Washington College of Law American University Adjunct Professor: Richard Mosier, Esq. FALL 2015 Antitrust Law (Law-692) 6:00 pm – 7:20 pm MW Updated Syllabus (August 30, 2015) Course Description This course examines Antitrust Law – the law that protects economic freedom and opportunity by promoting free and fair competition in the marketplace. We will focus on the current legal standards – including influential lower court decisions – and government enforcement guidelines, and how those standards and guidelines are used by practitioners and federal enforcers. We will review historic case law to see how the standards have evolved. Topics will include price-fixing, group boycotts, tying arrangements, exclusive dealing, monopolization, and mergers. Casebook Page references below are to Andrew I. Gavil, William E. Kovacic & Jonathan B. Baker, Antitrust Law in Perspective: Cases, Concepts and Problems in Competition Policy (2d ed. 2008). Assigned readings from materials other than the casebook will be posted. Evaluation, Class Participation, and Problems Course grading will be based primarily on a final examination, although class participation will also be considered. Casebook problems that are assigned in the syllabus will be discussed in class. First Assignment Please come to the first class prepared to discuss the assignment for the first class. 1 Assignments by Class Session (Principal Cases Indicated for Reference Only) Class 1: August 24 Introduction to Antitrust Law Chapter 1: 2-17, 40-53 (Andreas (2000), Brunswick (1977), JTC Petroleum (1999)) Appendix A: 1251 (Sherman Act §1 and §2) Background Reading (over the course when convenient): Chapter 1: 56-80 Preparation Questions 1. Who benefitted and who was harmed by the agreement condemned in Andreas? 2. What types of agreements among rivals should be permitted and what types should be prohibited? 3. Why did the Brunswick plaintiff challenge the merger at issue in that case? 4. Why did the Supreme Court in Brunswick decline to allow the plaintiff to pursue its complaint? 5. Who benefitted and who was harmed by the agreement alleged in JTC Petroleum? 6. Why did the appellate panel in JTC Petroleum permit the plaintiff to pursue its complaint? 7. Should antitrust law be concerned equally with collusive and exclusionary anticompetitive effects? 8. What counts as “harm to competition” in antitrust analysis? 9. Are the courts as institutions well-suited for identifying harmful business practices? Class 2: August 26 Agreements Among Rivals: Per Se Rule vs. The Rule of Reason Handout on the Per Se Rule and the Rule of Reason Chapter 2: 88-106, 154-65 (Trans-Missouri Freight (1897), CBOT (1918), Trenton Potteries (1927), Socony (1940), NSPE (1978)) Preparation Questions 1. Did the conduct reviewed in Chicago Board of Trade harm competition? 2. What factors did the Court consider in evaluating the conduct in CBOT? 3. What factors did the Court consider in evaluating the conduct in Trenton Potteries? 4. Did the conduct reviewed in Socony harm competition? 2 5. According to Socony’s footnote 59, what types of evidence can be offered in defense by firms accused of fixing prices? 6. Did the conduct reviewed in NSPE harm competition? 7. What legal rule did the court apply in NSPE? Class 3: August 31 Agreements Among Rivals: Traditional Per Se Categories (Price-fixing, market allocation, and group boycotts) Chapter 2: 107-122, 128-129, 135-153 (BMI (1979), Maricopa (1982), BRG (1990), SCTLA (1990)) Preparation Questions 1. Did the conduct reviewed in BMI harm competition? 2. Was the conduct reviewed in BMI prohibited by the terms of the Socony footnote? 3. Did the Court in BMI evaluate the legality of the conduct by applying the legal rule set forth in NSPE? 4. How did the Court balance concerns about providing guidance to firms and courts, minimizing administrative costs, and minimizing errors? 5. How do the potential harms and benefits of the conduct reviewed in BRG and SCTLA, respectively, compare with price-fixing? 6. How do the legal rules that govern the conduct reviewed in BRG and SCTLA, respectively, compare with the rule applied in BMI? Class 4: September 2 Agreements Among Rivals: Structured Rule of Reason and the Ancillary Restraints Doctrine Chapter 2: 165-171, 175-187, 193 (middle paragraph), 198-211, 213-223 (Addyston Pipe (1899), NCAA (1984), IFD (1986), California Dental (1999), Polygram (2005)) Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors (2000) pp. 30 & 3234 (Ex. 4 & 8), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/04/ftcdojguidelines.pdf Preparation Questions 1. Did the conduct reviewed in NCAA harm competition? 