Impact of trade reforms on labour`s share of firm revenues. July 25

advertisement
Ideas for India
http://www.ideasforindia.in/Article.aspx?article_id=322
Impact of trade reforms on labour’s share of firm revenues
Posted On: 25 Jul 2014
Reshad N. Ahsan
University of Melbourne
rahsan@unimelb.edu.au
Devashish Mitra
Syracuse University
dmitra@maxwell.syr.edu
The decline in labour’s share of national income in recent decades – a potential cause of rising inequality
– has coincided with an increase in world trade. This column analyses the impact of trade reforms in India
on labour’s share of total revenue at the firm level. It finds that the share of labour has been rising with
reforms for small, labour-intensive firms.
In recent years the perceived stability of labour’s share in national income has been challenged. For
example, International Labour Organization (ILO) (2011) shows that, since the early 1990’s, the labour
share of national income has declined in roughly three-quarters of the 69 countries that they studied. This
decline has been especially pronounced in developing countries. This is strongly supported by the recent
work of Karabarbounis and Neiman (2013) who find that the labour share of corporate value added1 has
declined for 38 out of the 56 countries that they studied. This declining labour share of national income is a
potential cause of the rising inequality in recent years (Atkinson 2009).
The decline in the labour’s share of national income in recent decades has also coincided with an increase
in world trade. This raises the possibility that international trade is one of the causes of this declining labour
share. Despite this, the focus of the trade and inequality literature in recent years has been on the rising
skilled-unskilled wage gap. By paying scant attention to labour’s declining share of income, this literature
provides us with an incomplete picture of the relationship between trade and inequality. We fill this
important gap in the literature by examining the impact of India’s 1991 trade reforms on labour’s share of
firm revenue among a sample of Indian firms (Ahsan and Mitra 2014). As these reforms were enacted at
the urging of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and came as a surprise to many within the country, it
provides us with an external variation in tariffs that allows us to identify the causal effect of trade
liberalisation on labour’s share of firm revenue.
A key contribution of our work is that we identify the presence of significant variation across firms in the
relationship between trade and labour’s share of firm revenue (Figure 1).
Figure 1. Changes in share of wages in total revenue in India, 1989-2004
Note: Large firms are firms with sales above the 67th percentile2 of the sample sales distribution. Small
firms are firms below the 33rd percentile of the sample sales distribution.
As Figure 1 illustrates, the trend in the average share of wages in total revenue for all firms masks a great
deal of variation across firms of different sizes. For example, the top line in the graph suggests that the
share of wages in total revenue increased rapidly between the initial point and the end point of our sample
period (1989-2004) among smaller firms (that are also found to be the relatively labour-intensive firms) in
the sample. In contrast, the bottom line indicates that the share of wages in total revenue declined among
the larger firms3. Furthermore, we see that, at least since the mid-1990s, the gap between labour shares of
the small firms and the large firms has consistently grown over time. Also, the difference between the
average labour share in small firms and the overall average labour share has been growing since the mid1990s, while the difference between average labour share in large firms and the overall average labour
share has been decreasing. Thus, the behaviour of smaller, more labour-intensive firms appears to be
drastically different than that of larger, less labour-intensive firms.
The channels at work: Price-cost mark-ups, labour’s bargaining power and their interactions
To explain this variation in the data, we develop a theoretical model of labour union-firm bargaining with
imperfect competition in the goods market4. Workers get paid for the increase in revenue due to an
additional worker employed (called the marginal revenue product of labour) as well as a share in the firm’s
rents depending on the union’s bargaining power 5. Our model suggests that there are two competing effects
of trade on labour’s share of firm revenue. First, the increased competition due to trade reforms (because
the firm now has to compete with exporters from other countries in addition to domestic firms) lowers the
gap between the good’s price and marginal cost and, in turn, the gap between the value of the marginal
product of labour and the marginal revenue product of labour 6. All else equal, this will lead to an increase
in labour’s share of firm revenue. On the other hand, the lower price-marginal cost mark-up due to more
liberalised trade also reduces the rents (as a share of firm revenue) that are available for bargaining between
the firm and the labour union. All else equal, this second effect will lower labour’s share of firm revenue.
Our model suggests that the first effect (lower mark-ups leading to an increase in labour’s share) is more
likely to dominate for a labour-intensive firm. This is because, other things remaining equal, workers in a
labour-intensive firm receive a higher fraction of their wages through their marginal revenue product
relative to their share in firms’ rents7. On the other hand, for less labour-intensive firms (which are larger),
our model predicts that trade liberalisation will lower labour’s share of total revenue. Further, following
Rodrik (1997), we assume that trade lowers the bargaining power of workers (by making them more
replaceable)8. All else equal, this effect will decrease labour’s share of firm revenue for all firms.
Tariffs, labour shares, labour intensity and firm size
To test our model’s predictions, we use a panel dataset of publicly-traded Indian firms that covers the
period 1989-2004. This data is made available by the Centre for Monitoring the Indian Economy (CMIE).
Together, the firms in the sample represent 60-70% of output in the organised industrial sector and 75% of
all corporate taxes paid in India. Note that informal sector firms, which are much smaller in size, are not
covered in this database. Finally, our data on output tariffs (tariffs on imports of products competing with
