effect for whites. Higher levels of neighborhood attainment among white families living in established immigrant gateway cities appears to have been channeled in part (via human capital development and/or cultural conditioning) to the second generation through the neighborhood status of the parents. The positive direct effects for whites and blacks are counter-intuitive to the expectations developed from place stratification theory and from the buffering hypothesis. It could be that foreign-born population concentration does facilitate greater racial neighborhood integration, but it occurs not through residential buffering—e.g., decreasing the neighborhood income status of whites while increasing the neighborhood status of blacks—but rather through a residential queuing process where blacks, and even more so for whites, are finding housing and job opportunities in highly settled immigrant areas that translate into higher levels of neighborhood attainment. Whether this queuing process enhances black-white residential contact is yet to be determined. The local structure of economic specialization in several core employment areas impacts neighborhood income attainment in several ways. As expected, high employment concentrations in finance, real estate and insurance are associated with higher levels of neighborhood income attainment, and the effect is positive for both whites and blacks. Interestingly, the FIRE effect operates almost entirely through the effects FIRE has on the previous generation’s neighborhood attainment (i.e., indirectly). It appears that local resources generated in areas of high FIRE employment help white and black families to develop the levels of human, cultural, and social 6 As noted earlier, the main concern with the PSID data for this study is the potential for an inflated type-two error rate. Thus, the effects for black population concentration may not be exactly zero, but its effects are likely not as large as the statistically significant effects observed here. The same interpretation applies to all non-significant findings. 29 capital in children that ultimately translate into high levels of neighborhood income attainment. Counter to expectations, neither public-sector employment nor manufacturing employment have positive effects on neighborhood income attainment. Instead, there is a modest negative direct effect of the public sector for whites, and a negative direct effect of manufacturing also for white families. Employment concentrations in the low-wage service sector do, however, produce the expected negative effects. The negative effects are large and universal for whites and are primarily direct and large for blacks. Urban development and suburbanization are expected to influence neighborhood attainment, but the reasons are more nuanced and complex than other structural conditions. In terms of the total, direct, and indirect effects of new housing on the second generation’s neighborhood attainment, the expectations depend on where exactly the new housing is being built and what kind of housing units are being built. The mediation analysis suggests that new housing primarily has a negative indirect effect for white families. This negative effect for whites is likely reflecting affordable housing initiatives in the 1970s that emphasized multi-unit rental complexes (cf. Massey et al. 2013). Although the pattern of effects for suburbanization behave according to expectations—larger negative effects for blacks—none of the effects are statistically significant. Cross-level Interactions: Table 4 presents the results from the cross-level interaction models estimating the effect of metropolitan-area characteristics on the varying rate of intergenerational neighborhood mobility across MSAs. Plots of the statistically significant crosslevel interactions with 95% confidence intervals are provided. These plots are based on the coefficients from the full models, where all the covariates are held constant at their race specific 30 grand means and where the MSA characteristics vary between the minimum and maximum values in Table 1. [Table 4 about here] The effect of racial residential segregation on intergenerational neighborhood mobility is positive for white families (β = -.219), and the effect is less positive for blacks (β = -.219 + .190 = -.029) but not statistically different from that of whites. Note that a negative effect on the intergenerational elasticity is a positive effect on spatial mobility. The interaction plot illustrates these modest interaction effects: Whites in highly segregated areas have the flattest slope (i.e., the least rigid elasticity), so that whites from relatively poor neighborhoods growing up tend to experience greater neighborhood mobility than other whites in poor neighborhoods and from black families in poor neighborhoods