2. What legal rule did the Court employ in NCAA to evaluate the legality of the conduct? 3 3. After NCAA, how are agreements among rivals tested, and when is the rule of reason analysis truncated or structured, or a “quick look” rule applied? 4. Did the conduct reviewed in Polygram harm competition? 5. What approach did the court employ in Polygram to evaluate the legality of the conduct? 6. Was the rule of reason analysis truncated for the same reason in NCAA, Polygram, and the examples in the Competitor Collaboration Guidelines? 7. Are truncated analyses under Sherman §1 better thought of as substantive legal rules (about what facts must be demonstrated as a predicate to liability) or burden shifting rules? No Class: September 7 (Labor Day) Class 5: September 9 Economics and Antitrust Special Guest: Helen Knudsen, Ph.D., Economic Analysis Group, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division Chapter 1: 17-32 Class 6: September 14 Tacit Collusion: Solving Cartel Problems Chapter 3: 227-36, 251-70 (Copperweld (1984), Interstate Circuit (1939), American Tobacco (1946)) Handout on Twombly (2007) and Apple (2015) [Review: Chapter 1: 4-14 (Andreas (2000)] Preparation Questions 1. What economic problems must firms solve to act collectively like a monopolist? 2. What practices help the firms solve those problems, and thus coordinate more effectively? 3. How did the lysine conspirators solve their “cartel problems”? 4. Are the Supreme Court’s information sharing decisions consistent with the modern economic understanding of factors that facilitate or frustrate coordination? 5. Did the conduct of the firms in Interstate Circuit, American Tobacco, Twombly, and Apple likely harm competition? 4 6. When should courts deem parallel conduct among oligopolists an “agreement” and thus subject the firms potentially to liability under Sherman Act §1? 7. If firms that recognize their interdependence can plausibly solve their cartel problems without communication, and raise prices above competitive levels, should a court infer an agreement among them to fix prices? Class 7: September 16 Tacit Collusion: Inferring Agreement Chapter 3: 283-88, 297-301 304-11, 335-37 (Foley (1979)) Handout on Blomkest (2000) Handout on In re Text Messaging (2010) Preparation Questions 1. Based on the facts set forth in Foley, did the realtors solve their “cartel problems,” permitting them to charge commission rates above the competitive level? 2. Why did the Fourth Circuit conclude in Foley that a jury could have found an agreement among the firms to fix prices? 3. What “plus factors” (beyond parallelism) do courts evaluate in determining whether to infer an agreement among rivals from circumstantial evidence? Class 8: September 21 Presentation on the Antitrust Division – Civil and Criminal Enforcement Special Guest: Kristina Srica, Special Assistant to the Directors of Civil and Criminal Enforcement, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division No Class: September 23 (Yom Kippur) Class 9: September 28 Agreements between Firms and their Suppliers or Customers Chapter 4: 352-70, 411 (bottom)-419 (top) (GTE Sylvania (1977), E&L Consulting (2006)) 5 Preparation Questions 1. Did the agreement challenged in GTE Sylvania harm either intrabrand competition or interbrand competition? 2. What kind of facts would tend to show that absent an agreement between manufacturer and dealer to restrict intrabrand competition, dealer free riding would undermine interbrand competition? 3. What legal rule did the Supreme Court apply to decide GTE Sylvania, and how (and why) did that rule vary from the rule previously applied in Schwinn? 4. If the upstream firm is a monopolist, as in E&L Consulting, are (vertical) agreements between that firm and a distributor restricting intrabrand competition always harmful (do they benefit interbrand competition?), always beneficial (is there only a single monopoly profit?), or sometimes harmful? Class 10: September 30 Agreements Between Firms and Their Suppliers or Customers Chapter 4: 370-406 (Leegin (2007)) Preparation Questions 1. How could agreements between a manufacturer and dealer specifying the resale price harm competition? How could they benefit competition? 2. Why did the Leegin majority decline to apply the longstanding rule set forth in Dr. Miles? Why did the dissenters disagree? 