Ideal Answers to Chapter 4 Questions QUESTION 4.1. As shown below, students did seem to be overrepresented at universities whose names included their surnames. This result was significant, 2 (1) = 3.97, p = .047. Because the study only used two names we cannot be sure whether this result was driven by only one name or by both. (We would need at least one additional name, preferably many names, to know exactly which names showed the effect.) University Name Student Surname Brown Lewis Brown University 42 14 Lewis University 9 9 This finding is consistent with implicit egotism, which states that people prefer people, places and things that resemble their own names. We can rule out one form of reverse causality. It’s extremely unlikely that attending Brown or Lewis University made anyone change his or her surname to match the name of the university. QUESTION 4.2. It is possible that these results are the product of a subtle confound. One possible confound is that the results may reflect some kind of “grandfather effect.” If, for whatever reason, a lot of people named Brown settled long ago in the place where Brown university is now located, this preponderance of Browns might have made it more likely that a Brown would become wealthy enough to found a university. If this preponderance still exists and many of Brown’s recruits are regional, this could conceivably generate this kind of name-matching effect. Perhaps more worrisome, if Brown had any grandchildren, or great, great, great grandchildren, it’s likely that many of them would be named Brown, and they’d have quite an advantage at being admitted to Brown. Though less likely it’s also possible that Brown is, on average, a wealthier surname than Lewis. If Brown is also a more expensive or elite university than Lewis, then this is a worrisome confound. QUESTION 4.3.Like the university choice study, the marriage study yielded results consistent with implicit egotism. As shown below, people were more likely to marry other people whose surnames began with the same letter as their own, 2 (1) =4.26, p = .039. Expected frequencies appear in parenthesis. Groom’s Surname Initial Bride’s Maiden Initial C D C 17 (13.2) 9 (12.8) D 10 (13.8) 17 (13.2) Like the first study, these findings are immune to some forms of reverse causality. It’s unlikely, for example, that bride’s changed their maiden names to Cooper after deciding to marry someone named Clarke. QUESTION 4.4. This archival study also suffers from some potential problems. First, although this sample seemed pretty ethnically homogenous, it is possible, in principle, that the letter name matching effects we observed are really some kind of ethnic matching effect in disguise. If Scottish names were more likely to begin with C and German names more likely to start with D, for example, this ethnic matching effect could masquerade as implicit egotism. Second, a few of these couples had the same last name. It’s possible that this was a coding error (if someone erroneously entered a woman’s married name where her maiden name should have gone). Third, it seems unlikely, but is conceivable, that there are SES (socioeconomic status) differences between people whose surnames begin with C and D. SES matching could operate much like ethnic matching. Finally, the study should have included all of the names in the complete set of marriage records. It would be much more impressive (and external validity would be much higher) if we were to see an average name-letter matching effect across all 26 letters of the alphabet rather than merely for two letters. In fact, this effect for only two letters could merely reflect sampling error.