A FREE MARKET IN KIDNEYS? by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute According to recent reports, the black market value of a kidney which can be transplanted is some $13,000 -- which translates to roughly seven times its weight in gold. Such an occurrence may occasion all sorts of references to King Midas -- who was supposed to have been turned into a statue of sold gold, but behind this rather dramatic way of characterizing the value of human organs lies in a story of untold and tragic human suffering. There are hundreds and even thousands of Canadians whose lives could be vastly improved could they but have the use of a healthy kidney. Paradoxically, there are other thousands of people who die each year, taking perfectly healthy kidneys to the grave with them, who have no financialincentive at all to bequeath these organs to those in need. Why, it may well be asked, cannot potential donors presently be given a pecuniary reward for doing the right thing? That is, what precludes a businessman from purchasing the future rights to a kidney from potential donors, and then selling these items to those suffering from kidney disease? The problem is, it is illegal to harness marketplace incentives in order to encourage kidney donors. Anyone who set up a business of this sort would be summarily imprisoned. Instead, our society must resort to all sort of inefficient stratagems toward this end. Famous personages have exhorted us, in the event that we suffer untimely death, to make a posthumous gift of these organs. Medical schools coach their students on the best techniques for approaching next-of-kin; the difficulty is that they must ask permission at the precise time when they are least likely to be given it -- upon the sudden demise of a loved one. As a result, all of this has been to little avail. While potential recipients languish on painful kidney dialysis machines waiting ghoulishly for a traffic fatality which may spell life for them, the public has refused to sign cards in sufficient numbers giving permission for automatic posthumous donor status. Things have even come to such a pass that there are grotesque and fascistic plans now being bruited about which would allow the government to seize the kidneys of accident victims unless they have signed cards denying such permission. The free enterprise system, were it allowed to be operated in this instance, might well be a God-send to the unfortunates who suffer from diseased kidneys. A legalized marketplace could encourage thousands of donors. Would you sign a card donating your kidney after death for 13,000 big ones, right now, in cold hard cash? There are very few people who would turn up their noses at such an offer. And if sufficient supplies were still not forthcoming at this level, prices would rise even further until all demand was satisfied. Given free enterprise incentives, pardon the pun, we would be up to our armpits in kidneys. Nor is there any danger that prices would rise so high as to out of the reach of those in need. For one thing, transplantable organs are now very difficult to attain for sufferers. For another, any incipient price rise would be met by an increase in the amount supplied, and this would tend to moderate the upward movement. This is the tried and true process we rely on to bring us all the other necessities of life: food, clothing and shelter. After all, we do not depend for the provision of these goods and services on voluntary donations. We know this to be a relatively unreliable system -notwithstanding the fact that it is flogged by numerous opinion leaders in the case of organ transplants. There is no doubt whatsoever that those presently responsible for preventing a free market in kidneys take these actions with the noblest of motives. To them, legalizing the purchase and sale of human organs would be the ultimate in degradation. Far better, from their viewpoint, that people donate their bodily parts for free so that thousands of kidney disease sufferers may live normal lives. However, no matter how benevolent the intentions of the prohibitionists, it cannot be denied that the effect of their ill-conceived actions is to render it less likely that those in need shall be served. It is time, it is long past time, for our society to put aside its archaic and prejudicial opposition to the marketplace, so that we can relieve the suffering, and in many cases, lift the death sentence we have inadvertently placed on as hopeless and hapless a group of citizens as ever existed. - 30 THE FRASER INSTITUTE 626 Bute Street, Vancouver, B.C. Canada V6E 3M1 (604)688-0221 HAVING IT ALL BY HELEN GURLEY BROWN An Editorial by Walter BlockSenior Economist, The Fraser Institute I recently read a book, Having It All by Helen Gurley Brown. I thought it was just filled to the brim with wise and witty advice. I enjoyed it immensely. However, there was one jarring sentence which detracted from, as far as I am concerned, an otherwise marvelous book. I refer to financial advice given to young women. "On the other hand, owning an apartment or house can protect you from greedy, rent-raising landlords if the rental market is tight" (page 349, pocketbook edition). As I see things, this is a very unsavory way of looking at the world, very much akin, I fear, to racism: "greedy profiteering Jews," "vI Ibus" conniving, price-raising Scottish businessmen," "price-gouging Orientals" come all too readily to mind. This sort of prejudice, it seems to me, has no place in an otherwise magnificent book. Moreover, this advice is inconsistent and hypocritical. Helen Gurley Brown recommends a whole host of financial strategies (and source materials) which aim to maximize interest returns on savings. But she advocates that her readers put their hard-earned savings into savings banks, stocks, bonds, etc., which offer the highest possible returns. Using the "logic" behind her "greedy, rent-raising landlords" remark, however, could not those who follow this financial advice be open to the charge "greedy, interest-maximizing investors?" But matters are even worse. For what if a reader buys a "property in a good neighbourhood," as advocated by Brown, such as a condominium, and then sublets it, for some reason -2or other. Should this person accept the lowest rent offered? Hardly. But if the highest rent offered is taken, such a person is guilty of being the very "greedy, rent-raising landlord" which Brown condemns. Whatever else can it be supposed that "greedy rent-raising landlords" do, apart from seeking out offers, and accepting the best one made them? And the same analysis applies to the reader who seeks a raise, as Brown advises, elsewhere in the book. For surely, such a person is no better than a "greedy, wage-raising employee." This view of landlords is akin to bigotry, and mars an otherwise very enjoyable book-- Having It All by Helen Gurley Brown. -30 Alberta Economic Policyby Walter Block Alberta Premier Peter Lougheed held a press conference the other day, to announce broad changes in his government's economic policy. Unfortunately for the people in that western province, the new policy is aimed in the direction of increased public sector intervention into the economy. To this end, the new plan calls for more government ownership of resource and development projects, a new provincial personal tax collection system, a greater government involvement in transportation and cargo container ventures, expansion of Provincial Treasury Branches (an Alberta government-owned bank), an industrial strategy of supporting high-technology winners and ignoring the weaker sisters, and a protectionistic "buy Alberta" policy for government construction projects. The main reason this will harm the economic prospects of Albertans, by extension, all Canadians, is that government is simply less capable a manager of commercial enterprise than is the private sector. And the explanation for this state of affairs is simple. In the marketplace, entrepreneurs are continually tested by profits and losses. If they make correct entrepreneurial decisions, they can prosper and expand the scope of their operations. If they fail to provide the goods and services most desired by consumers, and in the cheapest manner possible, they are forced to change the error of their ways. Failing that, they must lose money, and eventually go bankrupt. In the civil service, in contrast, there are no profit and loss incentives. Worse, rewards are sometimes given for inefficiency, for example for spending an entire year's budget, or for amassing more employees. Peter Lougheed would do well to reconsider his flirtation with misguided and discredited centralized economic planning. He could do worse than to begin by reading a new Fraser Institute publication called Focus on Alberta's Industrial and Science Strategy Proposals. -30B.C. Lions by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The British Columbia Social Credit government is at it again. Talking up the market system out of one side of its mouth, while violating its most basic premises on the other. One instance of this politically schizophrenic behaviour was its recent decision to raise the adult minimum wade from $3.65 to $4.00 per hour -- after publicly musing that they might eliminate it entirely, which would have been the only position compatible with the full free enterprise philosophy. And now comes news that the Socreds are going to bat for the financially troubled B.C. Lions football team. "We have made a commitment to assist. We want to see the sport and the league kept alive" said a prominent spokesman. This person considers the Lions a "worthwhile investment" and waxed eloquent about the importance of Grey Cup, which brings some $20 million to the economy of Vancouver. But if the Lions are such a worthwhile investment, why are they wallowing in a sea of red ink? Further, why don't some of the B.C. Ministers put some of their own money where their mouths are? Why are they threatening to force all the taxpayers, in effect, to underwrite their own personal entrepreneurial instincts? There is, after all, no guarantee that the B.C. Lions or the entire CFL for that matter is a viable economic enterprise. Such information is not given to us from on high, engraven on stone tablets. This business decision is necessarily a risky one, like all others. And even if this assessment is correct, there is still nojustification for government intervention. The free enterprise system is incompatible with public sector investment in~an commercial business concern, profitable or not. If the Social Credit government wishes to live up to its self-styled adherence to market principles, the sooner it leaves off this soviet-style central economic planning and control, the better. As for that pie-in-the-sky $20 million in "spill-over benefits," maybe they will come true and maybe they won't. In either case, however, the citizens and taxpayers of B.C. are likely to be losers. For what this calculation ignores is alternatives foregone. Suppose, for argument's sake, that without the B.C. bailout the Grey Cup would evaporate, and that with it an additional $20 million would indeed accrue to local Vancouver coffers. It does not follow, however, that this would be a good investment. For suppose that instead of subsidizing the B.C. Lions, the taxpayers were allowed to keep their own monies. Then, perhaps, they would spend them on toasters and lawn-mowers and VCRs and canoes and 1001 other such consumer items. Although it might be harder to trace, there would be reverberations, throughout the economy, of these expenditures. In total, they may even amount to more than the Grey Cup's million. In any case we know from the fact that consumers voluntarily spend their hard earned money on this array of consumer goods, that they value them even more highly than saving the B.C. Lions. Otherwise it would not have been necessary to forcibly divert the funds from the one use to the other. If the Socreds really want to promote the public good, they can best do so by leaving commercial decisions of this sort to the voluntary choices of the citizenry; and by acting on free enterprise principles, not merely giving them lip service. As well, one of the reasons for the decline of the CFL is the government-imposed limitation on the number of foreign players allowed on a team. If government wanted to help the sport, it could do so -- legitimately -- by ending this protectionist restriction. - 30 - A break for Big Apple beggars-Part II The lower-court Judge Sand ruled it would indeed be an abuse of the free-speech rights of these sometimes violent beggars to prohibit them from "doing their thing." Happily for the longsuffering mass-transit riders, Judge Altimari of the appeals court reversed him; holding that the rights of passengers to be safe must be "balanced" against the right of people to beg. According -to this balancing doctrine, safety considerations must sometimes be curtailed in favour of free speech. But without any balancing, there is danger that this doctrine will be reduced to arbitrariness. In our analysis, there cannot be a real conflict between rights. It only appears as if there is because of a lack of private-property rights. We argue that if the New York subway system were privatized, the conflict would disappear. Consider the following: A cleanshaven man dressed in a three-piece suit with five $100 bills in his wallet (which the Transit Authority cashier refuses to change) but coins amounting to 10 cents less than the required exact subway fare asks passersby to give him a dime. Or, a well-dressed elderly woman whose purse has just been stolen begs people for subway fare. According to Altimari's Second Circuit ruling, both of these people should be penalized. No matter how welldressed and benign they appear, they are still begging. Nonsense. If this determination is not a violation of their free-speech rights, nothing is. But if we are to be consistent, the same principle should apply to dishevelled smelly people whose panhandling takes on a threatening manner. They too have free-speech rights. Forbidding people to speak in public thoroughfares such as subway stations is a denial of their free-speech rights, plain and simple. If, however, the subway system were private property-as private as a bedroom-then the solution would follow simply and directly. The owner 'would have the right to determine the behaviour of his customers, while they are on or about his property . Just as restaurateurs now have the'right to expel unruly or inebriated patrons or people who refuse to wear shoes or a shirt (or in the finer eating establishments, business attire), so would the private subway firm have a right to exclude unkempt beggars. Free-speech rights would not even enter the picture, as people can have such rights only on their own property, not on premises belonging to others. Imagine if you will, a competitive subway industry consisting of several firms. It may be difficult to do, since people are accustomed to state-owned mass-transit monopolies. As it happens, the New York subway was built by private enterprise; the Brooklyn-Manhattan Transit Co. (BMT) and the Interborough Rapid Transit Co. (IRT) were taken over by the city only after severe governmental price controls made it impossible for them to operate. Under privatization, these firms would compete not only on price, service, cleanliness, safety, reliability and speed, but also on the basis of their antisolicitation rules. Some might welcome beggars with open arms. Others might forbid panhandling entirely. Still others might set up special facilities to deal with the problem of the well-dressed man or the victimized woman. There might even be "begging zones" on some premises similar to smoking areas in restaurants. Then, the people would speak, their voices clearly articulated through the intermediation of the profitand-loss market system. The presumption is that firms that strictly proscribe begging would prevail. If so, the commonsensical results desired by Altimari, and haughtily deprecated by Sand, will have been achieved. But this will be accomplished without the irrational fiction that basic rights conflict with each other. Why is it of practical importance that the subway be privatized, whether in New York or anywhere else? Apart from improved safety and operation,there are important legal precedents at stake. A similar analysis may be applied to leafletting in private malls, begging in restaurants, and the imposition of dress codes. In all cases, it is possible that authorities will try to "balance" rights, one against the other. If they do, we will substitute socialism for private-property rights. Judges will become central planners. The way to resolve the conflicts between free-speech and other rights is to determine where the confrontation takes place. If it is public property. privatize it. This is the second of a two-part series devoted to analyzing a lawsuit that has arisen concerning the freespeecb rights of panhandlers in the New York City subway system. Dr. Block is an economist with the Fraser Institute. BRITISH COLUMBtA REPORT, FEBRUARY 11, 1991 21 Begging in the Big Apple: Part II by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute This is the second in a two part series devoted to analysing a law suit which has arisen in New York concerning the free speech rights of panhandlers in that city's subway system. The lower court Judge Sand had ruled that it would indeed be an abuse of these of times violent beggar's free speech rights to prohibit them from doing their thing. Happily for the long suffering mass transit riders, Judge Altimari of the Appeals Courts reversed him, holding that the rights of passengers to be safe must be "balanced" against the right of people to beg. According to this balancing doctrine, sometimes safety considerations should be curtailed in favour of free speech, and sometimes the reverse should obtain. But without any balancing criterion, there is danger that this doctrine will reduce to arbitrariness. In our analysis, there cannot be a real conflict between rights. It only appears as if there is, because of a lack of private property rights. We are arguing that if the New York City subway system were privatized, the seeming conflict would disappear. Consider the following case. A clean shaven man dressed in a three piece suit with five one hundred dollar bills in his wallet (which the Transit Authority cashier refuses to change) and coins amounting to ten cents less than the required subway fare, asks passersby to give him a dime. Or better yet, a well dressed elderly woman whose purse has just been stolen begs people to give her the fare needed for entry into the subway. According to Altimari's Second Circuit ruling, both of these people should be penalized by law. No matter how well dressed and non threatening, they are still engaged in begging. What arrant nonsense. If this determination is not a violation of their free speech rights, then nothing is. Still others might set up special facilities to deal with the problem of the well dressed man, or the victimized woman. There might even be ''begging zones" set up on some premises, similar to "smoking zones" now established in many restaurants. Then, the people would speak, their voices clearly articulated through the intermediation of the profit and loss market system. The presumption is that firms which strictly proscribe begging would prevail in the competitive struggle. If so, the common sensical results desired by Altimari, and haughtily deprecated by Sand, will have been achieved. But this will be accomplished without the irrational fiction that basic rights can conflict with one another. Why is it of practical importance that the subway be privatized, whether in New York City or anywhere else? Apart from the increased safety and well functioning of the system, there are important legal precedents at issue. For a similar analyis may be applied to leafletting in private malls, begging in restaurants, and the private imposition of dress codes. In all of these cases, it is possible that the authorities will try to "balance" rights, one against the other. If they do, we will substitute the socialist system that brought down the Soviet Union for the private property rights one responsible for the success of our own. Judges will become the central planners. The way to resolve all seeming conflicts between free speech and other rights is to determine on whose property is the confrontation taking place. If it is public property, privatize it. - 30- BILLBOARD DEFACING by Walter Block There is a band of urban guerillas now active in Australia. No, they don't set fires, nor bomb innocent bystanders. They are even admired by respectable elements of society and treated with kid gloves by government authorities. What they do is spray-paint anti-smoking graffiti messages on billboard advertising. Everyone, it seems, who is anyone, is doing it. For example, consider Dr. Arthur Chesterfield-Evans, a 33-year-old surgeon with a practice in Sydney. He defaced a billboard slogan advertising a higher quality cigarette. Before his "surgery," the billboard read, "Darling, let's move up and save money." After the ministrations of the good doctor, it said, "Darling, let's give up smoking and save money!" At his trial, our man of medicine testified that his sloganeering would save more lives than any surgery he could perform on victims of tobacco. And, to add insult to injury, one Simon Chapman, a New South Wales state health department official, testified, in defending Dr. Graffiti, that such billboard advertising encourages children to smoke. As a result, Dr. Chesterfield-Evans was let off with a nominal fine. Why, they have even got an organization behind this effort. Not only is our medical friend a member of the Non-Smokers Movement of Australia, he is also an activist in BUGA-UP (I kid you not!) which stands for Billboard Utilizing Graffitists Against Unhealthy Promotion. Amazing what they do down under. Now hold on, just one cotton-picking minute! What is at stake here is no less than the sanctity of private property. And I say that, knowing full-well the howls of derision that are likely to emanate from some quarters as a response to such a statement. At issue is the right of consenting adults to be. informed, through billboard advertising, about a desired product. If anti-smoking vigilantes are allowed to deface property, shall we next have groups of vegetarians pillaging butcher shops? Of health fanatics ransacking candy stores and bakeries? Such violence, once unleashed, knows no political barriers. Also vulnerable are groups and organizations beloved of the trendy marxists. What about the spectre of enraged right-wingers attacking co-op food store advertising or intefering with day-care centres or gay bars? No. Let's not open that particular Pandora's box. Let's respect all private property rights, especially of those with whom we disagree. As for BUGA-UP, let them rent their own billboards and place antismoking messages on them. In a free society, with the sanctity of private property, they have a right to do just that. - 30 THE FRASER INSTITUTE 626 Bute Street, Vancouver, B.C. Canada V6E 3M1 (604)688-0221 BLOOD SHORTAGE An Editorial by Walter BlockSenior Economist, The Fraser Institute This may not bother most people reading this article but there is a recurring blood shortage in western Canada. Of course the vampires in the community are apt to be upset, and the Transylvanians can't be too happy either. But for most people, as I say, this is no big deal. Well, if that's your reaction, you are sadly mistaken. I fear you are seriously underestimating the importance of this problem. The Red Cross blood transfusion service thinks enough of this crisis to schedule emergency blood donor clinics. According to Dr. Terry Stout, medical director of the Red Cross, these clinics are needed to deal with the worst shortage of type 0-positive blood in 25 years. Responsible for this problem, in the view of Rick O'Brien, another Red Cross spokesman, is a combination of too few type-O donors at blood clinics, and heavy orders from hospitals. What is going on here? Has the marketplace failed? According to basic economic theory, if there is a shortage of something, then the price ought to rise, as unsatisfied demanders bid more and more, in an attempt to gain some of the limited amount for themselves. And, at the higher price, more care is supposed to be taken to preserve the stocks on hand, and suppliers are presumably encouraged to provide more of the good in question. And if there still is not enough supplied, then price is supposed to rise to such heights so that enough of the item will be supplied. So why isn't this process working? How can we have a serious blood shortage, with the much-vaunted price system working in our behalf? The answer, of course, is that we have outlawed the market system for things like blood transfusions. It has been thought that matters such a this are far too important to leave to the marketplace. That no one should profit on the misery of others. That it is somehow dirty, or even obscene, to charge those who need blood, and to pay a market price to people who voluntarily donate their life's fluids. And, as a result, we have been burdened by shortages of this vital item. But what is so wrong with the price system? Don't we rely upon it to provide us with food? Do not farmers profit because of rthe misery of those who are hungry? Is not the market system relied upon to produce shelter? What is so obscene about a process of voluntary trade, even in blood, of all things? Nor should we be deterred by the objection that were blood transfusions to be organized on a commercial basis, that suppliers with hepatitis or other such ailments would spread their illnesses and destroy the system. The same exact procedures which guard against such eventualities now, would still be employed were transfusions put on a rational economic footing. -30Building Codes and Roof Collapses by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. In recent months, the roofs of some commercial establishments have been caving in. First, it was the rooftop parking lot of Save-On Foods in British Columbia. This collapse, fortunately, injured only four people, who had to be hospitalized. But it could have been far, far worse. There were about one thousand shoppers and employees in the store right before the accident. Luckily, there was advance warning. Some of the ceiling beams began to buckle, and an announcement on the store's public address system was quickly made, urging people to leave, but not to panic. This, undoubtedly, saved many lives. The second occurrence was in Brownsville, Texas. Here, real tragedy struck. Eight people were killed outright, and almost 46 were hospitalized with serious injuries. The proximate cause of the Canadian devastation is still unknown. The Texas case has been described as a "freak disaster," since it was preceded by a heavy thunderstorm. But commercial dwellings, and all edifices for that matter, are built to withstand storms, heavy ones as well as light ones. Who is to blame for these calamities, and how can they be avoided in future? As can be expected, the spotlight has focussed on the architects, engineers, contractors and developers responsible for erecting the two buildings. It is widely presumed that the responsibility will be allocated fairly amongst them. This is all well and good. When the culprits are assigned their proper share of the blame, the market will see to it that they are less able, or better yet, completely unable, to ply their trades in future. The usual profit and loss incentives can be counted upon to penalize the guilty parties, as those who would otherwise have been their customers seek alternative sources of supply. There is, however, one fly in the ointment. In none of the accounts of these catastrophes has the role of government been even mentioned, let alone analyzed. And yet the state in the modern era has taken on a great responsibility for underwriting the safety of construction. In virtually all civilized jurisdictions, the public sector has enacted building code legislation. In such codes, there can usually be found requirements for building materials, safety margins, construction techniques, etc. As well, there are numerous civil servant inspectors who have been unleashed on the construction industry, and are charged with the responsibility of ascertaining code compliance. Under such conditions, the lion's share of the blame should logically be placed on the government. If it intervenes in the building process, it should be held accountable when this process unravels, as at present. This alone will not suffice, however. For even if the present analysis were widely supported, and the building code bureaucrats were seen by all as ultimately responsible for the tragedies, little good would come of it. This is because, unlike private enterprise, government bureaus are not funded by paying customers. Instead, their revenues are derived courtesy of the tax authorities. This means that no matter what loss of public confidence takes place, there will not be any necessary diminution of their powers. What is needed, then, is a complete rethinking of the theory under which building codes were created in the first place. We must begin to rely on the free enterprise system not only for architects, engineers, contractors and developers, but for the mechanism which certifies the quality of all their actions as well. We are talking, here, about privatizing the task of certifying the standards of the construction industry. How would this work in practice? Instead of placing all our eggs in one basket, and expecting a monopoly government bureaucracy to discharge this responsibility, society would rely on the private sector. An industry composed of competing firms or professional associations or committees would set the standards, and inspect the construction site from the ground up to make sure it was up to snuff. Only then would they place their imprimatur on it. The benefit of this system is that if a private certification firm made a mistake, unlike the present bureaucrats, it would quickly enough be forced out of business. In contrast, the people who approved of the Vancouver and Brownsville buildings are still doing business at the same old lemonade stands. - 30 August 3, 1988 THE BURNING BED by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute The T.V. movie "The Burning Bed" had everything going for it. It featured a first rate actress, Farah Fawcett-Majors in perhaps her most theatrical role. It boasted a dramatic plot-an abused wife doused her husband with gasoline while he slept, tossed a match on him and burned him to death. With this combination, the performance attracted wide interest from the television audience, and much attention from pundits and critics. In fact, there was only one thing wrong with this presentation: it led to a copy-cat murder in real life, only this time the genders were reversed. In a tragedy of life mimicking art, a Milwaukee man doused his estranged wife with gasoline, and set her afire right after watching "The Burning Bed" on T.V. She died a horrible death after lingering in hospital for a week, and he was sentenced to a 19 year prison term for perpetrating this truly evil act. This episode presents us with a bit of a dilemma. The movie "The Burning Bed" was produced by feminists, to illustrate the problem of wife-beating. Yet these very people have vociferously protested against pornography, on the ground that it leads to violence perpetrated on women. Were these feminists to be consistent with their anti-pornographic stand, they would have to eschew their own exhibition of "The Burning Bed", since it, like pornography, presumably promotes violence against women. If they refuse to do any such thing, then logic would compel them to drop their opposition to pornography, at least on this one ground-- which forms the major element in their case against this practice. No matter how they twist and turn, the feminists cannot have it both ways. Talk of painting yourself into a corner. - 30 300 words California Gunplay by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Suppose you place a half dozen scorpions in a bottle, and shake vigorously. What would be the result? One need not be a sophisticated biologist to know that each of the creatures, feeling crowded, frightened and put upon, would lash out at all the others. Something of this sort seems to have occurred in California in recent weeks, where motorists have been taking pistol shots at one another along the freeways. Although these are people, not scorpions, and they are on a highway, not in a bottle, the parallels in the two situations are ominous. Consider the following: The L.A. Standard Metropolitan Statistical Area has 730 miles of freeway, but a population of over eleven million Every day, 4.3 million people are carried on 8.3 million automobile trips, by 2.5 million motor vehicles In the morning rush hour alone, 757,000 cars carry 850,000 persons on 1.7 million trips Compared with 1970, fully three times as many vehicle hours are now forced to undergo mind-numbing stop and go traffic Further, most large communities supplement their roadways with a system of mass transit; Los Angeles does not, making it a unique commuting city, dependent upon the automobile in a way that others are not. As a result of these factors, each driver comes under greater and greater psychological pressure. Heightening the distress is the summer heat in southern California, with its fraying of tempers and resultant highway breakdowns. Because of the pressure of people and cars on limited road capacity, the "rush hour" has been extended until it now includes virtually every hour from 7:00 A.M. until long past midnight. There is also the ever present threat of gridlock, where no one moves at all. When you add up all these factors, we have all the ingredients for the tragedies that have already occurred: four dead and 11 seriously injured in some three dozen highway shootings. What solutions are in the offing? Unfortunately, it would appear, only more of the same is in store. According to the California Department of Transportation, an additional 90 to 100 miles of new highways will come on stream in each year from now through 1992. As well, bids shall soon be taken for double-decking five miles of the Harbor Freeway in the downtown core, which are particularly congested, even by L.A. standards. There is also some talk of setting up a mass transit system, but if that ever occurs, it will not be for decades. It is important to do better, if only because of the present crisis in southern California. But the problem of highway congestion is hardly confined to that part of the world. Los Angeles, in this as in so many other things, is a "leading indicator." It serves notice as to what is likely to happen to the rest of us, and traffic jams--if not this particular "California solution" -- are a feature of all city life. Fortunately, there is another option. It is called "peak load pricing," and is predicated on the idea that traffic congestion is merely an instance of excess demand. As is well known to all students of economics, there is only one way for the market to resolve a situation where the amount demanded exceeds the amount supplied: the price of the good or service in question must rise. How would this work in the present instance? First of all, the citizenry would have to get used to the idea of paying an explicit price for road usage. It might be thought, initially, that this would be difficult; after all, people look upon their freeways almost as a natural or God given right. But the truth of the matter is that highways are not free, even now. Their initial construction is paid for through taxes, and so could be more accurately called "taxways" than "freeways." Nor are they even free at present. All who use them must pay, in terms of time, while sitting in bumper to bumper traffic. The choice, thus, is not between paying and not paying; it is between paying in terms of money, or, as at present, in terms of time wasted, nerves and tempers frayed, and, in the extreme, bullets exchanged. Secondly, a system of pricing would have to be set up which would take account of the fact that the demands for "taxway" usage are not uniform throughout the day or week. Thus, at certain times on weekdays, say between the hours of 7:00 and 9:00 A.M., or 4:00 and 6:00 P.M., and at certain places, such as the Harbor Freeway, a premium charge would have to be exacted. The determination of the level of the fee would best be made through experimentation; it would be continued to be elevated until traffic could move relatively smoothly. This solution to congestion has been tried with great success in Singapore, where people buy different colored monthly tickets for display on their windshields, which allow them access to different parts of the city, at different times of day. (Severe fines are imposed on motorists who defy the rules). If traffic jams in large Canadian are to be avoided in future, we shall have to give a good hard look at such peak load pricing policies. Canadian Conference of Catholic Bishops Attacks Free Trade by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. According to Bishop Remi de Roo of Victoria, the free trade deal now in the process of being hammered out between Canada and the U.S. will harm this nation. In his view, the negotiations are likely to severely limit Canada's economic and political autonomy. These perspectives are presented in a discussion booklet entitled "Free Trade: At What Cost?" released last week at a highly touted press conference. In it, the bishops question not only the economics of free trade, but the ethics of it as well. They maintain that an end to trade barriers could hurt the poor, and create unemployment. While this viewpoint bespeaks a profound concern for Canada and its people, the bishops, unfortunately, may have been mislead by their economic advisors. It has been a basic premise of economic analysis, since the days of Adam Smith and even before, that voluntary trade across international boundaries helps both participants. Consider the trite but illuminating case of trade of a tropical for a temperate product, e.g., bananas for maple syrup. It is of course possible for a country such as Canada to grow both items. While our climate is hardly receptive to it, we could nurture banana trees - but only in large and very expensive hot houses. Similarly, a country such as Costa Rica could, if it very much wished to, cultivate maple trees. It would have to build gigantic refrigerators, hundreds of feet high, at the cost of a good deal of that nation's entire G.D.P. Promoting capitalism in Eastern Europe Under such an unlikely scenario, each country could attain "self sufficiency" in both commodities. Of course the poor, and everyone else for that matter, would suffer greatly. Maple syrup would be frightfully expensive in Costa Rica, as would bananas in Canada. Suppose, now, that under such conditions there began a movement toward free trade between the two countries. Without tariff barriers, Canada would end up specializing in maple products, while the production of bananas would tend to be concentrated in Costa Rica, to the enrichment of consumers in both places. However, it would be vociferously objected that "Canadian jobs would be lost in the banana industry." Similarly, the Costa Ricans — at least those engaged in the production of maple syrup - would bitterly complain about the rising tide of unemployment in their country. From the perspective of the economist, we can see that both grievances would be true. But contrary to the contention of bishop de Roo and his colleagues, this would be a reason for rejoicing, not for the wailing and gnashing of teeth. For if we want to economize on God's blessings, we do well to encourage unemployment in the misbegotten Canadian banana, and Costa Rican maple syrup industries. Further, perhaps the greatest benediction an industrialized country like Canada can confer on an economically backward nation such as Costa Rica is to offer to integrate its economy with our own. In "Ethical Reflections on the Economic Crises" the Conference of Canadian Bishops urges the "Preferential Option for the Poor." According to this doctrine, public policy should focus on the plight of the impoverished, and seek to improve their lot in life. Since the world's poor are clustered in the underdeveloped nations, this is an argument for open borders with the entire family of nations, not just with the U.S. But the Catholic bishops of Canada may not welcome advice from the economics profession. (In recent surveys, only 3.8% of Canadian economists, and 2.8% of their counterparts in the U.S. failed to support the view that "Tariffs and import quotas reduce general economic welfare.") Perhaps, then, they can borrow a leaf from their co-religionists south of the border. While the U.S. bishops are hardly flaming advocates of an Adam Smithian policy of full free trade, their text, "Catholic Social Teaching and the U.S. Economy" is greatly at variance with the views expressed by Bishops de Roo, Proulx and O'Byrne. In it they refer to "the flaws in the traditional notion of national boundaries," and perceptively state, "...within a frame of reference characterized by the 'preferential option for the poor,' we lean toward an open trading system." 