regardless of the level of residential segregation in the area. There is hardly any difference in the rate of intergenerational neighborhood mobility between black families in high versus low segregated areas. The important effect of racial segregation on intergenerational neighborhood mobility appears to be primarily in the residential choices and opportunities of whites, especially whites from poor neighborhoods in highly segregated areas. This pattern of effects is even stronger when based on the restricted PSID sample of nonmovers in large metropolitan areas (Model 2, Table 4). [Figure 2 about here: Segregation] There is a great deal of consistency between the results in Model 1 and Model 2 of Table 4. Where the effect is statistically significant in Model 1, the effect is of a similar magnitude and statistically significant under the more restrictive sample in Model 2. There are three exceptions. There is a larger and statistically significant positive effect of foreign-born population on neighborhood mobility for white families (β = -.287) using the more restrictive sample, and the 31 large difference in effect of manufacturing for black families is not reproduced using the more restrictive sample. Also, the large effects for FIRE employment are not reproduced in the more restricted model. In the case of FIRE employment this makes sense in that FIRE is concentrated among the largest cities and there is perhaps not enough variation among large cities in this type of employment to reproduce the same effect size. However, the patterns of effects are the same in all three instances. [Figure 3 about here: FIRE] Looking at the interaction plot to get more insight into the significance of these interaction effects; the negative effect of FIRE for whites and the positive effect for blacks on intergenerational mobility means that in areas of high FIRE employment it is easier for whites from better-off neighborhoods to maintain their position than it is for blacks from better-off neighborhoods. In fact, the widest neighborhood gap among white and black second generation members is between those from good neighborhoods that live in areas of high FIRE employment. It appears more difficult for upper-middle class black families in these cities to transfer their neighborhood status to their children. There are also significant interaction effects stemming from the low-wage service sector. High levels of employment in the low-wage service sector reduce prospects for intergenerational mobility for white and black families alike. [Figure 4 about here: Low Wage] As expected there are positive effects of new housing and suburbanization on rates of intergenerational neighborhood mobility, but the effects differ by race. New housing clearly effects neighborhood mobility for whites (β = -.517), but the effect is significantly less positive for black families (-.517 + .467 = -.05), and is not statistically different from zero (not shown). The interaction plot suggests that the positive effect of new housing on neighborhood mobility 32 hinders the neighborhood status attainment of whites from better-off backgrounds more than it helps the neighborhood attainment of whites from poor neighborhoods. This finding may reflect recent urban gentrification trends and/or trends toward housing growth in exurban areas with higher levels of rural poverty. A similar pattern emerges for suburbanization but for black families: Suburbanization has a positive effect on intergenerational neighborhood mobility for black families (β = -.024 + -.146 = -.170) which is statistically different from whites and from zero. Like white families, however, there is relatively little difference between black families from poor neighborhoods in high versus low areas of suburbanization; the effect of suburbanization seems to primarily lower the multigenerational prospects of stable neighborhood status attainment among black families from better-off neighborhoods. [Figure 5 about here: New Housing] Finally, a comparison of the null multilevel models with only family level controls to the models that include all metropolitan characteristics finds the proportional reduction of level-two variance is 50 percent for the random intercept and 33 percent of the random slope (not shown). In other words, the metropolitan characteristics included in this study account for about half of all the MSA-level variation in neighborhood income attainment and about a third of the MSAlevel variation in intergenerational neighborhood income mobility. [Figure 6 about here: Suburbanization] Conclusion Intergenerational neighborhood status attainment and mobility are important for general processes of social stratification. Access to opportunities, resources, and knowledge that determine status outcomes largely occur within specific locational