INB 311 India and China Dr. Lairson 9/9/14 Ideas, interests, and the tipping point: Economic change in India Rahul Mukherji Major questions: Why and how did India engage in economic reform in 1991 and not earlier? How did this model of state-led, import-substituting industrialization become transformed into an economic order that stressed deregulation and globalization? Why did India make changes to its established economic policies as a result of the 1991 events? What are the special features of the India Case? India’s transition to globalization and deregulation is a saga of a government promoting institutions that facilitated competitive markets within a democratic polity while powerful social actors opposed these changes. The literature on developmental states had not been optimistic about India’s growth potential, because the country did not possess the wherewithal of a ‘hard state’ with an authoritarian leadership that could deal decisively with powerful social actors (Evans, 1995; Chhibber, 2003; Kohli, 2004). India was characterized as a relatively soft state where the dominant political coalition of industrialists, farmers, and the powerful professional middle class was deeply interested in perpetuating a state- led, import-substituting model of development. Why did India choose reform in 1991 and not in 1966 The answer to this puzzle lies in the way that ideas about deregulation and globalization evolved within the Indian state – especially among the country’s technocrats, who were evaluating the results of different developmental outcomes. The gradual evolution of liberal ideas and policies brought India to a tipping point in 1991, when a balance of payments crisis provided an excellent window of opportunity for India’s distinguished technocrats and economists to deal decisively with parts of the dominant electoral coalition at the time of a foreign exchange shock. The tipping point constituted a moment when economic ideas and policies that had been evolving since the mid-1970s had begun undermining state-led import substitution quite significantly. Comparing the 1966 and 1991 decisions: 1966: When Indian politicians and technocrats were unconvinced about the need for globalization and deregulation in the 1960s, they only made a tactical retreat toward reform, then perpetuated the country’s most stringently autarkic institutions after 1969. During the country’s balance of payments shock of 1991, on the other hand, technocrats were convinced about the need for a more liberal approach after having experimented gradual policy change during the 1980s. Consequently, they exploited India’s dependence on the IMF to deal with parts of the country’s dominant electoral coalition, making virtue of the necessity of an IMF loan and its attendant conditions. Had the technocrats dithered or been unconvinced about the fruits of internal and external deregulation during the 1991 crisis, the Indian story would likely have played out very differently. Moreover, the 1991 reforms were a home-grown initiative rather than an IMF-driven approach, at a time when the IMF seemed concerned about the political durability of economic reforms in a democratic polity such as India. Were the 1991 decisions a result of capture or pressure from business elites in India? Did the business class or the middle class capture the state and force it to deregulate and globalize economic policy (Pederson, 2000; Kohli, 2012)? This paper clearly demonstrates that Indian industry was comfortable with gradual internal deregulation, but did not push towards either promoting substantial internal competition or global competitiveness. The captains of Indian industry were comfortable deriving monopoly rents from the country’s over- regulated economy. The state had to persuade parts of professional Indian industry in 1991, and nudge them towards accepting deregulation and globalization when they were hesitant to do so. Therefore the reforms of 1991 cannot be derived from what has been termed as the ‘pro-business’ orientation of the government in the 1980s (Kohli, 2012). Indian industry acquiesced to the government in 1991 when it had few options, as it was heavily dependent on the IMF for financing the imports that sustained the import-substitution industrialization system in India. The 1966 crisis: In spite of a very severe foreign exchange crisis brought on by increasing defense spending from the 1962 war with China and the 1965 war with Pakistan, and the role of foreign exchange in obtaining critically needed food imports, the Indian government in 1966 resisted the broad policy demands of the US and the World Bank. The US pushed India toward substantial deregulation and adoption of a policy of export promotion, The World Bank agreed, pushing India to o devaluation of the rupee; (2) the removal of direct controls on the importation of intermediate goods; (3) population control; and (4) increased investment in agriculture. The Indian government at the time – under Indira Gandhi – had a strong preference for socialist-communist positions. These included self-reliance and hostility to global capitalism. This led to substantial resistance to policies preferred by the US and WB from many parts of the Congress Party. Import dependent businesses also opposed the devaluation. Devaluation was done out of necessity but nothing else – indeed India became more regulatory in the years after and its economy less effective. The 1991 crisis and decisions These events were affected by the gradual