1. Dr. Block is an economist with the Fraser Institute. rime Minister Brian Mulroney announced, with great fanfare, that Canada would grant $42 million in foreign aid to Poland and Hungary in order to promote capitalism. That he could do this indicates, as much as anything, that he does not have even the most basic and elementary understanding of the free enterprise philosophy. That the nation's journalists and editorial writers, ever ready to pounce upon the Progressive Conservatives for just about anything under the sun, could let him get away with such a travesty speaks volumes about the sorry state of their economic understanding as well. Let it be said then, that capitalism is a system based upon private property, free markets, and the lure of profits. It is a total contradiction to this system that government should subsidize anything, let alone another government. This foreign aid is actually an attack on capitalism in several senses. For one thing, it undermines our free enterprise institutions here at home. The more aggrandized is Ottawa, the less economic power remains with "the people," in the form of individual initiative. That grant of $42 million will not come out of thin air. On the contrary, it will be exhorted out of the pockets of the long-suffering Canadian taxpayer. Given the rakeoff that inevitably goes to the bureaucrats, moreover, for our government to actually disburse $42 million means that taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been by a multiple of that amount. For another, it has the exact opposite of its intended effect in the recipient countries of Eastern Europe. The ostensible purpose of this income transfer is to promote capitalism in Poland and Hungary. Ultimately, of course, the goal is to help the citizens of these beleaguered countries lead a better life, but the underlying theory is that since central planning is responsible for their present plight, what is needed now is a healthy dose of individual initiative. But if aggrandizement of the public sector at the expense of the private fosters socialism, not free enterprise, in Canada, it has the same effect in formerly communist countries as well. Giving money to the Polish and Hungarian bureaucrats---even though their ministerial bosses are now democratically elected-will do no more good for their respective economies than it did in the past when they were appointed by a Communist party. Democratic socialism is still socialism. As far as the potential Eastern European entrepre. neur is concerned, it matters little whether he pays exorbitant taxes to the central planner who emerges from the ballot box or from the the totalitarian system of the bayonet. Nor does it matter whether the regulation that drives him out of business arises from one system or the other. The only economic benefit derived from a free vote is that the excesses of socialism can only be pushed so far before they can peacefully exchanged for an alternative. This option does not exist under totalitarianism. Transferring money from one government to another sets up perverse incentives in the recipient country. Instead of concentrating on consumer needs-people in these countries are faced with shortages of toilet paper, soap, bread, meat and countless other items we take for granted in the West-the best and brightest of the Poles and Hungarians will be sorely tempted to focus their attention on the government in order to obtain that 542 million for themselves. This is why it is extremely pejorative to refer to this money as foreign "aid." With all of these boomerang effects, it would be more accurate to call it foreign "harm." If we really wanted to help the people of Eastern Europe, the encouragement of Canadian private investment in these countries would be a far better plan. Unfortunately, because of Mulroney's unfortunate decision, there is now $42 million less forthis purpose. Let us at least resolve that no more money should be wasted in this manner in the future. Further, let us extend the Free Trade Agreement recently concluded with the U.S. to Poland, Hungary, other former Iron Curtain countries, and even to the entire world. But even more than investment, knowledge and understanding of how free enterprise really works is crucially needed by the people behind the former Iron Curtain. Such research is often dismissed by Canadian socialists as "ideological" and "Neanderthal." but it is the very life blood of those struggling to throw off the shackles created by the seven-decade-long experiment with publicsector economic planning. P 32 BRITISH COLUMBIA REPORT, AUGUST 27, 1990 Promoting Capitalism in Eastern Europe by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Prime Minister Brian Mulroney announced, with great fanfare, that Canada would be granting $42 million in foreign aid to Poland and Hungary, in order to promote capitalism. That he could do this indicates, if anything can, that he does not have even the most basic and elementary understanding of the free enterprise philosophy. That the nation's journalists and editorial writers, ever ready to pounce upon the Progressive Conservatives for just about anything under the sun, could let him get away with such a travesty, bespeaks volumes about the sorry state of their economic understanding as well. Let it be said, then, that capitalism is a system based upon private property, free markets, and the lure of profits. It is a total contradiction to this system that government should subsidize anything, let alone another government. This foreign aid is actually an attack on capitalism in several senses. For one thing, it undermines our free enterprise institutions here at home. The more aggrandized is Ottawa, the less economic power remains with "the people," in the form of individual initiative. That grant of $42 million will not come out of the thin air. On the contrary, it will be exhorted out of the pockets of the long suffering Canadian taxpayer. Given the rakeoff that inevitably goes to the bureaucrats, moreover, for our government to actually disburse $42 million means that taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been by a multiple of that amount. For another, it has the exact opposite to its intended effect in the recipient countries of Eastern Europe. The ostensible purpose of this income transfer is to promote capitalism in Poland and Hungary. Ultimately, of course, the goal is to help the citizens of these beleaguered countries to lead a better life, but the underlying theory is that since central planning is responsible for their present plight, what is needed now is a healthy dose of individual initiative. But if aggrandizement of the public sector at the expense of the private fosters socialism not free enterprise in Canada, it has the same effect in formerly communist countries as well. Giving money to the Polish and Hungarian bureaucrats -- even though they are now democratically elected -- will do no more good for their respective economies than it did in the past when they were appointed by a Communist Party. Democratic socialism is still socialism. As far as the potential eastern European entrepreneur is concerned, it matters little whether he pays exorbitant taxes to the central planner who emerges from the ballot box or from the the totalitarian system of the bayonet. Nor does it matter whether the regulation which drives him out of business arises from one system or the other. The only economic benefit derived from a free vote of the polity is that the excesses of socialism can only be pushed so far before they can peacefully exchanged for an alternative. This option does not exist under totali tarianism. Transferring money from one government to another sets up perverse incentives in the recipient country. Instead of concentrating on consumer needs -- people in these countries are faced with shortages of toilet paper, soap, bread, meat and countless other items we take for granted in the west -- the best and brightest of the Poles and Hungarians will be sorely tempted to focus their attention on the government, in order to obtain that $42 million for themselves. But this is the initial problem which created the felt need on the part of the Canadian government to grant the funds in the first place: too much economic emphasis on the public sector, too little on the private. This is why it is extremely pejorative to refer to this $42 million as foreign "aid." With all of these boomerang effects, it would be more accurate to call it foreign "harm." This amount of funding may not be any great shakes in the capitalist west, but it is an inordinate amount of money in the capital-starved east -- especially since it will not go to help the people there, but rather to divert the more entrepreneurial inclined away from needed private commercial endeavors. If we really wanted to help the people of Eastern Europe, the encouragement of Canadian private investment in these countries would be a far better plan. Unfortunately, because of Mulroney's unfortunate decision, there is now $42 million less available for this purpose. Let us at least resolve that no more money should be wasted in this manner in the future. Further, let us extend the Free Trade Agreement recently concluded with the U.S. to Poland, Hungary, other former Iron Curtain countries, and even to the entire world. But even more than investment, knowledge and understanding of how free enterprise really works is crucially needed by the people behind the former Iron Curtain. Such research is often dismissed by Canadian socialists as "ideological," and "neanderthal," but it is the very life blood of those who are struggling to throw off the shakles created by the seven decades long experiment with public sector economic planning. - 30- Promoting Capitalism in Eastern Europe by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Prime Minister Brian Mulroney announced, with great fanfare, that Canada would be granting $42 million in foreign aid to Poland and Hungary, in order to promote capitalism. That he could do this indicates, if anything can, that he does not have even the most basic and elementary understanding of the free enterprise philosophy. That the nation's journalists and editorial writers, ever ready to pounce upon the Progressive Conservatives for just about anything under the sun, could let him get away with such a travesty, bespeaks volumes about the sorry state of their economic understanding as well. Let it be said, then, that capitalism is a system based upon private property, free markets, and the lure of profits. It is a total contradiction to this system that government should subsidize anything, let alone another government. This foreign aid is actually an attack on capitalism in several senses. For one thing, it undermines our free enterprise institutions here at home. The more aggrandized is Ottawa, the less economic power remains with "the people," in the form of individual initiative. That grant of $42 million will not come out of the thin air. On the contrary, it will be exhorted out of the pockets of the long suffering Canadian taxpayer. Given the rake off that inevitably goes to the bureaucrats, moreover, for our government to actually disburse $42 million means that taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been by a multiple of that amount. For another, it has the exact opposite to its intended effect in the recipient countries of Eastern Europe. The ostensible purpose of this income transfer is to promote capitalism in Poland and Hungary. Ultimately, of course, the goal is to help the citizens of these beleaguered countries to lead a better life, but the underlying theory is that since central planning is responsible for their present plight, what is needed now is a healthy dose of individual initiative. But if aggrandizement of the public sector at the expense of the private fosters socialism not free enterprise in Canada, it has the same effect in formerly communist countries as well. Giving money to the Polish and Hungarian bureaucrats -- even though they are now democratically elected -- will do no more good for their respective economies than it did in the past when they were appointed by a Communist Party. Democratic socialism is still socialism. As far as the potential eastern European entrepreneur is concerned, it matters little whether he pays exorbitant taxes to the paper pusher who results from the ballot box or from the bayonet. Nor does it matter whether the regulation which drives him out of business arises from one system or the other. The only economic benefit derived from a free vote of the polity is that the excesses of socialism can only be pushed so far before they can peacefully exchanged for an alternative. This option does not exist under totalitarianism. Transferring money from one government to another sets up perverse incentives in the recipient country. Instead of concentrating on consumer needs -- people in these countries are faced with shortages of toilet paper, soap, bread, meat and countless other items we take for granted in the west -- the best and brightest of the Poles and Hungarians will be sorely tempted to focus their attention on the government, in order to obtain that $42 million for themselves. But this is the initial problem which created the felt need on the part of the Canadian government to grant the funds in the first place: too much economic emphasis on the public sector, too little on the private. This is why it is extremely pejorative to refer to this $42 million as foreign "aid." With all of these boomerang effects, it would be more accurate to call it foreign "harm." If we really wanted to help the people of Eastern Europe, the encouragement of Canadian private investment in these countries would be a far better plan. Unfortunately, because of Mulroney's unfortunate decision, there is now an excess of $42 million less available now for this purpose. Let us at least resolve that no more money should be wasted in this manner in the future. Further, let us extend the Free Trade Agreement recently concluded with the U.S. to Poland, Hungary, other former Iron Curtain countries, and even to the entire world. - 30- \ \." ( Promoting Capitalism in Eastern Europe by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. ,,!V. I\ \..- '1 ,J \ Prime Minister Brian Mulroney announced, with great fanfare, that Canada would .:'--// f.~~ ~ 3. 2. be granting $42 million in foreign aid to Poland and Hungary, in order to promote capitalism. That he could do this indicates, if anything can, that he does not have ~ even the most basic and elementary understanding of the free enterprise philosophy. That the nation's journalists and editorial writers, ever ready to pounce upon the Progressive Conservatives for just about anything under the sun, could let him get away with such a travesty, bespeaks volumes about the sorry state of their economic understanding as well. Let it be said, then, that capitalism is a system based upon private, property, free markets, and the lure of profits. It is totally inconsistent for government to subsidize anything, let alone another government. 1.'71r'- This foreign aid is actually attack on capitalism in several senses. For one thing, 1" it undermines our free enterprise institutions here at home. The more aggrandized is Ottawa, the less economic power remains with "the people," in the form of individual initiative. That grant of $42 million will not come out of the thin air. On the contrary, it will be exhorted out of the pockets of the long suffering Canadian taxpayer. Given the rakeoff that inevitably goes to the bureaucrats, moreover, for our government to actually disburse $42 million means that taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been by a multiple of that amount. For another, it has the exact opposite to its intended effect in the recipient countries of 'Eastern Europe. The ostensible purpose of this income transfer is to promote capitalism in Poland and Hungary. Ultimately, of course, the goal is to help the citizens of these beleaguered countries to lead a better life, but the underlying theory is that since central planning is responsible for their present plight, what is needed now is a healthy dose of individual initiative. But if aggrandizement of the __ ," 1,,,/ public sector at the expense of the private sector favors socialism not free enterprise in Canada, it has the same effect in formerly communist countries as well. j Giving money to the Polish and Hungarian bureaucrats -- even though they are now democratically elected -- will do no more good for their respective economies than it did in the past when they were appointed by a Communist Party. Democratic socialism is still socialism. As far as the potential eastern European entrepreneur is concerned, it matters little whether he pays exorbitant taxes to the paper pusher who j results from the ballot box or from the bayonet. I, Nor does it matter '~,.,~.~-~ whether the regulation which drives him out of business arises from one system or the other. The only economic benefit derived from a free vote of the polity is that the excesses of socialism can only be pushed so far before they can peacefully exchanged for an alternative. This option does not exist under totalitarianism. Transferring money from one government to another sets up perverse incentives in the recipient country. Instead of concentrating on consumer needs -- people in these countries are faced with shortages of toilet paper, soap, bread, meat and countless other items we take for granted in the west -- the best and brightest of the Poles and Hungarians will be sorely tempted to focus their attention on the government, in order to obtain that $42 million for themselves. But this is the initial problem which created the felt need on the part of the Canadian government to grant the funds in the first place: too much economic emphasis on the public sector, too little on the private. This is why it is extremely pejorative to refer to this $42 million as foreign "aid." With all of these boomerang effects, it would be more accurate to call it foreign "harm." If we really wanted to help the people of Eastern Europe, the encouragement of Canadian private investment in these countries would be a far better plan. Unfortunately, because of Mulroney's unfortunate decision, there is now an excess of $42 million less available now for this purpose. Let us at least resolve that no more money should be wasted in this manner in the future. Further, let us extend the Free Trad Agreement recently concluded with the U.S. to Poland, Hungary, other former Iron Curta countries, and even to the entire world. Capitalism, Old and New by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute - 30- Critics of the free market have recently taken to distinguishing and old and a new version of capitalism. In their view, the capitalist pigs of yesteryear weren't really so awful after all, at least compared to the businessmen of today. The old timers may have abused our economy, but at least the robber barons of the 19th century left us a legacy of railroads, steel mills, automobile assembly plants, oil refineries, mines, steamships, and much, much more. They created meaningful goods, services and jobs on a massive scale. But what do the modern paper-pushing junk-bonding yuppie take-over December 27, 1989 artists leave in their wake? Nothing. Unlike their forebears, this new breed of capitalist adds no wealth to our nation. This attack on contemporary capitalism appears well taken, but only on the surface. First of all, not all capitalists in years gone by were actually involved in the production of physical goods or tangible services. Then, as now, market participants provided such "intangibles" as insurance, accounting, banking, intermediation, arbitration, etc. Second, one has only to mention recent consumer breakthroughs to realize that we have benefitted from a whole host of new-fangled products in the present era: computers, VCRs, bigger and better televisions, electronic games, air travel, more and more sophisticated telephones and other communication devices, etc. And the future, with robotics, genetic engineering, new medical discoveries, bodes well to provide us with even more of the same. In order to see the fallacy of this challenge, we must realize that the capitalist is, at bottom, an entrepreneur. All entrepreneurs have in common an ability to predict future demand, and to mobilize land, labour and capital to best meet consumer needs, especially those that have not yet become apparent. In order to do this, the entrepreneur engages in two sorts of speculations: through time and through space. In the latter case, he perceives that the market price of an item in two different areas deviates by more than transportation costs alone could account for. He purchases in the cheaper market, and sells in the dearer, thus transferring material from those who value it less to those who value it more. In the process, he of course enriches both, otherwise neither would have cooperated with him. In the former, the entrepreneur thinks he notices a discrepancy between factor and final goods prices, in this case to an extent greater than that which could be accounted for by the rate of interest. In other words, land, labour and capital (and this includes new ideas) are now trading in some markets below the prices that the ultimate goods shall be able to be sold for, when finally produced. So the entrepreneur takes a risk. He purchases these items, and ofttimes mobilizes them for entirely different and better purposes. But he never physically creates material goods, even in the "good old days" of capitalism. He merely takes factors of production that otherwise would have ended up, say, in the horse and buggy industry, and diverts them to other alternatives. Although this new critique of the market has a veneer of freshness, it is actually as old as the hills. Can't you just picture one cave man telling another that although exploitative, at least the old hunting system produced real red meat; in contrast, the present "gathering stage" of grubbing for roots and berries does not add anything substantial to the economy. Or a Luddite complaining that only farming is a legitimate economic activity; in comparison, the machinery of the "robber barons" is superfluous and superficial. (Actually, this is very similar to the message of the ^•1) physiocrats, an early school of economics.) In recent history, we have passed through the agricultural to the manufacturing stages. We have now arrived at the informational revolution. Sometime in the future, perhaps, we will move toward an economy based on something altogether different, perhaps space exploration. And then, the interventionist of the day will muse that the informational stage at least provided computers; space exploration will be just a waste of time, in his opinion, adding nothing to the well being of those still on earth. THE FRASER INSTITUTE 626 Bute Street, Vancouver, B.C. Canada V6E 3M1 (604)688-0221 CHEAPER GOODS IN U.S. An Editorial by Walter BlockSenior Economist, The Fraser Institute Many Canadians live within a day's drive of U.S. cities. Starting in the West and working East, Vancouver is near Bellingham and Seattle; Lethbridge is close to Great Falls, Montana; Regina is not too far from Minot, North Dakota; Winnipeg is within 300 miles of Grand Forks, North Dakota; Toronto and Buffalo are practically inseparable; Thunder Bay is only 200 miles from Duluth, Minnesota; Rochester, New York is a 2h hour drive from Ottawa; and Montreal and Burlington, Vermont are not too distant neighbours. Many Canadians, therefore, have had first-hand experience with prices in the U.S. We northerners go down there and purchase meals, gasoline, electronic equipment, books, records, tapes, toys and hundreds of other goods and services. There is one thing unique about all of these purchases. It's not quality. Goods and services available in Canada are indistinguishable from those in the U.S. as far as quality is concerned. Nor is it even variety. Although a much smaller country, with some few exceptions, everything available there is available here. No. The amazing, startling, truly gigantic difference is price. Virtually everything in the U.S. may be had at a much lower price, ofttimes substantially cheaper. Meals, beer, toiletries, textile goods are all available at substantially reduced prices--even when the differential values of the U.S. and Canadian dollars are taken into account. If not for the steep tariffs, merchandise limits, quotas and other barriers to trade, almost all Canadians would rather buy in the U.S. -2What accounts for these sharp and dramatic differences? In the view of many people, this is the price of independence. Were we to lower the trade barriers, on this hypothesis, the maple leaf will vanish, trampled under foot by millions of Canadians on a bargain-hunt. What nonsense! Canada has higher prices than the U.S. because we have more government intervention which stultifies productivity. We have greater unionization, more inclusive welfare programs, socialized medicine, more vociferous protectionism, more highly developed marketing boards, government industrial strategies, central planning, Crown corporations (which are unknown in the U.S.), to say nothing of our interferences with intra-national trade. To this must be added that we are a much smaller country than our neighbours to the south. Even apart from our lesser reliance on free markets, this alone would lead to higher prices in real terms. But not if we eliminated our tariff barriers. Then, with an economy integrated with that of the U.S., although not a polity, we could enjoy their lower prices. -30Combines Investigation Act by Walter Block Consumer and Corporate Affairs Minister Andre Ouellet has prepared a most interesting document in order to elicit response to his intended amendments for the Combines Investigation Act. He is to be congratulated for this effort, and on several counts. The document, "A Framework for Discussion", sets forth, in a straighforward and even eloquent manner, the case for further government intervention into the marketplace. It is welcome, then, as a clear statement of this position. The public, moreoever, is invited to respond to these proposals before the introduction of an amending bill. This is in the finest traditions of the Canadian democratic process and of great importance, since legislation in this field is likely to have profound effects upon our economy well into the next century. And the announced purpose of this effort is to increase the competitiveness of the Canadian economy -- a goal which cannot but be shared by all men of good will in this country. Nevertheless, there are deep and abiding flaws in the "Framework for Discussion". The main difficulty is that the document (and presumably the amending bill which will follow as well) is based on an untenable and outmoded economic theory that economic concentration and competition are inconsistent. This theme runs throughout the manuscript, and can be expected to be found as the basis of any subsequent legislation which emerges as a result of the Ouellet proposals. But the truth is almost the exact opposite. Competition and concentration of achievement go hand in hand in the most human endeavours. This is the rule, not the exception. Given that talents and abilities are unequally spread round among the population, and given that full and rigorous competition takes place, it should occasion no surprise that there should be only a few "winners", "survivors", or eminent persons associated with each activity. This is true in all areas of human endeavour, sports, politics, the arts -- and business as well. But it is only regarding business where unequal results are seen as evidence of non-competitiveness. Far from an indication of lack of competition, inequality of retrospective results is perfectly compatible with rivalrous struggle. Consider the following examples. In classical music, Mozrt, Bach, Vivaldi, Beethoven, Chopin, and Handle tower above other composers; in art, such a list would include Rembrandt, Picasso, Van Gogh; in Canadian art, it is the group of (only) seven; in literature Tolstoy, Dostovesky and Dickens. Top playrights include Shakespeare, Chekov, Shaw and Ibsen; all-time great sports figures are limited to such as Jim Thorpe, Babe Ruth, Mohammad Ali, Joe Louis, Gor.die Howe; chess immortals include Capablanca, Alekhin, Spassky, Fisher and Karpov. Although very vigorously competitive, these widely diverse fields were each dominated by but a very few people. The winners in the highly competitive and democratic Canadian political arena are also highly concentrated. The social Credit Party of Alberta enjoyed an uninterrupted reign of 36 years, from 1935 to 1971; the United Farmers of Alberta party held sway from 1921 to 1935; and the Progressive Conservative Party has completely dominated provincial politics since 1971. From 1949 to 1966, the Liberal Party's proportion of Newfoundland Provincial Seats was so high, that it would have been considered a monopoly — had such dominance been attained by a businessman. The Liberal Party of Nova Scotia controlled the provincial legislature from 1881 to 1920 by overwhelming proportions, reaching no less than 94.7% of this "political market" in 1901. Ontario has been ruled by one party, the Progressive Conservatives, for 38 years in a row -longer than Poland or Bulgaria, where no competition between political parties is allowed to take place. And the national Liberals have been all but frozen out of the four western provinces in the past decade, while managing a virtual "monopoly" over the national Progressive Conservative and New Democratic parties in Quebec. As we can see, the attack on business concentration comes with particular ill-grace from the political sphere -- which is as highly concentrated as any institution in society. In focusing its attention on the red herring of concentration and their statistical manifestations, the "Framework for Discussion", is actually if unknowingly ignoring the real threat to the competitiveness of the Canadian playing into the hands of those who would reduce competition in the Canadian economy. It is literally impossible to overestimate the importance to the free operation of the marketplace that entry not be barred by the government. There is all the difference in the world between a company that attains a (temporary) monopoly position through service to the consumer (new product, lower price, better service, etc.) and one that attains a permanent monopoly position through the coercive power of the state. The pre-eminent example in the latter category is the Post Office. It owes its monopoly not to its superior competitive activity, but the law of the land which threatens those who would deliver mail privately with stiff fines and even jail sentences. The K.C. Irving case is a good illustrative example. The "Framework for Discussion" waxes apopletic over the fact that the Supreme Court failed to bring in a guilty verdict, even though the "Irving interests bought up all the English language daily newspapers in the Province of New Brunswick". Yet this Irving "monopoly" was not without competition. There were other language newspapers, non-daily English newspapers, comic books, magazines, journals, books, stock market and other specialized reports, radio and t.v. all in direct competition with the five Irving newspapers. There is also the Globe and Mail, Canada's national newspaper - all from the communications industry. There were hundreds and even thousands of alternative claimants for the New Brunswickers dollars from other industries" from things such as ice creams, shoeshines, tennis raquets and pencils. The crucial point, however, is that there were no legal barriers to entry. Anyone was free to set up his own English language daily newspaper in New Brunswick -- subject, of course, to the requirement that he have sufficient funds for newsprint, office space, salaries, etc., and that he be willing to contend with the professional standards maintained by the Irving chain. The CIA amendment proposals focus on unimportant inessentials and ignore the very crux of the problem. Industrial concentration is as much related to competition as fish to bicycles. Legal barriers to entry are the absolutely essential key to understanding how competition is undermined. Yet the "Framework for Discussion" focuses on the former, and completely ignores the latter. Let us make good this deficit, and explore some of the myriad areas in which the government is itself guilty of discouraging competition, by artificially protecting incumbent firms, and setting up legal barriers for new entrants, Industries where government reduces competition in this regard include: professional occupations, railroads, trucking, taxicabs, airlines and agricultural products. In each of these cases, governments — at federal, provincial, and local levels — have reduced economic competition by setting up barriers protecting incumbent firms and practitioners, at the expense of new entrants -and the public. Whether it be marketing boards, licensing arrangements, special permissions or franchises, by setting up manifold legal barriers to entry, government has been a major force disruptive of competition. If government truly had the interests of the public at heart, and wanted to promote competition, then instead of pressing the spurious connection between concentration and competition underlying the CIA, it could instead rescind this complex welter of regulations which discourages new entry. Perhaps the strongest and most significant manner in which government forecloses competition by preventing entry is in the area of trade protectionism. A tariff is a tax which must be paid by foreign, not domestic, producers. A quota is an outright prohibition of some or all of the goods and services which would be exported by other countries for sale in Canada. Both prevent or lessen the competition in the domestic economy that would otherwise be provided by foreign business firms. Labour unions. The "Framework for Discussion" is curiously silent about the monopolistic practices of labour unions. Not only does organized labour have a high concentratioin ratio in many industries, but ever so much more important, it engages in entry restrictions, and even prevention of job opportunity, to non-unionized workers. Imagine the hue and cry were business firms to engage in such practices. If corporations followed the example of organized labour not only would they "fail to supply" but they would physically prevent their customers from patronizing other establishments (this is exactly what a union of employees does when it goes out on strike). True, labour organizations have traditionally been exempt from anti-trust legislation in the U.S., and from anti-combines edicts in this country. But there is simply no justification for making such an exception. Labour unions, especially unions of public employees, have a power to distrupt an entire economy in a way incomparably greater than business, even "monopoly" business. If there is no case for including labour unions under the restrictions imposed by an amended CIA, there is even less case for including business enterprise. Conflicts of Interest by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute The newspapers have been recently filled to the brim with stories about conflicts of interest suffered by politicians. As a result, there has been widespread and renewed interest in patching up conflict-of-interest policy. According to a typical proposal, ministers and senior mandarins should be forced to either put their assets in a blind trust, or to make a "full and complete disclosure" of their investments. There are, however, numerous drawbacks to such a scenario. Openly acknowledging one's investment portfolio is no guarantee that the elected official or civil servant will not be able to use his public position for private gain. It may make things more difficult, but a person who is so minded may still be able to mix his public and private life in this manner. Nor is a blind trust even a necessary impediment to such activity. The public figure may rely on the fact that portfolios need not be changed, even when in blind trust and may act so as to increase the value of his holdings on the day they were given over to the administrator. Such a policy may not maximize his private wealth, but, especially if the portfolio has not been radically altered, it may well enhance the value of his property. In any case, the fact that this is a possibility may divert those in public office from discharging their duties as they would had they no potential conflict of interest to contend with. But this is only the tip of the ice berg. There is also the siren song of nepotism to deflect our public servants from their steely determination to "act in the public interest." This problem is easier to point to than it is to solve. First of all, if the activities of the wife of a government official must be scrutinized lest they cast doubt on the propriety of his own position, what about his children or his parents? What about his uncles, aunts, cousins, in-laws, grandchildren, etc. The difficulty is that there is no nonarbitrary way to draw the line. No matter where it is drawn, there will always be some (perhaps distant) relative whose business relations may cast aspersions on the legitimacy of the politician in question. Secondly, what about the rights of the relatives of politicians or leading civil servants? Must they be prohibited by law from engaging in commercial transactions? If they are, this is a clear breach of their own rights. If not, there is always the possibility that someone may treat them advantageously, in the hopes of currying favour with the principal (this would appear to be the allegation in the Stevens case.) These difficulties are basic, not superficial. They transcend political affiliation, jurisdiction, even national boundaries, and apply to all office holders and government officials. (They do not apply, however, to private enterprise. For if a corporate officer, for example, engages in a bit of nest feathering, it is in the interests of the firm to ferret out this behaviour. Business concerns may best be understood as competing not only with regard to providing their primary product, but also as regards their ability to stop employees from acting against their interests.) Conflicts of interest plague the public sector at present, and are likely to do so for the foreseeable future, or for at least as long as human nature remains the way it now is. What, then, may be done about this ubiquitous problem? The answer is simple. If there is no airtight way to avoid conflicts of interest amongst public servants, let us at least resolve to reduce their numbers as much as possible! Thus the best way to eliminate virtually all conflicts of interests amongst civil servants and public officials is to decrease the number of these positions to an irreducible minimum. There are many other good and sufficient reasons for cutting back on the public sector, but extirpating conflicts of interest is certainly one of them. CROWN CORPORATION SALARIES by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute In the past few weeks, the Canadian public has been stunned by the Mulroney government's announcement of the level of salaries paid to Crown Corporation executives. Although the long-suffering taxpayer in this country is really the employer of these denizens of the boardroom, such information was deemed too vulgar for his delicate ears by the former Trudeau government. Even the Progressive Conservatives will only give compensation ranges, not exact figures, as is done for Canadian companies whose securities are traded on U.S. stock exchanges. - And indeed the facts do portray a picture of public servants living high off the hog. When we consider the high pay scales--along with the accompanying fees, charges, per diems, bonuses, side payments, considerations, rewards, perks, favours, options, increments--it does appear rather unseemly. Consider the following: Petro Canada, cordially despised all throughout the western part of the nation, pays its top two executives nearly $900,000 in annual compensation. Chairman Wilbert Hopper pulls down in the neighourhood of $435,000 a year, while his sidekick, President Edward Lakusta nets a cool $414,260, or so. But this is only the tip of the iceberg. Other Crown Corporate fat cats include Air Canada's President Pierre Jeanniot, and Chairman Claude Taylor, both in the $135.000 - $210,000 range; Canada Post's President Michael Warren who earns between $160,000 and $185,000, and Chairman Judge Rene Marin, in the range between $97,090 and $114,260. Then there is Dr. J.H. LeClair, President, Canadian National Railways, who weighs in at the $210,000 -$240,000 range, plus a director's fee of $5,000 per annum and $250 per diem for attending meetings. Naturally, the release of this information by Prime Minister Brian. Mulroney has unleashed a storm of controversy and criticism. Mr. Mulroney himself has been only mildly critical, allowing that "these are pretty handsome numbers for anyone running a corporation that doesn't have to declare a profit". But the reaction of Regional Industrial Expansion Minister, Sinclair Stevens ("most excessive") has been more typical of the outrage that has scandalized the average Canadian income earner. There has been, however, a defense of sorts made in behalf of these astronomical public sector pay scales: the salaries of top management in the private sector are comparable, and in some cases even exceed, the compensation of crown corporation executives. But this is an improper comparison. Private executives must earn profits, public sector bureaucrats need not. A more apt comparison would be with top-earning civil servants and politicians. And the highest paid Crown Corporation leaders earn more than three times the salary and fringe benefits package paid to our nation's leader, the Prime Minister, and more than six times the amount paid to the ordinary Member of Parliament. These wages are way out of line. What has been the reaction of the Mulroney government? So far, it has been limited, reasonably, to focussing public attention on the phenomenon, and hinting that such pay scales in future will be lowered. As well, it has fired one of the top income earners, Joel Bell of the money losing Canadian Development Investment Corporation, ($1.67 billion in its first year of operation) who had earned a hefty $235,000 - $260,000 while still in the driver's seat. Thirdly, it is now ready to seriously consider some even more basic measures. Government has begun to rethink our entire commitment to the idea of government running businesses— usually on a money losing basis--through Crown Corporations. The short-lived minority Progressive Conservative government of Joe Clark may not have been able to privatize Crown Corporations such as Petro Canada, but such restrictions do not apply today. Crown Corporations were first created because national policy called for certain programs (e.g., the development of the north) that private enterprise -in the absence of strong consumer support -- was unwilling to undertake. Even then, it might have been preferable to subsidize the private sector to these ends, rather than create an entire additional level of bureaucracy. But nowadays, with the existence of over 300 Crown Corporations, many of which lose money every year on a vast scale, this argument is especiallly unconvincing. We must now realize that private companies tend to be far more efficient than Crown enterprises, if for no other reason than that they must pass the market test of profit and loss every day. Crown Corporations thus tend to become a drain on the federal budget. They are responsible, to no small degree, for the size of our present national debt. But if they were sold off to private investors, they could become the means of helping to solve the very deficit they helped to create. With Crown Corporation privatization, at one fell swoop we could plug a drain on the body economic, and reduce a national debt which now takes up one tax dollar of every three, and continually threatens to raise interest rates and retard economic recovery. November/84 CUTTING BACK THE CANADIAN LEVIATHAN by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute an article for the Financial Post Governments in Canada, at the federal, provincial and local levels, now spend about 45% of GNP in constant 1971 dollars. (This figure was 26.5% in 1950, 32.6% in 1960, 36.9% in 1970 and 40.7% in 1980). Roughly half of this amount is utilized at present for transfer payments, and the remainder is used to provide government services. But even this level of expenditure underestimates the true magnitude of government involvement in the economy. In addition to transferring income and providing services, government intervenes with a myriad of economic regulations, Crown Corporations, massive land ownership, tariffs, bailouts, loans, guarantees and subsidies to favoured business interests. Unlike the U.S., where the growth of the government sector has been subject to widespread public debate, this pattern has taken hold in Canada more by inadvertence than as the result of careful dialogue, widespread agreement and purposeful activity. This, of course, is not to deny that making Canada a government-centered society has been the goal of some people; it is to assert that the Canadian public as a whole has never explicitly accepted such a program. Consider just one indication. According to a 1982 Gallup poll which asked "which do you think will be the biggest threat to Canada in years to come?", 46% answered 'big government", 29% said big labour, and 13% replied "big business". This widespread dissatisfaction with a large and growing Leviathan Canada is certainly understandable in the light of a number of its shortcomings. According to Probing Leviathan: An Investigation of Government in the Economy, a book just published by the Fraser Institute, the following deficiencies now exist: o Despite a tripling in the real per capita welfare expenditutes over recent decades, the distribution of incomes remains virtually unchanged. (Fraser Institute calculations under conservative assumptions show that if these transfer payments were given directly to the poor, instead of being filtered through the welfare system, every Canadian household currently below the poverty level could be given an annual subsidy of $17,203.00.) o As tax rates increase, the "invisible" economy, based on 'barter and cash transactions that go unreported, flourishes. It is estimated that just under 10 per cent of GNP in Canada is unreported income. o In the light of a rapidly changing pattern of world demand, government induced rigidity serves to reduce economic well being. Paradoxically, immobility of economic resources is a frequent rationale for interventionist government policies. o Windfall profits and losses are the engine that drives the market economy's adaptation to changes. To eliminate unforeseen fluctuations in profits and losses, by bailing out losers and taxing winners, cancels out the market economy's driving force and effectively destroys it. o When special privileges for particular groups are put up for grabs in the political "market-place," the evidence suggests that the groups with the most power and votes will come away with the lion's share. In view of the foregoing, the question naturally arises, What can be done? A full answer would include reducing the level of government on all fronts. But one specific proposal, especially relevent to our present budgetary problems, would be to sell off a number of Crown Corporations. In addition to lowering the presence of the Leviathan government in the Canadian economy, such a move could make a downpayment on our $30 billion plus annual deficit, and on our national debt of some $200 billion. It is difficult to know what such a sale could fetch on the open market, but as of March 1983, the assets of Crown and other government corporations were estimated at $71.7 billion by the Auditor General of Canada. Taking 12% of this amount as an upper bound, their sale could reduce our deficit by $8.6.billion, annually. Fortunately, the new Progressive Conservative government has begun to rethink our entire commitment to the idea of public sector-run businesses. Mr. Mulroney has announced the intent to privatize CDIC, and the investigation of Petro Canada's takeover of Petro Fina may portend the selling off of that Crown Corporation. But there are over 300 other Crown Corporations, which could be returned to the private sector. Crown corporations were first created because national policy called for certain programs (e.g., the development of the north) that private enterprise -- in the absence of strong consumer support -- was unwilling to undertake. Even then, however unwise, it might have been preferable to subsidize the private sector to these ends, rather than create an entire additional level of bureaucracy. But nowadays, with the existence of 300 Crown Corporations, many of which lose money every year on a vast scale, this argument is especially unconvincing. We