contexts, like neighborhoods and local labor markets. Neighborhood location is especially key because it is the site where 33 micro-level social and cultural mechanisms, historical-structural antecedents, and contemporary structural constraints intersect to shape the next generation’s life-chances. Therefore, stratification theories that omit the causes and consequences of intergenerational spatial mobility will fail to fully appreciate the geographic pervasiveness of concentrated affluence and poverty in American society. This study builds on these ideas to further close the conceptual and empirical gap between intergenerational spatial mobility research and other forms of intergenerational mobility research. The academic components that are needed to understand the causes and consequences of intergenerational spatial mobility come from several established areas of research. First, human, social, and cultural capital theories, which often reference peer group affiliation and role model emulation as important forms of local social interaction (Jencks and Mayer 1990), explain why neighborhood environments for children affect skill formation (Sharkey and Elwert 2011) and the development of aspirations, expectations, and preferences (Sampson and Wilson 1995; Vartanian et al. 2007). Second, we know primarily through place stratification theory (Charles 2003; Logan and Molotch 1989) and the housing availability model (South and Crowder 1997) that there are structural constraints placed on many families that hinder their ability to attain housing in residential spaces that would conceivably maximize their children’s long-run prospects. The high degree of importance these perspectives give neighborhood environments, especially for child development, begs the question as to whether the residential constraints of preceding generations affect the status attainments of subsequent generations. This long-run view forces us to think more keenly about the historical aspects of the local opportunity structure, and their legacy effects on future generations. This legacy effects perspective produces novel insights into how racial residential segregation, racial and ethnic diversity, economic specialization, 34 suburban sprawl, and urban development initiatives are capable of affecting intergenerational mobility patterns and status attainments well into the future. Four empirical objectives help to establish the validity of these combined perspectives. First, replication of previous intergenerational elasticity estimates is an important step here for assessing the reliability of the data, measures, and methods. Replication is generally an underappreciated exercise, but this is likely to change, especially as contemporary social science comes to rely on increasingly complex datasets and methodological approaches. Second, it was important to establish the extent of metropolitan-area variation in the intergenerational neighborhood income elasticity as this indicates how relevant local opportunity structures are for intergenerational transmission processes. The variation is quite noteworthy: Some local opportunity structures produce intergenerational elasticities that could resonate up to nine generations, whereas in other areas the effect of parent’s neighborhood status only extends three generations. This clearly highlights the importance of local opportunity structure in understanding rates of intergenerational spatial mobility. Third, a multilevel mediation analysis decomposes the total, direct, and indirect effects of specific metropolitan-area characteristics on the second generation’s neighborhood income attainments. Several important findings that support the legacy effects perspective emerge. Foremost, among black families the effect of racial residential segregation on neighborhood income attainment operates almost entirely through the residential constraints placed on the first generation. This means that the prior generation’s exposure to residential segregation helps explain the difficulties of the current generation. According to the legacy effects perspective, the residential constraints faced by the parent’s likely affected the child’s skill development and general disposition in ways that influence adult status outcomes. Areas with high employment 35 concentrations in better paying sectors of the economy—like finance, real estate, and insurance—provides another example. Black and white families alike in these areas are better able to attain the kinds of neighborhoods that facilitate advantageous human, cultural, and social capital development in children, which in turn improves the status outcomes of the next generation. New housing in an area also indirectly effects the neighborhood attainments of later generations, but in a negative way and only for white families. Without