changes in ideas and policies after 1975 which reached a tipping point in 1991. These idea and policy changes were supported by small changes in the preferences of the dominant governing coalition – about 20% of the population. The politics of institutional change in India during non-crisis periods demonstrates why parts of the country’s dominant political coalition, such as the industrial class and the farmers, permitted limited deregulation during the 1980s. The dominant coalition comprising about 20 per cent of the population became quite influential in the 1980s. Indian industrialists wanted the state to protect their monopoly rights, lavish them with subsidies and also impose fewer restrictions on them. Farmers demanded subsidies, assured prices and cheap loans but were unwilling to be taxed. The professional middle class sought cheap higher education, better salaries and lower taxes. Those working for the government enjoyed their regulatory powers. The economy was thus locked in an equilibrium characterized by limited loosening of state controls for domestic investors and protectionism The technocrats’ preparation for change during the 1980s was essential, and the mood within the technocracy was quite different in 1991 than it was in 1966. The gradual preparation for change since the mid-1970s is critical for understanding the power of the tipping point model for India. Indian technocrats’ preference for state-led industrialization began to wane in the 1970s, owing to the country’s dismal rates of economic growth at a time when various sections of society were clamoring for more subsidies. The country’s technocrats began focusing on five policy issues: (1) the management of publicly owned enterprises; (2) deregulation of domestic investment; (3) import liberalization; (4) export promotion; and (5) promoting foreign investment. Gradual industrial deregulation became noticeable when Indira Gandhi became prime minister for the second time in 1980. This process accelerated gradually after 1984 when her son Rajiv Gandhi assumed premiership and continued up until 1991. 1991 events In October 1990, the credit rating agency Moody’s downgraded India’s credit rating, pointing to an unsustainable rise in the country’s debt-service ratio, increased exposure to commercial borrowing, the impact of the Gulf War, and a ballooning budget deficit. Non-resident Indians began withdrawing their deposits and India had to pledge gold in return for hard currency to import essential items. India was two weeks away from a default on its debt payments when P.V. Narasimha Rao was selected prime minister of India by the ruling Congress Party, which had formed a coalition government in June 1991. Only one month earlier, former PM Rajiv Gandhi had been assassinated. Many changes in the world had pushed Indian leaders in the dominant classes to rethink their views: The collapse of the Soviet Union Modest reform in the 1980s Economic success in East Asia A balance of payments crisis at this juncture necessitated a fundamental reshaping of India’s economic and foreign policies. Manmohan Singh, one India’s most experienced technocrat economists, was chosen to deal with the crisis as finance minister. A group of Indian economists with significant ties to global economic liberalism were deeply involved in making policy. These leaders were determined to break the hold of “state-led autarkic industrialization.” Curb government spending to support SOEs Increase competition in the Indian economy Expand foreign investment, but restrict this to FDI and NOT portfolio investment or foreign debt Export promotion over import substitution Near elimination of industrial licensing Eliminate controls on production location and quantities for large firms Resistance to these policies was significant and from powerful sources, including the Indian capitalists and most political parties. But the success of the policies in increasing the rate of growth helped to convince some of the benefits of globalization and liberalization. However, policies providing subsidies and support to business and agriculture continued and even expanded. This resulted in a large and persistent budget deficit and exposed India to potential crisis. India had become very dependent on global finance for its economic survival. Explaining India’s policy changes: We posit a theory of slow moving gradual ideational and policy change based on the puzzles posed by previous policies and the international demonstration effect of Asia. Slow economic growth till the mid-1970s, the fiscal unsustainability of autarkic pro-business liberalization in the 1980s and developments in Asia and Soviet Union pointed the policy elite towards the need for embracing deregulation and globalization. This ideational tip- ping point was the necessary condition that enabled technocrats to exploit the balance of payments crisis in 1991 to produce significant economic change in India. When Indian technocrats were not prepared for economic policy changes that occurred during the 1960s, IMF pressure was not able to bend the institutions and policies of import substitution in India. India’s executive technocratic team favoring globalization and deregulation in 1991 had to deal with the country’s politics. The paper demonstrates the centrality of a crisis in negotiating far reaching institutional change in a soft state with a powerful dominant coalition of industrialists, farmers and professional middle class. The team had to negotiate both with the IMF