must now realize that private companies tend to be far more efficient than Crown enterprises, if for no other reason than that they must pass the market test of profit and loss every day. Ridding the public sector of financial albatrosses will thus tend to increase economic efficiency as well as improve our deficit situation. THE DEALER IN SPARE BODY PARTS I by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute Baby Fae with a transplanted baboon heart; Dr. Barney dark, with a transplanted artificial heart; hundreds of heart transplants, starting with those performed by the famed Dr. Christian Barnard of South Africa; these are amongst the episodes that have seized the headlines, and captured the imaginations of millions of people. But behind the headlines, there are numerous other medical procedures which have substituted diseased organs with healthy ones on an interpersonal basis. For example, liver, bone marrow, blood, cornea, eyes, and kidney. The Organ Donor Association of the U.S., however, reports that only X people have signed the donor card, which gives permission for the various body parts to be taken and used in medical procedures upon the sudden demise of the grantor. In Canada, the figure is Y. The Red Cross, moveover, reports a blank shortage of blood supplies, especially (Walter, the insert for page 2 that goes here does not make sense.) The reason Baby Fae had to make do with a baboon heart, and Dr. Barney dark with an artificial one, was that there was not a sufficiency of human hearts available for transplant. The problem with present institutional arrangements is that the free enterprise system is not fully allowed to operate. To be sure voluntary organizations — such as Z Associations — are allowed to do their good works and these, along with all other non-governmental initiatives must be considered part of the marketplace. But commercial concerns, buying up spare body parts and reselling them at a profit, are prohibited in most places in the world, and where they are not prohibited outright, their blank is severely limited. And with good reason, in the view of many people. The very idea conjures up visions of ghoulishness, Frankenstein experiments, grave robbing. Count Dracula gone beserk, Robin Cook plots, and other unsavory scenarios. Imagine. Allowing the evil merchants of profit to get their grubby hands on such an enterprise! By its very nature, these people contend, bodily transplants must be left to the voluntary private sector, or perhaps made a responsibility of government. But there are problems with this view. The voluntary organizations, as we have seen, have not produced the &quotgoods", at least in sufficient quantities. And there is always the danger that the government, the embodiment of force in society, will use compulsion to attain the goal the voluntary sector could not accomplish. The spectre of the state compelling people to sign these donor cards, despite their religious or ethical beliefs to the contrary, is one that we can do without, thank you kindly. How would a marketplace in used body parts function? It is impossible to ever fully anticipate the actions of 100's of profiteering entrepreneurs, each reading for an end (a sufficient quantity of raw material for transplants) beyond their intention (profit). However, a few general principles become clear upon consideration. One possibility, for example, would be to continue the present policy of signing donor cards, only now these commercial firms could offer money to those who signed. This could not help increase the numbers of donors. And if it did not do so sufficiently to supply all those in need of organs, the firms would have to raise prices paid until it did. In the case of blood, the Red Cross does, of course, pay for its supply. But its prices are too low, as shown by the fact that only insufficient quantities are brought forth. As well, it has failed to adopt a policy of differential prices, to reflect the relative shortages of the various types of blood. And there is no reason to believe that these private companies would not be able to increase the supply of organs in accord with demand. Entreprenuers in every other field of endeavour known to man — some mundane, some exotic — have been able to accomplish this task with no fuss or fanfare. But this would mean, would it not, that organ recipients would have to pay for these items. And isn't that unconscionable? Shouldn't people have the right to receive these vital items, necessary for life itself in many cases, free of charge. To make this claim is to laugh. Why should people receive bodily parts for free? These items have value. To mandate that recipients have them at no cost is to prohibit the donors, and the middleman - facilitaters, from being paid. After all, we do not prohibit the farmer, or the miller, baker, retailer, from earning money from the sole of bread, even though bread (and other food) is also necessary for life. If we did, we would find bread to be in short supply, just hike human organs. Under the present system of prohibited or controlled payments, many potential organ recipients thus cannot receive them. Surely they would be better off having them, even for a fee, than being forced to do without, with the dubious privilege of not being required to pay for what they cannot in any case have. Suppose that under these conditions, some intrepid entreprenuer were willing to start up a black market service in this field. That is, he would offer large sums of money to those willing to sign organ donor agreements with him, and would charge even larger amounts to doctors in need of these items for purposes of transplant. (We assume away the insuperable legal difficulties that would confront our organ businessmen at both ends of the transaction). The question is, would such as underground badily parts company be a benefit or a detriment? One argument for the latter view is that the firm, if successful, would tend to undermine respect for law and order. It would be thumbing its nose at the duly constituted authoriteis, who have so far remained adamant in declaring such 'ghoulish" sales and purchases illegal. As against that, it could be argued that any legal code which in effect if not by intention consigns innocent individuals to death (heart failure, for example) or to lives of misery (kidney dialysis machines) richly deserves to be ignored. But one point is clear. Our black market will benefit organ donors, by offering them financial renumeration, as well as the satisfaction of knowing that the organs they may donate upon their devise will enable others to live. By doing so, it will, as we have seen, increase the number of organs made available, and this will be of inestimable benefit to those who might otherwise have been forced to go without. Now let us consider a case that really does have ghoulish attributes. Let us suppose that a marketplace in used body parts could not only work with donor cards, where the organ transfer takes place after the death of the donor. Let's assume that there would also be a market where live donors give up parts of their body — and then go on living. A heart transplant would be out of the question, but people could give up one (or even two) eyes(s), or one kidney, etc. Naturally, the price for a bodily part on this basis would tend to be higher than for that supplied only upon the death of the donor. But still, both parties to the transaction would benefit. True, the donor would give up a precious part of his body, at great inconvenience and rist, but the price he receives would more than compensate him for this onerous renunciation, otherwise he would not agree to do so. And of course the recipient would not agree to pay the outrageous expense unless the recipient of the organ was worth even more to him. But what about the case where the recipient was a old ne'er-do-well, lazy, shiftless millionaire heir, and the donor a young, healthy, brilliant, hard working person who had the misforturn to be born desperately poor, and needs large amounts of money for food to keep his family alive. Wouldn't an organ transplant from the latter to the former be exploitative? Anti thetical to public policy and the general good? The very idea seems replusive to most people. Part of the unsavoriness, however, arises from the nagging suspicion that it is unfair that the ne'er do well is fabulously wealthy, while the hard worker is desperately poor. Let us banish this from consideration, though. It is extrinsic to the case in point. Given the justice of their initial endowments of wealth, it is easy to see that both parties gain from the exchange, in that neither would enter into this commercial venture in the absence of such an expectation. And the experience of the Ethiopian famine of 198^ should underscore this point. If one of these unfortunates had been willing to give up a bodily part, so that he and his fellow sufferers could live, then any law enjoining such a possibility would not only be a grave injustice, but would consign these people to death. DEVIL MUSIC by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute A California teenager short himself in the head while lying in a bed he had just made -- an action urged in a suicide song by Ozzy Osbourne, a heavy-metal British rock star, brought to us courtesy of CBS Records. A part of the lyrics states: "... made your bed, rest your head, but you lie there and moan, where to hide, suicide is the only way out." As a result, the father of the young man, Mr. Jack McCollum, is suing CBS Records, the distributor. Jet Records, the recording company, Ozzy Osbourne the singer, plus two songwriters. He is seeking compensatory and punitive damages which could amount to millions of dollars. He is doing so, according to lawyer for the plaintiff Thomas Anderson a bornagain Christian, because under California law it is a felony to encourage anyone to commit suicide, "and this is exactly what these records do." In addition to the gory details, the case is buttressed by a finding in the coroner's report that the young McCollum committed suicide "while listening to devil music." There are several logical difficulties with the suit, despite this official report. First of all, it is a free speech issue, Mr. Anderson's views to the contrary notwithstanding. Impressionable people might be "driven" to suicide by all sorts of artistic offerings, besides the lyrics of rock music. If plaintiff wins his suit, there will be a chilling effect on novels and plays as well. Will any author dare include a scene in which one of the characters commits suicide? Further, there will be the risk that serious discussions of the phenomenon, even such as the present one, will some day be held liable for leading to untimely self-afflicted death. Secondly, there are grave philosophical problems with the proposition that one person can cause another to commit suicide, whether directly through exhortation, or indirectly, via movies, plays, or in our case, songs. This view flies in the face of the doctrine of free will, upon which our entire criminal code is predicated. If people are not responsible for their own acts, how can it be just to punish them? And if they are, how can we hold one person guilty for the suicide of another? The plaintiff's argument in this case deserves to be rejected. Further, he should be made to pay the defendant's expenses, and charged for bringing a frivolous and harassing suit. - 30 - 410 words THE FRASER INSTITUTE 626 Bute Street, Vancouver, B.C. Canada V6E 3M1 (604) 688-0221 Do Landlords Hate Pets? by Dr. Walter Block Based on a recent pet-related tenant eviction, it would appear that the evil landlords are "at- it again." They are exploiting tenants who wish to give a home to some of our furry or feathered friends. "Pet-hating landlords" is the way this phenomena was described by a leading Canadian newspaper. Nothing could be further from the truth, however. Actually, except for a miniscule number of cases, the landlord couldn't possibly care less which pets inhabit his dwelling units. Dogs, cats, parakeets -- or lions, elephants and alligators (on the assumption that no extra costs are thereby imposed on the landlord) -- it's all the same to him. The landlord, like all other businesspersons, is usually interested only in maximizing profits. And since the best way to increase profits is by satisfying renters, "the customer is always right" is the typical motto of the landlord. Why is it, then, that virtually all leases prohibit pets if the landlord's selfInterest lies in pleasing customers? First of all, while all standard written tenant agreements prohibit pets, they also provide for landlord waivers. And rental accommodation owners commonly grant exceptions for goldfish, parakeets in cages, and other such pets. More important, we must reject the view that all landlords are pet-hating, misbegotten misanthropes. In actual point of fact, most landlords do not care at all whether tenants maintain pets, as long as this practice (1) does not impose any additional (maintenance and repair) costs on them, and (2) does not annoy other tenants. The landlord typically brings no views of his own to this matter; he attempts to act as an agent for his tenants. Most important of all, we cannot accept the view that all tenants are filled with the milk of human kindness for our furry and feathered friends. The plain fact is that not every tenant likes pets! If so, then landlords can best please their customers not by indiscriminately allowing pets the run of their buildings, but by tailoring leases to the desires of their tenants. In a reasonably well ordered world, tenants who like pets would be segregated from those who dislike them, in much the same way that smokers and non-smokers are kept apart in restaurants and airplanes. For pets, just like tobacco smoke, are what the economist calls an "external diseconomy" or "neighbourhood effect:" they impose costs on third parties. Encouraging people with such divergent tastes to live in close proximity with each other reduces welfare all around: non-pet owners object to pets, and pet owners are unhappy with this opposition. Under a proper economic system, some landlords would simply announce that they welcome all sorts of pets, and charge more for this privilege. Others would staunchly refuse. Tenants could then sort themselves out according to which mode of living they preferred, and the proportion of rental buildings with pets would then tend to resemble the relative desire to own pets in the general tenant population. The difficulty is that our institutional arrangements do not make it easy for the landlord to collect additional rent to defray the increased costs of tenants with pets. This is why rental property owners are exceedingly reluctant to invite dogs and cats into their buildings -- not because of any innate hatred for animals. But unless landlords can, without any red tape or legal burdens, be fairly compensated for these additional costs, they will have no incentive whatsoever to set up entire buildings devoted to pet-owning tenants. Under these conditions, the segregation of tenants by pet status will be an unreachable ideal. Rent control is a particular problem in this regard. In the newer and luxury buildings to which controls do not apply, tenant wishes and desires can be met to some degree. But in units subject to rent control, there is not the slightest likelihood of the landlord collecting additional rent for allowing pets. Should it really be a surprise, then, that the rental property owner would be completely unresponsive to tenant wishes? There is one pressure vent open to the tenant in these circumstances: condominium, or better yet, single family home ownership. In condomiuniums, strata title, or cooperative housing, the "neighbourthood effects" problem still prevails. A majority of owners may vote to preclude pets. (And the high proportion of these groups which actually prohibit pets is further evidence that most people, tenants included, oppose this practice.) It is only by owning a home, with a backyard and a fence, that the pet owner need seek permission from no one. The problem, of course, is that many pet lovers cannot afford to buy a home of their own. All the more reason, then, to end rent controls, and to enact legislation which makes it easier for landlords to collection additional rents to defray the increased costs of renting to pet owners. In this way we can separate tenants based on their desire for pets. We can thus help remove a minor but important irritant to living together in a congested, complex, modern civilization. -30Drugs and the Olympics by Walter Block, Fraser Institute Canada's Ben Johnson was stripped of his gold medal for the 100 metre dash in the 1988 Seoul Olympics. According to his coach Charlie Francis, this instance of drug taking is only the tip of the ice-berg. Numerous other Canadian athletes have been implicated in the use of anabolic steroids, and world class athletes from several other countries have been implicated. The main reaction on the part of the leading sports authorities is a call for a "war" on muscle building medications. There are several shortcomings with this approach, however. For one thing, there is a matter of arbitrariness. Why is it that anabolic steroids are banned while other performance enhancing drugs, such as cortisone and Xylocaine, are allowed? Even aspirin, for that matter, is a performance-enhancing drug. For another, who gives the Olympic and sports authorities the right to ban anabolic steroids? They are widely used in Canada for patients suffering from rheumatoid arthritis and other debilitating diseases, and are available upon prescription. Ben Johnson's doctor, after all, prescribed them for him, at least according to present testimony. The case of Eleanor Holm, a U.S. swimmer entered in the 1936 Olympics is a case in point. Avery Brundage, President of the 1.0.C. at that time, banned her from competition because she had imbibed a glass of champagne at a ship's party on the trip across the Atlantic to Berlin. There are many who would question his right to have done so. A further difficulty is that the war against these particular-performance enhancing drugs seems almost as futile as the war against addictive drugs such as cocaine and heroin. Keeping pace with the development of newer and better body building pharmaceuticals, and often outstripping it, is the technology necessary to disguise their use. Whatever the shortcomings, there is a clear need to establish some sort of rules that everyone must follow. "A level playing field" is a much abused notion when applied to free trade, but when it comes to sports, it is vital. If there is no commonality to which sports participants must be held, the whole point of athletic competition vanishes. We might as well assign some people to the starting line, and others either 10 yards behind, or in front. The big question is, What must be equalized? In high schools and colleges, the amount of training is subjected to egalitarian considerations: team practices are limited to a specified number of weeks. This is not done in professional endeavors. In swimming there is virtually no difference in the type of equipment used. In sailboating and car racing, there are gigantic disparities. Here, the competition is as much between men as between gear. Bicycle racing could equalize the apparatus, by random assignments, but has chosen not to do so. The point is, some sort of equalization must be imposed, but its dimensions are not given to us from on high. The present scandal stems from the fact that commonality cannot now be achieved. We can impose stricter and more frequent controls, but we can only hope that the testing mechanisms will be able to overcome those which mask drug usage. A more radical solution to the present drug scandal is the suggestion that the rules be relaxed completely: allow everyone to take the muscle building drug of his choice. The problem with this is that we will no longer know of what the human body - unaided by drugs -- is capable; we will only see the result of the combination of such artificial stimulants plus training. (Yes, these materials may be harmful. But we're talking about adults here, and they have the right to weigh the pros and cons and decide such issues for themselves.) A compromise is to urge the creation of two completely different sections of the Olympic games (and all other related professional sports activities). One would be an "open" division, where medications of all kinds and varieties would be allowed. The other would be a "closed" division, open only to the drug free. Every subsequent world record would have an asterisk, or not, depending upon drug usage. This is no panacea; no compromise known to man ever is. We would still face the difficulty of drug users posing as drug free athletes. But this compromise would go a long way toward resolving a most perplexing difficulty, since with two divisions, there would be less incentive to cheat. - 30 - The Economics of the Parole System by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. In 1971 Allan George Foster brutally raped and murdered his 18 year-old sister-in-law. He was caught, sentenced and served 10 years of his jail term. He was released in 1981 on full parole, having been "rehabilitated," at least in the opinion of the so-called expert psychiatrists responsible for rendering this decision. The parole officers were unequivocal in their positive assessment of Foster. Said Vasha Starrie, his case management officer at Agasiz Mountain Prison: "I thought he had dealt with the (1971) offence and had developed character features that made him open and reliable." Further "He is one of the sanest people I have ever met ... a highly sensitive and intelligent person." According to psychologist Clifford Ratzlaff, who subjected Foster to an intensive battery of tests, "He appears to have overcome the life stress that caused him to flip out (in 1971) and take the life of another person." Late last yenr. however, this sane well-adjusted person struck again. This time the victims were his common-law wife Joan Pilling, 34, her daughter Linda Brewer, 12, and Brewer's school friend Megan Sue McCleary, also 12. Luckily for society, he committed suicide after this outbreak, because this second series of ghastly crimes would have allowed him yet another parole after 25 yearsprovided he could have convinced another set of dogooding experts of his intrinsic goodness. What does this gory tale have to do with economics? The murderer's own assessment of his situation was apropos to this point. Said Foster: "There is only one thing crazier than me and this is the society that let's me do what I do." But it is possible to pinpoint more exactly the precise locale of the craziness in 49 society. First and foremost it is a system which severs the connection between action and responsibility. The psychological experts, and the parole board members who rely on them make decisions that affect the rest of us in crucial ways. Yet, they are neither rewarded when they correctly assess these prisoners, nor, more important, are they penalized in any way when they are tragically wrong. Adam Smith stated so eloquently that it is not from benevolence but from self interest that the butcher and the baker provide their wares for us. But if these entrepreneurs had as little selfish interest as do the parole boards, we would all starve. Secondly, we must note that the Foster case is symptomatic of government failure. The state bureaucracy necessarily lacks the magic of the marketplace, and the supurb incentive system imposed by the lure of profits and the fear of losses. Incarceration of prisoners and parole are now responsibilities of the public sector. Given this state of affairs we must look toward privatization of these roles as a means of improving matters. Government is clearly derelict in its duty; and intrinsically so. It is thus difficult to see how private enterprise could do anything: but bring us a more socially responsible parole system. ECONOMICS AND THE CATHOLIC BISHOPS by Walter Block The Canadian Conference of Catholic Bishops (Episcopal Commission for Social Affairs) is to be congratulated for its recent report, Ethical Reflections on the Economic Crisis. If there were any doubt about it before, there can be none now: our double digit unemployment rate is evidence not only of an economic crisis, but, as the bishops say, of a "basic moral disorder." When 1.5 million people out of a labour force of slightly less than 12 million cannot find a job, in large part because of the economic policies pursued by government, this is not only an economic problem, but a moral problem as well. It took the moral authority of the Canadian Bishops to point this out in a way that cannot be overlooked, and to focus our concern on the plight of the downtrodden. Their statement is dramatic, compassionate and deeply ethical in its concern for our economy and its people. There is a second reason for welcoming this report: concern for a pluralistic society. In our epoch, there is a distinct danger that the growth of a centralizing, self-aggrandizing, interventionist government will succeed in gradually sweeping aside all other alternative institutions. This is why it is so important for the good of society that the churches speak out on economics, and on public policy issues (whether or not it is appropriate from a religious point of view is something each church must decide for itself). That a significant church group has dared to speak out against an establishment government cannot but help engender a more healthy pluralistic society in Canada. The report of the Canadian Conference of Catholic Bishops is grounded on, and begins with, a "fundamental gospel principle" called the preferential option for the poor, the afflicted and the oppressed. This means that in our analysis of political economy, the downtrodden should occupy centre stage in our minds and hearts. We must be especially vigilant in our concern for those who are the victims of injustice. It is indeed rare in the annals of political economy that such a concern should even be mentioned, let alone used as a foundation for the entire analysis. The bishops are therefore to be congratulated for this expression. However, it is one thing to identify with the oppressed emotionally; it is quite a different matter to fashion programs which will actually help them. The road to hell, after all, is paved with good intentions. One of the major shortcomings of the bishops' statement is that despite its avowed concern for those at the bottom of the economic pyramid, it urges policies which will have the diametric opposite effect of the results sought and expected. For example, the bishops claim that unemployment rather than inflation should be recognized as the number one problem, and recommend additional government spending for jobs creation and welfare. These, however, would fuel inflation. And inflation, apart from its other bad effects, is itself a major cause of unemployment. The bishops advocate an industrial strategy of low technology and high labour intensity. Motivated by the best intentions, they nevertheless fall victim to the hoary "lump of labour" fallacy. According to this specious argument, there is only so much work to be done, and if machines do more of it, less will remain for people to do. On these grounds, the logical conclusion would be to end modern technology. The entire earth's population, to say nothing of a mere 1.5 million Canadians, could be employed merely in carrying by hand (in 100 pound parcels) all freight now transported between, say, Vancouver and Halifax. But this Luddite vision would consign most of the world's peoples to death by starvation, and to those few who remained living a life of poverty known last in the Stone Age. The Episcopal Commission for Social Affairs sees a greater role for wage and price controls--of a more balanced and equitable variety, aimed more at the rich--as a way of stemming the rate of inflation. But a more radical vision would have seen wage and price controls--of any type--as a snare and a delusion. Wage and price controls do not cure inflation any more than pressing down on the water in a bathtub will lower its level. Inflation is caused by excessive money creation on the part of the government central banking authorities, and thus only a change in monetary policy can put an end to inflation. According to the authoritative Fraser Institute study, The Illusion of Wage Price Controls, moreover, this policy brings with it a host of other social and economic ills: black markets, shortages, queues, rationing, and a general disrespect for the law. The bishops call for greater emphasis on financial support for the poor and the unemployed. On humanitarian grounds, emergency economic aid of this sort can surely be justified. But once past a certain threshhold point, it can threaten to promote continued unemployment. If this aid is contrived in such a manner as to financially penalize those who accept jobs, this will retard reemployment, not enhance it. In Canada, a family of four with one breadwinner can actually receive more money from welfare payments, than in the form of after-tax income from low wage employment. In British Columbia, for example, the minimum wage level is $3.65 per hour. At 40 hours per week, this translates into a monthly after-tax, take-home pay of $562.52. But the same family can be entitled to $415 in support allowances, plus anywhere from $0 to $455 in the form of shelter allowances, adding up to a relatively hefty $870 per month, at maximum. True, such a family could apply to the B.C. Ministry of Human Resources to make up the difference between actual earnings and welfare entitlements, so it would not actually lose out by engaging in paid labour. But under such a system, it should occasion little surprise that few labourers indeed, voluntarily venture out into the cold winds of employment. For it is the rare individual who would willingly give up his full-time leisure for the dubious prospects of low wage employment. Such a system is truly generous--but generous to a fault. It should be curtailed--and in the interests of employment. Next, the bishops single out labour unions to play a more decisive role in curing unemployment. But this is like asking the fox to guard the chicken coop. The raison d'etre of the union movement is to raise wages for its own membership--whether or not justified by productivity increases--and the major cause of unemployment is wage rates artificially boosted beyond productivity levels. According to Lady Barbara Wootton, a Labour Party Peer in the U.K. House of Lords, "(It is) the business of a union to be anti-social; the members would have a just grievance if their officials and committees ceased to put sectional interests first." The view of unions held by most Canadians is that of a long-suffering underdog, struggling valiantly against overwhelming odds, to improve the wages and working conditions of all employees. Because of this image, most Canadians have been extremely sympathetic to the aims of the unions; our labour legislation is indicative of the warm support accorded by the citizenry. It is perhaps for this reason that our media have not subjected the unionized sector to the scrutiny it visits upon all other Canadian economic institutions. But the statement of Lady Barbara Wootton paints an entirely different picture. To be sure, in this view unions can still be counted upon to improve the employment package--but only for their own membership. But we must realize that the poor, the afflicted, the oppressed, those at the very bottom of the economic pyramid, are not found on union rolls in any great numbers. As well, unions have strongly supported legislation which impacts heavily, and negatively, on those at the bottom of the economic pyramid. Textile tariffs, the minimum wage law and opposition to prison labour all come to mind. Our first principle thus gives us pause before entrusting the welfare of the economically downtrodden to the tender mercies of organized labour. The reason this "first principle" is so important is that in the modern economy, it is the rich who so often in effect steal from the poor. They do it, unfortunately for the poor, not by stealth and in the dark of night (where they could be apprehended by the forces of law), but legally, out in the open, and in the light of day (where it is well nigh impossible to stop them). Bailouts for large corporations, subsidies to the arts, to sport, protective tariffs which make it impossible to import cheap products from abroad, marketing boards which artificially raise the prices of items such as eggs and milk, subsidies to export companies to allow them to sell more cheaply in foreign markets, foreign aid (which goes mainly to wealthy leaders of impoverished countries), these and more are all ways in which monies are forcibly transferred ("stolen from") the poor and given to the rich. One looks in vain to the bishops for any condemnation of practices such as these. The bishops themselves, and the pundits as well, have interpreted the statement as a critique of capitalism. Indeed, one newspaper went so far as to headline its coverage: "Bishops' attack on capitalism stirs up storm." But one thing must be made clear: whatever it is, the bishops' report is not, and cannot be, a critique of laissez-faire capitalism. For it deals with the Canadian economy of 1982-1983, an economy which has many facets of public ownership and involvement. Therefore, in objecting to the unemployment which characterizes the Canadian economy, the bishops can and must be interpreted as objecting to the operation of our modern mixed economy! This is an economy in which government production of goods and services and government regulation and taxation account for nearly 50 per cent of all economic activity. Had the bishops concentrated on this needless, inefficient and counterproductive government intervention, and on a swollen, burgeoning public sector, they would have much more nearly focused attention on the real cause of poverty in Canada--and in the rest of the world as well. Equal Pay Legislation by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The advocates of equal pay for work of equal value castigate the market for its inherent unfairness. Instead of the "anarchy" of free enterprise, they propose that all wages be set on the basis of skill, effort, responsibility and working conditions. These would be determined by boards of "experts," and tribunals of bureaucrats and civil servants, who substitute their "objective" assessments for the chaotic judgement of a system of competitive labour markets. There are many and serious objections which can be levelled against this scheme. Perhaps most important, the entire proposal is predicated upon a male-female wage "gap" resulting from employer discrimination. But as Fraser Institute research has shown, no such phenomenon actually exists. As well, contrary to the self-styled feminists, there is nothing intrinsic to a job that makes it worthy of compensation. Crucial in any determination of wage rates is the demand on the part of consumers for the service supplied. Right now, for example, the skill, effort, responsibility and working conditions of dentists are such that they receive high compensation. But were a cure for tooth decay to be uncovered tomorrow, their wages would plummet without any diminution whatsoever in these objective measurements on the part of the practitioners of this profession. Further, any proposal which artificially raises the salaries of a given calling beyond its productivity level threatens it with unemployment. But equal pay enactments are always couched in terms of raising female incomes, never reducing those of males. As such, they threaten to price women out of the market, in a manner similar to what has already happened to young people, who have been rendered less employable by minimum wage laws. There is also the embarrassment that when boards or tribunals in the different jurisdictions have attempted to "objectively" set the value of a job, the results have varied widely. When entrepreneurs poorly estimate the worth of a job, they are automatically penalized. If they set wages too high, they risk bankruptcy; too low and they are likely to suffer severe quit rates. Unfortunately, no such automatic reward and penalty device can operate in the public sector. Equal pay legislation is a form of wage - price control. As such, wages are frozen in place, despite changing market conditions. For example, if there is a sudden need for more nurses, and fewer fire fighters, an inflexible wage system will be unable to encourage the former, and discourage the latter. A decade ago Canada rashly experimented with wage - price controls. It was a disaster, in the view of all people of good will. That we are seriously flirting with this unsavory idea so soon after underscores the point that those who are ignorant of history are doomed to repeat the mistakes of the past. - 30 - 2 EXPO Walter Block The Fraser Institute Expo has gone out a blaze of glory, with a gigantic fireworks display accompanied by a Provincial-wide orgy of mutual self congratulation. In the afterglow of this splendid occurrence, critics can scarcely expect tci be heralded. However, certain aspects of the World's F'air need to be examined so that we do not draw the wrong public policy conclusions from it. That there were successes, no one can doubt. The original plans called for some 13 million visitors; in the event, over 20 million showed up, courtesy of good weather -- and heightened terrorist activities in Europe. In addition, EXPO was expected to lose a cool $310 million although the final and definitive iJigures are not yet in, it looks as if the shortfall will be significantly below that figure. In fact, the triumph was so great that the Social Credit party was able to rely heavily on this factor for its recent electoria1 win at the po11ing booths. But there were neqative aspects as well, and when these are balanced against positives, it is unclear that the people of British Colurctbia really turned out to be beneficiaries. Expense Let us first consider the large loss of money involved. This was an expenditure of huge proportions. While ordinary private businesses do ofttimes indeed suffer financial setbacks, they are never undertaken on purpose, nor contemplated with equanimity in advance, as was done in this case. And the reason is simple. People don't usually intend to lose their own hardearned cash. Those who do so, usually end up with little or nothing to show for their efforts. Had Jimmy Pattison treated revenues earmarked for EXPO s his own, for example, it is unlikely in the extreme that he would have spent them in this way. There is a social .justification for this phenomenon as well. Business losses imply that the revenues spent on the product by the entrepreneur were not valued as greatly by the paying customers. If EXPO ends up losing $300 million, we can deduce from that fact alone that the public valued the resources spent on this World's Fair precisely this much more than the benefits derived therefrom. This means that consumer welfare would have been $300 million higher had these monies been allowed to stay in the hands of their original owners, instead of being taken from them in the form of taxes. Had these dollars not been allotted to the public sector, they could have been spent in the ordinary way-- on toasters and skateboards, radios and cabbages, videos c-ind furniture -- and the people of the province would have been better off to the tune of some $300 million. A Party One argument in behalf of EXPO, intended to defend it against the charge of losing money, is that this event "was one vast party in behalf of all of British Columbia, and like it or not, parties cost money." True, all too true. Festivities are indeed indeed expensive, and the bigger and more lavish they are, the more they cost. But gala events are usually put on, and paid for, by the party giver. The invited quests may bring a present (although this is never mandatory) , but they are not forced to pay an admission price at the gate, nor to make up any shortfalls through increased taxes which would otherwise not have had to have been collected. If the leading politicians of B.C. had really wanted to give a party, and to do so in the manner in which most people engage in this activity, they could have invited anyone they had wanted to, but paid for it with their own money! Tourism A more serious attempt to defend the vast EXPO losses is to claim that they were really an investment in tourism for the province. But this, too, is problematic. If promoting future visits from out of towners were the goal, why build EXPO? Why not just subsidise their travel costs to Vancouver? After al1, it was recognised by everyone that EXPO would not last forever. The fair was seen only as the bait through which hordes of foreigners could be induced to see the many natural beauties of our province. But surely we could have enticed many more people to the lower mainland by paying their way here, than by setting up a world's fair, and charging them for the privilege of viewing it. Even this criticism does not go deeply enough. It accepts as given the desirability of subsidizing the tourist sector, and argues only that EXPO was an inefficient means toward that end, But we can ca1l into question the premise that it makes good public policy sense for government to artificially promote tourism. Once the issue is posed in this manner, it is not clear that there is a case for taking the revenues of the populace as a whole and diverting them into any one industry. First of all, why tourism? Why not forestry, or mining, or real estate, or farming, or frisbee production, for that matter? All of these employ thousands of people (or perhaps could, with a heavy enough subsidy), and are fine upstanding industries in their own right. Why is their claim to government largesse any the less than that of tourism? Secondly, if the EXPO ploy succeeds and the tourist sector does indeed receive a shot in the arm, the owners of the individual hotels, motels, trailesr camps, restaurants, gift shops, etc, are the ones who will mainly benefit. Why should they be allowed to recoup, based on the investment funds derived from the entire populace? Is it fair to ask all British Columbians, many of whom are far poorer than the businessmen in the tourist sector to finance investment aimed to help the latter? Such perverse income redistribution is hardly in the public interest. Further, in the free enterprise system, it is the consumer, not the producer, who is presumably sovereign. Money is not funneled into firms or industries at the behest of businessmen anxious to enhance their revenues, by government bureaucrats, who desire to control other people's property. On the contrary, disbursements are based solely on the desires of the paying customer. Given this system, there is no warrant to take money from all the people, and simply give it to the tourist industry (in the form of EXPO), since had consumers wished for this occurrence, they were perfectly free to re-order their priorities on their own accounts. Every penny spent on EXPO, it must be remembered, was a penny that could not be utilized for other goods and services. And in the view of the consumer, welfare was enhanced by spending it his own way, not in the manner designed by the well-intentioned government in Victoria, for a World's Fair. Lottery Had EXPO been financed through tax revenues, the case against it would have been simple, complete, and airtight. People would have been forced to pay through taxes for an item they could have supported through the stock market, but their funds were never solicited in this manner. However, the losses from this event have been funded not through the Finance Ministry, but out of the revenues of the B.C. lottery system. This completes the analysis, since it can no longer unambiguously be contended that the citizenry was forced to yield up revenues against its will, as would be true for the tax system. Despite this complication, there is still a case to be made against the financing of EXPO. For one thing, there is a curtailment of full free choice involved here: while the public can indeed choose whether or not to buy a lottery ticket, options have been circumscribed by the fact that only the government may legally offer to provide such a service. Apart from this, the monies raised from the lottery could have been used to defray the provincial deficit, or to 1ower other taxes. This would have benefitted the public, given that the people are able to spend their money in a way that can better promote their interests than can governement expenditures. As a result, even if no taxes at all are used to pay for the EXPO losses, taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been but for this event. The world's fair thus cannot be justified as a gigantic provincial party, nor as an "investment" in tourism, or excused on the basis that it was not supported by tax revenues. If anything, EXPO most resembles the bread and circuses given to the populace by the Roman emperors two millennia ago. And it certainly cannot he defended on these grounds, at least not in the modern era. Flag Burning by Walter Block In the libertarian