more specific information on the siting of new housing, it is difficult to be certain, but this finding likely reflects the affordable housing initiatives in the 1970s that emphasized multi-unit rental complexes in whiter and wealthier areas. The fourth empirical objective evaluates the effects of the local opportunity structure on varying rates of intergenerational neighborhood income mobility. The ideal opportunity structure should produce high levels of neighborhood income attainment and higher rates of intergenerational spatial mobility. Both absolute levels of neighborhood attainment (which was the primary focus of the mediation analysis) and neighborhood status mobility are essential components of the generational transmission process. A cross-level moderation analysis deals with the latter, and several noteworthy findings emerge: Racial residential segregation increases intergenerational spatial mobility among white families, which primary benefits whites from poor neighborhoods; high level of employment concentration in finance, real estate, and insurance industries increases intergenerational spatial mobility for blacks, but this mobility comes primarily at the expense of black middle-class families having more difficulty maintaining their neighborhood income status over the course of generations in these areas; high concentrations of low-wage service work reduce prospects for intergenerational spatial mobility for white and black families alike; new housing increases spatial mobility for white families, and 36 this benefits white families from poor neighborhoods more than whites from better-off neighborhoods; high levels of suburbanization increases intergenerational spatial mobility among black families, which primarily makes it more difficult for blacks from better-off neighborhoods to maintain their neighborhood income status. Together these focal opportunity structure characteristics account for about a third of the variation in intergenerational spatial mobility that exists across metropolitan areas. Having a multigenerational longitudinal panel for a nationally representative sample with geographic identifiers is invaluable to the study of intergenerational mobility research. However, the data, and this study in particular, is not without limitation. One primary concern is with the potential geographic sparseness of the PSID data and the amount observational clustering within metropolitan areas that is available for analysis. To determine whether this was an issue that would bias point-estimates and/or variance components, the analyses were run on a restricted sample which included only the metropolitan areas that had at least 10 PSID families of which had remained in those areas for the duration of the study period. The results between the full sample and restricted sample are quite similar, especially with regard to the amount variation for the intergenerational elasticity across metropolitan areas. If the amount of observational clustering, the size of the metropolitan area, and/or intermetropolitan migration had a substantial impact then we would expect the unadjusted random slope variance to be substantially different between samples, and it is not. Regardless of the sample used, there is still a possibility that the estimated structural effects are smaller, and the standard errors larger, then would be the case with ample data. As a result, we should be cautious to conclude that any of the non-significant effects are entirely unimportant for the intergenerational transmission process. Instead, it is best to view these non- 37 significant effects as of secondary importance to the effects that are statically significant. The focal structural characteristics in this study are prominent in the residential mobility literature, but the list of focal characteristics is by no means exhaustive. However, given a finite amount of statistical power, especially for the cross-level interaction analysis, future research should only examine additional structural characteristics that have significant potential to break new theoretical ground. This study is a step forward in the area of intergenerational spatial mobility research, but more work is needed. Future research should examine the intergenerational transmission process for alternative neighborhood outcomes. Racial and ethnic neighborhood composition is potentially an important outcome that could shed light on the relative salience of race and ethnicity for intergenerational spatial mobility. It would be interesting to compare the strength intergenerational elasticities for neighborhood income alongside neighborhood racial composition. Future research could also study the reciprocal linkage between neighborhood outcomes and other stratification outcomes over the course of generations. This would be useful for examining the explanatory power of specific mechanisms that ultimately support the generational persistence of concentrated affluence and poverty. Finally, when sufficient multigenerational data becomes available it will be interesting to see how rates of intergenerational spatial mobility actually effect the residential expectations and aspirations of future generations. This could be a key factor in understanding why the “mental maps” of large cities, and perhaps specific neighborhood reputations, persist despite significant physical and social change. 