PERSONAL NOTES CIRCULATED) ON NEW ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY (NOT TO BE CONCENTRATION OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITY (MAP OF CONCENTRATION OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITY) Economic activity is spatially concentrated. When we draw a map of economic activity in Europe, for instance, what will emerge is a very uneven distribution. There is a vast area comprising most of Germany and France, Netherland, Belgium, northern Italy and south England with a strong presence of industry and services and there is another vast area comprising most of Spain, Southern Italy, Portugal, Greece, the eastern European countries and part of the Scandinavian countries with a much lesser dense presence of industries and services. Economists name “core” the first area and “periphery” the second area. This dualistic division of Europe between core and periphery suggests that economic development is not distributed evenly in space, but that it entails the creation of agglomerations and peripheries. GDP PER CAPITA AT NATIONAL LEVEL (MAP OF GDP PER CAPITA AT NATIONAL LEVEL) Should we worry about concentration of economic activity? Should we worry in particular for the presence of peripheral regions in Europe? The problem is that concentration of economic activity is often associated with strong disparities in income per capita that we take as a proxy for people living standard. Have a look at the map reporting the GDP per capita at national level. You can appreciate that the huge gaps in GDP per capita among national states roughly corresponds to the concentration of economic activity. Where there is a concentration of economic activity, there people enjoy an higher standard of living in terms of consumption possibilities GDP PER CAPITA AT REGIONAL LEVEL (MAP OF GDP PER CAPITA AT REGIONAL LEVEL) A more careful analysis will show of course that the dualistic division between core and periphery is somewhat simplistic. Processes of agglomeration of economic activity do not coincide with national boundaries. There are important differences in the concentration of economic activity both, within the “core” and within the “periphery”. This Map reports the levels of GDP per capita at regional level rather than national level. You can immediately see that inequalities within national states can be very huge indeed. Let consider the Italian case, for instance, where regions fall under five different income brackets. The same is true in Spain where there is a strong divide between northern regions and southern regions. Further in most cases, we find a considerable gap between capital regions (regions where the capital of the state is placed) and other regions of the same nations. This is true for both the more and the less advanced countries of Europe (see Greater London, Ile de France or Warsaw and Prague). Finally, note that, if there were availability of data at sub regional level, we could appreciate significant differences even within each region. Processes of agglomeration do not coincide with regional administrative boundaries either. LABOUR MARKET AT NATIONAL LEVEL ( MAPS ON EMPLOYMENT AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATES AT NATIONAL LEVELS) Differences in income per capita are often associated with differences in the rate of employment, of unemployment, of long term unemployment or of youth unemployment. Peripheral regions in other terms are often at disadvantage not only in terms of consumption possibilities but also in terms of availability of jobs. These two Maps report the data on employment and unemployment rates at national level. You can appreciate a correlation between levels of Gdp per capita, rates of employment and rates of unemployment. Higher Gdp per capita is associated with higher rates of employment and lower rates of unemployment. But note also that this correlation is far from being perfect. Labour markets have strong national specificities so that employment and unemployment rates do not depend only on the level of economic development. LABOUR MARKETS AT REGIONAL LEVEL (MAPS ON EMPLOYMENT AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATES AT REGIONAL LEVELS) Again the same maps at regional level offer you a much more diversified picture of the national labour markets. In many cases regions with high and low rates of employment and high and low rates of unemployment coexist within the national state. An even more accurate analysis would show that peripheral regions are often at disadvantage in other crucial aspects of social and economic life, such as health provision or standards of education. There are of course important exceptions, but generally speaking, we can say that people in the peripheral regions or areas are at disadvantage relatively to people in the core regions or areas. The answer to our question “should we worry about agglomerations” is positive since concentration of economic activity is often associated with inequality of income, of employment and in several dimensions of well-being. CONVERGENCE OR DIVERGENCE? Is there any