philosophy, free speech rights are interpreted as but an aspect of the more basic rights to private property. For example, if someone breaks into my house at 3:00 A.M., and starts reading in a loud voice the sonnets of Shakespeare, he may not properly object if I toss him bodily out onto the street that I have violated his rights of free speech. He has no rights of free speech -- on my property. He has such rights only on his own property, or on that (a hall, auditorium, newspaper advertisement, etc.) which he has rented from someone else. - 30 December 27,1989 1 UREA FORMALDEHYDE FOAM INSULATION AND THE PROBLEM OF GOVERNMENT PRODUCT SAFETY CERTIFICATION By Walter Block June Financial Post Column The Canadian government's creation of the Urea Formaldehyde Foam Insulation (UFFI) crisis has brought into serious question the entire case for public sector involvement in the consumer product safety certification industry. What is the UFFI crisis? UFFI was made eligible in September, 1977 for a $500.00 grant under the Canadian Home Insulation Program by the Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation (CWHC), in an attempt on the part of the government to encourage the reinsulation of older housing accommodation. Although the program may well have been conceived with the best of intentions, its actual operation has proved to be nothing less than a disaster. According to experts commissioned by Ottawa, the foam tends to break down chemically after installation in wall cavities, and to release formaldehyde vapors which are injurious to human health. Complaints frequently cited include nausea, eye and nose irritation, dry throat and nose, coughing, nose bleeds, headaches, insomnia, dizziness, allergy, skin irritation, vomiting, shortness of breath, diarrhea in infants, and even some types of cancer. So dangerous are these symptons that UFFI was temporarily banned by the Federal government in Decembr, 1980 under the Hazardous Products Act. The problem is widespread, moreover, and costly to solve. Accordingly to the best estimates, 100,000 homes, and an undetermined (but suspected large) number of office buildings, factories and schools have been treated with UFFI. And the only way to make . the interior environment safe is to completely remove the offending UFFI (rhymes with "yuckie") from the premises. Removal charges alone are independently estimated at $20,000 for the average size home, but to this must be added costs for structural deterioration of houses, mildew damage, blistering paint, miscellaneous home repairs, psychic harm and inconvenience, and temporary relocation costs for people who suffer from respiratory problems. When all of these are added up, the total may come to the $75,000 damages claimed in an UFFI class action suit now before the Quebec Superior Court. As well, there are the costs of testing for UFFI damages (walls must be dismantled) even in cases where no harm is subsequently found. What has been the government's reaction? In a word, they have "stonewalled". On April 23, 1981, Health Minister Monique Begin continued indefinitely a temporary ban on UFFI begun in December of last year, but has said the government is not prepared to compensate those who used the insulation. Officials who granted subsidies for UFFI, who advertised and otherwise promoted it, said Begiry, in justification of her stance, "...were the victims, as much as the people were, of lack of knowledge of new chemicals". The difficulty with this response, of course, is that government has taken upon itself the certification role for consumer product safety, in this and in other areas as well. By advertising, recommending, promoting, and even offering subsidies for UFFI, Begin, the Health Ministry, the CMHC and other government agencies responsible for this fiasco were acting as experts, approving and thus in effect certifying the safety and other qualities of UFFI. True, they did so despite an alleged National Research Council warning that UFFI standards "were inadequate", and in the face of evidence from other countries such as Sweden and the U.S., suggesting that this material was hazardous. But this attests only to the irresponsible manner in which Canadian officials carried out their self-assumed Cmandate. It does not place them in the category of "innocent victims", as claimed by Begin. If there are any "innocent victims", they are the people who had their ordinary caution as purchasers removed -- by the government subsidy for UFFI. Then, too, there were a stream of official but contradictory excuses and suggestions for the alleviations of the problem. UFFI is really of "no danger"; a "study of the subject will be undertaken, perhaps, within the next two or three months"; the difficulties are really due to "faulty and inferior installation", and not to the chemical itself; the solution therefore resides in "sealing walls" and "increasing ventilation to push the air outdoors". "Opening the window", however, will probably sound to UFFI sufferers like urging ancient Romans to "fiddle faster" in an attempt to save their city from burning. It is also rather inconsistent to tell people to open up their windows to air out a house -- when it was insultated in the first place in order to save heating costs. What has been the response from the opposition parties? According to MPs Margaret Mitchell (NDP - Vancouver East), Health Critic James McGrath (PC - St. John's East) and Consumer Critic Geoffrey Scott (PC -Hamilton Wentworth), the government is responsible for UFFI and should pay the costs of its removal. The difficulty with this suggestion, however well-intentioned, is that government, by its very nature, cannot pay for these costs, or indeed for any other such costs. Rather, if called upon to do so, it will simply shift the burden to the taxpayers. The Mitchell-McGrath-Scott suggestion, then, translates into a demand that one group of innocent people, taxpayers in general, subsidze another innocent group, those whom have been victimized by the govermental UFFI policy. If these MPs had really wanted those responsible for UFFI to bear the costs of compensation, they would have urged that those individuals who inaugurated and carried through the program pay for it out of their own pockets. Mitchell also called for CMHC to make available to the stricken homeowners "information and advice" on how to handle the UFFI problem. But this is like asking the fox to guard the chicken coop, and must be rejected out of hand on that basis. For, as we have seen, it was the very same CMHC which approved the UFFI program in the first place. Why, for goodness sake, did the government become involved in UFFI subsidies? Government acted in this way as part of its energy self-sufficiency policy. Insulation cuts down on fuel bills, but the private marketplace was deemed to be underinvesting in such conservation initiatives. The difficulty, here, is that if private insultion demand were indeed underoptimal, it was due to yet another government policy -the "made-in-Canada" oil price which was artifically kept below world (market) levels. Had Canadians been forced to bear the full costs of their fuel requirements, they would have doubtless installed insulation in their homes and undertaken other conservation measures on a voluntary self-interested basis. Instead, economic reality was kept hidden. The artifically low oil prices subsidized (at taxpayer expense) overoptimal useage of home heating fuel, and discouraged insulation and other conservation. Here we have yet another instance of unwise government policy ## 1 leading to predictable but inefficient market reactions, and then unwise government policy #2 attempting to alleviate conditions brought about by #1, but instead creating still further problems. When will they ever learn? Speaking of which, what can we learn from this sorry mess? A good lesson in how not to conduct public policy could be obtained by considering UFFI, federal responsiblity, compensation, and errors made in this particular occurrence. On a more basic level, one might enquire as to the relative merits of the public vs. private sectors in certifying the quality (safety, reliability, durability, finess, weight, measure, etc.) of all consumer products. In the eyes of most people, this is clearly a government responsiblity. For does not the greedy capitalist have an incentive to sell the public dangerous, unreliable, easily broken, low quality and short weight merchandise? How then can this self-same private sector rise above such temptations, and be entrusted with the even more important task of certifying the quality of products? Won't manufacturers be able to bribe and subvert any private certification companies? Although such arguments have convinced many people, they are too facile by a half. First of all, there are many private companies and individuals long in existence who evaluate consumer products for a fee and/or who place their "stamp of approval" on goods which pass their own self-created "tests." Among the former are such prestigious and well respected organizations as the Consumers Association of Canada, Canadian Consumer magazine, Consumer Union, Consumer Reports magazine, "Consumer Research" test reports, various Auto Association magazines, Renters Associations and other consumer associations, and independent testing laboratories such as Dataquest and Buyers Laboratory. In the latter category are such highly trusted and world-renowned private certification agencies as the Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval and the institution of Kosher foods. As well, brand names as Heinz, Kellogg's, General Foods, Coca Cola and Campbells are trustworthy indications of quality, and retailers and department stores such as Eaton's stand behind each item sold. These firms could not have remained in existence, nor have been subject to bribes, inefficiency or just plain ignorance had they not been providing valuable certification service. Where is Vichyssiose Soup today? Can you imagine what would have happened to CMHC, the Health Ministry, Monique Begin, were they private corporations, or individuals whose paychecks were dependent on voluntary consumer payments? It is no accident moreover, that we expect better results in product certification from private sources. In the market system, such firms compete with each other. When they do a poor job, they lose profits and disappear from the scene. Automatically. Suppose you were trying to teach rats to run a maze. With one group of rats you automatically reward success with food, and punish failure with an electric shock. Call them the businessmen rats. In the other group, success is not materially rewarded, nor failure punished. Call these the bureaucrat rats. Is there any doubt as to which rats would perform better, even if talents and abilities were randomly distributed at first? No one can rationally claim that business is not given to error, greed, and subversion. The point, though, is that civil servants, subject to the same human failings, do not have their actions reined in by a market test of profit and loss, while businessmen do. The Financial Post Opinion March 28, 1981 19 Column by Walter Block There is evidence foreign aid can often be counterproductive The prime minister's recent whirlwind globetrotting trip on behalf of a closer NorthSouth dialogue makes it a good time to review Canadian foreign aid policy. At first blush, aid to underdeveloped countries seems noble, humanitarian, and serendipitously, in our own national interest as well. After all, Canadian aid to the less fortunate nations surely must save people from starvation, encourage the development of primitive economies, increase our exports and enhance freedom by forestalling the spread of communism. There is much evidence, however, showing aid programs to be questionable means toward these worthy ends. Further, there are indications that private trade and investment, currently shackled and hampered by tariff and import barriers in the Western industrial countries, may be more efficacious than intergovernmental transfers. Economic development Food grants arc a major part of foreign aid, and Canada is the world leader here, meeting about 30% of its bilateral commitments in this form. (Canada funnels 70% of its total donations bilaterally; 30% is given through multilateral channels such as the Organization for Economic Co-operation & Development.) Foodstuffs are obviously basic, because the malnutrition which unfortunately prevails in many less developed countries is one of the blocks to economic betterment. But compelling humanitarian requirements in cases of actual famine aside, even this sort of aid is fraught with danger: massive gifts can take the profit incentive out of local agriculture; with fewer farmers and less land under cultivation, this can paradoxically worsen, not improve, the long-term prospects of food production and hence safety from future starvation. Capital grants are likewise destructive to long-term productivity. Although the ancient Egyptian pyramids were an extraordinary instance of capital accumulation, they resulted in no economic gain in the basic sense of contributing to the well-being of the great masses of people. Even more wasteful are the modem equivalents of such monument-building made possible by foreign aid: the steel mills in Egypt, the modem chemical plants in India, the tractors given to aboriginal peoples who cannot operate them, the automobile assembly plants scattered widely throughout the Third World (which are the result of protective tariffs on automobile imports as well). These are wasteful because the products fabricated in this highly technological manner actually cost the underdeveloped countries more to manufacture themselves than they could have paid by importing the finished product from more developed countries. Many people deduce from the fact that the rich countries have much capital and the poor ones little that what is required is vast capital infusions. But this wet-sidewalkscause-rain reasoning points to almost the exact opposite of what is really needed. Capital, in and of itself, does not create wealth. It is rather the result of a process of economic development that also includes, as complementary factors, such things as the willingness to work, the skill and education of the labor force, and relatively free and private markets protected by a stable code of laws. One indication of the importance of these other phenomena is the fact that a large proportion of the very limited capital generated in the poor countries is actually invested in the more advanced nations, where private property rights are far more secure. Then there is foreign aid in the form of technological and other education. Canada ranks third among the donor nations in this category, behind only France and New Zealand, meeting just over 15% of its bilateral commitments to the underdeveloped world in this form. But the difficulty is that in the absence •of such facilities as fully equipped laboratories, libraries, computer centres, and without the mutual support of thousands of other similarly educated scientists and technologists, such aid cannot be efficiently utilized. And the proof can be seen in the immigration patterns of the educated classes in the Third World a "reverse brain drain," toward the more advanced countries. Foreign aid of whatever variety — food, capital, technology or outright. cash grants — moreover sets up a welfare-like dependency status on the recipient country. In much the same manner as domestic welfare programs sap the economic ambition, vitality and progress of their local clients, so do programs on international levels have similar effects. Canadian self-interest If foreign aid is unlikely to help the recipient, can it at least help the donor? (Note: the focus here is on economic, not military aid, which must be justified on entirely different grounds.) Pragmatic considerations would seem to support this view. For one thing, the Canadian International Development Agency requires that about 80% of its bilateral disbursements be spent on Canadian goods and services. But behind the bookkeeping legerdemain, this amounts only to a free gift of goods and services from Canada to other countries, with no offsetting returns. No one is foolish enough to •suppose that West German reparations to Israel actually benefited the economic selfinterest of West Germany — even though much of it took the form of exporting domestic items. Nor does the defendant in a civil case rejoice in his new-found wealth when he is forced by a court decision to compensate the plaintiff— even in the form of goods Ie himself produces. Will Canadian aid to other countries at least make it more likely that they will choose the path of democracy and market institutions rather than fall into the communist and collectivist ambit? Unfortunately, not only will Western foreign aid not attain this end — it is likely to undermine it, and instead to encourage socialism and totalitarianism :in the Third World. First of all, Canadian aid is traditionally in the form of govcmmcnt-to-gov-emment grants. This strengthens the role of the public vs the private sector in the underdeveloped countries. But political freedom is a delicate and precious flower, it cannot live where the bulk of economic activity is carried on in the public sector. Second, Canadian foreign aid has been given to countries that have made explicitly socialist avowals in their centralized economic plans — and our largesse has in no small degree shielded them from the repercussions of such policies and allowed them to continue unchecked down this path. For example, we find in the five-year plan of India, a country which continues to receive strong Canadian support, the view that "planning should take place with a view to the establishment of a socialistic pattern of society where the principal means of production are under social ownership or control." The alternative Of far greater benefit to the nations of both North and South is a policy of free trade and unregulated international flows of capital. This will greatly benefit the Canadian standard of living, as we can purchase many goods such as clothing from the* less developed world for far less than it costs to make them ourselves. But of far greater importance, such policies will truly lead to Third-World economic development — and to tighter integration with our own economy. How, then, to account for the hypocrisy of a nation whose leaders loudly proclaim their interest in economic development for the poor countries and yet remain steadfast in their determination to maintain protective tariffs, quotas and other impediments to economic intercourse with the Third World? walter BLOCKis senior economist at the Eraser Institute, Vancouver. FREE ENTERPRISE ZONES IN CHINA An Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block You'll never believe the latest from Red China - Are you ready for this? Right. now,, there are four free enterprise zones deep within the bowels of this gigantic Communist country. Here, capitalism, not communism, is practiced. Enterprise is not stifled, the economic rules are few, taxes are low and private investment is encouraged. The leader of mainland China, Deng Xiaoping, recently visited one of these four Special Economic Zones as they are termed, the one called Shenzhen, which is just north of now embattled Hong Kong. As a result of his approving visit, the communist government has announced that 14 new Free Enterprise Zones would soon be established. But all is not sweetness and light in China. Laissez-faire is not the order of the day there — not quite yet. The forces of darkness are still alive and kicking, thank you kindly. According to the People's Daily, there are traditionalists who feel that "it is unavoidable that some of the filth and mire of capitalism will be brought in" by such adventurism. Especially fearful, to these old time Communists, is the spectre of allowing foreigners to open factories on holy Chinese soil, employ Chinese workers and, gulp, export the profits. Nevertheless, in addition to comrade Deng Xiaoping, Premier Zhao Ziyang and party secretary Hu Yaobang are behind the new effort to expand free enterprise zones. It appears they were bowled over by the Shenzhen experience. There,_in a poor fishing village, the people had been permitted to sell their catch on the open market, at prices far higher than those prevailing in state-run shops. -2 As a result their standard of living catapulted up into the 20th century, and their huts were crammed full of new electronic gadgets. This is but the tip of the iceberg for free market zones, according to a study by the same name recently published by the Fraser Institute. Written by Simon Fraser University economics professor Herbert Grubel, the book makes the case for economic freedom everywhere. In China, yes. In the third world, yes. And even in relatively advanced nations such as Canada, which are always in danger of slipping back into the filth and mire of Marxist Socialism, unless new infusions of free market competitive principles are continually brought into play. For further information on this fascinating study: Free Market Zones by Herbert Grubel, you can write to the Fraser Institute. - 30 A FREE MARKET IN KIDNEYS? by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute According to recent reports, the black market value of a kidney which can be transplanted is some $13,000 -- which translates to roughly seven times its weight in gold. Such an occurrence may occasion all sorts of references to King Midas -- who was supposed to have been turned into a statue of sold gold, but behind this rather dramatic way of characterizing the value of human organs lies in a story of untold and tragic human suffering. There are hundreds and even thousands of Canadians whose lives could be vastly improved could they but have the use of a healthy kidney. Paradoxically, there are other thousands of people who die each year, taking perfectly healthy kidneys to the grave with them, who have no financial incentive at all to bequeath these organs to those in need. Why, it may well be asked, cannot potential donors presently be given a pecuniary reward for doing the right thing? That is, what precludes a businessman from purchasing the future rights to a kidney from potential donors, and then selling these items to those suffering from kidney disease? The problem is, it is illegal to harness marketplace incentives in order to encourage kidney donors. Anyone who set up a business of this sort would be summarily imprisoned. Instead, our society must resort to all sort of inefficient stratagems toward this end. Famous personages have exhorted us, in the event that we suffer untimely death, to make a posthumous gift of these organs. Medical schools coach their students on the best techniques for approaching next-of-kin; the difficulty is that they must ask permission at the precise time when they are least likely to be given it -- upon the sudden demise of a loved one. As a result, all of this has been to little avail. While potential recipients languish on painful kidney dialysis machines waiting ghoulishly for a traffic fatality which may spell life for them, the public has refused to sign cards in sufficient numbers giving permission for automatic posthumous donor status. Things have even come to such a pass that there are grotesque and fascistic plans now being bruited about which would allow the government to seize the kidneys of accident victims unless they have signed cards denying such permission. The free enterprise system, were it allowed to be operated in this instance, might well be a God-send to the unfortunates who suffer from diseased kidneys. A legalized marketplace could encourage thousands of donors. Would you sign a card donating your kidney after death for 13,000 big ones, right now, in cold hard cash? There are very few people who would turn up their noses at such an offer. And if sufficient supplies were still not forthcoming at this level, prices would rise even further until all demand was satisfied. Given free enterprise incentives, pardon the pun, we would be up to our armpits in kidneys. This is the tried and true process we rely on to bring us all the other necessities of life: food, clothing and shelter. After all, we do not depend for the provision of these goods and services on voluntary donations. We know this to be a relatively unreliable system -- notwithstanding the fact that it is flogged by numerous opinion leaders in the case of organ transplants. There is no doubt whatsoever that those presently responsible for preventing a free market in kidneys take these actions with the noblest of motives. To them, legalizing the purchase and sale of human organs would be the ultimate in degradation. Far better, from their viewpoint, that people donate their bodily parts for free so that thousands of kidney disease sufferers may live normal lives. However, no matter how benevolent the intentions of the prohibitionists, it cannot be denied that the effect of their ill-conceived actions is to render it less likely that those in need shall be served. It is time, it is long past time, for our society to put aside its archaic and prejudicial opposition to the marketplace, so that we can relieve the suffering, and in many cases, lift the death sentence we have inadvertently placed on as hopeless and hapless a group of citizens as ever existed. 30 October 28, 1986 The Free Trade Agreement and Job Creation By Walter Block Nowhere in the debate over the Free Trade Agreement has more economic confusion been allowed to run rampant than with regard to the question of job creation. According to the Economic Council of Canada, 250,000 net new jobs - that is, the total number created minus the total number lost - are likely to come into being as a result of the FTA. Brian Mulroney, perhaps the nation's number one cheerleader for the deal, hasten quoting this figure at the drop of a hat. Other pro free trade forces have not been slow on the uptake to parrot these figures. The opposition has been claiming that net job creation will be lower or even negative - more will be lost than generated -- or contenting themselves with the claim that such employment opportunities which arise will be of the hamburger flipping variety. The truth of the matter is that no permanent job creation whatsoever will occur as a result of free trade. Nor is this a /controversial matter within the profession of economics. The puzzle is that a group of reputable economists, such as presumably form the staff of the Economic Council of Canada, could have committed such a basic and elementary fallacy. Not that this is all to the bad: anything that promotes free trade will improve the lot of the average Canadian, and sometimes even falsehoods, as in this case, can prove beneficial. But there is a higher calling than mere economic prosperity for Canadians, and that is the pursuit of the truth, where ever it leads us. It is in view of this latter, more important goal that it behooves us to pierce the veil of ignorance surrounding the Council's claim, and to set the record straight. Why is it that the FTA will not create jobs, not a single one of them? The reason for this is simple. Free trade has nothing at all to do with employment. Its only effect will be on the kind of jobs available, not with their number. In order to see this quite clearly, we have to go back to fundamentals; we must reflect on what jobs are, why people want them, what are their economic purposes. Please excuse this voyage down memory lane, back to the introductory economics studied a decade or more ago, but with a fallacy as basic as this one that is our only option. A job is defined as something we would not do for its own sake. Those of us who earn a salary doing something we would be happy to do without compensation are really engaging in "play." The rest of us working slobs do so but because of the wages we are given in return. Why work at all, even for pay? We do so because we live in an environment of scarcity; that is, there are goods and services we cannot have unless we create them, and working is the way in which we produce things. If all sorts of manna continually rained down on us (food, clothing, shelter, VCRs, medical cures, sportscars), and no one wanted anything that was not in this way given to us, then no one would work. We would all play. Some of the "play" might be interesting and important-research, exploration, the arts - but it would still not be work in the technical economic sense. Why do employers hire people to work for them? Because of the productivity given to them by their employees. If a worker could not add to the value of the product created by the firm, he would be unemployable. And the wage he is paid in the market tends to reflect the value of his contribution. Given the importance of work in the real world, why do we have unemployment? There are all sorts of reasons, but most of them amount to government insisting that workers be paid more than their productivity levels. On the micro level, enactments such as minimum wages, fair labour standards, union legislation in effect price potential suppliers of labour out of the market. As well, unemployment insurance and generous welfare payments create joblessness by subsidizing it. On the macro level, government interference with the money supply, interest rates, stock markets and business decisions can render the economy unstable, and lead to recessions and depressions. Joblessness, however, can also occur in the free unfettered market. Frictional unemployment ensues when people are searching for situations; they are in between jobs, or are looking for a first job, or are rejecting present offers in the hope of better ones in future. How many jobs are there in an economy at any given time? As many as there are people willing to work. That is, as many as there are people who want more material goods than they have, and value these items more than the leisure they must forego when they become employed. New jobs are not something vouchsafed by governments upon a grateful citizenry, although ofttimes governments like to take credit for this process ("We created 4.2 million jobs over the last decade.") The fact that most new jobs are created by small businesses is irrelevant; if there were no small businesses, the jobs would emerge in large businesses or in self employment. Ra,ther, new employment slots occur automatically in the market, whenever people want them. When millions of new immigrants came to the U.S. at the turn of the century, no one had to create the millions of new jobs for them. They were created because these newcomers wanted to purchase goods and services, and were willing to trade their labour power in order to do so. And the same applies to the demobilization of millions of soldiers at the end of the war, and to the rise in labour force participation of women in the past few decades, or any other sudden onset of a need for more jobs. These people, too, achieved employment status, not through government, but through the magic of the marketplace. If jobs are limited only be people's desire to work, how then can a free trade agreement increase employment? The answer, it should now be clear, is that an end to tariffs and other such barriers cannot raise the number of a nation's jobs. The only thing that can increase employment slots is an additional number of people seeking work. All free trade can do is multiply the efficiency with which individuals labour. That is, instead of producing rice ourselves, directly, we can trade for rice produced in Texas or Louisiana with, say, maple syrup. Since Canadians are poor rice producers, but wise in the ways of all things having to do with the maple tree, we can, paradoxically, have more rice for the same amount of effort expended not by producing it ourselves, but by first gathering the syrup, and then trading it for rice. In similar manner, the carpenter can get more piano lessons, and the piano teacher more kitchen cabinets, not by doing the work of the other, but by sticking to one's own specialty, and then exchanging for the expertise of the other. Even were it possible, it is not advisable to raise the number of jobs that need to be done. We could, for example, increase employment opportunities merely by prohibiting railroads, and demanding that the cargo they used to haul be transported, instead, by people carrying 50 pound sacks on their backs. This could create work for literally trillions of people! But the important point to realize here is that we would not thereby necessarily expand the number of jobs available. Remember, people are already working to their desired extent (except for governmentally created unemployment - and there is no reason to expect that this rate will change as we embrace free trade); if we abolish railroads, the same number of people will still be working. Only now more of them, many, many more of them, will be needed to transport goods; consequently, fewer will be available to do other more important work. Society would suffer, poverty would increase, but joblessness need not change by one iota. The Gap between Science and Public Policy by Walter Block Our scientists and engineers are able to create automobiles capable of safely doing 150 miles per hour, at least on the straightaways. In the event, however, these cars do 10 m.p.h. in bumper to bumper rush hour traffic, courtesy of a public policy mired in the horse and buggy days. Our doctors are now capable of transplanting organs from one person to another. This is an art which would have been inconceivable just a few short years ago. Indeed, even today it still seems magical. But do not rejoice too quickly. Thanks to legislative ineptitude, there is a shortage of available kidneys, eyes, livers, hearts and lungs. Because of technology, we now have airplanes at our disposal that can cross the continent, a distance of some 3500 miles, in a matter of six hours or so. And yet all too often, before we even start out, there is a delay of several hours; and when we arrive, we are all too likely to find ourselves stacked up in a parade of airplanes waiting to touch down. Because of breakthroughs in building construction, it is now possible to create sufficient low cost housing for all Canadians. And yet in Ontario, presently the most prosperous of all the provinces, there are long queues of people futilely searching for rental suites. Why is it that physical scientists are able to supply society with such miraculous accomplishments on a seemingly endless basis, while our public policy, the domain of economists, is in such disarray that we are often precluded from the full enjoyment of what might otherwise be available to us? The short and simple answer to this question is that the findings of economics, are all too often completely ignored in public policy making. Take the four problems mentioned at the outset. They are all cases where public policy has failed to come to grips with the concept of supply and demand. According to this elementary bit of economic analysis, if a price minimum or price floor is placed on a good or service, there will be an excessive demand; more will be desired by the public than can be offered. With rent control, landlords are limited in the rents they may charge. Hence, new investors avoid this market like the plague. Tenants not only find it difficult to obtain housing, but paradoxically must even sometimes pay more for it than if incentives to build rental suites were not cut off at the knees. Present law prohibits the sale of human organs for transplant purposes. This, effectively, sets a zero price on such transactions. As a result, potential donors have less incentive than they would otherwise have to sign pledge cards, and many recipients are consigned to inferior medical techniques (e.g., kidney dialysis machines) and even to death, the ultimate degradation. Road and airport congestion are examples of the peak load problem. The demand for such services rises at certain times of the day. But unless there is a flexible pricing system in place which reflects the demand alterations, excessive demand, or crowding, are the inevitable result. . So the economic answers to all these problems are obvious and easy to operationalize: repeal rent control to end the housing shortage; allow commercial transactions in human organs, and alleviate the suffering of recipients who must now do without; and inaugurate a peak load pricing system to cure highway and airport congestion. "Easier said than done," is one possible response to these modest proposals. "Forget it," is the more likely assessment of those in charge of public policy planning. Which leads us to ask why the advice of economists is often ignored, while that of physical scientists is almost always implemented. There appear to be two main reasons. For one thing, self interest. Powerful people have much at stake with regard to economic arrangements; very rarely do special interests have anything to gain or lose in a dispute over theories in physics or chemistry. For another, very few non economists have much humility when it comes to questions of economics. People will often say, "I'm not an economist, but..." and then proceed to rhapsodize about their theories of economics. But no one says "I'm not a physicist, but..." and then articulates his views on this arcane science. The importance of German private property - 30 1. 3 Dr. Block is an economist with the F raser Insfifllt~_ uring and after the Second World War thousands of Germans fled their homes. They migrated to the four comers of the earth: Australia, South America, Western Europe, the U.S. In our own country, they formed the backbone of what is now the German-Canadian community, one known for its work ethic, its strong family orientation, its stick-to-itiveness and its intellectual brilliance. Now that East Germany has united with its western counterpart. its government has decided, quite appropriately, to take on the trappings of capitalism. Foremost amongst these is the institution of private property rights. In this regard it has embarked on a program of returning land. farms, homes and factories to their rightful owners. a policy for which it should be heartily congratulated. And it is one that should be emulated by all of the countries that formerly suffered behind the Iron Curtain. This visionary and courageous program, however, has run into several difficulties. First of all, the government has decided to exempt from the plan all property seized between May 8, 1945, and October 6, 1949, prior to the founding of the late-but-not-lamented German Democratic Republic. This is intolerable. Just because people emigrated does not mean it is legitimate to seize their property. There is simply no legitimate statute of limitations on justice. As long as the property owners have proof of titJe-photographs, letters, records. etc.-it should not matter whether their homes and farms were expropriated before. during or after the aegis of any particular government. There is a second problem as well: the irresolution of the government. Stated Petra Speyrer, vice-consul for Germany in Vancouver: "It will take years and years. I am sure. to resolve (the land ownership issue). First of all, you have to find out whether to give property back or compensate with money. If money, then how much? How do you find out the value of the land? I am sure there will be a lot of lawsuits because people will wan! their land back and not JUS! money. It is very complicated:' With all due respect, the issue is not complicated at all. On the contrary, it is exceedingly simple. Of course it is the land and physical property that should be returned-nothing else. If the rightful owners want money instead, they are free to sell their holdings for whatever the market dictates. "How much" should be no business at all of a state run under the principles of free enterprise. (It is only in the case of property destruction-which does not in any case apply to land, certainly not to its site value-that such thorny problems could conceivably arise. But this is a small part of the privatization effort.) There is another reason besides pure justice for returning property to its rightful owners: pragmatism. In most advanced economies, labour accounts for some 75C;C of the Gross Domestic Product. The rest-rent, interest, profit, etc.