The Experience of Australia and Kazakhstan in the Mineral Price Boom of 2006-2014. Ian Manning Deputy Director, National Institute of Economic and Industry Research, Australia Abstract Both Australia and Kazakhstan are large in physical area but relatively small in population. Both have extensive mineral deposits complemented by relatively fragile manufacturing sectors. Thanks to high prices for energy minerals and iron ore, the terms of trade of both countries were highly favourable from 2006 to 2014. Australia is well endowed with coal, iron ore and natural gas, all of which fetched high prices during the boom years; Kazakhstan has a similar endowment with the addition of oil. In Australia, the central and state governments have surrendered control over national investment strategy to the private sector and are also, with the exception of the petroleum sector, have foregone the capacity to exact additional revenue from the mining sector during times of high mineral prices. From 2009 high profitability in the sector triggered considerable investment in capacity expansion. Australia’s exchange rate is market-determined and followed the terms of trade, in the short term facilitating mining investment but in the long-term exacting a high cost: its manufacturing and other non-mining trade-exposed industries suffered loss of competitiveness, with a resulting lack of investment and industry closures. The Australian banks also borrowed overseas, and now that the boom has ended the Australian banking system finds itself with high levels of short-term overseas borrowing and very low levels of foreign exchange reserves. By contrast, Kazakhstan’s marketoriented reforms over the past three decades did not surrender broad state control of the pattern of investment. Its government responded to the high mineral prices by concentrating on the oil industry, using negotiated agreements to finance developmental investment and build up an Oil Fund. This allowed control of the exchange rate to give its manufacturing industries the opportunity to upgrade their competitiveness. Royalties on other minerals were maintained at rates which discouraged exploration. The author is much more familiar with the Australian history than with that in Kazakhstan (the two countries are seldom compared) and will seek views as to whether his interpretation of Kazakhstani history is correct. The initial conclusion is that Kazakhstan managed the mineral price boom much more effectively than Australia. Biography Ian Manning is Deputy Director of the National Institute of Economic and Industry Research, a private sector organisation based in Melbourne. Though he has taught in India, worked on macroeconomic strategy for the new government of South Africa in the mid-1990s and conducted investment appraisals for projects in a number of Asian countries his research has chiefly concerned his native Australia. He has worked in regional economics, urban economics, public finance and mineral economics, the latter as an adviser to the Land Councils which represent the interests of Aboriginal people in the Northern Territory of Australia. The Experience of Australia and Kazakhstan in the Mineral Price Boom of 2006-14. Ian Manning Despite striking similarities, Australia and Kazakhstan are seldom compared. This paper first identifies some of the common characteristics of the economies of the two countries, particularly the policy challenge presented by the high mineral prices which prevailed from 2006 to 2014. The paper then contrasts the responses of the two governments. What Australia and Kazakhstan have in Common In physical size, Australia is the world’s largest country without land borders while Kazakhstan is its largest landlocked country. Though Kazakhstan has but one-third the land area of Australia, the two countries have roughly similar populations (a little either side of 20 million) and both comprise a flat, arid core (desert, savannah, steppe) fringed (at least to the north and south) by better-watered country. Both have high ratios of mineral reserves to population and in both mineral resources contribute strongly to both exports and GDP but account for a relatively small proportion of total employment. In both countries the range of mineral resources includes coal, metal ores and hydrocarbons, but Kazakhstan is relatively rich in liquid petroleum resources and is able to export oil by pipeline; Australia is less than self-sufficient in liquid petroleum and though it has surplus production of gas, export requires the shipping of LNG. Despite the current prominence of mineral exports, both countries have diversified economies. Kazakhstan inherited significant manufacturing industries from the USSR. Some of these, notably defence industries, had a limited future under the new dispensation, while the rest required redevelopment to meet the challenge of competition from outside the Commonwealth of Independent States. Its trade-exposed industries also include pastoral production, broad-acre cropping and a small amount of specialised cropping, though it has yet to exploit its advantage as the country where apples originated. Australia used tariff protection to develop its manufacturing industries during most of the 20th Century but in the 1980s and 1990s realised that the domestic market was too small to support competitive scale; it was therefore