The Mutual-Aid Co-operatives and the Animal Products Trade in Mongolia, 1913-1928 CHRISTOPHER P. ATWOOD Central Eurasian Studies, Indiana University Goodbody Hall 157 1011 East 3rd St. Bloomington, IN 47405-7005 Email: catwood@indiana.edu ABSTRACT From the first decade of Mongolian independence after 1911, nationalist publicists and officials denounced the dominance of foreign merchants and capital in the Mongolian economy. Officials and historians declared co-operatives to be the road for simultaneous improving the peoples’ living standards and also strengthening national independence. Yet examination of statistics and the vigorous debates at the early party congresses and Great Khural meetings from 1924 to 1927 shows that the co-operatives were neither effective in their mandate nor popular with the herders they were intended to help. From the beginning, the co-operatives appear to have answered the needs of the new state more than those of the herding populace. The little word called Co-operative Put on a Mongol hat And in the year 1921 Came here for the first time The Chinese partners wiped their glasses Over and over, and didn’t worry at all Laughing aloud, saying shang this and pang that to each other. When the Mongolian People’s Mutual-Aid Co-operative’s Tiny little store For the first time at the Western Market Opened its doors for business The masses showed tremendous interest And when they swarmed in to look The goods for sale were very few But the prices were cheap. One thought, that this was ours Struck the people One aim, that we will win Gripped the Co-operative.1 Buyannemekhü, in Arad-un ündüsüten-ü erke. 77, 1936, for the fifteenth anniversary of the first co-operative store. 1 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural 118: 355-6. Accounts of the influence of trade on the Mongolian economy have generally stressed the dominant role of Chinese commercial and money-lending firms on the Mongolian plateau. With cheap capital and aided by predatory lending practices, Chinese firms like Dashengkui were, by 1796, able to secure a strong position in the Mongolian economy and later extended their activities and came to own a significant percentage of the total Mongolian livestock herd.2 This domination continued into the twentieth century, even after the Mongolian proclamation of independence in 1911 and the 1921 Revolution.3 Chinese domination of the Mongolian economy has been held responsible for many distinctive characteristics of Mongolia’s twentieth century history. It is a generally held view that since the country's middle class was an ethnically foreign and exploitative merchant-class, Mongols came to see trade and commerce as a morally suspect activity. The Mongols loss of control of their own economy gave credence to the socialist program of ‘by-passing capitalism’, using the power of the state to nationalise the economy and thus return it to Mongolian hands. By this argument then, the Chinese domination of the Mongolian economy played a vital role in making Communism a plausible choice for Mongolia. According to this view, from the Manchu-Chinese conquest until Mongolia was firmly folded into the autarchic economy of the Soviet block, Chinese merchants dominated an isolated Mongolian economy that had little or no direct access to the world capitalist economy. Thus, the free market transition that began in 1990 would represent the first time in recent centuries that Mongolia has been able to bypass Chinese domination and deal directly with the world economy. This traditional view, while generally valid for the nineteenth century, does not accurately describe the position of trade in Mongolia in the early decades of the twentieth century. Between 1911 and 1929, British, German and American firms rapidly rose to compete with Chinese firms for the animal-products export market from Mongolia and by the mid-1920s were clearly prevailing over the Chinese firms. The destination of this trade was no longer just China but the world and in particular the United States. Soviet and Mongolian writers of the Communist period, unlike the Western writers cited above, often recognised the important role played by non-Chinese firms between 1911 and 1929. Their characterisation of these Anglo-American firms was, of course, entirely negative, seeing them as continuing the exploitative practices of the Chinese and meddling in Mongolian political affairs, such as the alleged Bodô conspiracy of 1922. By these accounts, the Mutual Aid Co-operatives, founded soon after the revolution in 1921 and holding a major share in the Mongolian export markets from 1925 on, were the crucial means by which socialist trade, which was more beneficial to the 2 See the classic study of M. Sanjdorj, Manchu Chinese Colonial Rule in Northern Mongolia, trans. Urgunge Onon (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1980). 3 Charles R. Bawden, The Modern History of Mongolia (1968; reprinted London: Kegan Paul International, 1989), p. 203; cf. Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural: 1924 ony XI saryn 8-28. Delgerengüi tailan (Utaanbaatar: State Publishing House, 1984), p. 357. herdsmen, was able to oust the Anglo-American films and their businessmen - just as the Mongolians were ousting the Chinese püüs (companies) and their danjaad (managers). What methods did the Mongolian government use to displace the foreign traders, and what interests were driving this process? Accounts from the Communist period assert that there was a common national interest in expelling exploitative traders, and that stateaffiliated monopolies drove the capitalist firms out of business by selling goods cheaper and buying raw materials at higher prices than the foreign traders. This challenges the free-market economic dogma that competitive markets are better for consumers than monopolies, and contradicts the common historical experience that nationalist elites usually build their new nation states on the backs of, and not in co-operation with, the rural producers. An examination of the history of the co-operatives suggests, however, that in this case, free-market dogmas and a somewhat sceptical view of nation-building elites make better sense of the facts. THE ANIMAL-PRODUCTS TRADE FROM THE MONGOLIAN PLATEAU TO CHINESE CITIES Before 1870, Russia was the major foreign (i.e. outside the Qing empire) customer for Mongolian wool which, being of low quality, was mostly used in Russia for padding clothes. In 1870, the United States also began importing sheep’s wool from China, principally for the shawl trade, and by 1890, exports of wool from Tianjin to United States and Great Britain had become an important Qing export. In the years before World War I, the United States was buying more Chinese wool than all other countries put together and Russia and Japan replaced Britain as the major secondary markets. Wool from Tianjin was also used in the carpet trade, but up to 1914 was not used for clothing. World War I changed the Chinese wool trade. With the high demand for wool for uniforms and the wartime disruption of trade, the highest grades of Chinese wool were in demand for clothing, a situation which continued after the end of the war.4 There were also significant changes in the destination countries. Germany, Russia, and Great Britain all eventually stopped importing Chinese wool and, with the exception of brief surges directly after the war, were not the final market for Chinese wool in the 1920s. Japanese wool imports also surged during the war, and although they fell considerably in the postwar period, they remained much larger than they had been before the war. Thus by 1923, the United States and (on a much lower scale) Japan become the only significant markets for Chinese wool. Tianjin was the main centre for the export of Chinese wool, in 1925-6 accounting for 91 per cent of China’s total wool. Fifty per cent of this came from the Tibetan plateau via Gansu and Qinghai, while fifteen per cent came from Shanxi and Shaanxi provinces, and presumably originated in the area of western Inner Mongolia and twenty five per cent came from what is called ‘the rest of Mongolia’, including Outer Mongolia (or Mongolia proper) and central Inner Mongolia which sold its wool at Zhangjiakou.5 4 5 The China Year Book 1921-22, ed. H.G.W. Woodhead (Tianjin), pp. 138-9. The China Year Book 1925-6, ed. H.G.W. Woodhead (Tianjin), p. 489. Zhangjiakou was the centre for the collection of Mongolian skins, wool and hides.6 Until 1919, animal products were transported from Mongolia to Zhangjiakou by cattle or camel caravans. In 1916, after Mongolia’s status had been regularised as a separate state under Chinese suzerainty, the Americans Meyer and Larsen came to Khüriye to negotiate with the Mongolian government the establishment of motortransport between there and Zhangjiakou. This connection was established in 1918, with ten automobiles, under the name of the ‘Tianjin Automobile Transport Organisation’, The company had a multinational staff of six working in Khüriye: three Americans, two Japanese, and one Russian.7 From Zhangjiakou wool was moved southeast to Tianjin, which also received a considerable amount of the Manchurian wool trade, mostly from Barga, and a significant percentage of this would be transported south by rail to Niuzhuang and shipped to Tianjin or Shanghai. In Tianjin, by 1923, seven firms, all British, had hydraulic presses for wool, cotton, and skin packing and also handled wool cleaning and washing.8 A significant feature of the trade in animal products was its seasonality. Imports of wool into Zhangjiakou sta11ed in October and were over by March.9 In the Barga area shearing took place in June and July, and the wool was delivered to the foreign firms in the autumn.10 Incomplete quarterly breakdowns of exports show a general pattern of shipments abroad taking place largely in the first two quarters of the year, with the third and fourth quarters devoted to shearing and gathering. This was only a general pattern, however, and market conditions often forced exporters to store the wool in Tianjin and then sell off-season.11 Fur markets were more strictly seasonal, for example the marmot skin trade which was influenced by the seasonal change tram blue or blueish yellow in autumn to a yellow 6 The China Year Book 1926-7, ed. H.G.W. Woodhead (Tianjin), p. 670. Tumuriin Namjim, in William Rozycki (ed.), The Economy of Mongolia: From Traditional Times to the Present (Bloomington: The Mongolia Society, 2000), pp. 15-16. 