-is created by the other factors of production. The entire land of a nation, according to most responsible estimates, is responsible for less than 10%. The property in question in what was formerly East Germany is a tiny fraction of even this amount. So in returning it all to the foreign nationals of German extraction who are its rightful owners, Germans will lose very little indeed. But they will gain immeasurably. For what these economies lack at present more than anything else in the world is the entrepreneurial spirit. And there could be no better demonstration of the fact that not only is entrepreneurship welcomed in these countries. it is treasured, than to give back the land-all of it, without any strings attached-to irs rightful owners. The countries of Eastern Europe are crying out for investment. What do you think will occur if they make a clean break with the past and return this stolen property? The likelihood is that the new owners will return for at least part of the year--bringing with them millions of dollars of investment funds, and, far more important, their skills and talents. Down that path leads Germany and Eastern Europe to industrial peace, material prosperity and a true market economy. If these countries persist in their stinginess in the return of stolen property, they may keep for themselves a few additional thousands of acres of land, but these holdings will never become very valuable, because without a free and vibrant economy none of the factors of production amount to very much. D BRITISH COLUMBIA REPORT, MARCH 11, 1991 i3 Private German Property by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. Thousands of Germans fled their property during and after World War II, from what was then East Germany. They migrated to all four corners of the earth: to Australia, to South America, to Western Europe, to the U.S. In our own country, they formed the backbone of what is now the German-Canadian community, one known for its work ethic, its strong family orientation, its stick-to-itiveness and its intellectual brilliance. N ow that East Germany is on its way to a life of freedom, forming once again a united country with its western counterpart, its government has decided, quite appropriately, to take on the trappings of capitalism. Foremost amongst these is of course the institution of private property rights. In this regard they have embarked upon a program of returning land, farms, homes and factories to their rightful owners, a policy for which they should be heartily congratulated. It is one which should be emulated by all of the countries which formerly suffered behind the Iron Curtain. This visionary and courageous program, however, has run into several difficulties. First of all, the government has decided to exempt from this plan all property seized between May 8, 1945 and October 6, 1949 prior to the founding of the late but not lamented and so called German Democratic Republic. But this is intolerable. Just because people emigrated, does not mean it is legitimate to seize their property -- and this applies regardless of the official auspices under which such acts were undertaken. There is simply no legitimate statute of limitations on justice. As long as the property owners have proof of title -- pictures, letters, records, etc. -- it should not matter whether their homes and farms were expropriated before, during or after the aegis of any particular government. There is a second problem as well: the irresolution of the government. Stated Petra Speyrer, vice-consul for Germany in Vancouver: "It will take years and years, I am sure, to resolve (the land ownership issue). First of all, you have to find out whether to give property back or compensate with money. If money, then how much? How do you find out the value of the land? I am sure there will be a lot of lawsuits because people will want their land back and not just money. It is very complicated." With all due respect, the issue is not complicated at all. On the contrary, it is exceedingly simple. Of course it is the land and physical property which should be returned -- and not anything else. If the rightful owners want money instead, they are free to sell their holdings for whatever the market dictates. "How much?" should be no business at all of a state run under the principles of free enterprise. (It is only in the case of property destruction -- which does not in any case apply to land, certainly not to its site value -- that such thorny problems could conceivably arise. But this is a small part of the privatization effort). There is another reason besides pure justice for returning property to its rightful owners -- all of it, not merely that seized at any particular epoch: pragmatism. It most advanced economics, labour accounts for over 75% of the G.D.P. The rest-rent, interest, profit, etc. -- are created by the other factors of production. The entire land of a nation, according to most responsible estimates, is responsible for less than 10% of G.D.P. The property in question in what was formerly East Germany accounts for a tiny fraction of even this amount. So in returning it all to the foreign nationals of German extraction who are its rightful owners, Germany lose very little indeed. But they will gain immeasurably. For what these economies lack at present more than anything else in the world is the entrepreneurial spirit. And there could be not better demonstration of the fact that not only is entrepreneurship welcomed in these countries, it is treasured, than to give back the land, all of it, without any strings attached, to its rightful owners. The countries of eastern Europe are crying out for investment. What do you think will occur if they make a clean breast of the past and return this stolen property? The likelihood is that its owners will come back to stay for at least part of the year -- bringing with them millions of dollars of investment funds, and, far more important, their entrepreneurial skills and talents. Down that path leads Germany and Eastern Europe to industrial peace, material prosperity and a true market economy. If these countries persist in their miggardliness in the return of stolen property, they may keep for themselves a few additional thousands of acres of land, but these holdings will never become very valuable, because without a free and vibrant economy, none of its factors of production amount to very much. So the choice is clear. The peoples of Eastern Europe have nothing to fear. from the market system and everything to gain from it. But free markets can only be predicated on just titles to property. Return the property. All of it. And as soon as possible. - 30- Private German Property by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. Thousands of Germans fled their property during and after World War II, from what was then East Germany. They migrated to all four corners of the earth: to Australia, to South America, to Western Europe, to the U.S. In our own country, they formed the backbone of what is now the German-Canadian community, one known for its work ethic, its strong family orientation, its stick-to-itiveness and its intellectual brilliance. N ow that East Germany is on its way to a life of freedom, forming once again a united country with its western counterpart, its government has decided, quite appropriately, to take on the trappings of capitalism. Foremost amongst these is of course the institution of private property rights. In this regard they have embarked upon a program of returning land, farms, homes and factories to their rightful owners, a policy for which they should be heartily congratulated. It is one which should be emulated by all of the countries which formerly suffered behind the Iron Curtain. This visionary and courageous program, however, has run into several difficulties. First of all, the government has decided to exempt from this plan all property seized between May 8, 1945 and October 6, 1949 prior to the founding of the late but not lamented and so called German Democratic Republic. But this is intolerable. Just because people emigrated, does not mean it is a legitimate act to seize their property -- and this applies regardless of the official auspices under which such acts were undertaken. There is simply no legitimate statute of limitations on justice. As long as the property owners have proof of title -- pictures, letters, records, etc it should not matter whether their homes and farms were expropriated before, during or after the aegis of any particular government. There is a second problem as well: the irresolution of the government. Stated Petra Speyrer, vice-consul for Germany in Vancouver: "It will take years and years, I am sure, to resolve (the land ownership issue). First of all, you have to find out whether to give property back or compensate with money. If money, then how much? How do you find out the value of the land? I am sure there will be a lot of lawsuits because people will want their land back and not just money. It is very complicated." With all due respect, the issue is not complicated at all. On the contrary, it is exceedingly simple. Of course it is the land and physical property which should be returned and not anything else. If the rightful owners want money instead, they are free to sell their holdings for whatever the market dictates. "How much?" should be no business at all of a state run under the principles of free enterprise. (It is only in the case of property destruction -- which does not in any case apply to land, certainly not to its site value -- that thorny problems arise. But this is a small part of the privatization efforts). There is another reason besides pure justice for returning property to its rightful owners -- all of it, not merely that seized at any particular epoch: pragmatism. It most advanced economics, labour accounts for over 75% of the G.D.P. The rest-rent, interest, profit, etc. -are created by the other factors of production. The entire land of a nation, according to most responsible estimates, is responsible for less than 10% of G.D.P. The property in question in what was formerly East Germany accounts for a tiny fraction of even this amount. So in returning it all to the foreign nationals of German extraction who are its rightful owners, Germany lose very little indeed. But they will gain immeasurably. For what these economies lack at present more than anything else in the world is the entrepreneurial spirit. And there could be not better demonstration of the fact that not only is entrepreneurship welcomed in these countries, it is treasured, than to give back the land, all of it, without any strings attached, to its rightful owners. The countries of eastern Europe are crying out for investment. What do you think will occur if they make a clean breast of the past and return this stolen property? The likelihood is that its owners will come back to stay for at least part of the year -- bringing with them millions of dollars of investment funds, and, far more important, their entrepreneurial skills and talents. Down that path leads Germany and Eastern Europe to industrial peace, material prosperity and a true market economy. If these countries persist in their miggardliness in the return of stolen property, they may keep for themselves a few additional thousands of acres of land, but these holdings will never become very valuable, because without a free and vibrant economy, none of its factors of production amount to very much. So the choice is clear. The peoples of Eastern Europe have nothing to fear from the market system and everything to gain from it. But free markets can only be predicated on just titles to property. GOVERNMENT RESTRAINT an article for Financial Post by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute Government restraint has a bad press. The highly publicized B. - 30C. restraint program of Bill Bennett and his Social Credit government has been heavily criticized. In the land to the South of us, Ronald Reagan has been stymied by farmers, "welfare-rights" groups, businessmen (of the "corporatewelfare-bum" variety) and other organized pressure groups in his efforts to down-size government. And in Ottawa, our federal government seems unwilling to engage in any serious government cut-backs at all, despite a swollen and pendulous budget deficit. This is no doubt due, at least in part, to a healthy respect for the special interest groups who depend on government largesse. Given these occurrences, it is incumbent upon us to review the case for a smaller, tighter and leaner public sector. Why, then, should we prefer that as much economic activity as possible be assigned to the market, and as little as possible to government? Resource allocation. When consumers want more of a product, they buy it; this raises profits, and encourages entreprenuers to shift resources away from items in lesser demand, and toward those more urgently needed. Similarly, losses induce businesses to contract the manufacture of goods no longer sought by customers. This is why the transition from the horse and buggy to the automobile was achieved so easily. Had there been large scale government ready to bail out the losers ("in order to save jobs", to "promote equity", etc.) resources could never have been allocated so smoothly. Incentives. When you own it, you take care of it; when you don't, you "let George do it." In the Soviet Union, 97% of the arable land is owned by government in the form of collective farms; it produces 75% of the crops. In contrast, 3% of agricultural land is under the private control of individuals. These backyard plots receive care and attention -- since the owners benefit directly -- and on this land are grown 25% of Soviet farm staples. Efficiency. The usual rule of thumb is two or three to one. When governments contract out to the private sector -whether for fire protection, or sanitation services, or health care -- the typical statistical finding is that the job can be completed at a fraction of the cost. Risk. When a private firm blunders, it does so with its own money, and on a relatively small scale. When government errs, it does so with our money, and in huge proportions. Moreover, these mistakes (e.g., Mirabel, De Haviland, National Energy Program) can be repeated again and again, since the bureaucrats and politicians responsible cannot be forced into bankruptcy. Why put our money into one basket? The fewer the government enterprises, the less risk for the economy. Consumer Sovereignty. When government runs the economy, we the people can control them through the ballot box. But this occurs only every four or five years, and is very costly. As well, we must vote for a package deal, which includes foreign policy, unemployment, defence, mail delivery, inflation, welfare programs, tariffs, etc., etc. In contrast, when most economic activity is organized on market principles, we can vote with our dollars every day. The price system gives vital information, and is cheap to run. Moreover, we can focus our vote, registering our satisfaction not with the entire society, nor even with whole industries. We can focus on individual enterprises -- which makes them very responsive to our desires indeed. To be sure, there is a major scope for government even in the classical liberal philosophy. Courts, police, armies, prisons, roads and highways, setting a floor under incomes, are some of the dozens of tasks advocated by those with a limited - government viewpoint. But when government exceeds its proper, and vitally important mandate, two tragedies occur. One, as we have seen, it does a poor job, wasting precious resources. And two, it leaves undone those tasks to which it is uniquely suited. We have crime in the streets, while government spends its energies regulating the minutia of agriculture, with dozens of marketing boards. How far in excess of its limited mandate has the Canadian government strayed? In a landmark Fraser Institute publication Probing Leviathan: An Investigation of Government in the Economy, the sad story is told. Rolf Mirus of the University of Alberta, William Stanbury of UBC, John Howard of MacMillan Bloedel and Herbert Grubel of Simon Fraser measure various aspects of the Canadian Leviathan, and the results are truly gargantuan. Some 45% of GNP is absorbed by government, and at least partially as a result, the black market economy may comprise as much as 10% of GNP. There are over 600 Crown Corporations, but they are still growing. After an exhaustive search, the authors conclude that "Nobody knows precisely how many there are". Things have come to the point where Richard G. Lipsey of Queens University, entitles his contribution to the book "Can the Market Economy Survive?" It is time,it is long past time, to engage in a serious policy of government restraint, until the public sector is whittled down to more manageable proportions. THE GROSVENOR Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for C30R Radio Radio Station C30R has made Its home in the basement of the Grosvenor Hotel .for 52 years, but now this grande dame of Vancouver hostelries is scheduled for the wrecker's ball. The upper floors have been closed off, the furnishings have been sold, and all is in readiness for the demolition team. The other day as I approached the front door of the hotel in order to do my regular broadcast for C30R, I was met by an elderly lady. With tears in her eyes, she said "How could they do this? How could they knock down such an elegant building, filled with memories of a bygone era?" Many people empathize with these feelings. It is sad that yet another bit of Vancouver's history will vanish in a cloud of dust and rubble. But such is progress. If we are to grow and expand, to succeed and prosper, to take our places as one of the foremost cities in the world, build we must. Uneconomic structures, which occupy expensive downtown real estate, must be allowed to make way for even more valuable buildings. It is only in this and other similar ways thai our economic prospects may be enlarged, our standards of living improved, and the scourge of poverty wrestled to the ground. But there is a small but highly organized and influential group of people who are trying to force their views on aesthetics down the throats of the rest of us— whether we like it or not. I refer to those vociferous busy bodies who try to impose historical landmark status on old and decaying buildings in the central city. These people are usually highly educated, sophisticated and cultured. They want to indulge their own upper class tastes, and protect the older buildings that people such as they particularly enjoy. But this is at the expense of the tens of thousands of people who might benefit from the jobs and homes that could be created if modern office towers or large apartment blocks were erected on those sites instead. If these people want to save the buildings, well and good. Let them buy these heritage structures themselves—like they do in the case of their antiques and vintage cars. But it is entirely unfair to force other people, many of them poorer, to pay for this particular enjoyment. THE FRASER INSTITUTE 626 Bute Street, Vancouver, B.C. Canada V6E 3M1 (604)688-0221 HARLEQUIN by Walter Block Harlequin Enterprises Ltd. is the major publisher of romance fiction. In recent years, some of their best selling titles have included Castles of Sand, Madrona Island, and Call Back Yesterday. But now, the Harlequin company is in trouble. It has just laid off 35 of its Canadian employees, in an attempt to stem a plunge in profit levels. Competition in the romance fiction industry, it would appear, is fierce. While at one time Harlequin was the undisputed leader in the field, and even considered a monopolist by some, it must now compete with four or five large scale North American companies, which have lately entered the field. Although prosaic by business standards, this is a typical example of the workings of the free enterprise system. Its trailblazing efforts in romance fiction gained Harlequin huge profits. But these profits served as a magnet, drawing imitators into this lucrative field. As a result, the second quarter profits for Torstar, the owner of Harlequin, have fallen from $17.8 million last year to $5.2 million this year -- this is a decline of $12.6 million. Isn't it marvelous that Harlequin is a private enterprise, and not a recipient of Canada Council grants? For as a marketplace entity, consumers can vote with their dollars against Harlequin, and for its competitors, as they have done. In this way, the consumer is in control, and Harlequin has to mend its ways and make its heroines a little more romantic, or whatever it takes for success in this literary genre, otherwise it will face automatic bankruptcy. 2 But if Harlequin were a Crown Corporation, or a recipient of Canada Council grants (Don't laugh; our government gives billions of dollars toward programs which satisfy consumers far less than does Harlequin) this would not apply. For then, the consumers could not directly vote against Harlequin in any meaningful way. There would be no way to register consumer dissatisfaction. Rather, in this case, a band of bureaucrats would protect Harlequin from consumer wrath. True, citizens could use the political vote against a government which did this. But they would have to wait until the next election, which might not come for years. In any case, they could not fine tune their vote to focus on Harlequin. Rather, they would have to vote for a package deal, where book subsidies play a very small role. So, dear reader, when you go out and buy your next romance novel, just remember that you owe the quality of the product you buy to the gloiious free enterprise system. - 30 Historical Monuments / Judging from the quantity, quality, and high prices fetched for antiques, Canadians are a people who relish their history. Paradoxically, economics has a part to play in this enjoyment of the past: the price system tends to promote optimal preservation of past relics. If too few relics from the past had been saved, the price system could be counted upon to remedy this situation. Extremely high prices would encourage people to forage around in hopes of uncovering more marketable antiques, hence meeting the great demand. The movement would be toward discovery and increased supply. This is readily understood. But it is no less true that an oversupply of artifacts would also create problems. If our homes were too burdened with antiques, then there would be less room tor the modern conveniences we also enjoy. If such a situation were somehow to arise, many antiques would lose value and would be summarily thrown out. Neither of these scenarios is remotely likely. Indeed, the proof that the price system is working well is that both are ludicrous: there is no antique "problem." Things are entirely different, however, with regard to historical monuments and buildings. The market has all but been banished and zoning has instead held sway. Consequently, there are serious problems. Were a price system in effect for time-honoured buildings, some of them, those worth more in situ than demolished, would be preserved. But without a market the costs of maintaining such structures in pristine condition are ignored. There is no way of telling which are worth more as is, and which are more valuable for the space they release for new construction. A Price System How would it work? Why would the owner of an antique building preserve it, when he could sell it for millions to a developer? Given that this particular edifice is one that deserves preservation, consumers must value it more for its historical character than for the space it could cede to a skyscraper, (we assume away the possibility of moving the entire building to a cheaper site as too costly). If so, then the revenues the owner could extract via admission charges, plus his own psychic enjoyment, should more than offset alternative revenues. Why are so few historical buildings preserved, on the market? For one thing, cost" are relevent to present economic decisionmaking: this explains why small relics from the past have a greater chance of being preserved, other things equal, than larger ones. Old stamps and coins, jewelry and children's toys can be preserved at less cost than can automobiles, locomotives, sailing ships and buildings. Consequently, unless the larger artifacts are more valuable in proportion to the cubic space they occupy (abstracting from additional maintenance costs) fewer of them will be saved for posterity. Externalities But there is another difficulty posed for a market solution to the historic building question: externalities. There may not be any feasible way for consumers .to see the inside of the building without paying for the privilege, but the main attraction may be the facade, and all passersby can enjoy this without charge. How could the entrepreneur internalize this externality, and convert the outside of the building into a paying proposition. The problem arises because not ati elements are part of the competitive market. The streets are government controlled. If they were privately owned, one aspect of thu externality problem would disappear. The owners of the historic building and of the surrounding streets and sidewalks would presumably come to some agreement concerning the sharing of the revenues collected from the passersby. Possibly one would buy the other out There would remain the question of the surrounding skyscrapers. Their owners might well charge admission to their windows or roof - for the purpose of viewing the neighboring attraction. This, of course, could severely hamper the monument owner's efforts to maintain it as a paying proposition. Large Fences But there are several counter measures he could adopt. He could erect (or so threaten) a large fence around the building to cut off a view from the lower floors; or a large shield above the roof so that noone from the upper storeys could enjoy the vista. Given these possibilities the surrounding skyscraper owners might be willing to negotiate a payment for the viewing rights. Alternatively, the historic and the surrounding structures might come under the same ownership: from one landlord selling to the other, or both to a third party. In any of these eventualities, the externalities would be no more; they would be internalized. The facade of the building, as well as the inside would be brought into the economic nexus. Both could be charged for thus allowing people to register the importance they placed upon it. The antique monument would thus remain so, as long as market value is more than any alternative. It is important to realize that not all external benefits need be internalized. Many, if not most viable commercial establishments release external benefits for which they are unable to collect. People benefit from the knowledge alone of certain amenities in their city, such as the Canadian symphony orchestra even if they never patronize them. The owners of these establishments cannot of course send a bill to a1"l those who merely appreciate their existence, but they can still earn enough profit to stay in business despite this "failure." It is not necessary to ensure that each and every person who enjoys a historic monument pay for it. All that is necessary for its continued existence is that more $ be collectable from it than from alternative uses. Advertising There is always the possibility, if there are anough "free riders" anxious to see the monument, but not to pay for such a privilege, to use it for advertizing advantage. The most obvious way would be to erect bill boards on and about the edifice. But this might well detract from its beauty, or historic character. Alternatively, the commercial message could be delivered far away from the structure: on radio, T.V. or in print. Landmark Preservation Under Zoning Under zoning when property felt to be of historical interest is declared a landmark, it may not be altered, improved or demolished. Although it is (or was) private property, the owner has been relieved of valuable rights. Costs, or the alternative uses of the space occupied by the building, are not considered. Sufficient antiquarianism is the only criterion. Unlike antiques on the market, such monuments need not be more valuable as relics than put to other uses; they need only have some worth from a historical perspective in order to be saved. Thus there is little likelihood that consumer welfare will be increased by landmark zoning. Instead, a small group of antiquarian elitists can ignore the desires of the rest of the population, and impose the preservation of an excessive number of historical buildings. Perhaps one reason Canadians accept such policy is that it is difficult to discern the "what-might-have beens." The historic landmark is physically there: people see it, enjoy it, photograph it, touch it. It is more difficult to appreciate the factory that might have taken its place; to envision the extra employment its construction would have meant; or the lower-priced consumer goods it could have produced. These possibilities are no less important despite the present difficulty of recognizing this. JOB RETRAINING By Walter Block Are you ready for the latest wrinkle in the job retraining scam? According to the provisions of the National Training Act (NTA), proclaimed just last year, 82 specific skills have been designated as a national priority. Examples include electro-mechanical drafting, millwright, aircraft mechanics, electrical engineering technicians and chemical process operators. This new policy is very trendy. Instead of placing emphasis on the average out-ofwork Canadian with the more traditional skills, such as truck driving or secretarial training, the NTA focusses attention on the "glamour" industries: computers, electronics, hi-tech, microchips, etc. Says Ian Morrison, executive director of the Canadian Association for Adult Education, "The new act makes official a move from trying to improve the basic skill level of the general population, to investing in a smaller, more elite group". Although this new direction will leave the lesser educated Canadians out in the cold, and discriminate against women (who are proportionately under-represented in these elite areas) it was undertaken for an important reason. Previously, training programs had been out of synch with the needs of industry. There was very little match between the skills taught by the old programs and the ones needed to attain employment. So much so, that graduates has great difficulties in finding jobs. But the worm is still in the apple. The record of the graduates of a course given in St. Lawrence College, Brockville, Ontario, is a case in point. The students were given a one year accelerated course in electro-mechanical drafting -- one of the 82 skills. But six months after completion, 80% of them are still without jobs -- any jobs. The excuse given is that the new departure came just at the worst of the recession. But the real reason is quite different. The problem with retraining, of course, is that it takes time. Usually a year or two, and for the more complex skills, even three or four. And the needs of industry have an infuriating way of changing -and changing drastically -- between the time of initial enrolment and graduation. In other words, there is a serious forecasting problem. Our all loving government is not without a response to this challenge. In order to mesh training with future skills' demands, the federales are working on a formula for long range forecasting called the Canadian Occupational Projection System. But accurate forecasting is easier said than done. And the government's record in this regard is far from impressive -- not to put too fine a point on it. For one thing, as we have seen, graduates of these "new wave" courses are unable to find employment. For another, the government has only added to, not deleted from, its inventory of "priority" skills. The Critical Trade Skills Training program started with six skills four years ago, and now has 82. At this rate, we'll be up to our ears in retraining programs by the next century. Things have come to such a pass that according to the head of the Canadian Advanced Technology Association, most of the high-tech jobs the government is currently pushing on its unfortunate clients are almost obsolete. Clearly, the answer is to eliminate the heavy hand of government, root and branch, from this most crucial of endeavours. Instead, we must rely upon the far better record of private enterprise in this regard. In the marketplace, a school that retrained graduates for jobs no longer in existence would soon enough go bankrupt. Only those which successfully predict the future course of industrial events can grow and prosper. But this safety net, or safety valve, is unavailable to government enterprise. Whoever heard of a government ministry allowed to go bankrupt because of innumerable failures? That is why the sooner the funds being frittered away on retraining by the Ministry of Labour are returned to the private marketplace, the better the prospects for the unemployed of Canada. - 30 KENT COMMISSION FLUNKS BASIC ECONOMICS by Walter Block Among the criticisms of the Canadian newspaper business made by the Kent Commission (KC) is the abysmal lack of training of many journalists. For prime evidence of this contention, we can refer to the KC Report itself: it is blissfully innocent of even some of the most basic tenets of economics. This is particularly unfortunate, since the KC tries to deal with the economics of newspaper publishing and may well have an important impact on the entire industry. The most crucial error, the one from which most of all others follow, is the view that since private newspapers are profit seeking concerns, they cannot, to that extent, serve the public. According to the KC, for example, the blame for the deterioration of the Canadian newspaper industry should be placed on "owners who put profits above all else". Praise for the few bright spots is reserved for those who invest large sums in journalist training, editorial and reportorial coverage, and feature more content and less advertising pages than strict concern for the bottom line would indicate. Southam is singled out in this regard -- with the exception of its Ottawa Citizen -- and praised for its "journalistic conscience", and an "inherited sense of noblesse oblige". But certainly not for its profit seeking behaviour. This is a complete and utter misunderstanding of how a market system actually functions. In the real world, not the ivory tower occupied by the KC, profit is the very measure, and the only measure, by which success And in serving the public can be judged. the only way profits can be earned, in a competitive market economy, is through consumer satisfaction. For example, Raymond Burr, Lorne Green, Genevieve Bujold, Donald Sutherland, Anne Murray, Gordon Lightfoot, Canadian Pacific, Alcan, Noranda, Thompson, Southam and MacLean Hunter, all earn substantial profits and are widely celebrated for providing goods and services that are in great demand by the Canadian public; on the other hand, Chrysler, Massey-Ferguson, the "Edsel", the entire horse and buggy industry, and thousands of other firms have been unable to provide desired goods and services, or provide them at below-cost prices, and have thus been consigned to the dustbins of history. Their sin? Inability to earn profits, and to satisfy the public. The two go hand-in-hand. Contrary to the KC, newspaper firms are just like all other firms in this regard. They sink or swim according to their ability to earn profit, and they can earn profits only by satisfying their customers. It is of course true that newspapers have a "responsibility to the public" to provide a high quality product. But it is an insult to every other Canadian industry to single out newspapers in this regard. For every industry in this country has the same responsibility. The difficulty with the anti-profit KC proposals for a Canada Newspaper Act is that they will result in less consumer satisfaction, not more, for the following reasons: The proposal to increase editorial and reportorial coverage and decrease advertising content, is wide of the mark. Some people enjoy the advertising columns and pages, and rely upon them for important information. But noteveryone likes advertising. It has long been a great whipping boy for some people. Unlike radio or TV, however, newspaper advertising, if desired, can be easily ignored merely by flipping pages. And there is no doubt that the present proportion of advertising to other copy serves an important function: it makes newspapers cheaper than otherwise, thus further satisfying consumers. Owners have always been free to follow the KC suggestion. That they have not done so, and have nevertheless survived and prospered, is ample evidence that the present proportion better serves the public interest. The KC advocates that governments make up for these advertising revenues given up which will have to be / by offering subsidies to publishers (the 1970 Davey Senate Committee on the Media sought direct government funds, the KC urges tax incentives). But governments can, in the final analysis, only derive funds from the public -- whether in the form of higher prices or increased taxes. And the public, as we have seen, prefers more advertising pages and a cheaper newspaper than the KC wishes to impose. Government funding, moreover, means government control. KC proposals are merely the entering wedge. This initiave is entirely keeping with the New World Information Order, a blatant UNESCO resoultion which is aimed at complete and outright governmental control and liscensing of the newspaper business. We must, therefore, applaud the satand taken by the Canadian Press, stating that "CP would never accept a grant or subsidy from an outside source". We must likewise reject the view that concentration, whether associated with non-newspaper investments or not, is harmful to the public interest. As long as entry is unprohibited -- and anyone with money for ink, newsprint and journalists' salaries can set up shop -- high concentration is evidence of success, not failure, in communicating with the public. A large market share is certainly no indication of control, as attested to by the failure of such past giants as the New York Herald-Tribune, the Montreal Star, the Ottawa Journal, the Winnipeg Tribune and the Washington Star. Ironically, one of the KC's own recommendations will restrict entry, thus setting the stage for the "control" it presumably opposes. Requiringthat two-months' notice be given, and approved, before a newspaper can shut down, will only serve as a barrier to entry. Should this be approved,an additional penalty will have been imposed, in the-case of failure. A new firm will have to "think twice" before starting up a newspaper business. To shield editorial independence from the "meddling" of owners, the KC proposes a Press Rights Panel which would oversee a required contract between editor-in-chief and publisher. This will result in effects which are diametrically opposed to those intended. In the market system, the owner is the residual income claimant.That is, he collects whatever residual remains after all expenses are paid. Thus, he has an incentive to keep this differential as high as possible. Since the only way he can do this is by satisfying customers, consumer sovereignty is in the driver's seat when the owner is in control. In contrast, the editors (and other staff) are paid fixed salaries. Their remuneration does not vary with newspaper revenues (except in extreme cases of bankruptcy). The editor is thus once removed from the desires of the public. Within rather wide limits, he is free to indulge his "journalistic conscience", his "integrity", his "muse", or any other whim that strikes him. In other words, he is free, to a much greater degree than the owner, to ignore the paying customer. Elevating the editorial staff, and denigrating the role of the "meddlesome" owner will therefore result in less responsibility to the public, not more. If there is any villain in the piece, any group that wields wide power with no commensurate responsibility, it is not the newspaper industry. It is the KC itself, which used $3.1 million of taxpayers' dollars -- without their direct permission. Permission, that is, that the public grants the newspaper industry every day, through voluntary purchases. Labour Code Revision by Walter Block The present Labour Code of British Columbia has is its objective the protection of wage rates for the working men and women of the province. Its basic philosophy is based on the view that there exists an unequal bargaining power between employer and employee -- vastly to the advantage of the former. The methodology of the B.C. Labour Code is one of promoting collective bargaining - in order to balance the scales of power in favour of the latter. While well-motivated and based on the best of intentions, the Labour Code has had widespread negative unintended consequences. Under its rule, the union movement has obtained great powers, but, paradoxically, this has not benefited many working people, nor the population of the province as a whole. Thousands of person-hours have been lost as a result of strike activity. Bitterness and acrimony have afflicted labour relations; all the EXPOs in the world will not convince foreigners to bring their persons (tourism) or property (investments) to this province, into an atmosphere of strife and conflict. Worse for the labour force, unemployment has risen. Let us take Canada as a whole (this is a reasonable procedure, since the labour codes of the other province are much like those of B.C.), and compare it with the United States in this regard. [n 1961, the unionization rates in both countries were very similar, at 30 per cent of the labour force. By 1985, the rate in Canada had risen to 40 percent (45 percent in British Columbia), but fallen to below 20 per cent in the U.S. As a result, real wages n this country rose by 35 percent between 1965 and 1985, while they fell by 5 3ercent south of the border. LABOUR CODE REVISION by Walter Block - 30- In the next few months, several provinces will be re-examining their labour codes with a view to revising them. In the past, such attempts have been superficial; they have placed bubble gum, band aid, and scotch tape solutions on a corpus in need of major surgery. Our legislative representatives must go to the heart of the matter this time out, for the health of the Canadian economy depends upon it. This analysis will entirely concern itself with the ideal labour code, with how things should be. This is crucial, for as Yogi Berra put it "If you don't know where you're going, you probably won't get there." In the field of labour relations, the most important issue is the strike. Actually, this is a misnomer, as it refers not to one act, but to two. A strike is, first, a withdrawal of labour in unison from an employer, on the part of the relevent organized employees. To this, there can be no objection. If a single individual has a right to withdraw labour services, or to quit a job, he does not lose it merely because others choose to exercize their rights, simultaneously. There is a second aspect of the strike, however. And this element is pernicious, insidious and entirely improper. I refer here to the union practice of making it impossible for the struck employer to deal with alternative sources of labour, who are anxious to compete for the jobs the strikers have just vacated. This entry restriction can be accomplished in several ways. In the days of yore, organized labour would first brand their competitors as "scabs," or "strike breakers" and then use threatened or actual physical intimidation (mass picketing, trespass, sit down strikes, violence, arson) to make it impossible for the employer to hire replacement workers. Anyone who thinks that mass picketing is merely an exercize of free speech rights is confusing de jure with de facto. In theory, union picketing is an information generating exercise in free speech. In fact, it is an active threat of physical intimidation; it is harrassment, pure and simple. In the modern era, unions have added to this tactic a plethora of legislation which also effectively drives a compulsory wedge between employer and "scab." The businessman must convince the Labour Relations Board that he is "bargaining fairly" with those who have left his employ (even though what he most desires is to ignore them, and to deal with others instead); he must give special considerations to those who have left him in the lurch by striking. One argument of organized labour is that its present powers -or something like them -- are responsible for past wage increases, and are needed if wages are to continue to rise in the future. But this is fantasy. On the contrary, gains in labour productivity -- because of better skills, improved capital equipment and industrial peace -- are the causes of gains in take home pay. This is proven by relatively declining wages in the heavily unionized "smokestack" industries, compared to increased salaries in the far less unionized computer, microchip and other information and service industries. As well, there is the fact that real wages have been rising for centuries, while the earliest unions appeared only in the late 19th century. So-called "unequal bargaining power" thus has nothing to do with the matter. Another argument for the status quo is that the "scab" is stealing the job of the striker. But this is also the sheerest of nonsense. A job is an embodiment of an agreement between two consenting parties - employee and employer. It cannot be the possession of only one of them. A worker no more owns "his" job than does a husband own "his" wife. A striking union which forcibly prevents the employer from hiring a replacement is like a husband who divorces his wife -- and then threatens to beat her up, and any prospective new suitor as well -- if she tries to remarry. Just as one spouse may now divorce the other for any reason or for none at all, the employer should be able to fire an employee without being compelled to show "cause." Our laws do not force the worker to justify a decision to quit his job, and the employee-employer relationship should be an entirely symmetric one. A properly revised labour code, then, would allow strikes in the sense of mass refusals to work, or quits in unison. It would entrench this behavior, as a basic element of the rights of free men. But it would limit union activity to this one option. It would thus prohibit, to the full extent of the law, any and all interferences with the rights of alternative employees ("scabs") to compete for jobs held by union members. It would end, forevermore, all picketing, and other such forms of threatened or actual violence. Although many people think that pickets are aimed at the struck employer, they are actually an attack on competing workers ("scabs"). And just as our laws should not allow business firms to picket the premises of suppliers, competitors or customers, no group of workers should be able, by picketing, to forcibly prohibit another group of workers -- almost always poorer -- from bidding for jobs. A proper labour code would thus define a "legitimate union" as one which strictly limited its actions to organizing mass resignations. A "legitimate union" would eschew picketing, violence, and all other special advantages --- legislative or otherwise ---vis-a-vis its non unionized competitors. This would end, once and for all, the legal fiction that workers who have left their jobs can yet retain any right to employment status in those positions. Were this one basic change in labour relations to be made, then society would have to re-think a whole host of unjust and unwise elements now embodied in present labour legislation. o Right to work provisions. These would be an infringement upon the rights of employers and legitimate unions to sign mutually beneficial and consensual agreements. Under the ideal labour code, there would be no "right to work." o Wage restraints should be ended. These would be an unconscionable interference with the rights of legitimate unions to engage in collective bargaining. o Boycotts of whatever type are simply a refusal to deal with certain people. But everyone has the moral right to choose his friends and business associates. Any attempt to stop such behavior would be a severe violation of our human rights. And this goes for the secondary boycott as well. o Applying anti combines legislation to unions. A favorite of union bashers, this too would be inapplicable for legitimate unions. o Imposing "democracy" on unions. It would be no more justified to subject legitimate unions to "democracy", than it would be to impose the secret ballot, government supervision of voting procedures, or limited political activism on any other voluntary organization such as the corporation, the faculty club, or the Roman Catholic College of Cardinals. o Back to, work orders. This would be an infringement upon the right of free men to withdraw their labour services. Fines, jail sentences for labour organizers, imposed loss of check off privileges would be a completely unwarranted interference with the only tactic at the disposal of legitimate unionism. LABOUR CODE REVISION by Walter Block In the next few months, several provinces will be re-examining their labour codes with a view to revising them. In the past, such attempts have been superficial; they have placed bubble gum, band aid, and scotch tape solutions on a corpus in need of major surgery. Our legislative representatives must go to the heart of the matter this time out, for the health of the Canadian economy depends upon it. This analysis will entirely concern itself with the ideal labour code, with how things should be. This is crucial, for as Yogi Berra put it &quotIf you don't know where you're going, you probably won't get there." In the field of labour relations, the most important issue is the strike. Actually, this is a misnomer, as it refers not to one act, but to two. A strike is, first, a withdrawal of labour in unison from an employer, on the part of the relevent organized employees. To this, there can be no objection. If a single individual has a right to withdraw labour services, or to quit a job, he does