38 References: Alba, Richard D., and John R. Logan. 1991. “Variations on Two Themes: Racial and Ethnic Patterns in the Attainment of Suburban Residence.” Demography 28(3):431–53. Aaronson, Daniel, and Bhashkar Mazumder. 2008. “Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the United States, 1940 to 2000.” Journal of Human Resources 43(1):139–72. Blau, Peter Michael, and Otis Dudley Duncan. 1967. The American Occupational Structure. New York:NY:Free Press. Borjas, George J. 1995. “Ethnicity, Neighborhoods, and Human-Capital Externalities.” The American Economic Review 85(3):365–90. Bruch, Elizabeth E., and Robert D. Mare. 2006. “Neighborhood Choice and Neighborhood Change.” American Journal of Sociology 112(3):667–709. Charles, Camille Zubrinsky. 2000. “Neighborhood Racial-Composition Preferences: Evidence from a Multiethnic Metropolis.” Social Problems 47(3):379–407. Charles, Camille Zubrinsky. 2003. “The Dynamics of Racial Residential Segregation.” Annual Review of Sociology 29:167-207. Charles, Camille Zubrinsky. 2006. Won’t You Be My Neighbor? Race, Class, and Residence in Los Angeles. New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation. Clarke, Philippa. 2008. “When Can Group Level Clustering Be Ignored? Multilevel Models versus Single-Level Models with Sparse Data.” Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 62(8):752–58. Crowder, Kyle, Jeremy Pais, Scott J. South. 2012. “Neighborhood Diversity, Metropolitan Constraints, and Household Migration.” American Sociological Review 77(3):325-353. Crowder, Kyle, Matthew Hall, and Stewart E. Tolnay. 2011. “Neighborhood Immigration and Native Out-Migration.” American Sociological Review 76(1):25–47. Diez-Roux, Ana. 2001. “Investigating Neighborhood and Area Effects on Health.” American Journal of Public Health 97:344–52. Dwyer, Rachel E. 2007. “Expanding Homes and Increasing Inequalities: US Housing Development and the Residential Segregation of the Affluent.” Social Problems 54:23-46. Ellen, Ingrid Gould, and Margery Austin Turner. 1997. “Does Neighborhood Matter? Assessing Recent Evidence.” Housing Policy Debate 8:833–66. 39 Farley, Reynolds, and William H. Frey. 1994. "Changes in the Segregation of Whites from Blacks During the 1980s: Small Steps Toward a More Integrated Society." American Sociological Review 59:23-45. Fischer, Mary J., and Marta Tienda. 2006. “Redrawing Spatial Color Lines: Hispanic Metropolitan Dispersion, Segregation and Economic Opportunity.” Pp. 100-137 in Marta Tienda and Faith Mitchell (Eds.), Hispanics and the Future of America. Washington, DC: National Academies Press Frey, William H., and Reynolds Farley. 1996. “Latino, Asian, and Black Segregation in U.S. Metropolitan Areas: Are Multiethnic Metros Different.” Demography 33(1):35–50. Galster, George C. 1991. “Housing Discrimination and Urban Poverty of African-Americans.” Journal of Housing Research 2:87-122. Galster, G. et al. 2001. “Wrestling Sprawl to the Ground: Defining and Measuring an Elusive Concept.” Housing Policy Debate 12(4):681–718. Graham, Bryan and Patrick Sharkey. 2013. “Mobility and the Metropolis: How Communities Factor Into Economic Mobility." Economic Mobility Project. Washington D.C.: The Pew Charitable Trusts. Hedman, Lina. 2013. “Moving Near Family? The Influence of Extended Family on Neighbourhood Choice in an Intra-Urban Context.” Population Space and Place 19(1):32–45. Hertz, Tom. 2005. “Rags, Riches, and Race: The Intergenerational Economic Mobility of Black and White Families in the United States.” Pp. 165–91 in Unequal Chances: Family Background and Economic Success, edited by Samuel Bowles, Herbert Gintis, and Melissa Osborne Groves. New York,NY: Russell Sage. Howell, Aaron J., and Jeffrey M. Timberlake. 2014. “Racial and Ethnic Trends in the Suburbanization of Poverty in U.s. Metropolitan Areas, 1980–2010.” Journal of Urban Affairs 36(1):79–98. Jargowsky, Paul A. 1996. “Take the Money and Run: Economic Segregation in U.S. Metropolitan Areas.” American Sociological Review 61(6):984-998. Jencks, Christopher, and Susan E. Mayer. 1990. “The Social Consequences of Growing Up in a Poor Neighborhood.” Pp. 111-186 in Laurence E. Lynn and Michael G.H. McGeary. Inner-City Poverty in the United States. Washington D.C.:National Academy Press. Knox, Professor Paul L. 2008. Metroburbia, USA. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press. Krivo, Lauren J., Ruth D. Peterson, and Danielle C. Kuhl. 2009. “Segregation, Racial Structure, and Neighborhood Crime.” American Journal of Sociology 114:17651802. 40 Krull, Jennifer L., and David P. MacKinnon. 2001. “Multilevel Modeling of Individual and Group Level Mediated Effects.” Multivariate Behavioral Research 36(2):249–77. Krysan, Maria and Michael Bader 2007. “Perceiving the Metropolis: Seeing the City Through a Prism of Race.” Social Forces 86(2):699–733. Landale, Nancy S., and Avery M. Guest. 1985. “Constraints, Satisfaction and Residential Mobility: Speare's Model Reconsidered.” Demography 22:199-222. Lee, Eun Sul, and Ronald N. Forthofer. 2006. Analyzing Complex Survey Data. Sage. Logan, John and Harvey L. Molotch. 1987. Urban Fortunes: A Political Economy of Place. Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press. Logan, John R., Brian J. Stults, and Reynolds Farley. 2004. “Segregation of Minorities in the Metropolis: Two Decades of Change.” Demography 41:1-22. Logan, John R., and Charles Zhang. 2010. “Global Neighborhoods: New Pathways to Diversity and Separation.” American Journal of Sociology 115:1069-1109. Massey, Douglas S., and Nancy A. Denton. 1993. American Apartheid: Segregation and the Making of the Underclass. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Massey, Douglas S., Len Albright, Rebecca Casciano, Elizabeth Derickson, and David N. Kinsey. 2013. Climbing Mount Laurel: The Struggle for Affordable Housing and Social Mobility in an American Suburb. Princeton University Press. McDonald, Katrina Bell, and Bedelia Nicola Richards. 2008. “Downward Residential Mobility in Structural-Cultural Context: The Case of Disadvantaged Black Mothers.” Black Women, Gender & Families 2(1):25–53. Park, Robert E., Ernest W. Burgess, and Roderick Duncan McKenzie. 1925. The City. Chicago, IL:University of Chicago Press. Pais, Jeremy, Kyle Crowder, and Scott J. South. 2012. “Metropolitan Heterogeneity and Minority Neighborhood Attainment: Spatial Assimilation or Place Stratification?” Social Problems 59(2):258-281. Pickett, Kate E., and Michelle Pearl. 2001. “Multilevel Analyses of Neighborhood Socioeconomic Context and Health Outcomes: A Critical Review.” Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 55:111–22. Quillian, Lincoln, and Devah Pager. 2001. “Black Neighbors, Higher Crime? The Role of Racial Stereotypes in Evaluations of Neighborhood Crime.” American Journal of Sociology 107(3):717–67. 41 Robert, Stephanie A. 1999. “Socioeconomic position and health: The independent contribution of community context.” Annual Review of Sociology, 25, 489-516. Sampson, R. J. & Wilson, W. J. 1995. “Toward a Theory of Race, Crime, and Urban Inequality.” Pp. 37-56 in Crime and Inequality, edited J. Hagan & R. D. Peterson. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Sampson, Robert. J., Raudenbush, S. & Earls, F. 1997. “Neighborhood and Violent Crime: A Multilevel Study of Collective Efficacy.” Science 277:918–924. Sampson, Robert J., Jeffrey D. Morenoff, and Thomas Gannon-Rowley. 2002. “Assessing ‘Neighborhood Effects’: Social Processes and New Directions in Research.” Annual Review of Sociology 28:443–78. Sassen, Saskia. 2006. Cities in a World Economy. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press. Schelling, Thomas. 1971. “Dynamic Models of Segregation.” Journal of Mathematical Sociology 1:143–86. Sharkey, P. 2008. “The Intergenerational Transmission of Context.” American Journal of Sociology 113:931–69. Sharkey, Patrick, and F. Elwert. 2011. “The Legacy of Disadvantage: Multigenerational Neighborhood Effects on Cognitive Ability.” American Journal of Sociology 116(6):1934–81. Small, M. L, and K. Newman. 2001. “Urban poverty after The Truly Disadvantaged: The Rediscovery of the Family, the Neighborhood, and Culture.” Annual Review of Sociology 27:23– 45. Solon, Gary. 1992. “Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States." American Economic Review 82 (3): 393-408. South, Scott J., and Kyle D. Crowder. 1997. “Escaping Distressed Neighborhoods: Individual, Community, and Metropolitan Influences.” American Journal of Sociology 102:1040-84. South, Scott J., Jeremy Pais, and Kyle Crowder. 2011a. “Metropolitan Influences on Migration into Poor and Nonpoor Neighborhoods.” Social Science Research 40(3):950–64. South, Scott J., Kyle Crowder, and Jeremy Pais. 2011b. “Metropolitan Structure and Neighborhood Attainment: Exploring Intermetropolitan Variation in Racial Residential Segregation.” Demography 48(4):1263-1292 Speare, Alden Jr., Sidney Goldstein, and William H. Frey. 1975. Residential Mobility, Migration, and Metropolitan Change. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. 