8 The China Year Book 1923, ed. H.G.W. Woodhead (Tianjin), p. 517. 9 The China Year Book 1926-7, p. 670. That the fur trade season in Zhangjiakou and Khüriye started in October is confirmed by RRIAC roll no. 184, 893.6231/1, ‘Fur Business in Urga Influenced by Lack of Banking Facilities,’ 21 October 1922, from Consul Samuel Sokobin. 10 RRIAC, roll no. 184, 893.62222/3, ‘Wool Monopoly in Mongolia’ 13 July 1925, from Consul Samuel Sokobin. Note the letter of appreciation from the American firm worded about a local Mongolian monopoly on the wool trade came on 4 December 1925, presumably after the company had ascertained that the season's trade had gone through and the bulk of the wool gathered in; see RRIAC, roll 184, 893.62222/4, Consul G.C. Hanson to U.S. Secretary of State, 15 December 1925. 11 See figures in Chinwangtao & Tientsin Trade Returns, October-December Quarter 1920 and Trade Report 1920 (Shanghai: Statistical Department of the Inspectorate General of Customs, 1921). pp. 5-7; Chinwangtao & Tientsin Trade Returns, July-September Quarter, 1921 (Shanghai: Statistical Department of the Inspectorate General of Customs, 1921), pp. 5-6; Chinwangtao & Tientsin Trade Returns [October-December Quarter 1921] and Trade Reports 1920 (Shanghai: Statistical Department of the Inspectorate General of Customs, 1922), pp. 6-7. 7 colour in spring.12 The incomplete quarterly breakdowns of marmot skin exports through Manzhouli show very few sales in the third quarter, strong sales in the fourth quarter and somewhat less in the first half of the year (probably concentrated in the early spring). Another problem in these trades was the need for buyers to make large cash advances to those responsible for collecting the skins. One reporter on the fur trade in China remarked on this necessity as the trade’s main drawback.13 The need to advance cash was not restricted to the fur trade alone, but was found necessary for various reasons both in Barga and in Mongolia proper. In Barga, the shearing and felt-making was done by about 1,500 Han Chinese labourers, most of whom received cash advances, tools, and provisions from the British and American companies who dominated the market, although these funds would often be distributed through the intermediary of Chinese trading firms.14 The Chinese labourers had their own organisation, the ‘Chinese Felt Makers Association’. They would do the shearing and felt-making for the Barga and Solon Mongols who owned the herds and received wool in payment. Presumably after settling accounts with the firm that had supplied their advances, the felt-makers could then sell the wool to the highest bidder and they could also buy wool from the Mongols on their own account. In 1925, the American firms committed in advance to purchase about 200,000 silver dollars’-worth, while the British firms were committed to somewhat more.15 (The total sheep’s wool sale from Manchuria as a whole - and virtually all of that was from Barga - in 1925 was about 1 million haiguan taels, or about 1.5 million silver dollars). Chinese traders do not seem to have been so closely involved in the actual shearing and felt-making in the more remote parts of Mongolia proper, but the same need existed for cash advances. Shirendev, in his memoirs, gives a picture of two Chinese traders living in what is now the southernmost part of Khövsgöl province in the far northwest of the country. Like shearers in Barga, they traded almost completely by barter and labour service, mowing hay for and obtaining furs from most of the households in the banner. They also bought animal-skins in the slaughtering and calving season and wool in the shearing season. Although Shirendev does not explain how they traded, the large stores of flour, brick tea, silk, cotton cloth and tobacco kept by the traders suggests what commodities could be used for barter. The traders were visited periodically by Chinese merchants from other, larger monasteries and banners, who counted the goods and made inventories of the stock.16 In such a cash-poor society, the British and American merchants, like their Russian competitors had a significant advantage due to their access 12 U.M.S. Torresani, Furs and Skins (Shanghai: Statistical Department of the Inspectorate General of Customs), pp. 26-7. 13 The China Year Book 1924-5, ed. H.G.W. Woodhead (Tianjin), p. 525. 14 Owen Lattimore has some detailed comments about both the economic and technical aspects of the Chinese involvement in shearing and felt-making in Inner Mongolia in his Mongol Journeys (New York, 1941), pp. 210-14. 15 See the detailed report on the trade in RRIAC, roll no. 184, 893.62222/3, ‘Wool Monopoly in Mongolia’ 13 July 1925, from Consul Samuel Sokobin. 16 Bazaryn Shirendev, Through the Ocean Waves, trans. Temujin Onon (Bellingham: Center for East Asian Studies, Western Washington University, 1997), p. 33. to cash.17 The Chinese need for cash advances and the British and American unfamiliarity with the country apparently linked the British and American companies into the same relations of interdependence as in Barga. The Russian Revolution made the already complex Mongolian currency situation much worse. After the end of the Qing Dynasty in 1911 the principal currency for large transactions had been silver taels. Silver coins of Mexican origin (Chinese yangqian, Mongolian yanchaan) had circulated in the mid to late Qing, and in the early Republic they were replaced by the Yuan Shikai silver dollar. Fractional currency under the Qing was primarily tea bricks.18 After trade with Russia increased in volume, small Russian silver coins of the ten, fifteen, and twenty kopeck denominations came to be used, but World War I and the Russian Revolution led to inflation of the paper rubles which determined the value of these fractional currencies, and soon the face value of the kopecks was less than the silver content. As a result, large amounts of these coins were shipped to China to be sold and melted down and the Mongolians, who had a great preference for the relatively stable Chinese silver dollar, carried them away into the countryside leaving Khüriye without sufficient cash. As the U.S. Consul at Zhangjiakou reported in October 1922, local fur dealers were willing to sell at 20-25 per cent discount if the buyers would pay in cash in Khüriye, yet the buyers, unable to insure the shipment of cash across 700 miles of open country, still preferred to have the local dealers bring the furs by caravans to Zhangjiakou and sell at the higher prices there. Chinese firms in Zhangjiakou which had branches in Khüriye would charge remittance fees of 12 per cent.19 In November 1924, Tseden-Ishi, head of the Mutual-Aid Co-ops, estimated that one-third of the total trade turnover of Mongolia was conducted in barter, and only twothirds conducted in cash.20 Eventually the revolutionary Mongolian government would ease the situation by issuing its own silver-based currency, which until 1929 at least was relatively stable in value. Sources around 1924-1925 are consistent in stating that British and American firms dominated the trade in both Barga and Mongolia proper, although the local agents were often White Russian or Chinese. Mongolian figures from 1925 demonstrate that whilst the total capitalisation of Chinese firms considerably exceeded that of the German, American and British firms, the Chinese share of the market was divided between 283 small and individually very weak firms. Only the non-Chinese foreign firms, and in particular the British firms possessed a concentrated capitalisation that could conceivably match the state-supported Mongolian trade organisations (Table 1). In Barga, at least, the foreign traders worked amicably with the Chinese entrepreneurs. When the Mongolian co-operatives tried to monopolise the wool trade, both the Chinese Commercial Society (presumably shang hui, usually translated as 17 See, for example, Shirendev, Through the Ocean Waves, p. 22. See, for example, C.R. Bawden (trans. and ed.), Tales of an Old Lama (Tring: Institute of Buddhist Studies, 1997), pp. 4-5. 19 RRIAC roll no. 184, 893.6231/1, ‘Fur Business in Urga Influenced by Lack of Banking Facilities,’ 21 October 1922, from Consul Samuel Sokobin. 20 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, p. 236. 