the final output of domestic firms), covering the period 1988-2003, are from the Asian Development Bank
(ADB).
Our analysis involves examining whether changes in industry-level tariffs, due to India’s externally
imposed trade liberalisation of 1991, had varied effects on firms depending on their labour intensities. We
use a couple of alternative measures of labour intensity and control for other plausible channels of action as
well as possible reverse causation from labour shares to tariffs, as explained in detail in Ahsan and Mitra
(2014).
Our results indicate that trade liberalisation raised labour’s share of revenue for firms that are sufficiently
labour intensive (about 34.6% of the firms in our sample). When we use firm size indicators as our proxy
for labour intensity, we find that trade liberalisation led to an increase in the share of wages in total revenue
for small firms. For such firms, on average, a 1% fall in import tariff leads to a 0.05% increase in wage
share in total firm revenue.
The results also suggest that trade liberalisation led to a decrease in the share of wages for large firms. In
this case, a 1% fall in import tariff leads to a 0.09% decrease in the wage share. In other words, the wageshare increasing effect of lower mark-ups dominates for small firms while the combined impact through the
bargaining power and the mark-up channels leads to a decline in the share of wages in total revenue for
large firms.
Lastly, we examine the relationship between trade liberalisation and industry-level estimates of workers’
bargaining power, which is a measure of the fraction of a firm’s rents going to workers. Our results indicate
that, on average, industries that experienced greater decreases in output tariffs also experienced greater
decreases in the bargaining power of workers. This result clearly shows that for the firms that experienced
an increase in labour’s share of firm revenue, it was driven by the impact of the reduced mark-up on the
marginal revenue product of labour.
Conclusions
While our results underscore the need for social protection, the negative impact of trade on bargaining
power, by reducing effective wage costs as well as hiring and firing costs for employers, could increase
employment and reduce unemployment. In addition, by weakening labour unions (that often can make it
difficult for employers to pay wages that are non-uniform across workers) this reduction in bargaining
power could shift incentives such that greater effort receives bigger rewards. This can be productivity
enhancing and can ultimately lead to an increase in wages. Furthermore, a decline in the bargaining power
of labour can unleash political-economy forces that can potentially bring about reforms in labour
regulations, that make it easier for employers to hire and fire workers and reassign them from one task to
another as and when required. There is, by now, a large literature showing that restrictive labour regulations
have held back the performance of India’s manufacturing sector. This is especially the case in labourintensive industries, which has prevented a relatively labour-abundant country such as India from taking
advantage of its labour abundance-driven comparative advantage.
Finally, in the context of India’s rapid growth after trade liberalisation, a declining share of an expanding
pie may still mean a growth in the absolute size of the slice going to workers. However it is important to
reiterate here that in the relatively smaller, labour-intensive firms the share of labour has actually been
rising with trade reforms.
Notes:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
Corporate gross value added equals the sum of compensation paid to workers, taxes net of
subsidies on production, and everything that constitutes payments to capital (Karabarbounis and
Neiman 2013).
This means that large firms are those that have sales greater than those of 67% of firms in our
sample.
It is important to note that this finding also holds when we examine changes in the share of wages
in value added instead.
Each firm is assumed to have some monopoly power in the goods market.
Rents refer to the firm’s revenue minus the value of inputs, evaluated at the wage workers would
have received outside the firm. The bargaining power equals the share of workers in these rents.
Marginal Revenue (MR) of a firm refers to the additional revenue generated by the sale of an
additional unit of output produced. Marginal cost (MC) refers to the additional cost incurred due
to the production of an additional unit of output. Profit is maximised when MR = MC. Price at
which a unit of output is sold is greater than MC (and hence, MR). Marginal Revenue Product
(MRP) equals MR multiplied by marginal product (increase in output due to an additional
worker). This equals the wage that the worker is paid (net of share in rents). On the other hand, the
Value of Marginal Product (VMP) (loosely indicative of worker productivity) equals price
multiplied by marginal product. Since price is greater than MR, VMP is greater than MRP.
However, the gap between the two shrinks when the price-MC gap shrinks due to increased
competition from imported goods.
This is because in a labour-intensive firm, the contribution of labour, relative to other inputs, to
production is higher (compared to other firms), as a result of which the marginal product has a
relatively bigger role to play in wage determination.
This happens since trade makes possible the imports of goods that either substitute for the output
produced by domestic labour, or that act as inputs that directly substitute for labour in the
production process.
Further Reading



Ahsan, Reshad N and Devashish Mitra (2014), “Trade Liberalization and Labor’s Slice of the Pie:
Evidence from Indian Firms”, Journal of Development Economics 108, 1-16.
Atkinson, Anthony (2009), “Factor shares: the principal problem of political economy?”, Oxford
Review of Economic Policy 25(1): 3-16.
Goldberg, Pinelopi and Nina Pavcnik (2005) “Trade, Wages, and the Political Economy of Trade
Protection: Evidence from the Colombian Trade Reforms”, Journal of International Economics
66(1): 75-105.



International Labour Organization (ILO) (2011), ‘World of Work Report 2011: Making Markets
Work for Jobs’, International Labour Office, Geneva, Switzerland.
Karabarbounis, L and B Neiman (2013), ’The Global Decline of the Labor Share’, NBER Working
Paper 19136.
Rodrik, Dani (1997), ‘Has Globalization Gone Too Far?’, Institute for International Economics,
Washington, DC.
- See more at: http://www.ideasforindia.in/Article.aspx?article_id=322#sthash.jLXO0SZg.dpuf
Download