tendency for these inequalities to reduce over time? If this were the case, we could just rely on the passing of time to see inequalities gradually disappear. The data here do not lead to definite results. Focusing on Europe, there has been in the last decade a narrowing of the gaps in national per capita income relatively to the European average but not in regional per capita income. This implies that economic development in many countries has been very spatially unbalanced. There are nations, specially Eastern European countries, that experimented a process of rapid growth but spatially concentrated, the result being a narrowing of the gap with the rest of Europe at national level but a widening at regional level. THE IMPACT OF THE PRESENT CRISIS The last Table shows the overall rate of growth between 2000 and 2007 and the yearly rates of growth from 2007 to 2013 at national level. They show the process of catching up of several countries in the first part of the decade. They also show that all countries were heavily affected by the global crisis. But also that the strength of this impact has varied a lot for different countries and that also the speed and the strength of the recovery has been different START We have reached four conclusions so far: 1) Economic activity is spatially concentrated 2) The map of economic distribution of activity does not respect national or regional boundaries. Strong gaps can be found both between national states and among regions within each national states 3) These inequalities imply in most cases that people living in the core regions enjoy a standard of living higher than people living in peripheral regions 4) A process of convergence in the last decades can be detected at national level while this is not the case at regional level, where, if any, divergence has increased in most countries. SLIDE 27 FROM FACTS TO THEORIES We now live the facts and turn to the theory. Is there any theory which explains why economic development leads to concentration of economic activity? It is not our aim, not the aim of this course, to undertake a survey of theories of growth and of their implications in terms of balanced development. We know already that there are theories that predict a long run process of convergence and theories on the contrary that provide for inequalities to maintain or even to worsen. We shall focus exclusively on a strand of theoretical thought, known under the name of New Economic Geography, because it has been and still is at the centre of the current debate on agglomeration, on its consequences and on the policies to deal with. I shall focus on the original version of the model disregarding the complex and rich debate that followed the first seminal contribution by Krugman. SLIDE 28 THE NEG GOALS The defining issue of the new economic geography is how to explain the formation of a large variety of economic agglomeration (or concentration) in geographical space. Agglomeration or the clustering of economic activity occurs at many geographical levels and can take different forms. For example, one type of agglomeration arises when small shops and restaurants are clustered in a neighbourhood. Other types of agglomeration can be found in the formation of cities, all having different sizes, ranging from New York to Little Rock; in the emergence of a variety of industrial districts; or in the existence of strong regional disparities within the same country. At the other extreme of the spectrum lies the core-periphery structure of the global economy corresponding to the North-South dualism. A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPROACH The existence and the functioning of agglomerations was of course well known before the advent of the NEG. It was the main object of study by geographers and economic geographers. It was also a central issue for scholars in the fields of economic growth and development, such as Myrdal or Kaldor. They already identified and described the macroeconomic mechanisms which could lead to processes of cumulative causation. The novelty of the Neg is to explain agglomeration within a framework of general equilibrium, that is to explain agglomeration and dispersion within the same model. This entails clear up where the resources of agglomeration come from, what are the main motivations for resources to move and the effects not only on agglomerations but also on periphery. The Neg approach should also allow to analyse simultaneously the centripetal forces that pull economic activity together and the centrifugal forces that push it apart. Indeed, it should allow us to tell stories about how the geographical structure of an economy is shaped by the tension between these forces. And it should explain these forces in terms of more fundamental micro decisions, at firm and worker’s level. SLIDE 29-30-31 THE KEY ASSUMPTIONS OF THE ORIGINARY MODEL A first very simplified model- a core-periphery model- was put forward by Paul Krugman in 1991. The key assumptions of the model are: Positive transport costs. This means that space is important. The world is not flat. For a firm