obliged to redevelop its manufacturing sector and integrate it into the global economy. Like Kazakhstan its trade-exposed industries include pastoral production, broad-acre cropping and specialised cropping in addition to manufacturing, but unlike Kazakhstan it also exports services, notably tourism and education. Though GDP per capita in Kazakhstan is around one-fifth of that in Australia the industry structure of the two economies is sufficiently similar to make comparison of economic performance interesting. However, the two countries are seldom compared and few people are familiar with the circumstances of both. In the present case, I am far more familiar with Australia than with Kazakhstan and my references to the latter are necessarily tentative. Comparison is particularly instructive over the last decade. From 2006 to 2014 both countries experienced a substantial though temporary improvement in the terms of trade due mainly to booming international prices of their various minerals. Given its endowment, Kazakhstan has particular exposure to the price of oil and condensate but also benefits from high prices for coal, iron ore, chrome, manganese, uranium, base metals and bauxite. Australia’s major exposures are to the prices of iron ore and coal, but it also benefits from high prices for LNG, manganese, uranium, base metals and bauxite. Thanks to its less diversified export base, dominated by minerals, the boom in the terms of trade was more marked for Kazakhstan than it was for Australia – from an index value of 100 in 2000, the terms of trade of both countries peaked in 2011, reaching 234 in Kazakhstan and 200 in Australia. As resource price booms go this was of considerable amplitude and was also unusually long-lived. What caused this? Characteristics of the mining industry Several characteristics of the world mining/petroleum industry are relevant (we will treat this as one industry though there is little overlap between companies involved in petroleum and those primarily mining metal ores, with some overlap in coal). The industry is technology-intensive and capitalintensive. Except in the case of scavenging operations it generates few jobs for every million dollars invested or for every million dollars of value added. Much of the capital-intensity is due to the costs of mineral exploration, though production is also highly mechanised. Not only is mining capital-intensive; the industry likes to claim that it should be rewarded with high average profitability to compensate for high levels of risk. Mineral exploration is necessarily a chancy business, though scientific methods have improved the odds and exploration risk also varies considerably across mining industries, being much lower for coal and iron ore than for base or precious metals. Even when the deposits are found and developed risks remain, since deposits vary in quality and in the certainty with which reserves can be estimated. The treatment of risk divides the mining sector into three main types of business. First, there are small high-risk operators chiefly engaged in exploration but sometimes extending into mine operations, generally financed by people with a high appetite for risk. Second, there are large multi-national corporations which manage risk by maintaining a varied portfolio of mining tenements and also by accumulating technical expertise. Finally, national mining companies maintain asset portfolios confined within their country of ownership and aim to extract profits for the owning country. In Kazakhstan, to my limited knowledge, the mining sector consists of a mixture of national mining companies and multi-national operators. Compared to Australia, small businesses seem to be absent. Business types include corporations directly owned by the state, corporations indirectly owned by the state via its Samruk-Kazyna Sovereign Wealth Fund, joint ventures between these state-owned corporations and a multi-national mining company, and multi-national mining corporations operating in their own right. The need for high-order technical expertise in Kazakhstan’s oil and gas industry has seen joint ventures proliferate in the petroleum sector, including some in which the national interest is in a distinct minority. The Australian mining industry is dominated by multi-national corporations. However, Australia also has a tradition of fostering small mining companies, particularly speculative ventures in mineral exploration. Because of the large scale required for successful oil and gas exploration and the relatively small exploration component of iron ore and coal production, these small companies were less involved in the 2006-14 boom than they were in its predecessors based on base metals or gold, though the boom provided an opportunity for some of the ‘junior miners’ to become producers. By contrast with Kazakhstan, there is a complete absence of government equity participation in the industry, though each state government is deeply involved in the administration of mining tenements and maintains a geological survey, including a public archive of past exploration results. In both Kazakhstan and Australia sub-soil mineral resources are the property of the state (in Australia literally so – Australia is a federation with a central and state governments, and mineral resources belong to the states). In Australia this generates three-way