3. The Leegin majority observes that in the wake of its decision, courts can devise rules over time for offering proof, or presumptions, to make the rule of reason work effectively. What rules or presumptions would you propose that courts adopt? 4. Suppose a discounting dealer terminated by the manufacturer alleges that its termination was pursuant to a resale price maintenance agreement between the manufacturer and its dealers, and the manufacturer claims that there is no vertical agreement and it is simply adhering to a unilateral policy of not dealing with discounters. What effect could Leegin have on the interpretation of Colgate in such a setting? Class 11: October 5 Mergers Between Rivals: Structural Presumption and Market Concentration Chapter 5: 431-468, (but skip section II, pp. 458-60), 499-507 (Brown Shoe (1962), 6 Philadelphia Nat’l Bank (1963), General Dynamics (1974), Baker Hughes (1990), Heinz (2001)) Appendix A: 1256 (Clayton Act §7) U.S. Dept. of Justice & FTC, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (2010), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg-2010.pdf (read sections corresponding to readings as appropriate for classes 11 to 16 and entire document by class 18) Preparation Questions 1. What legal rule did the Supreme Court establish and apply in Phila. Nat’l Bank? 2. Was the decision in General Dynamics consistent with Philadelphia Nat’l Bank? 3. Was the decision in Baker Hughes consistent with General Dynamics and Philadelphia Nat’ Bank? 4. Was the decision in Heinz consistent with Baker Hughes? 5. What is the significance in market concentration in reviewing a horizontal merger under Clayton Act §7 today? 6. How is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) and the “delta” (change) in the HHI arising from a horizontal merger calculated from market shares, and what is the significance of those figures in the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines? 7. How strongly should courts presume harm to competition from a horizontal merger generating high and increasing market concentration? Class 12: October 7 Mergers Between Rivals: Market Definition and Market Concentration Chapter 5: 474-81, 491-99 Handout on H&R Block (2011) Chapter 7: 875-78 Preparation Questions 1. How did product market definition matter to the outcome of H&R Block? 2. Suppose a court was evaluating the merger of two Washington area firms producing bricks for residential consumption. What evidence, if available, would be relevant to determining whether the relevant product market is bricks (rather than all building materials) and whether the relevant geographic market is Washington, D.C. (rather than a broader midAtlantic region)? 7 3. Why did the court in H&R Block define digital do-it-yourself tax preparation as a product market, excluding assisted tax preparation or pen-and-paper? 4. When, if ever, should markets be defined with reference to targeted buyers (as well as a product and region)? Class 13: October 12 Mergers Between Rivals: Unilateral Competitive Effects Chapter 5: 535-54 (Staples (1997)) Preparation Questions 1. How does market definition matter to the economic analysis of the hypothetical Crunchies-Fruities merger? 2. What did the pricing evidence proffered by the FTC in Staples show about the way that prices varied with the number of office superstore chains in a metropolitan area, both across cites at a given time and over time within a city? 3. Assuming prices are higher in cities served by fewer office superstore chains, would the better explanation be that the firms are exercising market power in such locations or that costs are higher in those cities? 4. In Staples, the FTC alleged a narrow product market defined as consumable office supplies sold through superstores, while the merging firms argued that the transaction should be analyzed within a broader all office supplies product market. What difference did that choice make to the evidence that the FTC proffered or to the FTC’s prospects for litigation success? Class 14: October 14 Mergers Between Rivals: Coordinated Competitive Effects; Efficiencies Chapter 5: 517–35, 548-50 (review), 568-73 (HCA (1986), Staples (1997)) Handout on H&R Block (2011) Preparation Questions 1. How did the factors facilitating or frustrating coordination that we discussed in class 7 influence the analysis in HCA and H&R Block? 2. Why did the merger in each case make a difference to the likelihood or effectiveness of coordination? 3. Did the district court in Staples sufficiently credit the efficiencies claimed by the merging firms? 