18 Chamber of Commerce) in Hailar and the Chinese Felt Makers Association, co-operated closely with the foreign firms and the US and British consular personnel to pressure the Hailar authorities to allow free trade again. Category (no. of individual firms) Mongolian trade organisations Mongolian Mutual Aid Co-op Mongol-Soviet Bank Total capital (in tögrögs) 6,500,000 3,000,000 3,500,000 Soviet trade organizations Soviet state capital Private Russian capital (43) Soviet and Mongolian capital 1,971,500 1,267,000 704,500 8,471,500 British firms (10) Chinese firms (283) German firms (3) American firms (5) Non-Soviet/Mongolian capital 4,500,000 7,248,000 673,000 560,000 12,481,000 Percentage Average capital of private firms 16,384 40.5 450,000 25,611 224,333 112,000 59.5 TABLE 1. Capitalisation of Firms in Mongolia, 1925 (Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn V lkh Khural, p. 44). Note the discrepancy in the total for the non-Soviet/Mongolian capital is in the original; the figures presented actually total 12,921,000. The tögrög, introduced in 1925, was a convertible currency based on a unit of 18 ounces of silver and hence had a value of 75 per cent of the Chinese or Mexican silver dollar. THE CO-OPERATIVES The domination of Mongolian trade by foreign firms combined with Mongolian independence, or at least autonomy, to raise the issue of nativising trade even before the 1921 Revolution. Tsyben Zhamtsarano, an influential Buriat scholar closely affiliated with the Russian consulate in Neislel Khüriye, the capital of Mongolia, pursued a course of long-term intellectual preparation. In his journal, The New Mirror (Shine toli khemekhü bichig) with its motto ‘Letting a myriad things bloom, and letting all sciences spread’, he proclaimed a mission to enlighten Mongolia: Now that the Mongols have set up their state and established an independent country, it is only right that we should exert ourselves to master the various arts and rapidly to make our country strong and powerful. Therefore our publishing house has taken it upon itself to found a periodical publication which will survey all the arts and sciences at work in the foreign countries, so that the Mongols may be aided in their study.21 In this same first volume, Zhamtsarano not only explained the origin of natural phenomena and surveyed the major countries of the world, but he also introduced to the Mongols the concept of human development through stages, In a chapter entitled ‘On the way the world’s people make a living’ (Delkhei degerekhi khümün-ü aju törökhü-yin uchir-a), he first described the ‘wandering peoples’ (tenümel ulus) who lived by fishing or hunting birds, and gathering plants, then the ‘nomadic peoples’ (negüdel ulus), and finally the ‘settled people’ (sagurishigsan ulus), who not only farm but make all sorts of goods and set up special places called fabrig or ‘factories,’ where things can easily be made by machines.22 Zhamtsarano also explained the relevance of this information to the new Mongolian state, He noted that Mongolia traded wool, leather, and pelts to foreign countries such as China, Russia, Germany, and America, and in return bought from them everything she needed including her tea, cotton, silk, and woollen cloths, hatchets, and knives, He commented: ‘If one wants to become strong, it is necessary to be able to produce the various goods oneself. A country with raw materials which cannot do that will always be poor.’23 In later years, he made more concrete recommendations. In 1917, in his new newspaper the Neislel Khüriye News (Neyislel Küriyen-ü sonin bichig) he argued that ‘By development of agriculture, Mongolia will increase the supply of foodstuffs. Through the ability to produce textiles, paper, spoons, forks, cups, matches, and candles ourselves, the country will develop and people will become wealthy,’ He also suggested forming joint-capital organisations for the cattle-cart transportation business. A monastery-educated caravan leader, Chagdurjab, who was friends with Bodô (a staff member on the Neislel Khüriye News), took up this suggestion. In 1914 he had travelled to Russia, and thence to England, Italy, and China, on a mission to ‘learn through experience about the life and situation of foreign countries, their attitude towards the Mongolian question, and how in general Mongolians should be educated’, On returning in 1917, he, with 17 others, formed the ‘Mongolian Mutual-Aid Cooperative’ (Monggol-un khariltsan tusalakhu khorshiya), with an elective chairman and a fifteen-article charter. In their petition to the Treasury Ministry of theocratic Mongolia for approval of the new organisation, they showed a growing sense of economic nationalism: Now we eighteen people have discussed how through buying food and goods from foreign countries and trading to the Mongolian citizens as much as needed, and selling at a lower price than other traders, we, with a 21 Sin-e toli kemekü bichig, 20 December 1913, no. 1, p. 1. I would like to thank Sohn Hyun-sook of Pusan Women’s University for supplying me with a photocopy of the first four issues of this journal kept in the Toyo Bunko. 22 Sin-e toli kemekü bichig, 20 December 1913, no. 1, pp. 25-28. 23 Sin·e toli kemekü bichig, 20 December 1913, no. 1, p. 29. small profit for ourselves, might limit the profits of greedy merchants and their companies. With a certain profit from the money it would be of important assistance to our own nation (öörsdöö yazguur ündsee).24 This co-operative began the long and ultimately successful Khalkha Mongolian effort to displace foreign merchants from their dominant position in Mongolian commerce and replace them by an ostensibly more public-spirited Mongolian commercial organisation. Since Chagduljab eventually became Prime Minister of the provisional revolutionary government in March 1921, and was replaced by Bodô who had worked on the Neislel Khüriye News, clearly foreign domination of Mongolian commerce was a serious concern for Mongolia’s nascent intelligentsia. This was true even before the affiliation of this infant intelligentsia with Soviet Russia, and it was only to be expected that one of the first actions of the new revolutionary government in Mongolia would be to establish co-operatives, On 26 October 1921, the Treasury Ministry called on the people to buy shares in the planned cooperative and in November issued the statutes of the organisation, The first assembly of the Co-op members was held on 16 December in the Neislel Khüriye (‘Urga’) customs house, by which time 44 members had joined, including General Sükhebaatur, the poet Buyannemekhü, and the Jebdzundamba Khutugtu, Mongolia’s titular ruler, whose membership card is preserved in the Palace Museum.25 The stated aims of the co-operatives were both to improve the terms of trade for the Mongolian herdsmen and the gradual exclusion of foreign firms from Mongolia, which were justified by a rhetoric that linked the issue of national sovereignty with a struggle against exploitation and backwardness.26 As a co-operative organisation, the members had to purchase shares to take advantage of the co-operative facilities. The minimum share cost five taels and members could buy as many as they wanted. This expense was a considerable burden for poorer herders and constituted a formidable block to expanding its membership. When some delegates to the Party's Third Congress proposed that joining the Co-operative be compulsory for all party members, ‘Japanese’ Danzin noted: ‘We are informed from the provinces that poor people will not enter the Party, because they cannot afford to pay the fee for membership, If we add now that every member of the Party should also be in the Co-operative and pay for a share of it, all poor people will leave at once from the Party.’ The motion was changed to say only that it was ‘desirable’ for Party members to join the Cooperative.27 The initial 116 members from Neislel Khüriye and Maimaching (the S. Idshinnorov, ‘Dambyn Chagdarjav (1880-1922),’ Zasgiin gazryn medee, April 1992, no. 13, p. 16; D. Khatanbaatar, Yörönkhii saidyn örgöönd (Ulaanbaatar: People’s Army ‘Shuwuun Saaral’ Company, 1992), pp. 7-9. 25 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, pp. 355-611. 118; Ts. Nasanbaljir, ed., Ardyn zasgaas 1921-1924 onuudad avsan khuvisgalt arga khemjeenüüd (Barimt bichgiin emkhtgel) (Ulaanbaatar: State Press, 1954), pp. 154-9. 26 Mongol Ardyn Namyn gurawdugaar ikh khural: 1924 ony naim-yesdügeer sar. Delgerengüi temdeglel (Ulaanbaatar: State Publishing House, 1966), p. 228; Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, pp. 232-5. 27 Mongolia: Yesterday and Today (Tianjin: Tientsin Press, n.d.), pp. 65-6. 24 Chinatown of Neislel Khüriye) invested an average of 53.2 taels per person.28 Based on the 1,500 members in 1923-4, it was estimated that one-third invested more than 20 taels.29 These high investments prompted the frequent complaint that the Co-op members were primarily the well-to-do herders, At the Congress of the Cooperatives in April, 1923, the elected leadership included many of Mongolia’s richest men: Duke Tsedebsürüng (Chairman of the General Committee); Prince and lama Dashidindüb (Chairman of the General Office); Grand Duke Lubsangjantsan (Chairman of the Accounting Department); Grand Duke Shagdurjab (Chairman of the Trade Department).30 Initially the co-operatives played little role in the Mongolian economy. They had received 10,000 taels start-up capital, from the Treasury Ministry in December 1921, but until 1923 any increase in capital came either from shares bought by the members or from loans.31 The value of shares totalled 41,000 taels silver, making the Co-operatives rather better capitalised than the average Chinese firm but rather worse than the average European or American firm.32 Motor links between Mongolia and Zhangjiakou were restored in autumn, 1923.33 From 1921 to 1924, the number of foreign firms operating in Mongolia increased dramatically. Yet the Mongolian leadership seemed determined to use the co-operatives to nationalise the economy.34 In April 1923 the co-operatives’ previously elected aristocratic leadership was replaced and at the party congress in July 1923, the authorities called for them to be brought under the control of the party and youth league.35 Moreover, improvement in Mongolian government finances allowed the Finance Ministry to dramatically increase its investment in the co-operatives, to the tune of 300,000 taels silver. Unfortunately the money was disbursed between July and December which was too late to have a major effect on that wool-buying season, but it probably played a role in the expansion of the co-operatives' reach; increasing from 6 to 16 departments by the end of the year. The re-establishment of transportation links with China led also to the creation of departments in both Zhangjiakou and Hailar.36 Thus the co-operatives were, at least in theory, able to collect the raw materials in Mongolia and transport them abroad. In fact, however, the co-operatives still formed only a small part of the Mongolian trade, handling only 5.3 per cent of Mongolia’s exports and 4.1 per cent of its imports. 