conflicts of interest between governments, the mining companies and the users of the land surface. The mining companies seek unfettered access to mineral deposits, surface users sometimes oppose such access and, when access is granted, seek compensation and a guarantee against environmental degradation, while the states adjudicate these competing interests and also seek compensation for the sale of their sub-soil assets. In general, Australian mining law grants miners access to deposits subject to environmental guarantees and the payment to the state of a small proportion of the value of minerals produced – effectively a resource price. During the recent boom a proposed increase in this price was withdrawn after a well-resourced political campaign. The increase would have involved the collection of resources rents by the central government in addition to state resource prices. In Kazakhstan conflict over the sale price of minerals mined has been avoided by state ownership. However, potential conflicts arise when national mining companies seek the expertise of multinational miners, typically through joint ventures. The industry’s sensitivity over land access issues derives from the importance, for profitability, of low-cost access to quality mineral deposits. Compared with manufacturing, services or even agriculture, the industry has very limited capacity to raise profitability by engaging in product differentiation; it sells standard commodities. Further, it cannot browbeat its customers, who are in general manufacturers, many of which have substantial financial clout and the capacity to integrate backwards into mining should the mining specialists charge too much. Profitability accordingly depends on cost control, best achieved by mining high-quality deposits. In Australia the industry and the state governments bargain over the terms and conditions of access to deposits; in Kazakhstan bargaining is more likely to be concentrated on the formation of joint ventures. Ultimately the bargaining power of the state parties, as owners of unexploited resources, depends on their willingness to leave their minerals in the ground; hence the necessity for mining companies to offer such benefits as employment and local incomes. Needless to say the bargaining can be intense and in Australia at least there has been evidence of corruption. Despite the industry’s attempts to regulate supply, it has been unable to establish stable prices. A price increase such as that recently experienced begins with unanticipated demand. Prices rise, and the industry initially attempts to cash in by moving stocks and working mines at capacity. These are periods of high profitability for the established miners. A recognition lag ensues during with both established and would-be miners contemplate investing in capacity expansion. This lag was unusually long during the recent episode because the 2008 American crash dampened expectations of demand, particularly in Western capitals. The boom was also unusual in that expanded supply of the priceboom minerals – iron ore, coal and even oil – did not require major exploration expenditure; instead it required major investment in extraction and product transport. The investment phase of the boom lasted half a decade and was marked by optimistic forecasts of continuing demand. Eventually these investments raised supply capacity while several factors dampened demand prospects, including the effects of fracking on oil supply, a change in the pattern of Chinese economic growth and worries about the contribution of coal to global warming. The boom is now slumping towards the normal conclusion of mineral booms – expanded production at prices which are profitable for low-cost producers but which cause the closure of high-cost operations, including the more speculative of the investments made during the boom. When mineral prices rise, old hands in the industry expect prices to return to ‘normal’ and perhaps over-correct. They are accordingly cautious when considering capacity expansion, but two other factors favour investment: enhanced profits raise cash flow and allow capacity expansion to be funded from internal sources, and established mining companies can be anxious to protect market share. In Australia at least, the investment boom was further fuelled by new entrants to the industry and by small, high-risk companies anxious to gain substance. Many of these investors, including perhaps a majority of those who sank resources into mine expansion, expected that prices would fall but plateau at a level rather above that prevailing before the boom took off. High mineral prices also raise questions for governments. Governments are in as good a position as mining company executives to know that mineral price booms are generally temporary. Whatever the shortcomings of their royalty and taxation arrangements, they can expect a revenue windfall, with the amount of the windfall depending on the extent to which past bargaining has placed them in a profitsharing position with the miners. Prudent uses for the revenue thus received will emphasise strengthening the public balance sheet, which can be done in various ways – paying down debt, accumulating financial assets and accumulating infrastructure assets being the most widely recommended. Prudence would also direct support to the industries temporarily eclipsed by