8 4. Did the district court in Staples analyze efficiencies as part of the evaluation of competitive effects, or as a defense to an otherwise anticompetitive merger? Which approach do the Horizontal Merger Guidelines suggest? 5. Should efficiencies count only in cases in which the presumption of anticompetitive effect based on market concentration barely kicks in, or also operate to rebut the structural presumption when concentration is very high? Class 15: October 19 Mergers Between Rivals: Entry; Powerful Buyers Chapter 5: 458-60 (review), 462-63 (review), 559-64, (Waste Management (1984), Baker Hughes (1990)) Preparation Questions 1. Based on the facts set forth in Waste Management, would entry be expected to counteract or deter any competitive problem from that merger? 2. Based on the facts set forth in Baker Hughes, would entry be expected to counteract or deter any competitive problem from that merger? 3. How does the possibility of entry factor into the legal framework for horizontal merger review set forth in Philadelphia National Bank, once the government has demonstrated that the structural presumption should apply? Does it count only in cases in which the presumption of anticompetitive effect barely kicks in? Does it also count when market concentration is very high? 4. Is the approach of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines to entry analysis consistent with what the courts require? 5. Did the court in Baker Hughes adequately analyze the possibility that the presence of powerful buyers would counteract any harm to competition from merger? Classes 16, 17, and 18: October 21, 26, and 28 Merger Hypothetical Special Guests: Jesús Alvarado-Rivera and Bindi Bhagat, Trial Attorneys, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division Handout: The Soy Milk Hypothetical Class 19: November 2 Single Firm Exclusionary Conduct: Monopolization and Attempt to Monopolize 9 Chapter 5: 490-91 Chapter 6: 582-620 (Lorain Journal (1951), Alcoa (1945)) Appendix A: 1251 (Sherman Act §2) Preparation Questions 1. Did the Lorain Journal’s conduct harm competition? If so, in what market? 2. What market did Alcoa monopolize? Was that market properly defined? 3. Did Alcoa charge a price in excess of the competitive level? Or otherwise exercise market power? 4. Did Alcoa do anything that harmed competition? If so, did it obtain or maintain market power? 5. Should antitrust law insist on proof of anticompetitive conduct beyond mere monopoly pricing before finding monopolization? 6. What, if anything, about market definition would differ if the alleged harm is retrospective (as in Alcoa) rather than prospective (as in H&R Block)? Class 20: November 4 Monopolization: Non-Price Exclusionary Conduct Chapter 6: 620-40, 710 (last three full paragraphs on this page only) (Aspen Skiing (1985)) Preparation Questions 1. What market did Ski Co. monopolize? Was that market properly defined? 2. Did Ski Co. charge a price in excess of the competitive level? Or otherwise exercise market power? 3. Did Ski Co. do anything that harmed competition? If so, did it obtain or maintain market power? 4. On what basis does the court in Alcoa and Aspen distinguish “exclusionary” or “predatory” (non-price) conduct undertaken by a monopolist from conduct that does not constitute a “bad act” sufficient to support a finding of monopolization? Class 21: November 9 Monopolization: Non-Price Exclusionary Conduct Chapter 3: 347-49 Chapter 6: 640-57 (Microsoft (2001)) Chapter 8: 907-15 (Re/Max (1999)) Handout on Blue Cross Blue Shield of Michigan (2010) and Amex (2015) 10 Preparation Questions 1. How were monopoly power and anticompetitive effects demonstrated in Re/Max and Microsoft? 2. On what basis does the D.C. Circuit in Microsoft distinguish “exclusionary” or “predatory” (non-price) conduct undertaken by a monopolist from conduct that does not constitute a “bad act” sufficient to support a finding of monopolization? 3. Should the Justice Department investigate the use of “most favored customer” provisions by dominant health insurers contracting with physician groups or hospitals? Class 22: November 11 Monopolization: Predatory Pricing Chapter 1: 81-86 Chapter 6: 659-73, 675-80 (top), 763-64 (Brooke Group (1993)) Preparation Questions 1. What was Liggett’s theory about how Brown & Williamson’s conduct harmed competition? 2. Based on the facts recounted in Brooke Group, was Liggett’s theory plausible? 