and domestic constituencies to chart a politically and ideationally secure path towards a silent revolution. Indian industry had to be nudged toward reform by the technocrats, and the IMF needed to be convinced that areas of divergence between New Delhi and Washington would not derail the reform program. In addition India would not reform its labor laws or re- duce fertilizer subsidies, due to the political power of organized labor and the farmer’s lobby, respectively. India’s fiscal deficit was also allowed to grow after the first year of stabilization, which was not in accordance with the IMF’s preferences. Mukherji, R. (2009) ‘Interests, Wireless Technology and Institutional Change: From Government Monopoly to Regulated Competition in Indian Telecommunications’, The Journal of Asian Studies, 68(2): 491–517. Mukherji, R. (2007) ‘Economic Transition in a Plural Polity: India’, in R. Mukherji (eds) India’s Economic Transition, New Delhi: Oxford University Press, pp. 117–45. Why has China grown so fast? Mobilize capital and invest in market-enhancing infrastructure How did the investment process work? Lieberthal, Managing the China Challenge How do we understand how the Chinese system works? Using western or American assumptions about politics and economics won’t work All people want to be free and eliminate government restraints All people hate the government and want it to go away Government leaders only want to make more money for themselves What kinds of ideas have Chinese developed to direct their efforts to respond to the West after the 1840s? Develop uniquely Chinese ideas and reject the West Adopt western technology but reject western ideas Adopt western ideas and technology completely – nothing Chinese is sacred What are Chinese attitudes toward the West today? Page 6 How Does China Work? Chinese Communist Party – monopoly of political power Party Congress Central Committee Politiburo Standing Committee of Politiburo Xi Jinping General Secretary of the CCP and Chairman of the Central Military Commission Li Keqiang Premier and head of the State Council Party and Government at all levels – the party-state CCP 75 million Leninist in origin and operation Nomenklatura system – appointment of top leaders at next lower level Important national policies Policy and implementation Centralized? Flexible? Totalitarian? Authoritarian? What are the major themes and directions of Chinese policy today? Achieve wealth and power, security and prominence for the nation Pragmatism, trial and error, experimentation 1) Preservation of Communist Party rule at all costs 2) Expand and deepen the social safety net 3) Existing economic strategy – labor intensive, light manufacturing based on FDI – must be changed to continue Chinese growth 4) Develop global technological leadership through indigenous innovation such as green technologies 5) Expand modern urban areas inward What are the specific actions China is taking? Restructuring of the Chinese economy. The list is long and daunting: Agriculture Local manufacturing TVEs SOEs and restructuring Accommodation of domestic private firms Creating domestic markets and linking these markets to global prices and markets Integrating global firms into the Chinese economy Shifting large labor pools into eastern SEZs for global production Urbanization o Reduce and eliminate the hukou system Massive infrastructure investment on a national scale Infrastructure upgrading for global production networks Value chain upgrading Global standards for Education and Human Resource upgrading WTO accession changes to business practices and laws Layers of the Chinese state Center Province Municipality County Township The “DEAL” that defines the relationships of the levels of the party-state Fundamentally hierarchical – above directs below but allows considerable latitude to interpret specifics Support initiative and even entrepreneurialism to achieve broad policy goals Leaders of the party-state at all levels have a direct stake in the success of policy and economy Advancement increases the benefits of the system to leaders Local leaders make most appointments at their level Local leaders control local banks, courts and administrative agencies Wide latitude to act entrepreneurially to achieve economic growth Large role for market forces that provide incentives, information and constraints to entrepreneurs Deep and complex party-state relations to firms at a micro and local level: land, licenses, capital, regulations, purchasing decisions, ownership All business in China – foreign and domestic - is deeply connected to the party-state Success within the party-state is a result of developing leaders who can creatively and effectively promote economic growth at a micro-level Demonstrated entrepreneurial talent is the criteria for achievement and advancement in the party-state Local official are deeply connected to the business enterprises in their area, high significant autonomy and operate as active and important partners in promoting business success Consensus building across various lines of authority as decision-making system: at least 2 key players required to move an initiative forward The CCP and the party-state is a dynamic, flexible, decentralized and internally competitive organization The party-state is organized to promote economic growth Problems with the party-state system Local protectionism Fragments markets Undermines achievement of economies of scale Poor intellectual property protectionism Long tradition of copying the