it is not the same thing to sell his products in the home market (the market where the firm is located) and outer markets. To sell in the outer market is more costly. The firm must incur in various additional costs: the cost of shipping, first of all; then various other trade costs linked to legislative or cultural differences between the exporting and the importing regions. This means that the cost of production of selling in the outer market is higher than the cost of production of selling in the home market. This has obvious implications for the location of a firm. When one firm must decide where to open a plant, it must consider the level of transport costs. When the transport costs are very high, it will be very costly for a firm serve outer markets by means of exports. It will be cheaper to open a new plant in the outer market. This means that each market will be served exclusively by firms located in that market. There will be no exports. But if the transport costs are low, it may become realistic for a firm located in Market A, to export also in market B as an alternative to the opening a new plant in market B. Then transport costs matter a lot for the localization choice of a firm Increasing returns to scale and monopolistic competition in the manufacturing sector. This means that the average cost of production diminishes as the level of production increases and that firms located in bigger markets can benefit from economies of scale and incur in an average production cost lower than firms located in smaller markets. For instance, assuming a fixed cost for setting a plant, the average fixed cost will decrease as the size of the market, that is the level of production, increases. This means also that firms have some market power (there is product differentiation ), can fix the price above the marginal cost and have a competitive advantage relatively to firms operating in smaller markets. This matters a lot for the localization choice of a firm. Other things being equal, firms will find convenient to locate in the bigger market, to exploit economies of scale, to produce at a lower average cost and export in smaller markets (home market effect) Factor mobility. A third key hypothesis of the NEG models is factor mobility. To explain localisation choices of firms, we must assume some form of factor mobility. In case of perfect factor immobility, firms and workers could not move, only products would move. Agglomeration could not literally take place. Krugman, in his first version of Neg models assumed that workers in the manufacturing sector were fully mobile while farmers operating in the agricultural sector were perfectly immobile. This implies that if a manufacturing firm moves his location from one place to another, workers will move too. Under these hypotheses, the new economic geography will show how the interaction among increasing returns at the level of the firm, transport costs and factor mobility can cause agglomeration to emerge. SLIDES 31-32-33- 34 A SKETCH OF THE MODEL This is the simplified version of the model Two regions: region A and region B Two sectors: agriculture and manufacturing. Firms and farmers in the agriculture sector cannot move, while firms and workers in the manufacturing sector can. Manufactured goods can be produced in either or both locations. If a given manufactured good is produced in only one location, transportation costs must be incurred to serve the other market. On the other hand if the good is produced in both locations, an additional fixed set up cost is incurred. THREE OPTIONS A manufacturing firm must decide where to locate. It has three options. The first is to open in market A and export in market B; the second is to open in market B and export in market A; the third is to open two plants, one in A and the other in B. The decision will depend on two elements: the size of the market and the transport cost. THE SIZE OF THE MARKET The firm, other things being equal, has the convenience to open the plant in the bigger market for at least two reasons: one, because it exports a smaller fraction of its production, saving on transport costs; the second because it can operate at lower average total costs (increasing returns) and be more competitive on the external market relatively to the other firms. TRANSPORT COSTS The firm however must also consider transport costs. If transport costs are very high, then the option of having one location and export to the other location is unfeasible. Exports would be too expensive relatively to home produced goods. In this case the firm in order to sell its products in the two markets, must open two plants, one in market A and one in market B. If however transport costs are sufficiently low, then the firm may find more convenient to open only one plant in the bigger market and export in the smaller market. We have therefore two forces going in the opposite direction. The size of the market is a centripetal force pushing firms to open plants in the bigger market. The transport cost is a centrifugal force pushing firms to open a plant in each market. CUMULATIVE