3. Does the Court reject Liggett’s recoupment theory on the facts or the law? Taking the facts in a light most favorable to Liggett, was it correct to do so? 4. Treating Brooke Group as though it were an attempted monopolization case, how does the legal rule for proving attempted monopolization through predatory pricing differ from the legal rule that would be applied if the alleged exclusionary conduct did not involve price? Are differences in the rule justified? Class 23: November 16 Monopolization: Non-Price Exclusionary Conduct vs. Predatory Pricing Chapter 6: 680-718, 745-746 (Cascade (2008), Trinko (2004)) Handout on United Regional (2011) Preparation Questions 11 1. Did the bundled discounts offered by PeaceHealth in Cascade harm competition? 2. What standard did the court apply to test whether those discounts constituted predatory conduct sufficient to support a claim of attempted monopolization? The approach applied to predatory pricing? The approach applied to non-price conduct? A third approach? What standard should be applied? 3. What are the pros and cons of applying different standards to evaluate alleged exclusionary conduct in monopolization or attempted monopolization cases depending on the nature of the conduct? 4. What did the Court hold in Trinko? Is the holding limited to settings in which a complex regulatory framework exists to protect competition? To cases brought by private plaintiffs? To cases in which the proposed relief would require a monopolist to supply a rival with a key input or access to the market? 5. How well does the idea of targeting “cheap exclusion” rationalize the holdings of the monopolization cases we have read? Class 24: November 18 Concerted Exclusionary Conduct: Exclusionary Group Boycotts Chapter 7: 765-88 (Northwest Wholesale Stationers (1985), Visa (2003)) Chapter 8: 905-909 Preparation Questions 1. What distinction does the casebook make between exclusionary and collusive group boycotts? 2. Did the conduct challenged in Northwest Wholesale Stationers harm competition? 3. What legal rule did the Court employ to decide Northwest Wholesale Stationers? What additional analysis would be undertaken under an unstructured rule of reason that is not required under that rule? 4. Should it matter to the legality of an exclusionary group boycott whether the boycotting firms possessed a dominant position? Why or why not? 5. Did the conduct challenged in Visa harm competition? 6. What legal rule did the appeals court employ to decide Visa? 7. Could the government have alleged an exclusionary group boycott in Visa? Had it done so, would the court have analyzed the conduct differently? Reached a different result? 12 Class 25: November 23 Concerted Exclusionary Conduct: Tying Chapter 7: 788- 822 (Jefferson Parish (1982), Microsoft (2001)) Preparation Questions 1. Why is the conduct reviewed in Jefferson Parish a tie? How did the court determine whether the seller had conditioned the sale of separate products? 2. Did the tie in Jefferson Parish harm or benefit competition? Through what mechanism? 3. What legal rule did the Court apply to analyze the tying claim in Jefferson Parish? 4. Did the alleged tie in Microsoft harm or benefit competition? 5. What legal rule did the D.C. Circuit employ to analyze the tying claim in Microsoft? How did it justify deviating from the rule applied in Jefferson Parish? 6. Should the D.C. Circuit’s approach to analyzing tying allegations be limited to ties involving platform software? Class 26: November 25 Concerted Exclusionary Conduct: Exclusive Dealing Chapter 7: 823-51 (Jefferson Parish (1984), Omega (1997)) Appendix A: 1254 (Clayton Act §3) Preparation Questions 1. Is the Supreme Court’s approach to analyzing the exclusive dealing claim in Jefferson Parish consistent with the approach employed in Tampa Electric? 2. Would Jefferson Parish have come out differently if the incipiency standard of Clayton Act §3 had been applied? 3. In Omega, did Gilbarco’s conduct harm competition? 4. Did the Omega plaintiff have antitrust injury? Class 27: November 30 Vertical Mergers Chapter 7: 851-73 (top) (Brown Shoe (1962), O’Neill (1987)) Handout on Comcast 13 Preparation Questions 1. Should the court in O’Neill have allowed the plaintiff to obtain discovery on any theories of competitive harm? 2. Are efficiency explanations for vertical integration in O’Neill more plausible than anticompetitive ones? 3. Did the Comcast/NBCU joint venture likely harm competition or benefit competition through its consequences for video programming and video distribution? 4. How does the FCC’s approach to merger review resemble or differ from the way a court would approach the issue? Class 28: December 2 Review 14