best model Knockoffs Owners of best model want protection and profits Dangers from fake drugs, milk Corruption Can corruption support economic growth? Investment and infrastructure bias – local officials love new roads, buildings, fancy bridges Misallocates investment Lack of central government control Environmental protection Lack of an effective social safety net Retirement Health care Major challenges to the Chinese system Political coherence – Bo Xilai Managing the effects of rapid change Resource shortages and environmental destruction Water – 38, 40 The United States as supporter of or opponent of China’s growth? China must manage its relationship to the US and Europe to preserve a favorable international environment. Economic outcomes in China are a result of a relationship among the party state, state and private (domestic and foreign) firms and domestic and global market forces. Structure and Operation of the Party-State System The basic arrangement of General Secretary as most powerful actor combined with a top governmental official as chief executive (premier, governor, mayor, county head) operates throughout the nation at all levels. A system of ranks defines the power relationships among the various units of the party-state – including party, government, SOE, media organization, publishing company, school, research institute, hospital, museum. These ranks are not published but are not secret. Units cannot issue orders to another unit at the same or higher rank. There are unusual ranks that affect power relationships: Provinces have the same rank as ministries in Beijing, which means ministers cannot issue order to provinces. Only the Communist Party – which stands above the highest governmental body, the State Council - can command the military. The Minister of Defense does not command the military. Many large SOEs have the same rank as ministries and many others have a higher rank than the government of their city In addition to the system of ranks, the effect of reforms has been to empower territorial governments to control their own specialized agencies. Occasionally, the central government has altered this relationship when excessive localism has developed. It is very important to ascertain the nature of the power relationship: leadership relationship (lingdao quanxi) versus professional relationship (yewu guanxi). The outcomes of the system are a product of the relationships among the division of labor system, the ranking system and the leadership/professional system. Not all decision at the national level have the same operational implications: o Orders – must be implemented precisely o Instructions – develop a plan that considers local considerations o Circulars – the issue is of concern but do not require operational decisions o Opinions – suggest thinking at the top but without decision The consequence of the system of ranks, in combination with the various layers of government and party, results in a substantial distribution and even fragmentation of power in China. The system of power in China is far less centralized than most westerners realize. Local officials have considerable leeway on many issues of national policy as along as they do not directly contradict this policy. Policy is stated and defined in general terms and can be implemented based on local conditions. This means decisions on substantial business operations require a consensus across different jurisdictions and no one person can command such a consensus. Higherlevel official typically expect lower levels to work out a decision. This can frequently mean a determined opponent can veto a decision. Laws and regulations can vary considerably across different jurisdictions. Decision latitude for one level is a negotiated arrangement with the next highest level. There is a lot of play in the system. Lieberthal provides advice to TNCs operating in China. Government relations are a strategic issue in China. Governments at all levels must be seen as differentiated and complex Understand the complex network of government-business relations - 107 Products that qualify for indigenous innovation: mean and effect of the catalogue How Chinese reach conclusions about dealings with foreigners – 64 Understand the policy directions of the nation and make proposals that conform to these directions Develop plans to take advantage of the urbanization of 2nd and 3rd tier cities Local market research Chinese market is highly segmented Expect much lower price points for products Good enough products Decentralize product development to local units What are the political risks associated with China? Will the CCP be overthrown? What is the nature of political unrest in China? How does the Chinese government affect the choices on FDI? Can foreign firms participate in the creation of regulations that affect their operations? Disputes in China are negotiated and are not settled in a rules-based or laws-based setting. 85-86 Resolve versus win Costs of going to court to enforce contracts against firms with important political supporters What are the political risks associated with making corrupt payments? Milkmaids Foreign corrupts practices Reputation for operating without corruption Effects of US-China relations Tiananmen Square consequences Trade conflict on solar power panels Managing issues of product safety and quality across supply chains Ethical choices – 93-95 Cyber risks Taxis in Shanghai – microphones Large and sophisticated systems of penetrating corporate information systems