CAUSATION There is here one thing which is at the hearth of the model. The model is circular. The choice of location of a firm depends on the size of the market but the size of the market depends in turn on the choice of localization of the firms. When a firm decides to locate a plant in one region because the market there is bigger, it will hire new workers, who will move from the other region attracted by the availability of better jobs, by higher wages or by a more diversified market of consumption goods. But the migration of new workers will make the market of that region even bigger because they will represent an increase in demand for firms located in the bigger market (workers spend most of their money in the market where they live) So, a cumulative process starts with new firms entering the big market, new workers moving to the region, the big market becoming even bigger and attracting new firms and new workers …at the end, other things being equal, all manufacturing firms will locate in the big market and will export in the small markets. SLIDE 35-36-37-38-39-40-41 A NUMERICAL EXAMPLE FROM KRUGMAN Let assume that manufacturing labour force in each location is proportional to the share of manufacturing of that location; that demand is strictly proportional to the labour force. Let assume also that total demand of manufacturing is 10 and that labour force in agriculture is 60% of total labour force. Therefore 60% of demand for manufacturing comes from farmers. This is equal to 6 (60% of 10), 3 for each location. The trade cost for unit of production is 1. The cost of setting a new plant is 4. TOTAL DEMAND OF MANUFACTURING: 10= 6 FROM FARMERS + 4 FROM WORKERS DISTRIBUTION OF DEMAND FOR MANUFACTURING WHEN MANUFACTURING PRODUCTION IS PRODUCED IN A IN A: 3 FROM FARMERS LIVING IN A + 4 FROM WORKERS LIVING IN A IN B: 3 FROM FARMERS LIVING IN B ALL DISTRIBUTION OF DEMAND FOR MANUFACTURING WHEN ALL MANUFACTURING PRODUCTION IS PRODUCED IN B IN B: 3 FROM FARMERS LIVING IN B + 4 FROM WORKERS LIVING IN B IN A: 3 FROM FARMERS LIVING IN A DISTRIBUTION OF DEMAND FOR MANUFACTURING WHEN MANUFACTURING PRODUCTION IS EQUALLY SHARED BETWEEN A AND B A=3 FROM FARMERS LIVING IN A +2 FROM WORKERS LIVING IN A B=3 FROM FARMERS LIVING IN B + 2 FROM WORKERS LIVING IN B ALL MANUFACTURING PRODUCTION IN A AND FIRM IN A 4 FIXED COSTS + 3 TRANSPORT COSTS ALL MANUFACTURING PRODUCTION IN A AND FIRM IN B 4 FIXED COSTS + 7 TRANSPORT COSTS ALL MANUFACTURING PRODUCTION IN B AND FIRM IN B 4 FIXED COSTS + 3 TRANSPORT COSTS ALL MANUFACTURING PRODUCTION IN B AND FIRM IN A 4 FIXED COSTS + 7 TRANSPORT COSTS ALL MANUFACTURING IN A AND FIRM BOTH IN A AND B 8 FIXED COSTS ALL MANUFACTURING IN B AND FIRM BOTH IN A AND B 8 FIXED COSTS The final location of firms depends on the initial distribution of production and on the interplay of three parameters. 1) The cost of transport per unit of production (t). For sufficiently high values of this parameter, other things being equal, firms will choose to open two plants. (For instance, starting from Krugman example, if you increase the value from 1 to 1,5, the firm will always choose to open two plants whatever the initial distribution of production) 2) The fixed set up costs (F), that is the relevance of increasing returns to scale. The higher the fixed set up costs, the greater the convenience to concentrate production of manufacturing in only one location, the bigger market. (For instance, starting from the numerical example in Krugman, if you increase fixed costs from 4 to 6, the firm will always choose to concentrate production in only one location, even when the initial production is evenly distributed between the two regions). 3) The share of manufacturing in the total labour force(π). The convenience to concentrate location is higher, the higher is the share of manufacturing (mobile labour force) relatively to the share in agriculture (immobile labour force). The reason of that is straightforward. If the share of immobile population is very high, a firm with only one plant must sustain very high total costs of transports because external demand from farmers is high. In Krugman example this share (π) was 60%. The total cost of transport (t), locating the plant where the entire manufacturing production is concentrated, was t*(1/2) (1- π )*10)= 1(1/2)(1-0,40)*10= 3. If you decrease the share of manufacturing from 40% to 10%, the total transport cost will become 1(1/2)(1-0,90)*10= 4,5. It becomes then convenient to open two plants whatever the initial distribution of production SLIDE 42-43-44-45-46 Conclusions: 1) The choice of location of a firm will depend on the location of other firms 2) Other things being equal, the firm has the convenience to locate in the bigger market to exploit increasing returns and save transport costs. 3) The choice of the firm to locate in the bigger market, will make that market bigger, and a bigger market will attract new firms starting a circular process towards the concentration. 