42 Vartanian, Thomas P., Page Walker Buck, and Philip Gleason. 2007. “Intergenerational Neighborhood-Type Mobility: Examining Differences between Blacks and Whites.” Housing Studies 22:833-856. Venkatesh, Sudhir Alladi. 2006. Off the Books: The Underground Economy of the Urban Poor. Harvard University Press. Waldinger, Roger D. 1996. Still the Promised City?: African-Americans and New Immigrants in Postindustrial New York. Boston, MA: Harvard University Press. Wilson, Alan B. 1959. “Residential Segregation of Social Classes and Aspirations of High School Boys.” American Sociological Review 24(6):836–45. Wilson, William Julius, and Richard P. Taub. 2007. There Goes the Neighborhood: Racial, Ethnic, and Class Tensions in Four Chicago Neighborhoods and Their Meaning for America. New York, NY:Vintage Books. Wilson, William Julius. 2010. “Why Both Social Structure and Culture Matter in a Holistic Analysis of Inner-City Poverty.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 629:200–219. Yang, Rebecca, and Paul A. Jargowsky. 2006. “ Suburban Development and Economic Segregation in the 1990s.” Journal of Urban Affairs 28(3):253–73. 43 Figure 1: A Conceptual Model of the Intergenerational Spatial Mobility Process involving key Local Opportunity Structure Pathways and Effects ______________________________________________________________________________ First Gen. Neighborhood Status (a) (b) (d) Local Opp. Structure First Gen. (cT) Local Opp. Structure Second Gen. (c) Second Gen. Neighborhood Status Key Effects H0: a = intergenerational elasticity (null hypothesis: no different across local labor markets) H1: cT = total structural effect of first gen. opportunity structure on second gen. neighborhood attainment [i.e., not conditional on first gen. neighborhood status (a) or second gen. opportunity structure (c)] H1a: a*b = indirect structural [i.e., legacy] effect on second gen. neighborhood attainment H1b: c = direct structural effect on second gen. neighborhood attainment H2: d = moderating structural effect on the intergenerational elasticity ______________________________________________________________________________ 44 10.5 11 11.5 Figure 2: Metropolitan Area Black-White Residential Segregation 10.5 11 First Gen. Ave. Neighborhood Income (ln) Low Seg. White High Seg. White 11.5 Low Seg. Black High Seg. Black 10.5 11 11.5 12 Figure 3: Metropolitan Area Employment in Finance, Real Estate, and Insurance 10.5 11 First Gen. Ave. Neighborhood Income (ln) Low % FIRE, White High % FIRE, White 11.5 Low % FIRE, Black High % FIRE, Black 45 10.5 11 11.5 12 Figure 4: Metropolitan Area Employment in the Low Wage Service Sector 10.5 11 First Gen. Ave. Neighborhood Income (ln) Low % Low Serv., White High % Low Serv., White 11.5 Low % Low Serv., Black High % Low Serv., Black 10.5 11 11.5 Figure 5: Metropolitan Area Percent New Housing 10.5 11 First Gen. Ave. Neighborhood Income (ln) Low New Housing, White High New Housing, White 11.5 Low New Housing, Black High New Housing, Black 46 10.5 11 11.5 Figure 6: Metropolitan Area Percent Suburban Population 10.5 11 First Gen. Ave. Neighborhood Income (ln) Low Suburb, White High Suburb, White 11.5 Low Suburb, Black High Suburb, Black 47 Table 1: Descriptive Statistics for a Study of Intergenerational Spatial Mobility: Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 1968-2011 (n = 4633 parent-child pairs) First Generation Characteristics Mean S.D. Neighborhood income (ln) Individual Controls Black family (1=yes; 0=no) Family income (ln) Male head of household Education Less than high school (ref.) High school Some college College degree Home ownership (proportion of years owned) Parental aspirations Metropolitan Area Variables Black-white segregation (dissimilarity index) % Black pop. % Foreign-born pop. % FIRE employment % Public sector employment % Manufacturing % Low wage service % New housing (last ten years) % Suburban pop. Population size (ln) Median income (ln) 10.79 .39 .16 10.79 .83 .36 .66 .37 .16 .32 .22 .30 .33 .47 .41 .46 .73 5.25 .39 1.73 .69 .14 .07 .06 .16 .21 .05 .23 .56 13.96 9.74 .14 .11 .06 .03 .05 .07 .04 .11 .19 1.29 .84 Second Generation Characteristics Mean S.D. 11.11 Range Min Max .27 8.57 12.26 .50 .50 .00 6.80 .00 1.00 12.84 1.00 .05 .28 .29 .38 .25 .45 .45 .49 .00 .00 .00 .00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 .00 1.00 1.00 9.00 .14 .00 .01 .02 .02 .06 .02 .04 .00 10.92 9.63 .88 .56 .48 .20 .41 .36 .33 .56 .90 16.80 11.60 .60 .15 .10 .07 .13 .14 .11 .16 .60 14.24 10.84 .14 .11 .08 .02 .05 .04 .03 .08 .18 1.25 .27 48 Table 2, Replication of Sharkey (2008, Table 6): A Decomposition of Neighborhood Income Elasticity using the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 1968-2011 (robust standard errors) Dependent Variable: Second Generation Neighborhood Income Model 5 Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 (unweighted) β/(se) β/(se) β/(se) β/(se) β/(se) First Gen. Characteristics Neighborhood income (ln) .609 *** .540 *** .481 *** .472 *** (.013) (.013) (.014) (.011) Black family (1=yes; 0=no) -.411 *** -.215 *** -.198 *** -.193 *** (.010) (.007) (.007) (.005) Family income (ln) .014 * .015 *** (.005) (.003) Male head of household .009 .019 *** (.009) (.005) a High school degree .011 .012 *** (.006) (.004) Some collegea .024 *** .027 *** (.007) (.005) a College degree .051 *** .054 *** (.008) (.006) Home ownership (proportion of years owned) .006 .017 *** (.008) (.005) Parental aspirations -.002 .000 (.001) (.001) Second Gen. Characteristics Male head of household .006 .007 * (.004) (.003) a High school degree .031 ** .022 ** (.010) (.006) Some collegea .047 *** .036 *** (.011) (.006) a College degree .082 *** .062 *** (.011) (.007) Intercept 4.535 *** 11.170 *** 5.312 *** 5.716 *** 5.773 *** (.142) (.005) (.137) (.143) (.110) R2 .74 .30 N child-parent pairs 4633 4633 * p < .05; ** p < .01; *** p < .001 a. Reference group are those without high school degrees .81 4633 .83 4633 .88 4633 49 Table 3: A 2-1-1 Multilevel Mediation Analysis providing the Total, Direct and Indirect Effects of Metropolitan-level Characteristics on the Intergenerational Neighborhood Attainment Process by Race: Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 1968-2011 Metropolitan-Area Characteristics Black-White segregation Effects for Blacks Effects for Whites % Black population Effects for Blacks Effects for Whites % Foreign-born population Effects for Blacks Effects for Whites % FIRE employment Effects for Blacks Effects for Whites % Public sector employment Effects for Blacks Effects for Whites % Manufacturing employment Effects for Blacks Effects for Whites % Low-wage service employment Effects for Blacks Effects for Whites % New housing (last ten years) Effects for Blacks Effects for Whites % Suburban population Effects for Blacks Effects for Whites Total Effect -.312 *** -.042 Indirect Effect -.271 *** -.084 ** Direct Effect -.035 .083 * .027 .051 .029 .040 -.004 -.026 .229 * .307 *** .163 .230 *** .571 ** .543 ** .418 ** .392 ** -.064 -.297 .230 -.036 .147 .098 .031 -.083 ** .054 -.012 -.026 .017 .038 -.294 ** .018 -.601 *** -.135 -.384 *** -.383 * -.571 *** -.028 -.229 *** -.047 -.169 *** -.064 -.028 -.040 .018 -.046 .006 -.022 -.002 .154 ** .191 ** * p < .05; ** p < .01; *** p < .001: Two-tail probabilities based on a 1000 bootstrap replications. Note: All models control for family-level covariates. The total and indirect effects are based on the first generation’s MSA exposure. The direct effects are based on the second generation’s exposure and thus the direct and the indirect do not sum to the total effect (see page 11 for more information). 50 Table 4: Cross-Level Interactions predicting the Effects of Metropolitan-Level Characteristics on the Intergenerational Neighborhood Income Elasticities for White and Black Families from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 1968-2011a Model 2: Model 1: Non-mover families Full sample in large MSAsb BlackBlackEffects for White dif. Effects for White dif. Whites in Effects Whites in Effects β/(se) β/(se) β/(se) β/(se) First Gen. Neighborhood Income (ln) .438 *** .060 *** .453 *** .045 ** (.011) (.013) (.011) (.016) Cross-Level Interactions w/ First Gen. Neighborhood Income (ln) Black-white segregation -.219 * .190 -.355 * .096 (.108) (.181) (.142) (.224) % Black pop. .028 -.228 -.109 -.018 (.088) (.124) (.097) (.148) % Foreign-born pop. -.092 -.033 -.287 * -.048 (.128) (.153) (.136) (.174) % FIRE employment 1.654 ** -2.702 ** .319 -1.359 (.623) (.944) (.767) (1.119) % Public sector employment .056 .027 .524 .141 (.255) (.401) (.360) (.493) % Manufacturing .214 -.928 * .191 -.335 (.226) (.403) (.304) (.483) % Low wage service 1.486 *** -.161 1.765 *** .408 (.341) (.705) (.440) (.849) % New housing (last ten years) -.517 *** .467 * -.668 *** .510 * (.118) (.208) (.140) (.246) % Suburban pop. -.024 -.146 * -.020 -.201 * (.051) (.072) (.058) (.082) Population size (ln) .015 -.005 .073 *** -.032 (.012) (.018) (.016) (.024) Median income (ln) .037 .002 -.069 .047 (.038) (.062) (.044) (.074) Intercept 11.040 *** -.188 *** 11.034 *** -.183 *** (.004) (.005) (.004) (.006) Variance Components Level-one residual (s.d.) .092 .090 Level-two random intercept (s.d.) .021 .016 Level-two random slope (s.d.) .070 .048 Level-two correlation (int. slope) -.638 -.582 51 N level-one (child-parent pairs) N level-two (second gen. MSA) 4633 260 3247 78 * p < .05; ** p < .01; *** p < .001 a. The models also control for all family-level characteristics in Table 2. b. The sample is restricted to only those families that remained in the same MSA for the duration of the study period and lived in a MSA that had a minimum of 10 PSID families. 52