not lose it merely because others choose to exercize their rights, simultaneously. There is a second aspect of the strike, however. And this element is pernicious, insidious and entirely improper. I refer here to the union practice of making it impossible for the struck employer to deal with alternative sources of labour, who are anxious to compete for the jobs the strikers have just vacated. This entry restriction can be accomplished in several ways. In the days of yore, organized labour would first brand their competitors as &quotscabs," or &quotstrike breakers" and then use threatened or actual physical intimidation (mass picketing, trespass, sit down strikes, violence, arson) to make it impossible for the employer to hire replacement workers. Anyone who thinks that mass picketing is merely an exercize of free speech rights is confusing de jure with de facto. In theory, union picketing is an information generating exercise in free speech. In fact, it is an active threat of physical intimidation; it is harrassment, pure and simple. In the modern era, unions have added to this tactic a plethora of legislation which also effectively drives a compulsory wedge between employer and &quotscab." The businessman must convince the Labour Relations Board that he is &quotbargaining fairly" with those who have left his employ (even though what he most desires is to ignore them, and to deal with others instead); he must give special considerations to those who have left him in the lurch by striking. One argument of organized labour is that its present powers — or something like them -- are responsible for past wage increases, and are needed if wages are to continue to rise in the future. But this is fantasy. On the contrary, gains in labour productivity — because of better skills, improved capital equipment and industrial peace — are the causes of gains in take home pay. This is proven by relatively declining wages in the heavily unionized "smokestack" industries, compared to increased salaries in the far less unionized computer, microchip and other information and service industries. As well, there is the fact that real wages have been rising for centuries, while the earliest unions appeared only in the late 19th century. So-called &quotunequal bargaining power" thus has nothing to do with the matter. Another argument for the status quo is that the &quotscab" is stealing the job of the striker. But this is also the sheerest of nonsense. A job is an embodiment of an agreement between two consenting parties - employee and employer. It cannot be the possession of only one of them. A worker no more owns &quothis" job than does a husband own &quothis" wife. A striking union which forcibly prevents the employer from hiring a replacement is like a husband who divorces his wife — and then threatens to beat her up, and any prospective new suitor as well — if she tries to remarry. Just as one spouse may now divorce the other for any reason or for none at all, the employer should be able to fire an employee without being compelled to show &quotcause." Our laws do not force the worker to justify a decision to quit his job, and the employee-employer relationship should be an entirely symmetric one. A properly revised labour code, then, would allow strikes in the sense of mass refusals to work, or quits in unison. It would entrench this behavior, as a basic element of the rights of free men. But it would limit union activity to this one option. It would thus prohibit, to the full extent of the law, any and all interferences with the rights of alternative employees (&quotscabs") to compete for jobs held by union members. It would end, forevermore, all picketing, and other such forms of threatened or actual violence. Although many people think that pickets are aimed at the struck employer, they are actually an attack on competing workers (&quotscabs"). And just as our laws should not allow business firms to picket the premises of suppliers, competitors or customers, no group of workers should be able, by picketing, to forcibly prohibit another group of workers — almost always poorer — from bidding for jobs. A proper labour code would thus define a &quotlegitimate union" as one which strictly limited its actions to organizing mass resignations. A &quotlegitimate union" would eschew picketing, violence, and all other special advantages — legislative or otherwise —vis-a-vis its non unionized competitors. This would end, once and for all, the legal fiction that workers who have left their jobs can yet retain any right to employment status in those positions. Were this one basic change in labour relations to be made, then society would have to re-think a whole host of unjust and unwise elements now embodied in present labour legislation. o Right to work provisions. These would be an infringement upon the rights of employers and legitimate unions to sign mutually beneficial and consensual agreements. Under the ideal labour code, there would be no &quotright to work." o Wage restraints should be ended. These would be an unconscionable interference with the rights of legitimate unions to engage in collective bargaining. o Boycotts of whatever type are simply a refusal to deal with certain people. But everyone has the moral right to choose his friends and business associates. Any attempt to stop such behavior would be a severe violation of our human rights. And this goes for the secondary boycott as well. o Applying anti combines legislation to unions. A favorite of union bashers, this too would be inapplicable for legitimate unions. o Imposing &quotdemocracy" on unions. It would be no more justified to subject legitimate unions to &quotdemocracy", than it would be to impose the secret ballot, government supervision of voting procedures, or limited political activism on any other voluntary organization such as the corporation, the faculty club, or the Roman Catholic College of Cardinals. o Back to work orders. This would be an infringement upon the right of free men to withdraw their labour services. Fines, jail sentences for labour organizers, imposed loss of check off privileges would be a completely unwarranted interference with the only tactic at the disposal of legitimate unionism. -30LABOUR CODE REVISIONS By Walter Block, Senior Economist The Fraser Institute For The Financial Post Things are not going well for organized labour, as these incidents from around the world will attest: . In New Zealand, Prime Minister Robert Muldoon has just amended his nation's labour code, banning closed shops. Despite the fact that nearly half the countries' labour force is unionized, leaders of the Labour Party opposition see this as an election ploy! . In England, the birthplace of industrial unions, the barons of organized labour have been forced to call off a threatened shipyard strike. This was to have been in protest against employer demands to stremline work methodsimposed by some 17 different unions, to the virtual ruination of British shipbuilding. This industry, once the envy of the world, and responsible for building 80 per cent of all merchant shipping, is now a shadow of its former self, only half as efficient as its main European rivals. As well, a widely publicized "national day of protest" came to nought. This was the response to the Conservative Government's plan to ban unions at Communication Headquarters (in charge of national security intelligence gathering) in Cheltenham. . In the United States, the Supreme Court has just ruled union succession rights to be unconstitutional. Now, when a company becomes bankrupt, or undergoes reorganization through other transformation, the prior union contract no longer prevails. And what, pray tell, of the labour relations scene in Canada? In lotus-land by-the-sea, the labour movement is shooting itself in the foot. It shows signs of breaking up through internal dissension, while plunging the province of British Columbia into chaos. The situation is this. The International Woodworkers of America (IWA) had recently signed a three-year labour contract after much dissension with management. Because of this, and also due to recession-created economic hardships, they were only now beginning to draw full paycheques on a steady basis. At this point the 7,600-member Pulp, Paper and Woodworkers of Canada (PPWC), and the 9,000member Canadian Paperworkers Union (CPU), rejected a contract similar to the one signed by the IWA, and were locked out by their employers on February 2, 1984. Whereupon the PPWC and the CPU set up secondary pickets at IWA workplaces—which were crossed, despite Labour Relations Board approval, in violation of the most sacred taboo of the labour movement, by members of the latter union. Now the fur realty began to fly. Fist fights, and worse, broke out between the various bands of unionists. Townspeople and non-union truck loggers entered the fray. Due to the violence and chaos, the RCMP was unable to protect the locked-out workers, and the picket lines had to be abandoned. As a result of all this. Art Gruntman of CPU and Jim Sloan of PPWC have called for the resignation from the B.C. Federation of Labour of IWA president Jack Munro, who had publicly supported his members' actions. B.C. Labour Minister Bob McLelland had long been reputed to be considering changes in the province's Labour Code, widely regarded as among the most favourable to unionism in all of Canada. If so, he has been handed, on a silver platter, ample reason for doing just that. Specifically, secondary picketing, with its interference in plants where there are no present labour grievances, would appear to be highly unpopular with the long-suffering B.C. citizenry. If this one practice could be prohibited, or at least made more difficult, then one burr under the saddle of labour-management, relations will have been removed. But while we are talking about secondary picketing, we might reconsider the role of primary picke. ig as well. In theory, and as a matter of law, this type of picketing serves only informational purposes. It advises all and sundry that the organized employees are at variance with their employer. But the facts are often far different. Instead of merely notifying the public about a labour dispute, picketing serves as a threat to all those who might be interested in competing for the jobs and salary spurned by the union. Since all Canadians have, or at least should have, a right to compete for any given employment opportunity, such a practice is a de facto, although not de jure violation of liberty. A more accurate interpretation of picketing (whether primary or secondary) is as a nuisance or harassment. This is precisely how it would be regarded were it to take place in any other commercial or personal arena. Suppose, that is, that a person vacates the premises of landlord A, and patronizes landlord B instead. Surely the courts would cast a baleful eye on A, if he, together with his family, cronies, and business associates, began to picket the tenant for being &quotunfair." Or take another case. Suppose that a man divorces his spouse, and then along with all his friends "pickets" the home of his exwife, warning off possible suitors. Would this be considered an informational exercise in free speech rights? Hardly. On the contrary, it would be clearly seen for the harassment it is, and be summarily prohibited by any court in the land. Can we as a nation afford any less rigorous a definition of justice in labourmanagement relations? -30March 9, 1984 LABOUR CODE REVISIONS By Walter Block, Senior EconomistThe Fraser InstituteFor The Financial Post Things are not going well for organized labour, as these incidents from around the world will attest: • In New Zealand, Prime Minister Robert Muldoon has just amended his nation's labour code, banning closed shops. Despite the fact that nearly half the countries' labour force is unionized, leaders of the Labour Party opposition see this as an election ploy! • In England, the birthplace of industrial unions, the barons of organized labour have been forced to call off a threatened shipyard strike. This was to have been in protest against employer demands to stremline work methods--imposed by some 17 different unions, to the virtual ruination of British shipbuilding. This industry, once the envy of the world, and responsible for building 80 per cent of all merchant shipping, is now a shadow of its former self, only half as efficient as its main European rivals. As well, a widely publicized "national day of protest" came to nought. This was the response to the Conservative Government's plan to ban unions at Communication Headquarters (in charge of national security intelligence gathering) in Cheltenham. • In the United States, the Supreme Court has just ruled union succession rights to be unconstitutional. Now, when a company becomes bankrupt, or undergoes reorganization through other transformation, the prior union contract no longer prevails. And what, pray tell, of the labour relations scene in Canada? In lotus-land by-the-sea, the labour movement is shooting itself in the foot. It shows signs of breaking up through internal dissension, while plunging the province of British Columbia into chaos. The situation is this. The International Woodworkers of America (IWA) had recently signed a three-year labour contract after much dissension with management. Because of this, and also due to recession-created economic hardships, they were only now beginning to draw full paycheques on a steady basis. At this point the 7,600-member Pulp, Paper and Woodworkers of Canada (PPWC), and the 9,000-member Canadian Paperworkers Union (CPU), rejected a contract similar to the one signed by the IWA, and were locked out by their employers on February 2, 1984. Whereupon the PPWC and the CPU set up secondary pickets at IWA workplaces--which were crossed, despite Labour Relations Board approval, in violation of the most sacred taboo of the labour movement, by members of the latter union. Now the fur really began to fly. Fist fights, and worse, broke out between the various bands of unionists. Townspeople and non-union truck loggers entered the fray. Due to the violence and chaos, the RCMP was unable to protect the locked-out workers, and the picket lines had to be abandoned. As a result of all this, Art Gruntman of CPU and Jim Sloan of PPWC have called for the resignation from the B.C. Federation of Labour of IWA president Jack Munro, who had publicly supported his members' actions. B.C. Labour Minister Bob McLelland had long been reputed to be considering changes in the province's Labour Code, widely regarded as among the most favourable to unionism in all of Canada. If so, he has been handed, on a silver platter, ample reason for doing just that. Specifically, secondary picketing, with its interference in plants where there are no present labour grievances, would appear to be highly unpopular with the long-suffering B.C. citizenry. If this one practice could be prohibited, or at least made more difficult, then one burr under the saddle of labour-management relations will have been removed. But while we are talking about secondary picketing, we might reconsider the role of primary picketing as well. In theory, and as a matter of law, this type of picketing serves only informational purposes. It advises all and sundry that the organized employees are at variance with their employer. But the facts are often far different. Instead of merely notifying the public about a labour dispute, picketing serves as a threat to all those who might be interested in competing for the jobs and salary spurned by the union. Since all Canadians have, or at least should have, a right to compete for any given employment opportunity, such a practice is a de facto, although not de jure violation of liberty. A more accurate interpretation of picketing (whether primary or secondary) is as a nuisance or harassment. This is precisely how it would be regarded were it to take place in any other commercial or personal arena. Suppose, that is, that a person vacates the premises of landlord A, and patronizes landlord B instead. Surely the courts would cast a baleful eye on A, if he, together with his family, cronies, and business associates, began to picket the tenant for being "unfair." Or take another case. Suppose that a man divorces his spouse, and then along with all his friends "pickets" the home of his ex-wife, warning off possible suitors. Would this be considered an informational exercise in free speech rights? Hardly. On the contrary, it would be clearly seen for the harassment it is, and be summarily prohibited by any court in the land. Can we as a nation afford any less rigorous a definition of justice in labour-management relations? March 9, 1984 Gabriel Bruce: The Liver Transplant Boy by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute According to recent reports, the black market value of a kidney which can be transplanted is some $13,000 -- which translates to roughly seven times its weight in gold. Such an occurrence may occasion all sorts of references to King Midas -- who was supposed to have been turned into a statue of sold gold, but behind this rather dramatic way of characterizing the value of human organs lies in a story of untold and tragic human suffering. The leaders of our medical establishment are ideologically opposed to the use of the market system. So implacable and fervent is their hatred of free enterprise that they will gladly countenance the deaths of hundreds of their patients -- thousands if need be -- as long as no spectre of prices and profits infringes into their little world. We make this rather hysterical-sounding charge because the medical establishment in this country is largely responsible for arranging matters in such a way that it is illegal to harness marketplace incentives in order to encourage kidney donors. Instead, our society must resort to all sort of inefficient stratagems toward this end. Famous personages have exhorted us, in the event that we suffer untimely death, to make a posthumous gift of these organs; medical schools coach their students on the best techniques for approaching next-of-kin -- and asking permission of them at the precise time when they are least likely to give it -- upon the sudden demise of a loved one. But all of this has been to little avail. While potential recipients languish on painful kidney dialysis machines waiting ghoulishly for a traffic fatality which may spell life for them, the public has refused to sign cards giving permission for automatic posthumous donor status. Things have even come to such a pass that there are grotesque and fascistic plans now being bruited about which would allow the government to seize the kidneys of accident victims unless they have signed cards denying such permission. The free enterprise system could be a God-send to the unfortunates who suffer from diseased kidneys. A legalized marketplace would encourage thousands of donors. Would you sign a card donating your kidney after death for 13,000 big ones, right now, in cold hard cash? There are very few people who would turn up their noses at such an offer. And if sufficient supplies were still not forthcoming at this level, prices would rise even further until all demand was satisfied. Given free enterprise incentives, pardon the pun, we would be up to our armpits in kidneys. This is the tried and true process we rely on to bring us all the other necessities of life: food, clothing and shelter. After all, we do not depend for the provision of these goods and services on voluntary donations. We know this to be an unreliable system -- however much it is flogged by opinion leaders in the case of organ transplants. No one is contending that those responsible for preventing a free market in kidneys are purposefully murdering thousands of kidney disease sufferers. But no matter how benevolent their intentions, it cannot be denied that this is the effect of their ill-conceived actions. It is time, it is long past time, for our society to put aside its archaic and prejudicial opposition to the marketplace, so that we can lift a death sentence we have inadvertently placed on as hopeless and hapless a group of citizens that ever existed. 30 585 words THE LORD'S PRAYER by Walter Block Chris Tait is a seventeen-year-old high school student who is now sitting -- on a matter of principle. He refuses to stand up while his classmates in the rural southwestern Manitoba town of McGregor recite the Lord's Prayer. Young Mr. Tait is an atheist, and contends that such an act would be incompatible with his fervently held beliefs. But the authorities are having none of this. "It is simply a case of defiance," stated school superintendent Joe Mudry, who has suspended Tait from class twice so far, and threatens him with permanent expulsion if the lad persists in the error of his ways, and refuses to repent. In the view of Mr. Mudry, "The issue here has simply to dowith compliance with the school regulations and the (Manitoba)Public Schools Act," which makes one wonder at the intelligenceof those who have been placed in charge of the nation's children. Chris Tate, for his part, claims it is a matter of religious freedom and human rights. "Under section two (of the Charter of Rights and Freedoms)," he says, "we're guaranteed freedom of religion and conscience, and under section 15 all citizens are guaranteed equal protection and benefit under the law." If he knuckled under and stood up on his feet during the Lord's Prayer "it would be a tribute to the Lord God," said Tait, and thus a violation of his freedom. We must award this young student at least a "B" for effort, and must certainly salute the moral courage it took for a person of such tender years to so publicly swim against the tide of accepted opinion. As well, his behaviour should be upheld in a court of law. However, Mr. Tait's reasoning leaves something to be desired. There cannot be any exceptionless "human right to self-expression," Charter or no Charter. For surely Mr. Tait would have no right to go into a church and disrupt their services with such atheistic behaviour. Nor would he be blameless if he came into Mr. Mudry's living room, for example, and violated the wishes of that worthy gentleman in this regard, while refusing to depart. No, the question of right and wrong in this matter turns crucially on the matter of who is the owner of the rights of private property in the place where Mr. Tait is resisting the blandishments of theology. If MacGregor High School were a private institution, that would be the end of the case. Its owners would have the right to set the rules for appropriate behaviour, and all those who objected would be free to pick themselves up and go elsewhere. (The only constraint on such private entrepreneurs is that if they act arbitrarily and capriciously, they will lose customers to their competitors. They certainly have the right to insist, for instance, that their students wear beanies to class, and propellors on their noses, but if they do so, they are likely to lose customers to competing institutions.) But that seat of higher learning known as MacGregor High School is a public institution, not a private one. As such, its managers have no more right to require people to stand for the recitation of the Lord's Prayer there, than they would to impose such a condition on the people using the public streets. Namely, they have no right at all to do this. So Chris Tait, even if he is unaware of the proper defense open to him, is certainly acting in the right. And Mr. Mudry, the heavy of the piece, would be well advised to cease and desist, lest he worsen an already unfortuate situation. THE FRASER INSTITUTE 626 Bute Street, Vancouver, B.C. Canada V6E 3M1 (604) 688-0221 LUMBER AND BUNS by Walter Block There is an economic schizophrenia operating in Canada. On the one hand, some people are positively frothing at the mouth at the prospect of McDonalds Restaurants purchasing hamburger buns from a Seattle bakery. They are horrified to realize that the former supplier, McGavins Foods Ltd., had to lay off 70 workers, swelling the Canadian unemployment figures. Some Canadian trade unions have gone so far as to plan for a boycott of Ronald McDonald. On the other hand, however, several small lumber companies in the U.S. Pacific Northwest have banded together to try to impose heavy duties on southbound wood and wood products. If successful, they could deal the already moribund B.C. forest industry a death blow. What is the reasoning behind the new initiative? U.S. producers, suffering from the American recession, have seen the demise of much of their own industry, and the accompanying disappearance of many forestry jobs. They are incensed at what they consider "dumping": the advantages they say are given to B.C. firms through the stumpage system, where the provincial government sets prices for Crown land timber. As usual, the economic nationalists are barking up the wrong tree--in both countries. True, Canada lost some bakery jobs. But as a result, McDonalds will be able to buy cheaper buns. Competition with Burger King, Wendy's, White Spot, Denny's and hundreds of other food purveyors will force McDonald's to pass these savings onto their Canadian customers in the form of lower prices. And what will these consumers do with their extra money? They will spend it on other things (what things, it is impossible to tell) creating new jobs in the relevant industries. Or they will save it, and drive down interest rates, creating more jobs in capital intensive industries such as housing. As a result, without any loss in employment, Canada will benefit from purchasing something that can be produced more cheaply in Seattle. This will increase the purchasing power of our dollar and enhance our sorely declining standards of living. (We pass lightly over the role of the Canadian Wheat Board in raising flour prices faced by domestic bakeries. That is a story for another day.) And let us assume for the sake of argument that the American charges of Canadian lumber "dumping" are absolutely true. In that case, such dumping would help the U.S. economy, not hurt it. In order to see this, we may ask what would be the effect on their economy if instead of "dumping" lumber, we gave it to them completely gratis. This would be "dumping" with a vengeance. But free gifts can hardly hurt a mature, sophisticated economy of the sort that operates below our border. The important point to realize is that the lumber and bun cases are the opposite sides of the same coin. How can we oppose the purchase of cheap buns in the U.S., and object when U.S. interests try to stop the importing of cheap Canadian lumber in to their country? We cannot have it both ways. This economic nationalist world view is hypocritical. It will be seen as such and it will backfire on us. Luxury Hotel Debacle by Walter Block Vancouver's most luxurious hotel, the Mandarin, cost $42 million to build in 1984. Early in 1987, it was sold for $6 million, a loss of over three quarters of its initial value. Behind this financial tragedy lay a stupendous failure to anticipate the desires of the public. The Mandarin featured 24-karat gold leaf in its thickly covered lobby. There were genuine marble floors in each of its bathrooms. Instead of the standard hotel drinking glass, the Mandarin offered crystal wine goblets. Each palatial room had at least two television sets; many had three. When you add in the extravagantly costly silverware, the complimentary wine and cheese, the free umbrellas, double the usual complement of doormen, and the type of towels, bathrobes and linen that cannot be found in the usual run of the mill luxury hotel, the result was a truly lavish package. And the room rates were set to match. They ranged from a "poor boy special" of $175, on up to an astounding $750. And we're talking about the price for one evening, here. The only problem was that there were simply not enough millionaires regularly visiting Vancouver to make this a paying proposition. The ordinary tourist might have the courage to march, in to the opulent lobby, right up to the front desk, and might even have had the temerity to ask to inspect one of the rooms. But as for actually booking in, forget it. Further, even when the demand for this sort of service was ebullient, as during the EXPO period, the 197 rooms, woefully inadequate by modern standards, was insufficient to carry the hotel during slack periods. The result, as we have seen, was bankruptcy. Under the reorganization, the new owners will have no choice but to scale down the level of service, until it approaches that which the traveller can afford. The reaction from some quarters was that this was a terrible waste of "society's resources," and that the capitalist system, under which this gigantic investment was made, has therefore shown itself once again to be inadequate. Nothing, however, could be further from the truth. First of all, there was no loss whatsoever of "society's resources." There were specific people, the owners, that is, who bore the entire setback. And this tends to have a salutary effect on the market. Not only will Vancouver Mandarin Hotel Limited Partnership be less likely to make such a colossal blunder in future -- certainly the loss of a cool $36 million will put somewhat of a crimp in their plans -- but all other investors will have been served notice not to misanticipate the desires of the paying customer in this way. Secondly, although it may sound a bit paradoxical, this experience is a strength of the market system, not a weakness . For suppose the same miscalculation was made not by a businessman, on his own account, but by the bureaucratic head of a Crown Corporation in charge of owning and managing hotels. Under such circumstances, it is likely that instead of being forced to withdraw from the operation, this manager would have been able to draw on tax revenues to finance the deficit, much in the manner of Canada Post. To add insult to injury, there would have been no automatic penalty imposed, such as occurs through the loss of funds in the private market. The enthusiasm for white elephant hotels might have continued unabated, until dozens more were built. No, in the marketplace, only the stockholders bear the burdens of risk from unwise investments. When the activity is organized in the public sector, all taxpayers are forced to bear the risk. This is yet another reason for pursuing the privatization option, with all due deliberate speed. THE MACDONALD ROYAL COMMISSION by Walter Block The hearings of the Royal Commission on the Economic Union and Development Prospects for Canada are now in the news. And the average Canadian must have a strong feeling of deja vu. For if these hearings continue on the path they have taken so far, he will be just as familiar with the Commission findings as he is with the palm of his own hand. As of this date, it's the same old stuff. Organized labour doesn't much like management, and management cordially reciprocates this sentiment. Some business and academic leaders are anxious to increase their government subsidies -- all in the public interest, of course. Others take a more free market stance, and argue against an ever-expanding government role in the economy. The Canadian Manufacturers Association argues for more flexibility in the face of technological change. The senate should be reformed, says another. The export industry favours lower tariffs, and the importers advocate higher tariffs. Business concentration is the enemy of all that is good, says a third. There have, to be sure, been some high points. As for example, when one Mr. Bill W. Weaver of British Columbia treated the Commission on Canada's future to a long and much needed quote from Friedrich A. Hayek's The Road to Serfdom. Surely, everyone would benefit from reading this book. But it was published in 1944. People of a mind to, have thus already had a bit of time to acquaint themselves with its brilliant insights. Even the commissioners have been around the track once or twice already. (Some, even three times.) First, there is of course Donald MacDonald, Chief Poobah of the entire gathering. For those of us who were born yesterday, Mr. MacDonald is a former finance minister of the Liberal Government -- one that has in no small measure been responsible for the economic malaise now plaguing Canada. Thus, Mr. MacDonald occupies a rather tenuous position. As head of the Royal Commission on the Economic Union & Development Prospects for Canada, he may well be subjected to criticisms for actions taken when he was finance minister. Many of the other commissioners are also leading players on the stage of Canadian economics, politics, and public policy. Thus they may also find themselves in anomolous situations regarding the economic situation in which Canada now finds herself. There is William Hamilton, former Post Master in the Diefenbaker government; John Messer, former Saskatchewan Minister of Agriculture, Industry and Commerce; Thomas Shoyama, former deputy finance minister; Gerard Docquier, Vice President of the Canadian Labour Congress; Clarence Barber, former president of the Canadian Economics Association, and Commissioner of Welfare in Manitoba; Albert Breton and Laurent Pickard, prestigious economists from the University of Toronto and McGill, respectively, who have long had an influential voice in national councils; Jean Wadds, former High Commissioner to Great Britain. There is also the fact that the MacDonald Commission is a creature of cabinet. It was created by, of and for the cabinet, presumably to help this august body make up its mind about public policy issues. What, then, are cabinet members doing testifying to the MacDonald Commission? Why is Senator Jack Austin underutilizing his and taxpayers' time and money by suggesting that the senate be reformed? Can he not tell the cabinet this directly? There is surely a logical difficulty here, when a cabinet creates a commission to advise it, and then goes out and advises the commission on what advice it ought to give the cabinet. If anything, it gives the appearance of a dog chasing its tail. Then, there is the issue of cost. The MacDonald Royal Commission will set us back an estimated $10 to $15 million. Was it really necessary to arrange for a three year belly flop into the public trough? Would a commission of one year not have gained for government all it needs from a Royal Commission? And why allow thirteen commissioners (and their numerous retinues) to batten down at our expense? Would not eleven, nine, seven, five, or even three commissioners have sufficed? And, in the supposed age of government restraint and cutbacks, at a time where millions of Canadians are unemployed, how can we justify an $800 per day fee for Mr. MacDonald, and a payment of $350 per diem to his associates? If asked, how many Canadian taxpayers would have agreed that their hard-earned dollars be used for such a purpose? True, these eminent public leaders can earn far in excess of their commission salaries in the private sector. That is not the point. The question concerns more the message given by the government to the Canadian people. And that is likely to be interpreted as "cutbacks apply to the average person, but not to the public sector." It is time that we consider a radical departure from business-as-usual. Let us, in future, privatize all Royal Commissions. After all, our tax monies already support a swollen senior civil service, whose function is presumably to do just this very type of research. The efforts of the mandarins are supposed to be at least on a par with that which can be accomplished by our Royal Commissions. As well, government funds already support several economic and public policy research think tanks. How would privatization work? If, in future, a felt need for another Royal Commission suddenly overcomes government, let it make an announcement to this effect. Then, private enterprise (that is, cooperating individuals) can carry through, if there is enough support for such an idea. People could spend their own money, and organize it themselves on an entrepreneurial basis. For example, the recent panel hearings on ethics and the economy, sponsored by the Roman Catholic Archdiocese of Toronto, under the leadership of Cardinal Carter, was such an event. (The church is not usually seen as an example of free enterprise, but it is, it is. Every penny it spends comes to it on a voluntary basis. No part of this comes from general tax revenues.) Alternatively, private enterprisers might choose to organize hearings for admission, and by selling the final report as a book. Who knows? Something good may yet come out of a Royal Commission. But if they were privatized in this manner, then their expenditures will be based on voluntary payments. No one would be forced to financially support such an endeavour, as is the practice at present. And then no one could object on moral grounds, if they plowed over old ground. The main objection to the MacDonald Royal Commission, then, is one of finance. Let it be privatized, and take its chances along with all other competitors for the consumer dollar. Then, we could only wish it well. -30- Marian Regional High School Closing by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Now that the closing of the Marian Regional High School in Vancouver has receded from the front pages, it might he appropriate to more carefully consider the implications of this occurence from a public policy perspective. The decision to suspend the operations of this Catholic school for girls has been widely condemned. The schoolgirls themselves have engaged in a highly publicized protest at this action. The Catholic Secondary School Teachers' Association has asked the Industrial Relations Council to call a halt to this plan. According to a high profile leader of organized labour, the man responsible for this determination, Archbishop James Carney, is guilty of "the basest form of union busting." A local Vancouver newspaper columnist has gone so far as to characterize Catholics who support their church in this regard as unthinking sheep who blindly follow orders. "The church has long taught good Catholics their place. Good Catholics belong on their knees," were the c\;irt words. It doesn't seem to have occurred to many people that such a description could easily be interpreted as purposefully spreading hatred against an identifiable group, behaviour condemned by the anti hate-mongering Section 281.2 of the Criminal Code under which several now well known bigots were charged. Criminal or not, such a characterization, were it uttered against a group such as Sikhs. Jews, natives, blacks or any other minority, would be instantly condemned by all people of good will. Judging from the absence of protest about these intemperate words, it would appear to be open season on Catholics. For shame. Why was this exceedingly unpopular decision made? According to an announcement made by Archbishop Carney, the school was closed because the church had lost confidence in the teachers' ability to provide a Catholic education. / But there would appear to be more to this than meets the eye. After all, when / one loses confidence in one's housekeeper, one does not commonly close down one's / domicile; one merely fires the unrelkihle housekeeper, and hires another. When a ( person loses confidence in his attorney, it would be ludicrous to think that his only - \ option consists of giving up the lawsuit. Obviously, the more rational alternative is v ^-to dismiss that lawyer, and retain a replacement. Why then did not the Archbishop, having lost confidence in the seventeen Marian High School faculty members, simply fire the lot of them, and hire a replacement crew? The reason is not hard to discern: the B.C. Labour Code hung like a sword of Damocles above his head. The law compels him to "bargain fairly" with a group of people he wished to have nothing further to do with. In a word, it would have been deemed an "unfair labour practice" for him to replace the seventeen teachers with people he could trust to set a good example for the students, on a 24 hour per day basis. The ordinary businessman who loses confidence in his work force rarely closes up shop. Instead, he grits his teeth and carries on. Perhaps this is what the Archbishop might have done had the work force in question consisted of painters, electricians, plumbers or custodians. But when it came to the molders of young minds (these children, remember, were ultimately his responsibility), he could not tailor his beliefs to conform to the niceties of the labour code. Archbishop Carney was unwilling to compromise or "bargain." He has, at least from his own perspective, no less than a sacred mission, which leaves no room for negotiation. So. instead, he chose the only honorable course open to him, which was to close down the school. There are many who are quite understandably unhappy with this situation. But they should seek the root cause of the Archbishop's decision in an unwise, rigid and inflexible legal code, not as an cii'hiti';iry whim of the rricin himself. By in effect closing down a Catholic school which otherwise would have remained open, union legislation contravenes religions freedom. By forcing employers to deal with workers who no longer have their trust, the British Columbia labour code also violates the law of free association. True. rarely in our society does this denial of basic human rights result in such an altercation. But then, rarely do we find in public life a man of strong principle such as Archbishop Carney. 30 Market Failure by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Many professional economists subscribe to what might be called the argument from market failure. In this perspective, the market is imperfect, and therefore the government is justified in intervening in commercial activities, in order to improve matters. But this view has not gone unchallenged. First of all, any attempt to "justify" government regulation of business on this ground violates a distinction which is axiomatic in economics, that between the normative and the positive. Justification is by its very nature a normative, i.e., value-laden procedure; but economics is a value free subject. The point is, there is nothing in the value free corpus of economic science that could possibly justify anyone doing anything. Economics as sncli is limited to describing, explaining, understanding and perhaps predicting: the justification of action is entirely outside its realm. Second, even if there were any such thing as "market failure," and even if economics could somehow justify acting so as to obviate such a phenomenon, it by no means follows that its mere existence would justify state activity. For there is such a thing as "government failure" (the inability of state bureaucrats to act efficiently, due to a lack of the proper profit and loss incentives) and in any given case the latter might outweigh the former. That is, in ordinary parlance, the cure might be worse than the disease. Third, there has been no definitive demonstration that there exists any real world example of market failure. The major candidates put forth by the proponents of this doctrine include monopoly and pollution. Let us briefly consider each. .Trusts, or combines, or monopolies are said to misallocate resources, when they attain too great a degree of control over a given industry. But economists cannot even unambiguously define an industry. There may be only one widget producer in a given city, but if the whole province, country or the entire world is defined as the relevant market the concentration ratio (the proportion of sales, employment or profits accounted for by the top few firms) can be made to appear very low. Similarly, the more all inclusive the definition of the good in question, the less "control" there can be. That is. one is far more likely to find "monopoly" in the industry limited to colas, then in the one which includes all beverages, and yet there is no unambiguous way to define the industry. As well, the misallocative or dead weight losses described by some economists are solely a product of their narrowly constricted "blackboard" economics. Firms depicted in these models are timeless and static, while those which earn a living in the real world are forced to act in The market manipulator, Part I a dynamic setting. Nor is there an independent criteria (the perfectly competitive result, beloved of the blackboard economist) against which to measure the actual operation of a business concern which might run afoul of combines legislation. Rather, the proponent of such legislation must claim the contrary to fact conditional that were such an industry to exist, it would have arrived at a different pricing and quantity decision than the defendant accused of restraining trade. But here the firm finds itself in a "Catch 22" no-win situation. For if it charges more than its competitors, it can be found guilty of monopolizing or profiteering; if its prices are lower, it can be fined for "cutthroat or predatory competition." It cannot escape even if it proves it did neither: for then it stands condemned of engaging in collusive behaviour. Pollution is claimed as another instance of "market failure." The charge, here, is that the business firm need only calculate the costs of its inputs -- land, labour and capital - and can safely ignore the costs of smoke, wastes and pollution, since these are imposed on others. It is for this reason, claim the critics, that the capitalist system is earmarked by excessively dirty air and water and by noise inundations. There is of course a failure of some sort that must be used to explain these unfortunate circumstances. But it is not "market failure." On the contrary it is "government failure," in this case the neglect of the courts to carefully define and assiduously protect the property rights of those victimized by polluters. Were the state to have awarded injunctions to the plaintiffs in the early 19th century pollution or nuisance cases (as they were called then), our entire experience with smoke prevention devices and technology would have taken a far different turn than it has, and our environment would have been far more adequately protected. (For a Fraser Institute perspective that challenges the view that market failure is responsible for our poor ecological conditions, see The Environmentalists versus the Economy.) There may well indeed be market failure in the sense that commerce is conducted by flesh and blood creatures who are of course imperfect, and hence given to error. But no one has shown the existence of any "market failure" in the real world, apart from the fallibility of human beings. 