28 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, p. 356 n. 118. Mongolia: Yesterday and Today, pp. 64-5. 30 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, p 357 n. 124. 31 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, p. 234. 32 Mongolia: Yesterday and Today, p. 64. 33 The China Year Book, 1924-5, p. 1259; The China Year Book, 1925-6, pp. 382,388, 428. 34 The China Year Book, 1924-5, p. 1259; The China Year Book, 1925-6, pp. 382,388, 428. 35 Mongol Ardyn Namyn khoyordugaar ikh khural (barimt bichgüüd). 1923 ony doloo-naimdugaar sar. (Ulaanbaatar: State Publishing House, 1974), p. 127. 36 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, p. 235; Mongol Ardyn Namyn gurawdugaar ikh khural, p. 184; Mongolia: Yesterday and Today, pp. 63-4. 29 Around the same time as this loan from the Finance Ministry, the government also invested a million taels of revenue in the co-ops, thus becoming the overwhelming stockholder. This massive purchase of shares by the government effectively made the cooperatives a government organisation, supplying profit to the government and being very responsive to its needs. In 1924, total shares of the Finance Ministry, the Central Committee and other governmental organisations, were 15 times the size of funds from private members. To the Finance Ministry the co-operatives were primarily an investment from which they budgeted revenues of up to 300,000 taels.37 Elbek-Dorzhi Rinchino complained that ‘The Central Committee has invested some money in the cooperative, but has so far received no interest, whereas the Ministry of Finance, being a partner of the same kind, gets its dividends regularly.’38 It is not surprising then that the co-operative leadership also thought it only right that they should have access to the compulsory corvée labour of literate men as clerks, which the party and government had at their disposal.39 Politics hung heavily over Mongolia’s southern relations during the first three years of the co-operative, and· accentuated the pressure to squeeze out both the Chinese and the Anglo-American fiems. Bodô, the government’s first prime minister, having been forced from office after unpopular attempts to force Khüriye’s population to adopt revolutionary dress, was shot in August 1922 on charges of conspiring with the American consul in Zhangjiakou, Samuel Sokobin. Sokobin was established there in spring 1921 largely in response to the growing commercial connection between the United States and the Mongolian plateau.40 He had visited Mongolia and met Bodô in September 1921, while party chief Danzin and General Sükhebaatur, the two other members of the ruling troika, were in Moscow, something which aroused suspicions particularly in ElbekDorzhi Rinchino.41 Thus from the beginning of the Mongolian government, a general concern with nationalising the economy, common in revolutionary governments, came into explosive contact with the Soviet suspicion of both China and the rest of the capitalist world. Leadership passed to Danzin, who after Sükhebaatur’s death took over the position of Commander-in-Chief and dominated the government. At the People’s Party’s Third Congress, he was suddenly executed, on charges of protecting Chinese interests and making personal profits, being accused of links with Chinese generals and of close connections with the Mongolian wool export. He had resisted the reestablishment of the motor-car service as a Mongolian monopoly, holding out for a role for the Dalaihe firm, in which he held shares. He was also accused of having connections 37 Mongolia: Yesterday and Today, pp. 50, 63. Mongolia: Yesterday and Today, p. 68. 39 Mongolia: Yesterday and Today, pp. 63, 64. 40 See Alicia J. Campi, The Political Relationship between the United States and Outer Mongolia 1915-1927: The Kalgan Consular Records, Ph. D. Thesis, Indiana University, 1987, or her brief account in ‘Early U.S.-Mongolian Diplomatic Contacts,’ Mongolia Survey, No.6 (1999), pp. 47-57. 41 On Bodoo’s execution, see Baabar [Bat-Erdene Batbayar], XX zuuny Mongol: nüüdel suudal, olz garz (Ulaanbaatar: State Photography Office, 1996), pp. 279-282, 284-286; cf. the translation in Twentieth-Century Mongolia, trans. D. Sühjargalmaa et. al., ed. C. Kaplonski (Cambridge: White Horse Press, 1999), pp. 229-231, 233-4. 38 with the British firms D. Biederman and Robert Smith & Co. and the American firm Joseph Ullman & Co., allowing their representatives to travel m Mongolia with rifles without a permit. When the motor-car route opened up again between Khüriye and Zhangjiakou without the participation of Chinese firms, he helped Dalaihe construct dian (that is, fandian, or hotels), to profit from travel on the route. His dealings with a Chinese firm called Tonghehe, in which he held shares, seemed directly contrary to the aims of the Mutual-Aid Co-operatives and he was accused of having allowed them to compete with the co-operatives. In 1922, the harvest at Kharaa Gal was poor and flour prices rose from 2-3.5 rubles per pood to 7 rubles. Danzin, it was charged, had invalidated an agreement to import flour from Verkhneudinsk at 3.25 rubles per pood, and instead, when the military needs for flour became too pressing, contracted to purchase flour from Tonghehe firm at 6 silver dollars per pood. By the time the flour actually arrived the price had dropped to 2.05-3.5 rubles per pood, but the flour was sold for 6 rubles per pood. This was much lower than the buying price, and the government lost thousands of silver dollars on the sale. Danzin also sent representatives from Tonghehe into Eastern Mongolia with an armed guard, claiming to be working for the State Treasury and the co-ops themselves. There they purchased marmot and ground-squirrel skins, using their position as government buyers to intimidate the locals into selling goods at below market price. Eventually the Office of Internal Security, effectively controlled by Danzan’s enemy Elbek-Dorzhi Rinchino, arrested these merchants and their guards and put an end to their trading.42 The most important policy issue centred on the repayment of banner (county administration) debts owed to Chinese merchants. Some of these debts had been contracted by the banner rulers in times dating back to the Qing dynasty, and the cooperatives viewed them as exploitative remnants of the feudal system. Danzin, however, at one point had debts owed to the once-great but now virtually bankrupt film Dashengkui from Setsen Khan Aimag repaid from public funds. As the historian Baabar speculates, such repayment may well have been intended to repair Mongolia’s credit in the eyes of the Chinese and foreign firms, and so to relieve the serious shortage of capital in Mongolia.43 In so doing, however, he ran directly contrary to the strategy of the cooperatives, two of whose chief advantages were sole access to government-supplied capital and a more reliable ability to enforce contracts than the Chinese firms possessed. The execution of Danzin thus opened the road for a full-scale offensive by the cooperatives to monopolise Mongolian foreign trade. The new head of the cooperatives, Babasang (1899-1924), was also executed at the Third Congress. He had joined the People’s Party in 1921 and served as the head of the training department of the Mongolian People’s Army before replacing Duke Tsedebsürüng as Chairman of the 42 Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, pp. 166-8, 209. Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, pp. 170, 209. See also the brief account in Baabar, XX zuuny Mongol, p. 339; Baabar, Twentieth-Century Mongolia, p. 262-3. 43 General Committee of the Mongolian Mutual Aid Co-operatives.44 He apparently held this post until 1924, when he moved on to positions in the government and the Youth League and Jaddamba was elected Co-op chairman in his place.45 Babasang was linked to Danzin, and his elimination opened the way for a new policy. THE CO-OPERATIVES IN 1924 If 1923 had been the milestone in restoring Mongolia’s connections with the south, 1924 was the milestone in the move towards monopolising Mongolia’s animal-products exports. Jaddamba had been elected head of the co-operatives, but Tseden-Ishi (also known as Gochitskii), a Buriat who had been active in the Pan-Mongolian movement, was the mainspring of the co-operatives in the following years. The 300,000 taels loaned by the Treasury Ministry in 1923 was fully put into play in the 1924 buying season, and a stronger network of 24 domestic departments and 82 branches was already in place. The co-operative planned to buy 1,000,000 silver dollars’ -worth of goods for import and 2,980,000 silver dollars’-worth of raw materials for export. The latter figure would have given the co-operative an estimated 21 per cent share of the Mongolian export trade, a huge jump from the 1923 estimate of 5.3 per cent.46 In the event, the cooperatives actually sold abroad 4,029,000 silver dollars’ -worth of Mongolian raw materials, amounting to an estimated 28.7 per cent of their total exports. Imports, however, exceeded their target only slightly with purchases of 1,080,000 sliver dollars’-worth of goods from abroad, for a total of 5.8 per cent of Mongolia’s imports.47 (The percentages were based on 1925 estimatess of Mongolia’s exports and imports of 14,000,000 silver dollars and 18,500,000 dollars respectively. Since these figures were actually substantial under-estimates of Mongolia's total trade, the co-operative officials were thus overestimating their impact on the economy.)48 Suddenly the co-operatives were the single largest player in Mongolia’s export market. The relatively small purchases from abroad reflected the greater profitability of the export trade (raw materials collected were sold abroad for an 86 per cent profit, but the markup on foreign goods sold in Mongolia was only 15 per cent),49 as well as a concern for Mongolia’s persistent trade deficit. The sorts of products the co-ops dealt in can be seen from Tsedn-Ishi’s report to the First Congress of the Mongolian People’s Republic in November, 1924. In June, 1924, the co-operatives purchased sheep and camel wool, marmot skins, cattle hides, sheep and goat skins, mares, live oxen and sheep, lard and sheep guts from the Mongolian pastoral 44 See his congratulatory address to the People's Party's First Congress in Mongol Ardyn Namyn khoyordugaar ikh khural, p. 17 and his brief biography in Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, p. 256. 