4) Agglomeration is only a possibility. Whether agglomeration will take place or not depends on the relative values of transport costs, fixed costs, share of immobile population. High transport costs and an high share of immobile population are an obstacle for agglomeration while high fixed costs are an incentive for agglomeration 5) There are then multiple equilibria. You can find equilibrium producing manufacturing entirely in West, entirely at East or with two plants both at west and at east 6) You can also appreciate that when t=0 (no transport cost) the solution of one plant is always convenient. The world is flat. Spatial distance is irrelevant and the firm can locate the plant indifferently everywhere. SLIDES 47-48-49 A MORE COMPREHENSIVE VIEW OF CENTRIFUGAL AND CENTRIPETAL FORCES AT WORK The first version of the model put forward by Krugman was organized on the interaction of only two variables: increasing returns and transport costs. It was however clear to the same author that this model was offering an exceedingly simplified description of real processes of economic agglomeration. Several studies by other authors and by Krugman himself, after 1991, contributed to a more realistic and complete account of these processes. It was recognized that various centripetal and centrifugal forces were at play, other than market size and transport cost. Let us introduce and briefly comment these forces. BACKWARD AND FORWARD LINKAGES The original model was assuming that manufacturing firms were using only labour as a factor of production and all were producing consumption goods. In reality however firms use also intermediate inputs as factors of production which are produced by other manufacturing firms. We must think of manufacturing industry as a vertical structure of production in which one or more upstream sectors produce inputs for one or more downstream sectors, while both upstream and downstream producers are subject to increasing returns and transport costs. This means that there are backward (Venables 1996) and forward linkages among producers that tend to concentrate both the upstream and downstream producers in a single location. Why is that? Producers of intermediate goods have an incentive to locate where they have the largest market to exploit increasing returns and save on transport costs, which is where the downstream industry is; and producers of final goods have an incentive to locate where their suppliers are, which is where the upstream industry is located, because they can find their intermediate inputs more easily and more cheaply. The existence of backward and forward linkages act as a centripetal force inducing firms to open plants in the same location. This is the reason why in the real world we observe economic agglomerations specialized in a specific sector, as for instance in the case of Italian industrial districts. MARSHALLIAN EXTERNAL ECONOMIES The first contribution by Krugman focused on economies of scale internal to the single firm. There is however a long tradition of scholars, starting from Marshall, which focused on external economies. External economies are factors external to the single firms and outside of their control, which increase the productivity of the firms and reduce their cost of production. They act on the supply side and not on the demand side. These external factors refer to an industry operating in a specific and limited geographical area. They are then highly specific to that industry and to that territory. Since all firms can benefit from these positive factors and none of them can be excluded from their use, these factors assume the form of a public good (or rather of a club good). Following Marshall description, it is possible to identify three of these factors: specialized providers of industry inputs, thick markets for specialized labour skills, information and knowledge spillovers. Firms operating in an agglomeration can benefit from the availability of a vast range of specialized inputs and a large pool of skilled workers. For instance, a firm operating in the tile industry get important benefits from locating a plant in an industrial district specialized in the tile industry. There, this firm can easily access better and more specialized inputs and better and more skilled workers. On the contrary, a firm, located in an area where there are not other firms operating in the same sector, will encounter difficulties in finding the right inputs and the right workers. This implies that this firm will incur in higher costs or will suffer of a lower productivity. Skilled workers will benefit too from moving to specialized industrial areas. The demand of labour for workers with specific skills in these areas will be greater and more diversified. Firms operating in an agglomeration can also benefit from a more rapid and complete flow of information and of knowledge. Employers and skilled workers have the possibility of a continuous interaction; they can compare their work experiences, discuss problems and solutions, communicate technological novelties on a daily basis. This continuous interaction creates a fertile ground for innovation, in the form of incremental technical progress. A technical progress that does