the mining boom, but which will be required to carry the national economy once the mining boom is over. Imprudent uses for the revenue will include investing it in ways which heighten the boom (for example, supporting marginal capacity expansion in mining) and, even worse, spending it on consumption, either directly on current government services or indirectly through cuts in general taxation. The Australian response Whatever prudence might dictate, as soon as the boom begins to elicit significant investment and construction activity increases, governments have perforce to respond. In Australia the investments generated by the recent mining boom took place in mainly in regions more than a thousand kilometres from the nearest metropolitan area, though activity in coal mining increased in one region close to a city which could supply former industrial workers to work in construction. Similarly Kazakhstan’s oil industry is located mainly in the west of the country, well removed from major population centres though with an inheritance of Soviet-era oil towns. In both countries, accordingly, the mining boom had distinct geographic aspects. In a market economy like Australia the primary mechanisms for transferring construction industry resources to the booming region are prices – high wages and high returns for capital employed in construction. These high wages and high returns add to the windfall profits generated by high mineral prices and can easily result in increases in aggregate demand which run beyond economic capacity, so resulting in demand inflation. However, this did not eventuate in the recent Australian experience, for several reasons. First, many mining industry inputs, such as diesel fuel, are sourced overseas, and the industry itself is substantially overseas-owned so much of its windfall profit went straight back overseas. Again, much of its investment demand was spent overseas buying construction materials and mining equipment. However, the industry contributed directly to domestic demand for labour, and here lay a potential contribution to demand inflation. Price incentives indeed play an important role in mining industry labour recruitment. The industry and its construction contractors pay high wages, not only to attract workers to remote locations but to compensate for the industry’s lack of commitment to training and in exchange for strict observance of employment conditions. The geographic effect of these policies is spread by fly-in fly-out labour contracts, which combine 12-hour shifts on site and off-duty periods at residential locations generally far removed from the mine. Australia also has a propensity to address perceived labour shortages by overseas recruitment, which is perceived to be cheaper than domestic training. Immigration, onerous working conditions and fly-in fly-out minimised the pressure to extend the high wages paid in mining to labour generally and in general the wage-increasing effects of the mining boom were confined to the mining regions. Though the confinement of mining-related wage increases to the mining regions (admittedly with some flow-through to the fly-in fly-out source areas) helped to limit the inflationary effects of the boom, this does not explain why the increase in incomes did not generate inflation. One reason was that much of the Australian economy – many regions, many industries – was not operating at full employment and could increase output readily without any increase in costs. A second reason was the behaviour of the exchange rate. Since the adoption of American-style free market policies in the 1980s, Australia has charged its Reserve Bank with manipulating the official interest rate so that consumer price inflation remains in the 2-3 per cent range. Faced with an increase in demand due to enhanced incomes resulting from the mining boom, the Reserve Bank maintained a significant positive differential between its interest rates and those of the major Western economies, so encouraging an inflow of funds, chiefly short-term deposits with Australian banks. The result was an increase in the exchange value of the Australian dollar, which in 2012 rose to the point where the market rate against the US dollar was 1.55 times the purchasing power parity rate. The resulting reduction in the prices of imported consumers’ goods ensured that the Reserve Bank met its consumer price index target. Unfortunately this strategy for avoiding consumer price inflation had two costs – the effect on nonmining trade-exposed industries and the effect on the national balance sheet. Australia’s non-mining trade-exposed industries include agriculture, manufacturing and services. Australian agriculture is accustomed to variable profitability brought about both by adverse seasons and by fluctuating world prices. To this extent it was better prepared than the other trade-exposed industries for the adverse effects of the over-valued exchange rate on its competitiveness. On the other hand, it lost the opportunity to rebuild financially after the prolonged drought which overlapped with the mining boom, and was also deprived of funds to invest in product differentiation and marketing. The effect of the over-valued exchange rate on Australia’s major service exports – tourism and education – was more direct. Sales fell and in tourism at least personnel and assets were