45 See Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, p. 21. 46 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar Ikh khural, p. 236. 47 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn dörövdügeer ikh khural: 1925 ony yesdügeer saryn 23arawdugaar saryn 1. Delegerengüi tailan (Ulaanbaatar: State Publishing House, 1978), p. 220. 48 For the 1925 estimates, see Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn dörövdügeer ikh khural, pp. 219, 220. For the revised figures, see Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn V Ikh Khural: 1926 ony yesdügeer saryn 26-naas aravdugaar saryn 3. Delgerengüi Tailan (Ulaanbaatar: State Publishing House, 1981), p. 43. 49 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn dörövdügeer ikh khural, pp. 219, 220. nomads and foreign traders.50 These items together were valued at a total of 1,430,000 silver dollars and so constituted a significant portion of the total 2,159,000 silver dollars’ purchases for that year. The figures on the amount collected were over-optimistic in one sense; the cooperatives had a difficult time finding buyers for much of the goods. It is possible that the British and American firms were trying to freeze out the new rivals, but Tseden-Ishi in his reports on the co-operatives described the destinations as primarily Soviet or Mongolian. Some could be sold domestically to the small factories, mostly in Altanbulag, producing military uniforms, felt boots, and other products. 100,000 silver dollars’ -worth of raw materials were sent to the fair at Nizhnii Novgorod in order to raise the profile of Mongolian goods. All the sheep guts were sold to buyers in the Soviet Far East, and about 5,000 of the cattle had already been sold in various places. Most of the wool was sold in the Soviet Union, only to be eventually sold to the United States by way of Vladivostok.51 It should be remembered that the co-operative’s first foreign offices were in Zhangjiakou and Hailar, with the addition in late 1924 of first Tianjin, and then Moscow.52 Moreover, the eventual destination for wool the largest single item, was still the United States; the operations of the co-operatives did not change this but added a Soviet middleman between the Mongolian sellers and the eventual American buyers. Tseden-Ishi was fully aware of the continuing significance of the British firms and the American market. To the Third Congress he explained that ‘Although it is our aim to sell our own raw materials directly to the users, we have as yet not been able to execute it. Since our users are England and America, we would like to send people to conduct negotiations but there is no one to send. Right now, a representative of ours is in Kalgan and Tientsin, and soon we will have representatives in Moscow.’ The ultimate aim was to resolve Mongolia’s constant negative balance of trade by raising the price for Mongolian goods in the world market. Believing that Mongolia exported 9.5 million silver dollars’-worth of goods while importing 13 million silver dollars (these estimates both underestimated the amount of trade, and overestimated the deficit), he explained to the delegates that Mongolia would have to increase its sales by 3.5 million silver dollars. ‘For this reason, our co-operative is trying above all else to get all the raw materials being exported from Mongolia into its own hands.’ In the meantime, while the monopoly was still incomplete, a fall-back strategy was used: ‘Leaving the market price as it is, we are making it our aim to allow only a certain amount of goods to be imported.’53 While the expansion of tile Co-ops and the pressure on other traders certainly assisted the political goals of nationalising trade, it is less clear that it benefited the Mongolian herdsmen, The party and national congresses of 1924 gave ample space for delegates from the rural areas to air their grievances over the high prices, bad service, and 50 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, p. 238. Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural. pp. 237, 238. 52 In the party's Third Congress report (Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, p. 184), an office (kheltes) has been established in Tianjin but not in Moscow yet, while in the State First Congress report the one in Moscow has been established (Büge Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar Ikh khural, p. 236). 53 Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, pp. 184, 185; Mongolia: Yesterday and Today, p. 64. 51 generally inefficient operations of this growing would-be monopoly. Elbek-Dorzhi Rinchino, a Buriat who was closer than most to Soviet policy, in addressing questions of Mongolian national security, found the free operations of Chinese door-to-door salesmen a clear threat: “. . . it is wrong that there is no supervision and no registration whatsoever over Chinese door-to-door traders,54 and moreover, since they bring harm to the economy, it is necessary to prohibit rural door-to-door trade.’ Rinchino’s assumption was that having traders actually go out to their customers was certainly harmful to the economy, and this has been reflected in decades of nationalist and socialist historiography. Yet the Buriat politician had only to raise the issue for rural delegates to suddenly object: ‘If door-to-door trading is prohibited, what will happen to the people in places that don’t have branches of the co-operatives?’ Once on the topic of door-to-door traders, another delegate raised the question of consumer credit. The existing historiography sees the consumer credit extended by Chinese traders as a form of exploitation which caused much resentment. Yet at the Third Congress, this delegate saw the willingness of the Chinese to grant credit as a strong advantage: ‘Since the Chinese traders loan us goods when important occasions roll around, they are helpful. But the Mongolian co-operatives don’t give loans. . .’ At that point the soon-to-be purged Danzin contrasted the document-oriented style of assessing risk which prevailed in the new organs of trade and commerce with the more flexible style employed by Chinese traders: ‘The banks and the cooperatives only believe in paper and in documents . .’ Rinchino, however, insisted that all such appearances were deceptive, and then changed the subject: ‘As a rule the loans granted by the Chinese door-to-door traders are harmful and their seeming to help is actually a false appearance. Let’s talk about this question together with the question of the co-operatives.’55 Tseden-Ishi, also aware of complaints in the Third Congress, admitted, ‘You are hear it everywhere that the Chinese goods are cheaper than ours, and the Chinese buy raw materials at a high price compared an ours’ but he claimed that such ideas had no foundation; the Chinese were using dishonest weights and ‘spreading rumours to slander us’ This attempt to claim that the co-ops were too honest to use Chinese methods provoked the delegates to relate some embarrassing anecdotes in public: In our banner, there is an office of the co-operative, and the office trades with different weights, using different weight when buying than it does when selling. In a word, they are no different from the Chinese. The cooperatives buy wool when the weather is sunny and clear, but when the weather gets even the least bit cloudy they say the wool will weigh more and they’re too afraid of that to buy it. But right next to them the Chinese are buying regardless of the weather. The officials are all Russians and are hot-tempered foreigners with rough, arrogant manners. While the Chinese buy a really lot of wool, the co54 Donshuur khudaldaa cf. donshuurch, a loafer, someone who wanders from house to house without clear business. 