not depend on big technological discoveries but on processes of learning by doing socialized at local level. As Marshall put it: “The mysteries of the trade become no mystery, but are, as it were, in the air.” Note that proximity is important in all three cases. The ability of employers and workers to meet face to face allows a continuous exchange of information and knowledge and facilitates the creation of trust relationships. This reduces transaction costs, costs of collecting information and costs of innovation. OTHER EXTERNAL ECONOMIES Other authors have enlarged the scope of external economies. These are not referred only to properties of industrial clusters but also to features of the context at large. Quality of public services in sectors such as health, education, transport infrastructure, communication network may represent a powerful factor of attraction for firms and workers. The same can be argued for social characteristics such as low level of inequality, good industrial relations, satisfactory level of social integration, endowment of social capital. The same for the quality of institutions, that has always been identified as one of the crucial conditions for development to take place. That of institutions is a very big issue we can only mention here. CENTRIFUGAL FORCES The NEG focused the attention on centripetal forces to explain why agglomeration could result from economic growth. Scholars of this line of thought however are well aware that powerful centrifugal forces are at work alongside the centripetal forces. Agglomeration then takes place when centripetal forces prevail on centrifugal forces. Let examine then the forces pushing for the dispersion of economic activity, let aside of course transport costs, the role of which has been already examined. THE PRICE EFFECT The NEG has emphasized the advantages for the firm of agglomeration. It has however underscored some important drawbacks. The firm that locates in an agglomeration suffers a stiffer competition compared to a firm that locates in a peripheral area with a much less density of economic activity. More competition may imply lower prices and then minor profits for the firm located in an agglomeration. Each time then that a firm move from the small to the big market, we have two effects on its profitability: a market size effect that, as we have seen before, makes the agglomeration more attractive, and a price effect that makes it less attractive. A sufficiently strong price effect may obstacle or even stop the process of territorial concentration. CONGESTION COSTS AND EXTERNAL DISECONOMIES Under the heading “congestion costs” are grouped different factors. Some of these costs refer to inputs. It is well known that concentration of economic activity above a certain threshold may result in an increase of prices of productive factors. The typical example is the price of land that in an agglomeration may be several times higher than in a peripheral area. Other costs may refer to the quality of life. People well-being may be affected in agglomerations by air and noise pollution, traffic congestion, high crime rates, low social cohesion. These phenomena may encourage workers and firms alike to move to less chaotic and safer areas, where the standard of living for some respects is higher. This is what happened in several cities where a part of population moved to outlying areas where prices were lower and the perceived quality of life higher. IMMOBILE FACTORS A powerful factor of dispersion of economic activity is the immobility of factors. The Neg approach is based on the hypothesis of mobility of an important part, at least, of the labour force. This is of course a necessary assumption for agglomeration to take place. The alternative extreme hypothesis of perfect immobility would lead to a distribution of the economic activity roughly in line with that of population. Firms would distribute on the territory in function of consumers’ demand, which in turn would depend on resident population. Generally speaking, the lower is the share of mobile labour force and population, the less is the room for agglomeration processes to occur. Population and labour force are not the only immobile factors of a territory. Natural resources, cultural and architectural heritage, some types of human capital are immobile factors that may represent an important force of dispersion of economic activity. All territories, peripheral areas included, have, to a greater or lesser degree, an endowment of endogenous and not transferable resources, whose exploitation represents a development opportunity. Let us now put it all together. The spatial effect of economic development depends on the balance of centripetal and centrifugal forces. CENTRIPETAL FORCES MARKET SIZE CENTRIFUGAL FORCES TRANSPORT COST BACKWARD AND FORWARD PRICE EFFECT LINKAGES MARSHALLIAN ECONOMIES OF SCALE CONGESTION COSTS AND OTHER DISECONOMIES OF SCALE OTHER EXTERNAL ECONOMIES: IMMOBILE FACTORS institutions, social capital, public goods The final effect of the interplay of these forces cannot be known in advance. Agglomeration