1. 30 - he public is frightened and highly suspicious of those who profit through stock market manipulations. And their fears are often reflected by legislation. For example. according to the securities commissions that govern the stock markets in Canada, the U.S. and virtually every other advanced industrial country, it is illegal to intentionally sell shares in order to lower their pri •. .e, and then to profit by buying them back at those cut-rate prices. The law regards the market manipulator as having engaged in a fraudulent act. It is a false assumption. Take the case of the merchant who sells a sack labelled potatoes but which actually turns out to contain a bunch of wonhless rocks. This is a theft of the sale price, and is therefore properly held to be illegal. No such thing occurs in the case of stock manipulation. The purchases and sales are in bona fide tokens of ownership. so the charge of fraud is fallacious. Nevertheless. even though it cannot be fraudulem, buying and selling shares of stock in such a pattern raises several important questions: Ought such sales be prohibited on the grounds of being inimical to the public interest? What are the economic ramifications? What role do such transactions play in the economy? In order to answer these questions, let us consider stock manipulation in some detail. Suppose that the price of a share in a given finn, call it XYZ Corp., was trading at S 100 before the arrival of the manipulator, Mr. M. and suppose that it would have continued at this level for the foreseeable future if not for his intervention. At the outset of this process, at least according to traditional theory, the manipulator engages in massive sales, which drive down the price to say $50. At this point he begins repurchasing shares at these rock-bottom levels. catapulting the stock back up to its former price of 5100. In doing this, he earns a fortune for himself, and imposes great losses on the other XYZ stockholders. But there are grave flaws in this analysis. First of all, how did our manipulator obtain the massive position in XYZ in the first place that allowed him to sell off enough stock to drive down the price? If we assume that his sole interest in the corporation was to manipulate its stock. and that he first had to buy his shares in order to sell them later. then the economic picrure looks very different. All was going along swimmingly at the 5100 level, until Mr. \1 purchased enough shares for his operation. which caused the share price to climb. Suppose that his purchases raise XYZ's shares to $150. Then, when our boy M sells them off, he succeeds in lowering the price back down to the $100 level. But he has not yet earned any profits. On the contrary, he has suffered losses. showing nothing to offset the costs of his time, interest forgone or brokerage fees. So far we have been assuming that M's doings have no effect on the expectations of the other market participants. It is now time to retire that assumption. For in the real world, expectations play an important role in decisions in the marketplace, and they are altered by the actions of others. As well, for argument's sake we ignore the point that M must first purchase the shares of any stock he wishes to manipulate. In this scenario, when Mr. M begins his selloff he does so on such a massive scale that the bottom drops out of the market for XYZ. Others panic. selling their shares for whatever pittance they will fetch. As a result, the price drops farther arid faster than one would expect, based upon the unloading of the M's holdings alone. Then, when the price hits rock bottom. the clever M starts buying surreptitiously in bits and pieces, through frontmen. In this way he makes money both going and coming: the price goes down faster than his own sales could account for, and slower than might be expected. This way he can buy up all or at nearly all of the artificially undervalued shares (we assume that XYZ Corp. is as sound as a bell) before other people realize what a great bargain they are and begin placing purchase orders on their own accounts. T To he continued. Dr. Block is an economist with the Fraser Institute. BRITISH COLUMBIA REPORT. MARCH 25, 1997 15 STOCK MARKET MANIPUlATOR: Part I I by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute i , I The public is greatly frightened and highly suspicious of the stock market manipulator. This fear is commonly reflected in legislation forbidding such practices. For example, according to the securities and exchange regulations which govern stock markets in Canada, the U.S., and virtually all other advanced industrial countries, it is a fraudulent act to intentionally sell shares in order to lower their prices, and then i to buy them back when they hit bottom, in order to make a profit. This, however, is ill-conceived law. It is predicated on the false assumption that the stock market manipulator engages in a fraudulent act, and nothing could be further from the truth. The paradigm case of fraud is the sale of a good such as potatoes, when, what actually turn out to be in the sack is a bunch of worthless I ; I rocks. This is i equivalent to a theft of the sale price, and is therefore properly held to be illegal.. No such thing is even alleged to occur in the case of stock manipulation -j the purchases and sales are in bone fide tokens of ownership -- so the charge of fraud is entirely fallacious. Nevertheless, even though it cannot be fraudulent, buying and selling shares of I I stock in such a pattern, and with such a motive, raises several important questions. Ought it to be prohibited on other grounds, such as being inimical to the public , interest? Is there any justification for this behaviour? What are its economic I functions? What role does it play in the economy? In order to answer such questions, let us consider stock manipulation in some detail. Suppose that the price of a share in a given firm, call it XYZ corporation, was trading at $100 before the advent of the manipulator, and that it would have continued at this level for the foreseeable future but for his activity. We now have a market bench mark against which these transactions can be contrasted. At the outset of this process, at least according to the traditional theory we are I i considering, the manipulator engages in massive sales, which drive down the price to, say, $50. Whereupon he begins his repurchasing operations at these rock bottom levels catapulting the price back up to its former level of $100. By doing this he earns a fortune for himself, and imposes great losses on his hapless fellow investors inXYZ. i But there, are grave flaws in this analysis. First of all, how did our manipulator obtain the massive position in XYZ in the first place, which allowed him to sell off enough stock ~o so appreciably lower the price? If we assume that his sole interest ! in the corporation is to manipulate its stock, and that he first had to buy shares (in order sell them at high prices so that he could later repurchase them) then the economic pictu looks very different. Here, all was going along swimmingly at the $100 level, until Mr. (the manipulator) purchased enough shares for his operation. But this, as can been see sharply increases prices compared to what they would have been, other things equal, ha he not so acted. Suppose that these purchases raise the shares to $150. Then, when our bo M sells them off, he only succeeds in lowering the price back down to the $100 level, b which time no profits have yet been earned for him. Indeed, on the contrary, he h suffered losses, having no gains to offset the costs of the time involved in the operatio the interest foregone, and the brokerage fees. So far we have been implicitly assuming that M's doings have no effect on th expectations of the other market participants. It is now time to relax this assumption. W do this in order to make our analysis more realistic. For in the real world, expectation play an important role in market decision making, and they are altered by the commerci actions of others. As well, for argument's sake, we now ignore the point that th manipulator must first purchase the shares of any stock he wishes to manipulate. In this scenario, when Mr. M begins his sell off, he does so on such a massive sca that, seemingly, the bottom drops out of the market for XYZ. Other market participan panic, throwing away their shares for whatever pittance they will fetch. As a result, th price drops farther and faster than one would expect based upon the unloading of th manipulator's holdings alone. Then, when the price hits the rock bottom, our clever Mr. M starts buying surreptitiously in bits and pieces, through numerous fronts. In this way h makes money both going and coming: the price goes down faster than his own sales cou account for, and slower than that which might be expected to result from his purchases. this way he can buy up all or at least most of the artificially undervalued shares (we a still assuming that XYZ Inc is as sound as a bell, apart from all the finagling) before oth people realize what a great bargain they are, and begin placing purchase orders on the own accounts. (This is part I of a two part series on the stock market manipulator, which will be concluded in my next column.) MEDICAL LICENSING IN CANADA by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute an article for Financial Post According to U. S. Representative Claude Pepper (Democrat, Florida) over 10,000 "doctors" are now practicing in that country without benefit of proper medical licensing. These are not people with questionable credentials, or graduates from diploma mills, or physician's assistants or nurses practicing beyond their qualifications. We're talking about outright impostors here, individuals who have no official qualifications at all. Apart from this, fully 10% of the 450,000 duly licensed physicians practicing south of our border are incompetent. This, at least, is the opinion of Dr. Robert Derbyshire, past president of the Federation of State Medical Boards, and is seconded by Dr. David Axelrod, New York's Health Commissioner. What is the situation in Canada? There are no official estimates of fake doctors in this country, but according to the College of Physicians and Surgeons of Ontario, a random sample of doctors from that province showed that 13% either practiced medicine in a way that caused "serious concern" or kept poor records. This crisis applied mainly to family doctors, not specialists, and to ciderly doctors. An astounding 49% of physicians aged 70 and above caused "concern". Thus the situation here might even be worse than in the U. S. However, even if the usual ten-to-one rule of thumb applies, this would mean that about 1,000 practicing doctors in this country are outright frauds, and another 4,500 are unskilled — despite their legitimate credentials. How could this possibly be true? Are not this nation's doctors subjected to a complete and up-to-date medical school education, an exhaustive system of initial pre-diploma testing, and airtight procedures which ensure competence throughout their careers? This, at least, is the theory. But the practice, according to University of Alberta History Professor Ronald Hamowy, is far different. According to Hamowy, the author of Canadian Medicine: A Study in Restricted Entry, a book recently published by The Fraser Institute, the function of medical licensing in this country is not so much to insure physician quality, as it is to limit entry into the field, so as to increase the income, power and prestige of those doctors already in practice. According to the evidence amassed in this book, the Canadian medical establishment at one point or another in its history has: banned price and other advertising for licensed doctors; set minimum price schedules; acted to prevent "overcrowding," or an oversupply of physicians by setting up a whole host of irrelevant criteria for licensing - examples include a knowledge of grammar, mathematics, Latin, history, philosophy, and other academic studies, language requirements, citizenship, etc.; outlawed the uncontrolled study of medicine, even for those who do not intend to practice; placed roadblocks against foreign doctors practicing in Canada, where they would compete with domestic physicians; been content with imposing entry examinations only. If the certification of quality were the true goal of these exams, they would more likely be required of practicing physicians at least every decade or so. For, says Hamowy, there is little guarantee - certainly not on the basis of testing -that a doctor of seventy years of age is still qualified, merely for having successfully sat an examination forty years earlier; fought against pre-payment contract practice, opposed doctors testifying for plaintiffs in malpractice suits, and discouraged charity work as undermining minimum fee schedules and professional prestige; raised medical student lees in order to increase the costs of entry into the profession; succeeded, from time to time, in raising physicians' income levels beyond that of other, equally skilled, professions in Canada. If the present licensing system has failed, what, then, can be done about the epidemic of doctors who are either incompetent and/or sheer frauds? The public policy recommendation which follows from Hamowy's analysis would be to install a system of competitive certification, in place of the present system of monopoly licensing. Under licensing, if the applicant fails the test, he cannot practice (as in the motor vehicle licence); under certification, a rejected applicant can still practice (a non chartered accountant may legally help people fill out tax forms), but he cannot pass himself off as certified. The problem with monopoly licencing (as with all other coercive monopolies) is that if the institution in charge does a poor job, consumers have no alternative. Under competition, there is an incentive system for all competitors to try to outdistance each other in terms of quality control, innovativeness, cost-cutting, etc. The weakest producers are forced to the sidelines, the strongest can expand the scope of their operations, to the ultimate and on-going improvement of the industry. Although provision of knowledge to health care consumers about the skill, qualifications, experience, and general trustworthiness of doctors may not appear at first blush to be an "industry," the effects of competition would operate here as well. How might competition work in the medical profession? Were government so minded, it could announce that at some time hence (say, ten years) it would call a halt to the present monopoly system of licensing doctors. This would usher in a competitive certification system to begin at present, to co-exist with licensing for the next decade, and to be launched out on its own at that point. What kind of firms might undertake such an endeavor? One likely scenario would have various certification agencies - the Canadian Medical Association itself, the Royal College of Physicians and Surgeons of the provinces, the McGill University Medical Faculty, major insurance companies, for example - all competing with each other as to which might best be able to ensure the quality of physicians to the general public. Under such a system, the quality of medicine and the extent of monitoring medical practice would improve, to the great benefit of the health care of the Canadian populace. MEDICAL LICENSING IN CANADA by Walter Block, Senior Economist, Fraser Institute, an article for Financial Post According to U.S. Representative Claud? Pepper {Democrat, Florida) over 10,000 "doctors" are now practicing in that country without benefit of proper medical licensing. These are not people with questionable credentials or graduates from diploma mills, or physicians assistants or nurses practicing beyond their qualifications. We're talking about outright impostors here, individuals who have no official qualifications at all. Apart from this, fully 10% of the 10000 duly licensed physicians practicing south of our border are incompetent. This, at least, is the opinion of Dr. Robert Derbyshire, past president of the Federation of State Medical Boards, and is seconded by Dr. David Axelrod, New York's Health Commissioner. What Is the situation in Canada? There are no official estimates of fake doctors in this country, but according to the College of Physicians and Surgeons of Ontario, a random sample of doctors from that province showed that 13% either practiced medicine In a way that caused "serious concern" or kept poor records. This crisis applied mainly to [family doctors, not specialists, and to elderly doctors. An astounding 49% of physicians aged 70 and above caused "concern." Thus the situation here might even be worse than in the U.S. However, even if the usual ten-to-one rule of thumb applies, this would mean that about 1,000 practicing doctors In this country are outright frauds, and another 4,500 are unskilled —despite their legitimate credentials. How could this possibly be true? Are not this nation's doctors subjected to a complete and up-ro-date medical school education, an exhaustive system of initial pre-diploma testing, and airtight procedures which ensure competence throughout their careers? This, at least, is the theory. But the practice, according to University of Alberta History Professor Ronald Hamowy, is far different. According to Hamowy, the author of Canadian Medicine: A Study in Restricted Entry, a book recently published by The Fraser Institute, the function of medical licensing in this country is not so much to insure physician quality, as it is to limit entry into every field, so as to increase the income, power, and prestige of those doctors already in practice. According to the evidence amassed in this book, the Canadian medical establishment at one point or another n its history has: banned price and other advertising for licensed doctors: set minimum price schedules; acted to prevent "overcrowding," or an oversupply of physicians by setting up a whole host of irrelevant criteria for licensing- examples include a knowledge of grammar, mathematics, Latin, history, philosophy, and other academic studies, language requirements, citizenship, etc; Outlawed the uncontrolled study of medicine, even for those who do not intend to practice; placed roadblocks against foreign doctors practicing in Canada, where they would compete with domestic physicians; been content with imposing entry examinations only. If The certification of quality were the true goal of these exams, they would more likely be required of practicing physicians at least every decade or so. For, says Hamowy, there is little guarantee - certainly not on the basis of testing -that a doctor of seventy years of age is still qualified, merely for having successfully sat an examination forty years earlier; fought against pre-payment contract practice, opposed doctors testifying for plaintiffs in malpractice suits, and discouraged charity work as undermining minimum fee schedules and professional prestige; raised medical student fees in order to increase the cost of entry Into the profession; Succeeded, from time to time, in raising physicians' income levels beyond that of other, equally skilled, professions in Canada. These claims, and much of the data Professor Hamowy has unearthed, are a part of the Canadian historical record with which most people, even doctors, may not be familiar. The evidence he cites will thus come as a distinct and uncomfortable surprise to most Canadians. And for good reason. This is because the typical doctor in this country is not at all involved in limiting entry into the field as a means of feathering his own nest. On the contrary the average physician works long hard hours (Winston Churchill's oft-quoted remark about "blood, sweat, and tears" is a particularly apt description of medical practice), and has as his main concern the practice of his profession, not the financial exploitation of his patients. Thus the truth or falsity of Hamowy's claims cannot be based on the experience of individual physicians who do not perceive themselves to be engaged in restricting their competitors. On the other hand, as Hamowy's research shows, the leadership of the medical profession in conjuncture with well-meaning, though paternalist, bureaucrats have been doing just that for a century. If the present licensing system has failed, what, then, can be done about the epidemic of doctors who are either incompetent and/or sheer frauds? The public policy recommendation which follows from Hamowy's analysis would be to install a system of competitive certification, in place of the present system of monopoly licensing, Under licensing, if the applicant fails the test, he cannot practice (as in the motor vehicle license); under certification, a rejected applicant can still practice (a non chartered accountant ma» legally help people fill out tax forms), but he cannot pass himself off as certified. The problem with monopoly licensing (as with all other coercive monopolies) is that If the institution in charge does a poor job, consumers have no alternative. Under competition, there is an incentive system for all competitors to try to outdistance each other in terms of quality control, innovativeness, cost-cutting, etc. The weakest producers are forced to the sidelines, the strongest can expand the scope of their operations, to the ultimate and on-going improvement of the industry. Although provision of knowledge to health care consumers about the skill, qualifications, experience, and general trustworthiness of doctors may not appear at first blush to be an "industry," the effects of competition would operate here as well. How might competition work in the medical profession? Were government so minded, it could announce that at some time hence (say, ten years) it would call a halt to the present monopoly system of licensing doctors. This would usher In a competitive certification system to begin at present, to co-exist with licensing for the next decade, and to be launched out on its own at that point. What kind of firms might undertake such an endeavor? One likely scenario would have various certification agencies- the Canadian Medical Association itself, the Royal College of Physicians and Surgeons of the provinces, the McGill University Medical Faculty, major insurance companies, for example - all competing with each other as to which might best be able to ensure the quality of physicians to the general public. Under such a system, the quality of medicine and the extent of monitoring medical practice would improve to the great benefit of the health care of the Canadian populace. 1 MEDICAL LICENSING IN CANADA by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute an article for Financial Post According to U. S. Representative Claude Pepper (Democrat, Florida) over 10,000 "doctors" are now practicing in that country without benefit of proper medical licensing. These are not people with questionable credentials, or graduates from diploma mills, or physician's assistants or nurses practicing beyond their qualifications. We're talking about outright imposters here, individuals who have no official qualifications at all. Apart from this, fully 10% of the 450,000 duly licensed physicians practicing south of our border are incompetent. This, at least, is the opinion of Dr. Robert Derbyshire, past president of the Federation of State Medical Boards, and is seconded by Dr. David Axelrod, New York's Health Commissioner. What is the situation in Canada? There are no official estimates of fake doctors in this country, but according to the College of Physicians and Surgeons of Ontario, a random sample of doctors from that province showed that 13% either practiced medicine in a way that caused "serious concern" or kept poor records. This crisis applied mainly to family doctors, not specialists, and to elderly doctors. An astounding 49% of physicians aged 70 and above caused "concern". Thus the situation here might even be worse than in the U. S. However, even if the usual ten-to-one rule of thumb applies, this would mean that about 1,000 practicing doctors in this country are outright frauds, and another 4,500 are unskilled -- despite their legitimate credentials. How could this possibly be true? Are not this nation's doctors subjected to a complete and up-to-date medical school education, an exhaustive system of initial pre-diploma testing, and airtight procedures which ensure competence throughout their careers? This, at least, is the theory. But the practice, according to University of Alberta History Professor Ronald Hamowy, is far different. According to Hamowy, the author of Canadian Medicine: A Study in Restricted Entry, a book recently published by The Fraser Institute, the function of medical licensing in this country is not so much to insure physician quality, as it is to limit entry into the field, so as to increase the income, power and prestige of those doctors already in practice. According to the evidence amassed in this book, the Canadian medical establishment at one point or another in its history has: banned price and other advertising for licensed doctors; set minimum price schedules; acted to prevent "overcrowding," or an oversupply of physicians by setting up a whole host of irrelevant criteria for licensing - examples include a knowledge of grammar, mathematics, Latin, history, philosophy, and other academic studies, language requirements, citizenship, etc.; outlawed the uncontrolled study of medicine, even for those who do not intend to practice; placed roadblocks against foreign doctors practicing in Canada, where they would compete with domestic physicians; been content with imposing entry examinations only. If the certification of quality were the true goal of these exams, they would more likely be required of practicing physicians at least every decade or so. For, says Hamowy, there is little guarantee - certainly not on the basis of testing - that a doctor of seventy years of age is still qualified, merely for having successfully sat an examination forty years earlier; fought against pre-payment contract practice, opposed doctors testifying for plaintiffs in malpractice suits, and discouraged charity work as undermining minimum fee schedules and professional prestige; raised medical student fees in order to increase the costs of entry into the profession; succeeded, from time to time, in raising physicians' income levels beyond that of other, equally skilled, professions in Canada. If the present licensing system has failed, what, then, can be done about the epidemic of doctors who are either incompetent and/or sheer frauds? The public policy recommendation which follows from Hamowy's analysis would be to install a system of competitive certification, in place of the present system of monopoly licensing. Under licensing, if the applicant fails the test, he cannot practice (as in the motor vehicle licence); under certification, a rejected applicant can still practice (a non chartered accountant may legally help people fill out tax forms), but he cannot pass himself off as certified. The problem with monopoly licencing (as with all other coercive monopolies) is that if the institution in charge does a poor job, consumers have no alternative. Under competition, there is an incentive system for all competitors to try to outdistance each other in terms of quality control, innovativeness, cost-cutting, etc. The weakest producers are forced to the sidelines, the strongest can expand the scope of their operations, to the ultimate and on-going improvement of the industry. Although provision of knowledge to health care consumers about the skill, qualifications, experience, and general trustworthiness of doctors may not appear at first blush to be an "industry," the effects of competition would operate here as well. How might competition work in the medical profession? Were government so minded, it could announce that at some time hence (say, ten years) it would call a halt to the present monopoly system of licensing doctors. This would usher in a competitive certification system to begin at present, to co-exist with licensing for the next decade, and to be launched out on its own at that point. What kind of firms might undertake such an endeavor? One likely scenario would have various certification agencies - the Canadian Medical Association itself, the Royal College of Physicians and Surgeons of the provinces, the McGill University Medical Faculty, major insurance companies, for example - all competing with each other as to which might best be able to ensure the quality of physicians to the general public. Under such a system, the quality of medicine and the extent of monitoring medical practice would improve, to the great benefit of the health care of the Canadian populace. MILTON FRIEDMAN, POLITICAL DISHONESTY & JOURNALISTIC INTEGRITY by Walter Block The latest book written by Milton (and his wife Rose) Friedman seems to be making quite a stir here in Canada. Entitled Tyranny of the Status Quo, this book is quite simply a brilliant tour de force of what has come to be known as the Friedmanite Philosophy. Once again the Friedmans demonstrate that our burgeoning public sector, with its regulations, wealth transfers, price supports, government enterprises, trade protectionism, subsidies for big business, etc., does not benefit but rather harms the well-being and economic freedom of the average person. In this volume, the authors closely analyze the "Iron Triangle", the direct recipients of government largesse, the bureaucrats who administer the welter of regulations and red tape, and the politicians who carry on, and continually expand, the mixed-economy system. All of this of course has direct relevance for Canadians. Despite all the rhetoric of helping the poor in this nation, and in the underdeveloped countries of the third world, Canada remains dedicated to trade protectionism. Its ubiquitous Crown Corporations misallocate resources, lose money by the bushelful and yet inexorably take on more and more tasks. In addition to such uniquely "made-in Canada" policies such as F.I.R.A., N.E.P., Canada Health Act, Agricultural Land Reserves and Marketing Boards, we undermine free markets with rent controls, minimum wage laws, zoning, union restrictions, excessive taxation, and in literally hundreds of other ways. For this reason alone, Tyranny of the Status Quo ought to be read by all Canadians concerned with public policy issues. But there is another reason as well. For in this book, for the first time in all their writings, the Friedmans specifically mention political events which have taken place in Canada. To wit, the recent election of British Columbia premier William R. Bennett to a third term, and his sweeping program to reduce the civil service by 25%, to phase out and/or abolish a number of politically sensitive commissions, and to cut expenditures over a wide range of other programs -- all to the great dismay of the Iron Triangle of direct beneficiaries, bureaucrats, and socialist politicians. (Dr. Friedman's familiarity with this event came about because of his meeting with Mr. Bennett at the luncheon meeting of the Mont Pelerin Society in Vancouver, organized by the Fraser Institute.) But why wait to spell out the details of restraint until after the election? Why not announce them during the campaign? In attempting to explain and understand this occurence, the Friedmans utilize the concept of political concentration. The typical government intervention into the economy costs large amounts of money, taxed from the citizenry as a whole. Due to inherent inefficiencies, it will distribute goods and services worth far less. Yet because the taxes are spread out over millions of people, and the benefits confined to only a relatively few recipients, civil-service administrators and politicians, the former hardly notice their loss, while practically the entire economic well being of the latter is dependent on these transfers. If all 23 million Canadians pay an extra 10 each per year, and of the resulting $23 million, $1.0 million is wasted, and "deserving citizens" XYZ receive the remaining $1.3 million, then the populace will hardly notice their loss, while the X YZs will fight tooth and claw to retain their privileges. For example, they will hire the best minds available to convince the public that the program is really in the national interest, or the pillar of motherhood, or some such, and that any and all restraint threatens the very foundations of western civilization. This is why analysts observe politicians acting as they do. Had Premier Bill Bennett announced the curtailment or eradication of the XYZ program during the election, he would have had to contend with an aroused opposition from a small minority, and garnered only lukewarm support, at best, from the "silent" majority. There would have been the great risk that the minority, willing to pull out all stops in defense of its place in the public trough, would have been able to beguile the majority, at least in the short run. If he wants to succeed, according to this theory, the politician cannot run this risk. Rather, he must give the majority sufficient time for a careful weighing of the pros and cons, so as to be free to place the strident calls of the XYZs in a more rational context. Notice that this analysis, strictly speaking, is an attempt to describe, and explain a bit of political-economic reality. It seeks to study the behaviour of politicians as the chemist studies molecular activity. That is, this theory attempts to understand political reality, not to cheer it on from the sidelines. As such, it falls squarely within the realm of what is called "positive economics". By contrast, "normative economics" attempts not to comprehend, analyze and perhaps predict, but to justify. And yet this rather straightforward distinction seems to have been lost sight of in Canadian journalistic circles. According to a recent column appearing in a widely-circulated and highly respected Canadian newspaper, Milton Friedman is interpreted as stating that "Premier William Bennett did the right thing by not revealing his plans to reduce government services before the last election". Headlined "Bennett right to hide plan, book states", the article goes on, in effect, to charge Bennett with outright dishonesty, and Friedman with favouring such a policy. Politics may be a dirty business, but it behooves those who wish to make it intelligible to pay diligent attention to the Friedman theory of political concentration and diffusion, and to correctly interpret it. THE MINIMUM WAGE LAW DISCRIMINATES AGAINST YOUNG WORKERS prepared for the "Financial Post" by Walter Block, Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B. C. B.C. Labour Minister Terry Segarty has a problem, and is resolved to do something about it in the fall. The Province of British Columbia has the lowest minimum wage rate in the nation -- $3.65 per hour -- and tremendous pressure has been placed upon him to raise it at least to $4.00 per hour, the average level obtaining in the other nine provinces. At first blush, this would seem like a good idea, even one that is long overdue. If, as its name implies, the minimum wage law can boost wages up to whatever level is prescribed, that is to say set a floor under incomes for the poor, then why not? Surely the presently wobbling economy in Lotus Land could use a shot in the arm of that sort. But a moment's reflection will show that this is a mirage. For example, if prohibiting compensation below some arbitrarily determined level can really enhance salaries, why stop at the paltry, mean and niggardly $4.00 level? Why not go for, say, $40.00 per hour, or even better yet, really reach for the stars and demand that no employee be paid less than $400 per hour? The answer is obvious. To mandate that a skilled craftsman with a productivity level of $25.00 be paid $400.00 is to invite disaster. Any employer who complied would rack up $375.00 per hour in red ink. Even at the more modest $40.00 per hour, any such firm would still lost $15 per hour -- and thus be forced into eventual bankruptcy. No, the reason wages are as high as they are has nothing whatever to do with legal compulsion. It is because productivity is relatively great in this country, and because salaries tend to be equal productivity levels, that we enjoy our relative prosperity. True, a minimum wage level of $4.00 would not threaten the livelihood of the person who can produce $25.00 worth of goods and services per hour, but it certainly can put at risk the jobs of people with lesser skills. For example, the employment of an individual who can only create goods valued by the market at $3.25 per hour, would sure to be obliterated by a minimum wage level of $4.00 per hour. How can we test the economic principle that high minimum wage levels lead to relatively increased unemployment rates for unskilled workers? One way is to calculate the unemployment rates of youthful Canadians as a percentage of those of the more highly productive adult employees in this nation, and then compare this figure with the minimum wage levels which apply in each of the provinces. (We choose workers between 20 and 24 as our control because this is the youngest group subject to the "adult" minimum wage law). Unemployment Rate for 20-24 year olds Provincial relative to employees Minimum Wage aged 25+ Level Newfoundland 204% $4.00 Nova Scotia 213% $4.00 New Brunswick 237% $3.80 Quebec 206% $4.00 Ontario 251% $4.00 Manitoba 289% $4.30 Saskatchewan 257% $4.25 Alberta 182% $3.80 British Columbia 190% $3.65 Prince Edward Island n.a. $3.75 Source: Statistics Canada, Labour Department, May 1985 The results are painfully obvious. Manitoba, with the highest minimum wage level ($4.30) has the largest unemployment rate for its young workers, relative to the general population (289%). Saskatchewan, with the next greatest level ($4.25), weighs in with the second biggest relative unemployment rate for youth (257%). And at the bottom of the pack in terms of the disenfranchisement of their young people, come B.C. and Alberta with two of the country's lowest minimum wage levels. Are you listening, Mr. Segarty? July 15, 1985 MOVIE REVIEW LIBEL by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute Attention all novelists, poets, artists, playwrights, actors, musicians, dancers, athletes, composers, and writ-era. You say you don't like the reviews you've been receiving lately? Who the hell do those critics think they are, right? Have you ever felt, "Let them get out on stage and perform, we'll see how they do," eh? Well, as the old aphorism goes, "Don't get mad, get even." Have I got an idea for you: sue theml This, at least, was the response taken by Cineplex Odeon Corp. to a negative review which appeared in the Toronto Star. Not that the nation's largest movie distributor didn't try to block publication of the offending column in the first place. They indeed made this attempt, and succeeded in obtaining an injunction, but when this was later set aside, Cineplex launched a libel suit against Toronto's afternoon newspaper. The newspaper column in question is entitled "On Your Behalf," and appeared on the front page of the entertainment section. Written by Toronto Star editor Douglas Marshall, the piece objected not to the movie exhibited by Cineplex, but to its practice of showing a 30second advertisement for an athletic shoe company right before the feature film. In the humble opinion of the present writer, Marshall's attack on the ancient and honorable practice was as snarly, low-down and worthless a piece of journalism as has ever graced the pages of a major newspaper. Further, it was hypocritical in the extreme, in that Marshall's employer, the Toronto Star, depends for a large part of its revenues upon this self-same practice of advertising. Cineplex Odeon could have contented itself with a back of the hand slap at Marshall along the lines of pots calling kettles black. Better yet, it might have launched an ad campaign of its own, publicly defending its decision to help make consumers :iware of products being made available to them under our marvelous system of free enterprise (commercial advertising of this sort is virtually unknown behind the Iron,Curtain.) Had they done any of these things, they would have been completely in the right. In the event, however, the movie distributor chose to deny Douglas Marshall his right to express his ludicrous opinions and the Star to print them. (I realize I am opening myself up to a possible libel suit, this time from Mr. Marshall or the Toronto Star; all I can say is, someone has to defend free speech, somewhere along the line, otherwise there will be no advertising and ultimately, no newspapers either). Odeon did so on the ground that "On Your Behalf" was "false, scurrilous and malicious," and would damage its reputation in the eyes of the cinema-going public. Unfortunately, our libel laws are based on the premise that reputations are the legitimate possessions of those to whom they refer. That is to say, I own my reputation, you own yours, Marshall, the Star and Cineplex Odeon own theirs. But nothing could be further from the truth. As a matter of fact, the reputation of each of us consists of the thoughts of everyone else except its purported owner. In other words, my reputation consists of the thoughts that everyone else may have about me. My own thoughts about myself do not form part of my reputation. Similarly, the reputation claimed by Cineplex consists of the thoughts of all other persons, except for this movie distributor. Since no one can properly claim to own the thoughts of other people, they cannot legitimately own their "own" reputations. As if this were not paradox enough, our reputations would undoubtedly be safer (even though they cannot be owned by ourselves) in the complete absence of all libel prohibitions. Right now, if we are "victimized" by a scurrilous attack, it may easily succeed in loss of good will and other economic setbacks. People reason that were the story not true, the victim would sue for libel. The problem with this is that libel suits are expensive, and only rich individuals or corporations can undertake them. (When was the last bisr.e you heard of Joe lunch-bucket suing for libel). As well, were libel legislation completely rescinded, attacks on reputation would come so thick and fast that they would lose all power to injure. Under a regime of full free speech, mere allegation would no longer be able to damage a reputation; the facts would have to be ascertained. - 30 742 words .