55 Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, p. 87; Mongolia: Yesterday and Today, pp. 39-40. operatives buy very little. This is because the officials have very nasty, evil tempers and act fierce and irritable, and since they always hold the Mongols at a distance, they stopped buying things from the co-operatives. When they set the price for goods, they don’t pay attention to the need for them. This is not a big disaster by itself, but it’s worse because they are not thinking about our situation. They buy very little wool. There are also people who steal from what they do buy. The co-operative manager was saying that 500 jin of wool had been lost, and the original thief was arrested and the 500 jin of wool returned, but the co-op manager told the banner authority that that thief had not taken 500 but 1000 jin of wool. That’s the kind of men our co-op managers are. I met a person in Khovd province, and that person called himself a representative of the co-operatives, and when he was selling Berdan guns56 and bullets and when he was giving loans, the interest he took was no lower than the Chinese did. I don’t know who he was. That man is really ruining the reputation of the co-operatives, dragging its name into the dirt! Where we live, someone calling himself a representative of the cooperatives arrived and using the post-road requisitions had four sheep slaughtered and ate them, and then left and we never heard anything more about him. What was his position in the co-ops? In the spring, we heard that the co-o goods had arrived. When we got to the co-op bringing a good load of lamb skins, the manager drove us away saying, ‘You don’t have many lamb skins, I don’t need to talk to the likes of you’, and wouldn’t let us into the co-op. So then we went to the Chinese and they were willing and excited to talk to us, and invited us in for tea, and bought everything that we’d brought with us. That co-op manager of ours curses us, puts on the ‘paper snake’, frightens the horses, and scares the children. Now not one of the Mongols, and especially the poor, goes to the co-op; they are afraid to go. This co-op only trades with the rich.57 Tseden-Ishi himself anticipated the criticism that the foreign staff of the cooperatives would receive. In his report to the Third Congress, he explicitly addressed the issue saying: ‘We have some people who say that foreign instructors are unnecessary, and that no matter how, Mongols must, be used. But in reality, this simply won’t work.’ There were not enough Mongolians working in the co-operative, he explained, and those who were Mongolian didn’t know accounting. He pointed out that in the process of expansion 56 A single-shot breech-loading rifle used in the Russian army until the arrival of the repeating Mosin in 1891. The Berdan No. 2 was still widely used by civilians in both Barga and Mongolia proper up to the 1920s. 57 Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, pp. 186-7; Mongolia: Yesterday and Today, p. 65. the Finance Ministry sought new officials and received 200 applications from Mongols, but hardly 15 of them were literate and the rest could only be used for menial tasks.58 In his report to the First Congress of the MPR in November, Tseden-Ishi again admitted the inadequacy of the personnel and mentioned bureaucratic problems that made it hard even to employ qualified foreigners: Because . . . the Mongols trained in writing are almost all serving as officials in the state organs, to try to employ Mongols is just about impossible. Moreover men trained in trade and commerce and keeping books are very rare. Therefore we have ended up employing foreigners and since it is not easy for them to get travel documents, etc., it has almost got to the point of employing the first person we meet, so there are many places where the people in the co-ops are not of that good quality.59 By the end of 1924, after the hiring for the expansion was over, the total staff for the co-operatives was 615 persons, of which 226 were Mongols, 77 Buriats, 39 Chinese and 273 were Russians.60 Given the comments noted above, it is likely that the Russians were concentrated in the managerial positions, while the Mongols were in the menial ones. In general, however, the comments seem.to indicate a more fundamental problem: as salaried employees of a state-affiliated organisation created primarily by national policy considerations, the co-operative managers showed little interest in actually doing business. Shirendev’s memoirs of his childhood in the 1920s are typical. In his banner the leading representative of the new government was the manager of the local co-operative, Choisdoo. While Choisdoo was not a terrifying Russian (the Russians who frightened Shirendev belonged to Centro-Soiuz the Russian state-supported co-operative organisation), as concurrent head of the party cell his primary interest lay in popularising the new regime, discrediting the lamas, and recruiting young children for the Pioneers. In short, Choisdoo’s primary impact on the district was as a political agitator, not as a facilitator of the district’s trade, and it is hard to imagine that his office managed to secure a large percentage of the local wool market. Indeed Shirendev points out that as late as 1928 the local Chinese merchants played a major role, and he does not mention any commercial role of Choisdoo at al1.61 In this situation, expanding the co-operatives and out-competing foreign merchants by the use of legal privileges and appeals to revolutionary patriotism would not improve the level of service for the herdsmen. Although Tseden-Ishi certainly had a good sense of what the reality on the ground was, he was not the only one who responded to criticism of the co-operatives by blaming their problems on the Chinese. Typical was 58 Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, p. 184. Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, p. 235. 60 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn dörövdügeer ikh khural, p. 224. This figure does not include the 160 workers at Altanbulag factory. 61 Shirendev, Through the Ocean Waves, on Choisdoo, see p. 26, 36-40. On Russian traders buying livestock, see pp. 21-2. 59 the comment of Zhamtsarano, originator of the whole idea of displacing foreign traders almost a decade earlier, who saw sinister reasons behind the co-op’s incompetence: A directive was issued to take the co-op into our hands, but there has not been any work on this. It is called the ‘People’s’ co-operative, but is it really a people’s cooperative? In fact, isn’t it only the co-operative of ten or twelve rich people? Isn’t it the co-operative of the Chinese firms who stay in shadows behind it? . . . The congress should take up and discuss this question. . .62 The Comintern agent Turar Ryskulov, newly appointed to Mongolia, in his report to his superiors in Moscow labelled the complaints voiced by the rural delegates ‘interesting opinions and criticisms’. Yet completely ignoring the negative references to the Russians and the at least relatively favourable portrait of some Chinese business practices, he reported to his superiors that the co-operatives were not only exploitative in their own right but actually operating in collusion with the Chinese.63 CO-OPERATIVES, 1925-1928 The response in subsequent years was to pursue a policy of monopolisation of trade while also attempting to address the obvious problems of the co-operatives. The Third Congress’s resolution on Tseden-Ishi’s report began by emphasising that ‘In a sovereign country, developing the economy is of most vital significance’. It ended by directing that branches of the co-op should be established everywhere and that these branches ‘should find ways as opportunities present themselves to liquidate the exploitation by the merchants of foreign petty commerce’. In between, the directives emphasised getting all party members to become co-op members, ordering local government organs to turn over all in-kind taxes on animals and raw materials to the co-ops to be turned into cash, allowing the co-ops better access to the pool of educated Mongols, asking the government to give the co-operatives ‘special privilege’ (ontsa erkhe - that is, a monopoly) in importing and exporting materials so as better to unify all trade in its hands, and finally to improve the training of managers and fire the incompetent, lazy, and dishonest.64 The Congress of the MPR added its own directives in November, asking the People’s Co-operatives to become truly people’s co-operatives, reform their organisation, employ Mongols as the officials, and explain to the people the significance of the co-ops’ work and gain their vigorous support.65 In the next half-year the implementation of these directives was at least ostensibly held up by the snarling feud between Turar Ryskulov and Elbek-Dorzhi Rinchino. By June 1925, Ryskulov was writing to Moscow that Rinchino was opposing the Third Congress’s directives which he, as a loyal Comintern agent, fully supported. Writing about the implementation of a state monopoly on foreign trade, Ryskulov charged that: 62 Dashdavaa and Kazlov, Komintern ba Mongol, p. 90. Dashdavaa and Kazlov, Komintern ba Mongol, pp. 90-91. 64 Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, p. 228-9. 65 Dashdavaa and Kozlov, Komintern ba Mongol, p. 101. 63 Rinchino criticises [the decrees] saying ‘They aspire to apply the experiences and principles implemented in the Soviet government’s own territory in Mongolia.’ He says ‘No one is ready to implement it this way and exactly whom [the decrees] criticise is not understood, and to execute the country’s foreign and domestic trade as a result of this criticism along the lines of the National Congress will not work.’66 Although the feud between these two Comintern-affiliated agents in Mongolia ended with the recall of them both, the evidence indicates that neither Rinchino’s views about the impracticablility of instituting a Soviet-style foreign trade monopoly nor his dispute with Ryskulov significantly slowed the monopolisation programme. As Tseden-Ishi had pointed out, the primary obstacles were not political, but technical. With subsidy of the co-ops’ operations and increased resources being put into education, the obvious problems could in time be resolved. An important guarantee of success for the co-operatives was that they received the ‘special privilege’ or monopoly (ontsa erkhe) on foreign trade. At the Fourth Congress this monopoly, which was based on the Soviet model, was temporarily entrusted to the co-operatives. Subsequently it was planned to transfer foreign trade to a state-owned trading firm, leaving the co-operatives operating only in domestic trade. For the moment, however, foreign trade was the largest money-maker for the co-operatives and their members. In the first half of 1925, one of the large British firms, W. Kaufman & Co., sold their Mongolian branches to the Mutual Aid-Co-operatives as they were unable to compete successfully, and other firms followed suit.67 In reality, however, the monopoly was not actually applied with full legal rigour until December 1930; up to that year a dwindling number of foreigners continued trading.68 The steady displacement of foreign firms meant that in 1925 the co-ops were able to negotiate with the foreign firms from a position of strength. Their representatives secured a three-year contract with the British Wilson firm in Tianjin which gave three advantages to the co-operatives: 1) 83,000 poods of the co-operatives’ unsold 1924 stock was sold at a good profit; 2) the three year term would guarantee sales of at least part of the co-operatives’s market; 3) the Wilson firm paid a large advance on the later years’ shipments, which supplied valuable capital for their activities. In 1924 on the Tianjin wool market 83,000 poods was worth about 1,038,000 Chinese or Mexican silver dollars.69 The combination of the improved security of trade with the south and the cooperative’s monopoly on trade, meant that from 1925 on it could dispense with the services of private firms. At the First Congress of the MPRP in 1924 one delegate asked Tseden-Ishi, ‘What is the reason that the co-op bought several cart-loads of goods from Sonomdorji’s and other companies? Isn't it more expensive than if it bought these things 66 Dashdavaa and Kozlov, Komintern ba Mongol, p. 101. RRIAC, roll no. 184, 893.62222/3, ‘Wool Monopoly in Mongolia’ July 13, 1925, from Consul Samuel Sokobin, p. 9. 68 Alan J.K. Sanders, Mongolia: Politics, Economics, and Society, p. 100. 69 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn dörövdügeer ikh khural, p. 220. 67 from abroad?’ and Tseden-Ishi had to reply, ‘Because there are difficulties in bringing in goods across the southern frontier, we buy them from here.’70 A year later at the Fourth Congress, the delegate Amur, speaking for the co-operatives was able to answer a similar question in a very different way. Q: ‘Does the Mutual-Aid Co-operative buy all the finished goods from foreign cities and other places beyond the frontier or is there anything that it buys from the trading companies here?’ A: ‘The Mutual-Aid Cooperative buys all finished goods from the places where those goods were originally processed [abroad].’ Equally revealing in light of the comments at the Third Congress were the changes in the nationality of the personnel. The representation of Mongols in the staff increased, and efforts were being made to train educated Mongolian personnel. The Mutual-Aid School was separated from the People’s College (Oyutan-u surgaguli), and opened as a separate school on 25 November 1924 with 4 teachers training 25 students on short courses. Over the next five years (1925-1930), the school trained more than 400 students with a programme extended to two years. Graduates included accountants, salesmen, cashiers, as well as buyers in raw materials and coloured skins (‘hunting hairs’).71 For the most advanced students further education was available in Moscow, where ten Mongolian citizens (five native Mongols and five naturalised Buriats) were sent in 1925.72 At the same time however, the number of Russians in managerial positions, about whom the rural delegates had complained most, also increased. The group that saw the most drastic decline was that of naturalised Buriats (who as refugees from the Russian Revolution were politically suspect) and the Chinese, whose combined percentage declined from 19 per cent to 9 per cent.73 The figures on nationality thus show a pattern in which changes in staffing were motivated primarily by political considerations, rather than a desire to respond to the dissatisfaction of the co-operatives’ clients. In 1927 delegate Batutemür repeated continued problems with the employment of Russians both in the co-operatives and the veterinary stations: They say the work of the co-operatives and veterinary stations is not good, and if you study the reason, since there foreigners are common at those stations, when you talk to them, you can’t understand the language. They are unable to improve it like this, and it seems like it is easier for them to call those bosses together, listen to speeches and give directives to implement.74 70 Bügd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar ikh khural, pp. 243 (question), 243-4 (answer). Sh. Nacugdorji [Natsagdorj], ed., Bügüde Nayiramdaqu Monggol Arad Ulus-un soyol-un teüke (1921-1940) (Hailar: Inner Mongolia Cultural Press, 1988), pp. 174, 179. 72 Mongol Ardyn khuvisgalt namyn dörövdügeer ikh khural, pp. 249 (question), 252 (answer). 73 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn döröwdügeer ikh khural, p. 224; Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn V ikh khural, p. 46 74 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn VI Ikh Khural: 1927 ony yesdügeer saryn 22-arawdugaar saryn 5. Delgerengüi tailan. (Ulaanbaatar: State Publishing House, 1980), p. 131. The vagueness of the translation follows that of the original. 71 The changes in the nationality of the co-operative staff matched changes in the direction of trade. Despite the three-year contract with the Wilson firm, Mongolian trade moved steadily north. Without exact figures on the direction of sale of the co-operative goods, it is hard to tell how much of this transfer of trade from China to the Soviet Union was the result of the co-operative's own policy or of the Soviet Stormong company, or both. (Stormong was a state-owned Soviet company created in 1927 specifically to handle the Soviet Union's purchases of raw materials and the sale of finished goods in Mongolia.)75 Yet the shift was clear and steady and presumably reflected the domination of the Mongolian export market by state-owned or state-assisted Soviet and Mongolian organisations. While sources show rather large disagreement on both the absolute numbers and the balance of overall trade circulation, the change in the north-south balance is similar, showing the Soviet share of Mongolia’s exports rising from less than a quarter in 1925 to half or more in 1927.76 The figures are contradictory, however, on whether Tseden-Ishi’s plan of creating a favourable balance of trade by deliberately limiting imports was achieved. Yet after some advances in 1924 and especially 1925, the drive to dominate imports would stabilise at between one-fifth and one-quarter of the market. Not until extreme political pressures were brought to bear in 1929 and 1930 did Mongolia finally decisively turn to the Soviet Union for imports. Soviet and Mongolian sources from the Communist period claim that the stateaffiliated trade organisations achieved their market dominance by out-competing the capitalist firms. In 1927, for example, foreign films sold a pood of sugar for 16.85 tögrögs, while the new Soviet state-owned trading firm Mongolia, Stormong, sold sugar at 12.19 tögrögs per pood. On the other side, 1928, Chinese films paid 20 tögrögs per pood of sheep’s wool, while the remaining American firms paid 22 tögrögs, but the Soviet firms paid 28 tögrögs.77 In evaluating these figures, it must be borne in mind that figures for the Soviet Stormong may not be applicable to the co-operatives. Even if they were, however, the wide fluctuations in prices mean that single figures cannot make a definitive case. Indeed occasional comments at Party Congresses indicate that for the herdsmen, poor service and unfavourable prices continued to limit the appeal of the cooperatives, although there was less and less alternative to them. At the Fourth Congress, rural delegates made the following comments about the co-operatives: A representative: The report of the co-operatives has been very opaque, and moreover due to the situation of the rural branches not being good, there are many instances in which they have not been able to bring 75 Sanders, Mongolia: Politics, Economics and Society, p. 85. Two sets of figures are found in 1) Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn doldugaar ikh khural, p. 17; and 2) N. Ochirbal, BNMAU-yn gadaad khudaldaa p. 22 and Mongol-Zöwlöltiin khariltsaany tüükh, p. 106, 109. By showing trade surpluses in 1923-1925, figures found in Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn V Ikh Khural, p. 43, seem to run against other statements of trade balances, and indeed the editors of the congress minutes note some difference with figures presented in the journal Khoziastvo Mongolii. 77 Shirendev and Gafurov, Mongol-Zöwlöltiin khariltsaany tüükh (Ulaanbaatar, 1981), p. 108. 