is not an inevitable result of growth but it is a concrete possibility, confirmed by empirical data. GEOGRAPHY, ACCIDENTS AND HISTORY IN THE BIRTH, GROWTH AND MANTAINANCE OF AGGLOMERATIONS What factors originally determine the distribution of industry? Why agglomeration in the first place takes place in one region rather than another? The original reasons behind the concentration of economic activity in one region rather than another may depend on several factors. Some of these factors may be linked to the geographical characteristics of the area- such as the presence of a river or of a canal-(New York) or it may be due to a pure accident (Silicon Valley). This is not a topic much investigated by Neg economists. What is really important for NEG economists is that once an agglomeration has taken place, the original factors that historically had produced that agglomeration, may become irrelevant. The advantages of locating in a region today may not depend anymore from the initial advantages but may depend entirely on the advantages of the agglomeration per se. And these advantages tend to persist, that is there is a strong element of path dependency in the choice of economic localization SLIDES 51-52-53 AGGLOMERATION AND EUROPEAN ECONOMIC INTEGRATION Next step is to understand whether the process of European economic integration and the creation of the single market affect the concentration of economic activity or not. European economic integration has different potential effects. Some of these effects are expected to be positive for the whole European Union. POSITIVE EFFECTS OF EUROPEAN INTEGRATION A first expected positive effect is that of specialization. The openness of trade within Europe should push national countries to specialize according to their comparative advantage. The principle of comparative advantage (see below) establishes that the opening of trade will push countries to specialize in the sectors where they have a comparative advantage and increase trade in the sectors where they have not a comparative advantage. For instance, to make a very simplistic example, if one country has a comparative advantage in textiles and another country has a comparative advantage in machinery, the opening of trade between these two countries will push the former country to specialize in textiles, increasing production in textiles and exporting textiles to the latter country and will push the latter country to specialize in machinery increasing production in machinery and exporting machinery to the other country. Standard international trade theory shows that both countries will benefit from trade, that is, they will get after trade more of both goods. (under certain conditions) A second expected result derives from the exploitation of increasing returns. In an enlarged market firms could increase their level of production, get economies of scale and reduce the average cost of production. These efficiency gains would translate in lower prices and a higher real income of consumers. A third expected benefit from integration derives from more competitive markets. The process of integration has been accompanied by measures to make the markets more competitive and more flexible, eliminating monopoly and rent positions and distortions of various kind. More competitive markets lead again to efficiency gains with a reduction of the average costs of production and of prices. Other potential positive effects of integration derive finally from increased flows of knowledge and from an higher mobility of researchers and high skilled workers with positive effects on the speed of technical innovation. SPATIAL EFFECTS OF EUROPEAN INTEGRATION These expected positive effects of integration however refer to Europe as a whole or to national countries. Nothing is said about their spatial distribution. It may well be that an overall gain results from a gain of some regions and a loss of other regions. This will occur if the process of European economic integration leads to a spatial concentration of economic activity, according to a model of agglomeration. Is there any reason why we should expect or at least contemplate the possibility that the integration process leads to concentration of economic activity and therefore to an increase in regional inequalities? The answer is positive. This is so because the process of European integration leads to a lowering of transport costs, to a larger scope for increasing returns and to a greater factor mobility. Lower trade costs, because the integration process and in particular the creation of the single market, have eliminated all sorts of tariff and non tariff barriers to trade. Export and import within Europe has been made much simpler and much cheaper. Further, the huge investment made by the European Union on infrastructure such as roads, motorways, airports have decreased dramatically the cost of transport, strictly speaking. The dramatic enlargement of the size of the market as a result of the integration process has also led to an increase in the scope of increasing returns to scale. Firms have a bigger incentive