underutilised. However, these two industries can be expected to recover as their price-competitiveness is restored. In the early 1990s Australia reduced tariff protection for manufacturing industries and substituted various forms of industry modernisation plan. The effects included closure of much of the textile, clothing and footwear industry balanced by modest prosperity for most other manufacturing industries. However, from 1996 onwards the central government withdrew from industry modernisation, making it harder for domestic manufacturers to develop export markets and to meet import competition. As the Australian dollar became over-valued, the central government backed away from industry assistance even in the established forms of expenditure on industry-related education and infrastructure. The resulting squeeze on industry profitability was all the more serious since it lasted for five or six years and so exceeded the capacity of manufacturing industries to rideout short term adversity. It has (at best) reduced industry investment due to constrained cash flow and (at worst) brought about industry closures. Unlike tourism, the industries so closed are unlikely to reopen, since they depend on specialist skills and product development which are difficult to recover once lost. Not only did the Reserve Bank’s high exchange rate policy impose serious costs on the non-mining trade-exposed industries, it had more direct effects on the financial side of the national balance sheet. The chief of these arose because it encouraged the trading banks to borrow overseas. The banks proceeded to on-lend these funds to the household sector chiefly as mortgages. The conventional wisdom is that funds borrowed from overseas should be invested in enterprises which generate overseas earnings with which to repay the loans, but in this case trade-exposed businesses had little appetite for borrowing owing to their constrained profitability while the mining sector either financed itself or was overseas financed. Some of these bank loans to households financed urban residential extension, though the pace of extension was limited by lack of public investment to maintain accessibility. Other loans, either directly or via the purchase of established properties leading to land price inflation (which is not included in consumer price inflation) brought on a burst of debt-financed, import-satisfied consumption. The most that can be said is that the government used prudential controls of the finance sector to curb the proliferation of sub-prime loans and derivatives which so destabilise the American finance system. Compounding the problem, the central government deemed the increase in revenue which resulted from the mining boom to be permanent and granted tax cuts, chiefly to the wealthy. To be fair it collected enough tax and controlled expenditure sufficiently to maintain a public sector surplus and made a half-hearted attempt to accumulate financial assets (officially as a superannuation fund for public servants). It also increased its level of infrastructure investment, though not sufficiently to overcome the backlog which had been accumulating since the privatisation of the public utilities in the 1990s. These fiscal responses did little to counterbalance the Reserve Bank’s policies and probably, on balance, intensified their effect on debt accumulation. The household sector became heavily indebted to the banks (at least relative to income) and the banks became heavily indebted to overseas lenders (at least relative to export earnings). In real assets, therefore, over the mining boom Australia gained mining capacity and urban extensions, but lost investment in manufacturing and also, less seriously perhaps, in its other tradeexposed non-mining industries. In financial structure, it became exposed to the availability of shortterm international finance. Counterfactuals are always problematic, but it is at least arguable that Australia as a whole would have been better off without the mining boom, or at least that the nonmining regions would have been better off, the more so as lost opportunities in manufacturing continue to accumulate and the results of mining investments continue to disappoint. Australia has recently had a reputation for astute economic management – it avoided both the 1998 Asian financial crisis and the 2007 global financial crisis. Its governments, as distinct from its finance sector, are not heavily indebted. With the limited range of policy instruments it allows itself, the government could certainly have done worse in its management of the mining boom. It could also have done better – it could have forgone tax cuts and spent more on industry modernisation; it could have applied stronger prudential controls to inhibit bank overseas borrowing, though by limiting the increase in the exchange rate this may have imperilled achievement of the inflation target. This highlights Australia’s lack of means to control inflation other than interest rates. Australia still has the remains of a centralised wage-bargaining system, but has never succeeded in developing incomes policies to control inflation due to excess income claims – hence the targeting of interest rates on inflation rather than on industry competitiveness and hence, perhaps, the failure to derive lasting benefit from the high mineral prices of 2006-12. Kazakhstan’s