76 assistance to the people. I suggest we improve this situation as soon as possible. A representative: Since the Mutual Aid Co-ops buy raw materials from the people at a lower price than do the foreign merchants, which should we sell them to? Representative Tsevenjab: As the price of the goods sold by the Chinese who bring them across the Mongolian frontier from Höhhot is cheaper than the price of the goods of the Mongolian Mutual-Aid Co-operatives, I suggest the reasons and conditions behind these instances ought to be closely investigated. The price of goods should be reduced and the number of stores increased so that the co-operatives can develop their assistance to the people, and no longer let them be exploited by the greedy foreign merchants.78 Suggestively, whilst the first two comments, rather neutral in tone, were anonymous, the last, more ideological voice, belonged not to a herdsman but to a 26-year-old soldier in the 4th company of the Khovd border regiment. Subsequent congresses saw repeats of the same comments. At the Fifth Congress in 1926, Navanglubsang, rural delegate from Khan Taishir Mountain (former Zasagtu Khan) Province, was fooled by the favourable report: The report that the co-operative offices and branches are carrying on their business well seems pretty hypocritical. If you look at the co-operative branches now, most of them are really bad, and the trade circulation is basically empty numbers. Moreover when party and league members becomes co-operative members, they do not give them a certificate and there are cases when the money paid in as their share has been completely wasted - that’s just not right, is it?79 Problems with the co-operatives were reflected in the frustratingly slow growth in the number of members. Superficially, the increase in the number of co-operative members would look encouraging: between 1922 and 1927 the membership increased from 116 members to 10,048 members.80 Yet as the figures were reported they were always preceded by a reminder that Mongolia had 80,000 herding households, all of whom ought to be members of the co-op. Clearly the reach of the co-operatives was exceeding its 78 Mongol Ardyn khuvisgalt Namyn dörövdügeer ikh khural, pp. 256, 261. On Tsevenjab (Cyrillic Tseveenjav), see pp. 301, 306. 79 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn V ikh khural, p. 81. On Navanglubsang (Cyrillic Navaanluvsan), see p. 259. 80 Mongol Ardyn Namyn guravdugaar ikh khural, p. 186; Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn dörövdügeer ikh khural, p. 226; Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn V Ikh Khural, p. 46; Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn VI Ikh Khural,p. 64; Bögd Nairamdakh Mongol Ard Ulsyn ankhdugaar Ikh khural, p. 238, 356 n. 118. grasp. The worst problem was the low percentage of party members. Since membership in the co-ops was a way of expressing party and patriotic feeling, refusal to join the coops on the part of party members indicated a strong resistance to participate in what was one of the new regime’s main vehicles for its nationalist aims. Navanglubsang’s criticism showed that just because party members were supposed to join, some co-op managers made no effort to keep them as satisfied members. One question and answer session at the Sixth Party Congress in 1927 revealed some of the leadership’s frustration with this situation: Question: Why are there few party members among the members of the Mongolian Mutual-Aid Co-operative? --No special directive has been issued about having the co-operatives take party members as their members, but all party members enroll as cooperative membership on their own initiative.81 One delegate, Odsürüng, proposed the obvious political solution of simply ordering all party members to join the co-operatives, and having those who were members already increase their shares.82 Another delegate, loyal to the idea behind the co-operatives, pleaded for patience. There are a lot of criticisms about the Mutual-Aid Co-operatives talking about this or that, but the co-operatives’ aim is to carry on wholesale commerce all by itself, and this business was never an easy or simple thing. Now the number of party members among the share-holders in the co-operatives is barely two thousand, which is really few, and the central organs have time and time again done propaganda about this to party members about purchasing shares in the cooperative. Yet when they are so few, it is not right and you could say this fact already is proof that discipline has become slack. It is hard to wipe out all at once all the wrong things about the co-operatives and these goings-on are something that needs to be slowly corrected and reformed from within. Moreover, the Mongolisation of the Mutual-Aid Co-operatives is being held up constantly by the lack of trained cadres among the Mongols who are up to the job, and so they are continually trying to petition the appropriate offices to implement this Mongolisation with due attention to the conditions.83 Indeed short of challenging the co-operative’s fundamental aim of ‘carrying on wholesale commerce all by itself’ those delivering the criticisms could find no real reply to this angry rebuttal. In the final year before the sudden left turn of 1928 made the question of foreign traders in Mongolia irrelevant, party, league, and even labour union members (!) were brought in to increase the numbers in the co-operatives. 1,983 new members were recorded in 1928, of whom more than 1,600 belonged to one of the three above 81 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn VI ikh khural, pp. 86, 87. Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn VI ikh khural, p. 122. 83 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn VI ikh khural, p. 140. 82 mentioned organisations. The report on the People’s Mutual-Aid Co-operatives for the Seventh Congress went through the usual litany of problems: most of the share-holders were party, league, or union members, and those from the ordinary people (engiin ardaas) were extremely few, inspection of the books was lax so there were large losses, many of the managers were untrained and did not know how to buy raw materials or sell good, and so sat in their offices doing nothing, while others caused large losses by mishandling of the goods traded. The solutions were similar to those proposed earlier: encourage the public to join the co-operatives through propaganda disseminated by the party, league, and union members, as well as soldiers. Another suggestion was to found more ‘Red Corners’ and ‘Co-op Clubs’ and use photographs to popularise the co-operatives.84 Ironically, the problems with the Mutual-Aid Co-operatives ended up causing problems for the fledgling herding collectives, started just that year. In 1928, the new regime had established four ‘people’s initial collectives’ (ardyn ankhny khorshoo) near aimag (region) centres, The report to the Seventh Congress however, revealed that these four collectives not only had little participation from the people, but were in fact established and controlled by ‘middle-men traders’ (damyn khudaldaachid), These people had used the name of initial collectives and the offer of start-up capital from the state to carry on trade, The authorities thus had to insist that the new trial collectives were not to try to compete with the co-operatives in trade, but that the two organisations should cooperate.85 Evidently, it was hard to close-off permanently the commercial opportunities left by inefficient operations of the progressively more complete monopoly of the cooperatives. CONCLUSION The conclusion of the story of the monopolisation of the Mongolian economy came in the Left Turn after the Seventh Party Congress in Autumn 1928, The last British and American films were expelled from Mongolia, the Chinese firms reduced to impotence, and although the volume of imports declined dramatically, the Soviet Union finally achieved a dominant position in Mongolia’s import market. Within two years the disaster of collectivisation almost brought the regime to destruction as popular revolts swept much of the north-central part of the country. Yet though the sudden completion of the nationalisation agenda for the economy caused a dramatic economic and political crisis, the fundamental ideology that saw commerce as a matter of patriotism and national strength had been active throughout the 1920s. Indeed this was a continuation of Tsyben Zhamtsarano’s first proposals in embryo under the theocratic regime. The anecdotal evidence from Mongolia strongly suggests that the co-operatives did not replace the foreign merchants by offering less exploitative terms of trade, but only by the application, covertly and overtly, of monopoly privileges. The driving force behind this monopoly was not the herdsmen, but rather the nationalist intelligentsia for 84 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn doldugaar ikh khural: 1928 ony aravdugaar saryn 23-arban khoyordugaar saryn 11 (barimt bichig materialuud) (Ulaanbaatar: State Publishing House, 1980), pp. 71-3. 85 Mongol Ardyn Khuvisgalt Namyn doldugaar ikh khural, pp. 71-72. whom the co-operatives fulfilled a crucial national need. For them, the degraded service and unfavourable prices offered by the co-operatives were a small price to pay for national sovereignty over the economy. Donald Horowitz in his Ethnic Groups in Conflict has written of the Common belief that peasants naturally have an intense dislike of entrepreneurial minorities and a deep desire to escape their grasp. His own survey of the literature found that peasants often were ambivalent about these ethnically alien commercial minorities, appreciating the skilled services they provided and admiring their dedication to profit, at the same time as disdaining their materialism. It was only the nationalist intelligentsia, he found, intensely focused on the future of the nation and convinced that competitive emulation of the more ‘advanced’ countries was the only way out of national extinction, who could conceive both the ambition of wiping out these alien mercantile elements and the concrete plans to achieve them. Judging from the initial research presented here, the Mongolian Mutual-Aid Co-operatives is a case in point. NOTES An earlier version of this paper was presented at the Association for Asian Studies Annual Meeting in San Diego, 9 March 2000. I would like to thank David Sneath for his helpful comments on that earlier draft.