in the new environment to increase their size and exploit potential increasing returns to scale. Finally, the integration process has also led to a greater mobility of factors of production. The goal of the single market was from the beginning to create a market where not only goods, but also firms, workers and capital could move feely. These three changes induced by the single market, lower transport costs, more scope for increasing returns to scale due to an increase in the overall size of the market and greater factor mobility, favour the process of economic agglomeration. These three changes act as centripetal forces in regard to the localization of economic activity. When transport costs are lower and potential increasing returns are higher, it becomes more advantageous for the firms to localize in the region where the market is bigger rather than to open more plants in various regions, as we have seen in our previous analysis. REGIONAL AND NATIONAL FACTOR MOBILITY This conclusion however must be qualified. This conclusion is much more true for regions and much less true for nations. The reason is that the international mobility of factors of production is much stronger within a country than between different countries. Firms and workers are much more mobile within countries rather than between countries. Agglomeration to take place presupposes mobility of factors of production. This may explain why the integration process ha been accompanied by a narrowing of the income disparities at national level but not at regional level. At national level agglomeration has been hampered by a still weak mobility of factors of production while the greater mobility of factors between regions of the same country has made possible an increase in the spatial concentration of economic activity. SINGLE MARKET, EMU AND COHESION POLICIES The theoretical and potential link between the integration process of the European Union and the agglomeration of economic activity has been historically a strong reason to implement cohesion policies. The launch and the strengthening of the cohesion policies have been always associated with the plans to create and deep the single market and to proceed towards the monetary union. There was the conviction that the single market first and the monetary union afterwards, may produce asymmetric benefits at spatial level. In particular there was the perception of the risk that backwards countries and backwards regions could be damaged by the liberalization and unification of the markets. It was necessary then to implement policies in these regions to remove the structural obstacles which prevented them to get the potential benefits of integration. This was clearly so, for instance, in the approach by Jacques Delors when he launched the single market programme. His approach was not just an approach of simple market liberalisation. On the contrary, the single market and cohesion policies had to go hand in hand. The strengthening of cohesion was presented by the Commission as the sine qua non of the ambitious program of single market in recognition of the potentially damaging effects of the 1992 Programme on the more fragile economies of the Union. The message found intellectual support in two influential reports sponsored by the Commission, the Padoa-Schioppa and Cecchini Reports It is then not a coincidence that in the mid eighties we have the most important process of reform of the cohesion policy. The process starts in 1985 changing the legal basis of cohesion policy through the introduction in the Single Act Treaty of a specific title of Economic and social cohesion. The policy objective of the policy was defined in the Treaty as promoting the “overall harmonious development of the Community and “strengthening economic and social cohesion” The process ends with the reform of 1988 which changes drastically the institutional architecture of the policy and which doubles the financial resources devoted to the policy for the programming period 1988-1993. The reform transforms the policy from a mere redistribution mechanism of resources between member states with no role for the Commission to a genuine regional development tool managed in conjunction by the Commission and by the Member states. And it is not a coincidence that economic and social cohesion becomes a core EU objective on a par with the internal market and EMU in the Maastricht Treaty, that is in the Treaty which contained the road to monetary unification . And that the following year a new reform of the cohesion policy is approved which doubles the endowment of resources for the planning period 1994-1999 and introduces a new instrument of cohesion. The necessity and the possibility of conciliating liberalization of the markets and free competition on one side and social and territorial cohesion on the other hand represents the heart of the so called European social model. The intellectual and political conviction that there is not a trade off between competition and cohesion. The two things on the contrary are, at the very least compatible, and at most complementary.