response As noted above, from 2003 to 2011 Kazakhstan experienced an improvement in its terms of trade which was even more marked than that for Australia. (In both countries there was a single-year decline in 2009 but in both the peak came in 2011.) However, it was not all easy going. In Kazakhstan the downward blip in the terms of trade between 2008 and 2009 induced a rather violent financial reaction. As in Australia, the banking sector had been supporting the property market with mortgage loans, resulting in a construction boom and increasing housing prices. Unlike Australia, where the 2009 downturn in the terms of trade was disconnected from housing prices by a government stimulus package, in Kazakhstan the downturn was rapidly transmitted into house prices and hence into the stability of bank balance sheets. However, the Kazakhstan government was able to make use of its very substantial reserves of foreign exchange (the result of prudent administration of its oil revenues) to stabilise the economy and renegotiate the terms of borrowing to take advantage of the general decline in world interest rates. The stock of overseas debt continued to grow, but the debt service ratio peaked at 58 per cent of export earnings in 2010 but fell to 35 per cent in 2011 despite a small further increase in debt outstanding. During the first part of the mineral price boom, the years to 2007, Kazakhstan’s gross national income per capita expanded by 10 per cent a year or more, but the financial troubles saw the rate fall back to 1.5 per cent in 2008. With confidence improving as the terms of trade continued favourable, the rate increased, returning to nearly 10 per cent in 2013. However the terms of trade are now definitely in decline, the rate has again fallen and the government is once again taking reserves out of the stabilisation fund. By contrast with Australia, with its Reserve Bank steadily pursuing low consumer price inflation, the first part of the mining boom was associated with significant inflation – around 21 per cent in 2006 and again in 2008 (IMF GDP deflator). The events of 2008 brought this sharply back to 5 per cent in 2009, with a quick recovery to nearly 20 per cent in 2010 from which it subsided to 9 per cent in 2014. It is likely that the terms of trade had a major influence on these movements. Thanks to its substantial foreign exchange reserves, Kazakhstan has been able to maintain a managed float of the tenge. Given the divergence of exchange rate trends among Kazakhstan’s major trading partners, the appropriate value for the currency must be much debated – the value considered appropriate for industries closely linked to Russia is likely to diverge from the value considered appropriate for industries linked to China or Germany. The policy seems to have been to maintain a gentle appreciation of the real value of the tenge, resulting in the IMF implied purchasing power parity exchange rate inflating each year by less than the GDP deflator. The difference was least in the crisis year of 2008 – less than one percentage point – but in the early boom years 2005-07 approached 4 percentage points. This modest appreciation contrasts strongly with the high exchange rates experienced in Australia. With significant capture of the windfall gain in the terms of trade by the state, not least through its sovereign wealth fund, Kazakhstan was able to raise gross capital formation to 35 per cent of GDP at the peak of the boom. This has favoured industrial growth, as has the maintenance of a reasonably competitive exchange rate, and high technology exports have increased as a proportion of manufactured exports. However, the Kazakhstan government has been criticised by the World Bank for its failure to encourage multi-national mining companies to developing its non-petroleum mineral reserves. The Bank follows mining industry practice in characterising royalties as a tax rather than as the sale price of state-owned resources and argues that Kazakhstan has set its non-petroleum mineral resource prices too high to attract overseas investment. The contrary argument is that, despite high prices for produced minerals, competition between resource-selling nations has resulted in mining of metallic minerals generating such low resource rents that, in Kazakhstan’s case, the minerals are best left in the ground, at least for as long as the petroleum industry yields a satisfactory flow of export revenue. Conclusion We have argued that loss of capital stock in the non-mining trade-exposed industries due to overvaluation of the exchange rate has meant that Australia would probably have been better off had its terms of trade remained steady from 2003. It would be difficult to apply the same reasoning to Kazakhstan, where despite inflation and a financial crisis, the exchange rate has been kept under control and the boom in the terms of trade has been used to enhance the national capital stock. Notes on sources For greater detail on the account of the Australian economy in this paper see the National Institute of Economic and Industry Research State of the Regions reports, published annually by the Australian Local Government Association. The account of Kazakhstan is drawn mainly from IMF and World Bank sources, including the World Bank paper ‘Comparative Study of the Mining Tax Regime for Mineral Exploitation in Kazakhstan’, 2014.