-^ -\^!S JC-'C"' Newfoundland Labour Strike jV^U by Walter Block, Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The labour scene in Newfoundland is heating up once again. This time it is the Newfoundland Association of Public Employees (N.A.P.E.) which finds itself on the barricades. This 1,700 member union is engaged in a struggle with the Newfoundland Transportation and Public Works Department over a demand that their $6 to $8 an hour wages be lifted to match those which prevail in other provincial ministries. The organized workers are also campaigning against Bill 59, a law which declares essential (and therefore prohibits from striking) a proportion of all public sector bargaining units. The altercation over these issues has turned bitter. The strike has been declared illegal, and several N.A.P.E. officials have already been jailed for persisting in it. The likelihood is that more imprisonments will follow. John Fryer, president of the 250,000-strong National Union of Provincial Government Employees, vows that his group will fully support the local union. A member of the Canadian delegation to the International Labour Organization, Mr. Fryer has characterized Bill 59's strike limitation provisions as a "threat to the rights of free people in a free society," and intends to raise this issue with the I.L.O. Tempers are short, and all that is needed for a "made-in-Canada" version of the Arthur Scargill led British miners strike, is a spark hitting the dry tinder. This Newfoundland labour fracas raises an important question which has application far beyond its provincial borders. If we sit back and look at the issue with a some historical perspective, we can see that this episode does not really fit the classical economic model wherein business and labour meet in head-on confrontation. In that scenario, the capitalist was presumed to be a profit maximizer, and therefore unwilling and even unable to deal fairly with his employees. The government was thus brought into the picture, in order to play an unbiased and intermediary role. But in the present Newfoundland controversy, business has no part at all. We rather find the forces of unionism in confrontation with government, the institution presumed by the classical theory to be above the labour-management struggle. It is almost as if one hockey team were now trying to overcome not its opponent, but rather the referee, and the latter, instead of insisting that its role be respected, has entered the fray with alacrity. In such a case, who can act as the nonpartisan umpire? The answer is. No one! (The courts and judges in this country are correctly seen as part and parcel of the government which pays their salary, and through whose good offices they are appointed.) This is why labour strikes against government are so threatening to the very social fabric upon which civilization rests, in a way that business-union quarrels are not, and can never be. What can be done about this? We must first recognize that the classical theory was predicated upon the state truly being above the fray, apart from the hurley burley world of commerce. But once the modern government entered the realm of business, with its panoply of crown corporations and product-oriented ministries, a fatal contradiction arose. It was as if the hockey referee picked up the stick, and tried to knock the puck into one (or both) of the goals, all the while insisting that he be allowed to keep the whistle between his lips, and that the two teams respect his position as umpire. The point is, the two roles are simply incompatible. Government can be the referee (the classical-liberal definition of this institution), or government can be a player, but it cannot (successfully) be both. One or the other must go. When put into these terms, it is painfully obvious which way our society must move. There is only one choice if we are to avoid the chaos involved in having either no referee at all, or what is almost worse, a referee who is not respected because correctly perceived as party to the altercation. And that of course is a move toward privitization: government must be encouraged to sell off crown corporations in a wholesale manner not yet even contemplated by the present administration; the public sector must divest itself on a massive scale of its lands, businesses, commercial undertakings, and those ministries involved in competing with the private sector; the apparatus of the state must cease and desist from attempting to provide goods and services whose manufacture could be organized through the marketplace. Then, secure in the knowledge that it can at last play a truly judiciary role in labour management relations, government can in good conscience ban public sector unions. (This i^ould not mean that individual civil servants could not quit, nor even that they could not quit, or threaten to do so, en masse; it would only mean that society would no longer grant to these institutions special privileges to picket -- privileges denied all other citizens.) First of all, there would no longer be much of a public sector left for unions to organize. And what of those functions which would still remain even after a wholesale privitization (police, fire, army, courts, welfare, etc.)? Here, we could at last approach the classical model where government could be sharply distinguished from business enterprise: the latter might be seen by some as having interests diametrically opposed to organized labour, but this would no longer apply to the former. In this way respect for the refereeing process in Canada could be resurrected. In this way, and only in this way, can our nation be spared some of the agonized labour strife suffered by many of our neighbors. - 30 - Olympic Standings: What do they mean? by Walter Block, Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Many people in the west have been emotionally cast down by the results of the Seoul Olympics. Apart from the Ben Johnson incident, which is still notfully resolved as of this writing, they see the final standings as an indication of political economic success, and they do not like the implication that the communist regimes of the U.S.S.R. and Eastern Europe seem to be more viable than those of North America and Western Europe. It was bad enough that the Soviets trounced the U.S. team. Even worse was the fact that the relatively small country, East Germany, also nosed out the Americans. To add insult to injury, the Bulgarians, Chinese and Romanians outperformed the British, French, Australians and Canadians, and others who are part of the western ambit. One way to confront this wailing and gnashing of teeth is to realize that the Olympic Games are just that: games. As such, they do not at all amount to an objective assessment of the accomplishments of a nation, and the desirability of living there. If proof be needed of this obvious point, one need do no more than compare the results of the two Germanys. The East Germans, although far fewer in numbers, garnered 102 medals compared to the 40 earned by their counterparts in the West. Yet any comparison of the two societies, on the basis of living standards, freedom, G.D.P. etc., will show West Germany to be vastly preferable to East Germany. It was not the Federal Republic (west) which built the Berlin Wall to keep their people locked up inside, after all; on the contrary, this "honor" belongs to the so called Democratic Republic of Germany (east). There are no people who flee from West Berlin to East Berlin at great risk of life and limb; no, the one way traffic is all the other way. The poorer showing of the western industrialized democracies may also be explained by the hypocritical "amateur" rules which, although on the way out, and good riddance to them, still continue to bedevil the Olympic Games. According to the popular mythology, there are no Soviet athletes who are professional, and thereby excluded from the games. But the same does not apply in the U.S. Is there any doubt that were such top flight American professional athletes as Mike Tyson, Sugar Ray Leonard, Michael Jordan, Larry Bird, Magic Johnson, Reynaldo Nehemiah allowed to compete, that the American totals would have been higher, and those of the Soviets and East Germans correspondingly lower? As well, there is a great bias in the choice of sports represented at the Olympics. The U.S. and Canada are preeminent the world over in football and baseball, and yet these activities were not officially represented in Seoul at all. The worst team in the N.B.A. would blow the representative of any other country off the court, and yet this sport accounts for only one set of medals. In contrast, there are many minor sports with virtually no adherents in North America, which offer literally dozens of medals. There is yet another sense in which medal standings are a poor indication of the athletic prowess to be found in the nations of the world; they have not been controlled for population. This is absolutely crucial to any appreciation of the true accomplishments of a nation in this regard. For little credit should be given to a large country which piles up many victories -- but only through sheer force of numbers. In the accompanying table, the medal harvest of each country has been divided by its population. The number of medals per population is given in column 2, and the ranking thereby derived in column 3. Columns 4 and 5 show the actual number of medals won, and the rankings obtained from these figures. Column 6 shows the number of ranks higher (+) or lower (-) a country moves as a result of comparing the adjusted to the unadjusted medal count. A perusal of this table yields some surprising results. East Germany still retains its rank as the second most prolific athletic country in the world, but the Virgin Islands, not the Soviet Union, has captured the top spot. Other small countries vaulting into the top ten include the Netherlands Antilles, Djibouti, Surinam and Norway. The U.S.S.R. still outshines the U.S., but both of them appear in the middle of the pack, in 25th and 28th places, respectively. So much for the vaunted athletic positions of both these two super powers. Games, it would appear, have very little indeed to do with the armed might of a nation. Besides these two, other major losers in terms of ranking are the relatively large countries China, Japan, Brazil, Poland, U.K., Italy, Belgium, Turkey, Mexico, and Spain. All have lost at least 10 ranking places as a result of comparing the new system with the old. Adjusting the medal count is also in keeping with the common sense notion that people from similar and neighboring countries tend to have comparable sports prowess. In the adjusted ranking scheme, the South American countries of Chile, Argentina, Peru, Brazil, Colombia and Mexico are all grouped in the 40th to 46th ranks. Similarly, the Scandinavian nations of Sweden, Norway, Finland and Denmark are all to be found within the 9th to 16th positions. The Iberian countries Spain and Portugal occupy similar ground (37th and 39th positions) and are closely joined by other European southern Mediterraneans such as Greece (38th), France (30th) and Italy (31st). Likewise, we can see that the inferiority complex that Canadians have long held with regard to the U.S. is entirely unjustified. These countries are alike as two peas in a pod, holding down positions 28th and 29th. The medal differences are virtually insignificant. The implications that follow from this analysis are sharp and dramatic. There is simply no reason for either superpower to invest millions of dollars in a quest for athletic excellence -- at least if their goal is a demonstration of the superiority of their respective systems. They are the leading two countries of the world in terms of armaments, and one of them has an economic system the other is now in the flattering process of copying. But as far as athletics are concerned, both are at best mediocre. Nor is there any justification for countries of moderate size, such as our own, to pour millions of tax dollars into a quest to appear larger than life on the world's stage. This may gratify some nationalist chauvanists, but the average Canadian would prefer to make his own choice on the matter. Let us, then, privatize the Olympic movement, and cut it off from all further government funding. - 30 October 6, 1988 Country Medals/Population Per Capita Rank Actual Medals Rank + /Vigin Islands 1030.9 1 1 45 East Germany 610.5 2 102 2 N. Antilles 431.0 3 1 42 New Zealand 409.3 4 13 16 Bulgaria 401.0 5 35 5 Djibouti 384.6 6 1 47 Surinam 284.0 7 1 37 Hungary 214.7 8 23 10 Sweden 132.2 9 11 18 Norway 122.2 10 5 24 Romania 111.3 11 24 8 Australia 96.0 12 14 15 Jamaica 95.4 13 2 31 South Korea 88.1 14 33 6 Finland 83.5 15 4 26 Denmark 78.0 16 4 25 Netherlands 68.9 17 9 20 West Germany 65.9 18 40 4 Switzerland 62.8 19 4 28 Mongolia 62.6 20 1 49 Kenya 58.7 21 9 20 Yugoslavia 53.5 22 12 17 Costa Rica 53.4 23 1 39 Czechoslovakia 52.3 24 8 22 U.S.S.R. 50.2 25 132 1 Poland 45.6 26 16 12 U.K. 42.9 27 24 9 U.S. 41.2 28 94 3 Canada 41.0 29 10 19 France 29.4 30 16 11 Italy 24.7 31 14 13 Belgium 20.3 32 2 33 Senegal 19.7 33 1 44 Morocco 14.7 34 3 29 Austria 13.2 35 1 35 Japan 11.9 36 14 14 Spain 10.6 37 4 27 Greece 10.2 38 1 48 Portugal 10.1 39 1 36 Chile 8.8 40 1 38 Argentina 7.1 41 2 32 Peru 5.8 42 1 43 Brazil 5.0 43 6 23 + 44 + 39 + 12 +41 + 30 +2 +9 + 14 -3 +3 + 18 -8 + 11 +9 -3 -14 + 11 + 29 -1 -5 + 16 -2 -24 -14 -18 -25 -10 -19 -18 +1 + 11 -5 -22 -10 + 10 -3 -2 -9 +1 -20 Colombia Turkey Mexico Iran China Thailand Philippines Pakistan Indonesia 4.7 4.4 2.9 2.9 2.7 2.2 2.0 1.1 .6 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 1 2 2 1 28 1 1 1 1 46 30 34 41 7 52 51 50 40 Pay Equity-by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Canada is now in the process of implementing a spate of legislation in order to promote "equality in employment", as called for most notably by Judge Rosalie Abella. The main finding of the Abella Royal Commission is that the female-male wage ratio of 63.9 percent in 1982 is largely due to sexual discrimination on the part of the nation's employers, both public and private. Its chief recommendation is that a new affirmative action policy of "employment equity" be implemented, which would require business and Crown corporations to change their hiring and promotion practices, until balanced job representation and equal pay have been much more nearly attained. However, this is the wrong solution to a non-existent problem. The major finding of the Fraser Institute study is that the income gap between genders is not due to employer discrimination, but rather to differences in productivity. There is no determination that these differences are inherent, or based on genetics. Rather, one major factor is the asymmetrical effect of marriage on earnings. It raises the earnings of the husband, and reduces those of the wife. This, in turn, is because of unequal child care and house management responsibilities, different psychic, attachments to the labour force vs. home and hearth. The proof? Women who have never been touched by the institution of marriage, and who thus can be presumed to have productivity levels similar to those of men, do not suffer from lower incomes. The statistics are revealing. In 1981, the last year for which such data is available, the female-male ratio for Canadians who have never been married was 83.1 percent. But even this is an underestimate of the true relationship, because the statistics have not been corrected for labour force experience, age, education, unionization, etc. When just one of these corrections is made, for example, and we compare female to male incomes ratios for never-marrieds with a university degree, the figure rises to 91.3 percent. (For 1971. such university educated nevermarried females actually earned 9.8 percent more than their equally accomplished male counterparts!). In other words, when we consider only males and females who have never been touched by the productivity-differentiating institution of marriage, that is, compare men and women who are likely to have similar market productivities, we find no statistically significant differences in their earnings. The Perils of Nuclear Energy? by Dr. Waiter Block +2 -15 -12 -6 -41 +3 +1 -1 -12 The recent death of 84 men with the sinking of the oil drilling rig Ocean Ranger off Newfoundland was a great tragedy. All the more reason, then to re-examine the widely publicized misgivings about nuclear energy foisted upon us by the "ecology" movement. The Ocean Ranger tragedy was not, unfortunately, the first energyrelated accident to claim numerous lives. Ralher, the non-nuclear energy field has been plagued with a series of similar mishaps. Other recent offshore oil drilling rig mass fatalities include: the capsizing of the 10,000 ton Alexander Kielland accommodation rig off Norway in the North Sea in March 1980, with the catastrophic loss of 123 lives. A November 1979 oil rig collapse during a storm in the Bohai Gulf of northeast China, which killed 72 workmen. A blow out in October 1980 of the U.S.-owned rig Tappmeyer off Saudi Arabia in which 18 people perished. Coal mining, too, has been marred by numerous large-scale accidents, the world over: In Canada, the Nova Scotia coal mine "Springhill" was the site of a disaster which claimed 39 lives in 1956, and another 74 in 1958. In the US roughly 300 coal miners die In the line of duty every year. In addition to cave-ins, coal miners have long been subject to the dreaded "black-lung" disease which has crippled many, and directly or indirectly killed many others. If this past record looks bleak, the future bodes ill as well. Despite ever-improving technologies, as the quest for offshore oil continues apace, into evermore inhospitable environments, the only rational expectation is for more of the same, only more so. The same holds true for coal mining. If energy prices continue their recently interrupted upward path, one source of additional coal supplies may be to dig deeper — into increasingly more dangerous terrain. Strip-mining of coal nearer to the surface brings in its wake the risk of water run offs, and slides, and other hazards — vociferously pointed out to us by the self-styled "ecologists". And other alternative energy supplies come with dangers of their own. The recent hydro-electric dam eruption which drowned thousands of people in India is a chilling case in point. What of nuclear power? Despite the widespread media-led wailing and gnashing of teeth which accompanied the meltdown at Three Mile Island in Pennsylvania, the plain fact is that not a single solitary radiation-related death has occurred in the quarter century of commercial nuclear power generation. And yet the litany goes on. Protestors at nuclear power station continually attempt to halt operations — and are accorded a respectful-to-fawning hearing by the nation's press. Although trespassers on private property, the protesters are given credit for "morality" and "concern". Based on the well-attended movie "China Syndrome" starring trendy lefties Jane Fonda and Jack Lemmon, the impartial observer would A policy that needs some improvements be led to think that oil, gas, coal, and hydroelectric power were cheap and safe energy sources, while nuclear was a mass killer. Can anyone imagine how the media would have reacted had the victims of the Ocean Ranger instead perished In a nuclear accident? There is little doubt that the nuclear industry would have been brought to its knees. A sea of front page news coverage would have made the publicity accompanying the repatriation of the Canadian Constitution seem pale by comparison. It is time, it is long past time to redress this imbalanced analysis which has been perpetrated upon society. This does not mean, of course, that we must bring the same unreasoning passion to bear on the traditional energy industries, as the left wing "ecologists" have long aimed at nuclear power. This would mean a serious curtailment of all energy supplies — and the death of millions of consumers who are dependent upon energy for their very lives. On the contrary, a more sober and measured evaluation would appear to be in order. One which looks carefully at the evidence before launching into public policy recommendations. And when this is done, the conclusion is inescapable that nuclear must be allowed to compete fairly with all other energy industries without fear or favor on either side. May, 1982 Sterling Newspapers. 1. ew Democratic Party housing critic Robin Blencoe (MLA, Victoria) released a position paper which proposes to provide adequate shelter at affordable prices for all British Columbians. Unfortunately, this missive is part ofthe problem, not part of the solution. It advocates precisely the policies which have brought us to our present sorry housing mess. If acted upon, the document will worsen our situation, not improve it. It is tempting to dismiss this initiative as the blatherings of an unreconstructed socialist, and to let it go at that. Unfortunately, however, we cannot do this. Mr. Blencoe is more than likely to become the minister of housing in any future NDP government, and that scenario is fully within the realm of possibility. So his proposal, if for no other reason, deserves our serious consideration. Let us consider the elements of the program: • A tax on speculative housing flippers. Although the continual move of housing prices toward the stratosphere has been somewhat curtailed of late, prices are still far too high for many first-time homebuyers and young families. But prices can rise whether or not speculators enter the market. Successful speculators sell when prices are high and buy when they are low. By doing so, they iron out price fluctuations, lowering the pinnacles, and raising the troughs. Taxing such public beneficiaries will only increase the violability of this sector of the economy, something no one wants, even NDP housing ministers. • Re-institute the Rentalsman. Rent control or rent review reduces the supply of rental accommodation. Other things equal, investors will be less likely to place their hard-earned money in this sector with these programs in effect. With fewer units available, vacancy rates cannot rise. Office towers have ~ever been subject to controls of this sort; their supply is continually increasing, and vacancy rates are relatively high. • Allow municipalities to charge developers for added burdens on roads, sewers, schools, etc. This excrescence from the slow-growth philosophy will have precisely the opposite results from those intended. Its purpose is presumably to promote house-building, so as to combat the shortage now afflicting the citizenry. How will placing rates and greater burdens on builders encourage them to create more housing? • Develop a comprehensive government program for affordable rental to home ownership. If we have learned anything from the disarray of the Soviet and Eastern European economies, it is that central planning doesn't work. That decades-long experiment should have convinced all of us that what is needed for a sound economy, and a healthy vibrant housing sector, is greater reliance on decentralized markets, not on provincial economic czars. . • Land banking, a ban on public land sales, and a retention of the Agricultural Land Reserve. These programs, too, are part of the problem, not part of the solution. The last thing we need to solve the housing crisis is for land to be artificially kept off the market. Building lots are a major part of the costs of new housing. The greater their supply, the lower their price, and the lower their price, the more housing that can be inexpensively created. In B.c., great gobs of land, perfectly suited for development, are being held off the market, courtesy of the Agricultural Land Reserve, a policy created by the 1972-75 NDP government. If Mr. Blencoe really wants to lower housing prices, he would urge wiping this element of Soviet-style central planning off the books, something the supposedly freeenterprise Social Credit government has so far-in its 15 years in power-been unable or unwilling to do. This housing agenda shows that the NDP has not yet changed its socialist spots. At a time when the momentum is toward economic freedom, their stance takes on all the attributes of an ostrich with its head in the sand. And that is really too bad, especially given the New Zealand experience. There, under the inspired leadership of Roger Douglas, a social democratic labour -based party was able to modernize and rationalize the economy, in a decentralized direction. When will our home-grown socialists learn to borrow a leaf from their New Zealand counterparts? N Dr. Block is an economist with the Fraser Institute. BRITISH COLUMBIA REPORT, JUL Y 16, 1990 19 NDP Housing Policy by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. New Democratic Party Housing Critic Robin Blencoe (MIA, Victoria) released a position paper which attempts to help provide adequate shelter at affordable prices for all British Columbians. Unfortunately, this missive is part of the problem, not part of the solution. It advocates precisely the policies which have brought us to our present sorry housing mess. If acted upon, the document will worsen our situation, not improve it. It is tempting to dismiss this initiative as the blatherings of an unreconstructed socialist, and to let it go at that. Unfortunately, however, we cannot do this. Blencoe is more than likely to become the Minister of Housing in any future NDP government, and that scenario is fully within the realm of possibility. So his proposal, if for no other reason, deserves our serious consideration. Let us consider the elements of the program: · A tax on speculative housing flippers. Although the continual move of housing prices toward the stratosphere has been somewhat curtailed of late, they are still far too expensive for many first time home buyers and young families. But prices can rise whether or not speculators enter the market. Successful speculators sell when prices are high and buy when they are low. By doing so, they iron out price fluctuations, lowering the pinnacles, and raising the troughs. Taxing such public beneficiaries will only increase the violability of this sector of the economy, something that no one wants, even potential NDP housing ministers. · Re-institute the Rentalsman. Rent control or rent review reduces the supply of rental accommodation. Other things equal, investors will be less likely to place their hard earned money in this sector with these programs in effect. With fewer units available, vacancy rates cannot rise. Office towers have never been subject to controls of this sort; their supply is continually increasing, and vacancy rates are relatively high. Instead of the rentalsman, we should move in the opposite direction and constitutionally guarantee that government rent monitoring will never again occur. Then residential renters will be placed in the enviable position how enjoyed by their commercial counterparts. · Allow municipalities to charge developers for added burdens on roads, sewers, schools, etc. This excrescence from the slow growth philosophy will have precisely the opposite results from those intended. Its purpose is presumably to promote house building, so as to combat the shortage now afflicting the citizenry. How will placing rates and greater burdens on builders encourage them to create more housing? Why, in any case, impose the costs of infrastructure on developers? Is that not the very purpose for which taxes are collected in the first place? Nor is it any accident that economic development is seen as a ''burden'' on such facilities. They are now, unfortunately, provided to us by government. Were they to be privatized, as they should be, development would no more be seen as a burden on infrastructure than infrastructure is now seen as a burden on housing. . Develop a comprehensive government program for affordable rental to home ownership. If there is anything that we have learned from the disarray of the Soviet and Eastern European economies, it is that central planning doesn't work. That decades long experiment should have convinced all of us that what is needed for a sound economy, and a healthy vibrant housing sector, is greater reliance on decentralized markets, not on provincial economic czars. . Land banking, a ban on public land sales, and a retention of the Agricultural Land Reserve. These programs, too, are part of the problem, not part of the solution. The last thing we need to solve the housing crisis is for land to be artificially kept off the market. Building lots are a major part of the costs of new housing. The greater their supply, the lower their price; and the lower their price, the more housing that can be inexpensively created. In B.C., great gobs of land, perfectly suited for development, are being held off the market, courtesy of the Agricultural Land Reserve, a policy created by the 197275 NDP government. If Blencoe really wants to lower housing prices, he would urge wiping this element of Soviet-style central planning off the books, something the supposedly free enterprise Social Credit government has so far -- in its 15 years in power -- been unable or unwilling to do. This housing agenda shows that the NDP has not yet changed its socialist spots. At a time when the momentum is toward economic freedom, their stance takes on all the attributes of an ostrich with its head in the sand. And that is really too bad, especially given the New Zealand experience. There, under the inspired leadership of Roger Douglas, a social democratic labour-based party was able to modernize and rationalize the economy, in a decentralized direction. When will our home-grown socialists learn to borrow a leaf from their New Zealand counterparts? - 30- NDP Housing Policy by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. NDP Housing Critic Robin Blencoe (MLA, Victoria) has just released a position paper which attempts to solve problems in that field. Unfortunately, it is part of the problem, not part of the solution. It advocates precisely the policies which have brought us to our present sorry housing mess. If acted upon, it will worsen our situation, not improve it. Let us consider the elements of the program: · A tax on speculative housing flippers. House prices are escalating toward the stratosphere because demand is vastly outstripping supply. Prices rise whether or not speculators enter the market. Successful speculators sell when prices are high and buy when they are low. By doing so, they iron out prices, lowering the pinnacles, and raising the troughs. Taxing such public beneficiaries will only increase the violability of this sector of the economy, something that no one wants, even potential NDP housing ministers. · Re-institute the Rentalsman. Rent control or rent review reduces the supply of rental accommodation. Other things equal, investors will be less likely to place their hard earned money in this sector with these programs in effect. With fewer units available, vacancy rates cannot rise. Office towers have never been subject to controls of this sort; their supply is continually increasing, and vacancy rates are relatively high. Instead of the rentalsman, we should move in the opposite direction and constitutionally guarantee that government rent monitoring will never again occur. Then residential renters will be placed in the enviable position how enjoyed by their commercial counterparts. · Allow municipalities to charge developers for added burdens on roads, sewers, schools, etc. This excrescence from the slow growth philosophy will have precisely the opposite results from those intended. The purpose of this proposal is presumably to promote house building, so as to combat the shortage now afflicting the citizenry. How will placing rates and greater burdens on builders encourage them to create more housing? Why, in any case, impose the costs of infrastructure on developers? Is that not the very purpose for which taxes are collected in the first place? Nor is it any accident that economic development is seen as a "burden" on such facilities. They are now, unfortunately, provided to us by government. Were they to be privatized, as 1 they should be, development would no more be a burden on infrastructure than infrastructure is now a burden on housing. . Develop a comprehensive government program for affordable rental to home ownership. If there is anything that we have learned from the disarray of the Soviet and Eastern European economies, it is that central planning doesn't work. That decades long experiment should have convinced all of us that what is needed for a sound economy, and a healthy vibrant housing sector, is greater reliance on decentralized markets, not on provincial economic czars. . Land banking, a ban on public land sales, a retention of the Agricultural Land Reserve. These programs, too, are part of the problem, not part of the solution. The last thing we need to solve the housing crisis is for land to be artificially kept off the market. Building lots are a major part of the costs of new housing. The greater their supply, the lower their price; and the lower their price, the more housing that can be inexpensively created. This housing agenda shows that the NDP has not yet changed its socialist spots. At a time when the momentum is toward economic freedom, their stance takes on all the attributes of an ostrich with its head in the sand. And that is really too bad, especially given the New Zealand experience. There, under the inspired leadership of Roger Douglas, a social democratic labour-based party was able to modernize and rationalize the economy, in a decentralized direction. When will our home-grown socialists learn to borrow a leaf from their New Zealand counterparts? - 30- 2 A policy that needs some improvements 2. ew Democratic Party housing critic Robin Blencoe (MLA, Victoria) released a position paper which proposes to provide adequate shelter at affordable prices for all British Columbians. Unfortunately, this missive is part ofthe problem, not part of the solution. It advocates precisely the policies which have brought us to our present sorry housing mess. If acted upon, the document will worsen our situation, not improve it. It is tempting to dismiss this initiative as the blatherings of an unreconstructed socialist, and to let it go at that. Unfortunately, however, we cannot do this. Mr. Blencoe is more than likely to become the minister of housing in any future NDP government, and that scenario is fully within the realm of possibility. So his proposal, if for no other reason, deserves our serious consideration. Let us consider the elements of the program: • A tax on speculative housing flippers. Although the continual move of housing prices toward the stratosphere has been somewhat curtailed of late, prices are still far too high for many first-time homebuyers and young families. But prices can rise whether or not speculators enter the market. Successful speculators sell when prices are high and buy when they are low. By doing so, they iron out price fluctuations, lowering the pinnacles, and raising the troughs. Taxing such public beneficiaries will only increase the violability of this sector of the economy, something no one wants, even NDP housing ministers. • Re-institute the Rentalsman. Rent control or rent review reduces the supply of rental accommodation. Other things equal, investors will be less likely to place their hard-earned money in this sector with these programs in effect. With fewer units available, vacancy rates cannot rise. Office towers have ~ever been subject to controls of this sort; their supply is continually increasing, and vacancy rates are relatively high. • Allow municipalities to charge developers for added burdens on roads, sewers, schools, etc. This excrescence from the slow-growth philosophy will have precisely the opposite results from those intended. Its purpose is presumably to promote house-building, so as to combat the shortage now afflicting the citizenry. How will placing rates and greater burdens on builders encourage them to create more housing? • Develop a comprehensive government program for affordable rental to home ownership. If we have learned anything from the disarray of the Soviet and Eastern European economies, it is that central planning doesn't work. That decades-long experiment should have convinced all of us that what is needed for a sound economy, and a healthy vibrant housing sector, is greater reliance on decentralized markets, not on provincial economic czars. . • Land banking, a ban on public land sales, and a retention of the Agricultural Land Reserve. These programs, too, are part of the problem, not part of the solution. The last thing we need to solve the housing crisis is for land to be artificially kept off the market. Building lots are a major part of the costs of new housing. The greater their supply, the lower their price, and the lower their price, the more housing that can be inexpensively created. In B.c., great gobs of land, perfectly suited for development, are being held off the market, courtesy of the Agricultural Land Reserve, a policy created by the 1972-75 NDP government. If Mr. Blencoe really wants to lower housing prices, he would urge wiping this element of Soviet-style central planning off the books, something the supposedly freeenterprise Social Credit government has so far-in its 15 years in power-been unable or unwilling to do. This housing agenda shows that the NDP has not yet changed its socialist spots. At a time when the momentum is toward economic freedom, their stance takes on all the attributes of an ostrich with its head in the sand. And that is really too bad, especially given the New Zealand experience. There, under the inspired leadership of Roger Douglas, a social democratic labour -based party was able to modernize and rationalize the economy, in a decentralized direction. When will our home-grown socialists learn to borrow a leaf from their New Zealand counterparts? N Dr. Block is an economist with the Fraser Institute. BRITISH COLUMBIA REPORT, JUL Y 16, 1990 19 NDP Housing Policy by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. New Democratic Party Housing Critic Robin Blencoe (MIA, Victoria) released a position paper which attempts to help provide adequate shelter at affordable prices for all British Columbians. Unfortunately, this missive is part of the problem, not part of the solution. It advocates precisely the policies which have brought us to our present sorry housing mess. If acted upon, the document will worsen our situation, not improve it. It is tempting to dismiss this initiative as the blatherings of an unreconstructed socialist, and to let it go at that. Unfortunately, however, we cannot do this. Blencoe is more than likely to become the Minister of Housing in any future NDP government, and that scenario is fully within the realm of possibility. So his proposal, if for no other reason, deserves our serious consideration. Let us consider the elements of the program: · A tax on speculative housing flippers. Although the continual move of housing prices toward the stratosphere has been somewhat curtailed of late, they are still far too expensive for many first time home buyers and young families. But prices can rise whether or not speculators enter the market. Successful speculators sell when prices are high and buy when they are low. By doing so, they iron out price fluctuations, lowering the pinnacles, and raising the troughs. Taxing such public beneficiaries will only increase the violability of this sector of the economy, something that no one wants, even potential NDP housing ministers. · Re-institute the Rentalsman. Rent control or rent review reduces the supply of rental accommodation. Other things equal, investors will be less likely to place their hard earned money in this sector with these programs in effect. With fewer units available, vacancy rates cannot rise. Office towers have never been subject to controls of this sort; their supply is continually increasing, and vacancy rates are relatively high. Instead of the rentalsman, we should move in the opposite direction and constitutionally guarantee that government rent monitoring will never again occur. Then residential renters will be placed in the enviable position how enjoyed by their commercial counterparts. · Allow municipalities to charge developers for added burdens on roads, sewers, schools, etc. This excrescence from the slow growth philosophy will have precisely the opposite results from those intended. Its purpose is presumably to promote house building, so as to combat the shortage now afflicting the citizenry. How will placing rates and greater burdens on builders encourage them to create more housing? Why, in any case, impose the costs of infrastructure on developers? Is that not the very purpose for which taxes are collected in the first place? Nor is it any accident that economic development is seen as a ''burden'' on such facilities. They are now, unfortunately, provided to us by government. Were they to be privatized, as they should be, development would no more be seen as a burden on infrastructure than infrastructure is now seen as a burden on housing. . Develop a comprehensive government program for affordable rental to home ownership. If there is anything that we have learned from the disarray of the Soviet and Eastern European economies, it is that central planning doesn't work. That decades long experiment should have convinced all of us that what is needed for a sound economy, and a healthy vibrant housing sector, is greater reliance on decentralized markets, not on provincial economic czars. . Land banking, a ban on public land sales, and a retention of the Agricultural Land Reserve. These programs, too, are part of the problem, not part of the solution. The last thing we need to solve the housing crisis is for land to be artificially kept off the market. Building lots are a major part of the costs of new housing. The greater their supply, the lower their price; and the lower their price, the more housing that can be inexpensively created. In B.C., great gobs of land, perfectly suited for development, are being held off the market, courtesy of the Agricultural Land Reserve, a policy created by the 197275 NDP government. If Blencoe really wants to lower housing prices, he would urge wiping this element of Soviet-style central planning off the books, something the supposedly free enterprise Social Credit government has so far -- in its 15 years in power -- been unable or unwilling to do. This housing agenda shows that the NDP has not yet changed its socialist spots. At a time when the momentum is toward economic freedom, their stance takes on all the attributes of an ostrich with its head in the sand. And that is really too bad, especially given the New Zealand experience. There, under the inspired leadership of Roger Douglas, a social democratic labour-based party was able to modernize and rationalize the economy, in a decentralized direction. When will our home-grown socialists learn to borrow a leaf from their New Zealand counterparts? - 30- NDP Housing Policy by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. NDP Housing Critic Robin Blencoe (MLA, Victoria) has just released a position paper which attempts to solve problems in that field. Unfortunately, it is part of the problem, not part of the solution. It advocates precisely the policies which have brought us to our present sorry housing mess. If acted upon, it will worsen our situation, not improve it. Let us consider the elements of the program: · A tax on speculative housing flippers. House prices are escalating toward the stratosphere because demand is vastly outstripping supply. Prices rise whether or not speculators enter the market. Successful speculators sell when prices are high and buy when they are low. By doing so, they iron out prices, lowering the pinnacles, and raising the troughs. Taxing such public beneficiaries will only increase the violability of this sector of the economy, something that no one wants, even potential NDP housing ministers. · Re-institute the Rentalsman. Rent control or rent review reduces the supply of rental accommodation. Other things equal, investors will be less likely to place their hard earned money in this sector with these programs in effect. With fewer units available, vacancy rates cannot rise. Office towers have never been subject to controls of this sort; their supply is continually increasing, and vacancy rates are relatively high. Instead of the rentalsman, we should move in the opposite direction and constitutionally guarantee that government rent monitoring will never again occur. Then residential renters will be placed in the enviable position how enjoyed by their commercial counterparts. · Allow municipalities to charge developers for added burdens on roads, sewers, schools, etc. This excrescence from the slow growth philosophy will have precisely the opposite results from those intended. The purpose of this proposal is presumably to promote house building, so as to combat the shortage now afflicting the citizenry. How will placing rates and greater burdens on builders encourage them to create more housing? Why, in any case, impose the costs of infrastructure on developers? Is that not the very purpose for which taxes are collected in the first place? Nor is it any accident that economic development is seen as a "burden" on such facilities. They are now, unfortunately, provided to us by government. Were they to be privatized, as 1 they should be, development would no more be a burden on infrastructure than infrastructure is now a burden on housing. . Develop a comprehensive government program for affordable rental to home ownership. If there is anything that we have learned from the disarray of the Soviet and Eastern European economies, it is that central planning doesn't work. That decades long experiment should have convinced all of us that what is needed for a sound economy, and a healthy vibrant housing sector, is greater reliance on decentralized markets, not on provincial economic czars. . Land banking, a ban on public land sales, a retention of the Agricultural Land Reserve. These programs, too, are part of the problem, not part of the solution. The last thing we need to solve the housing crisis is for land to be artificially kept off the market. Building lots are a major part of the costs of new housing. The greater their supply, the lower their price; and the lower their price, the more housing that can be inexpensively created. This housing agenda shows that the NDP has not yet changed its socialist spots. At a time when the momentum is toward economic freedom, their stance takes on all the attributes of an ostrich with its head in the sand. And that is really too bad, especially given the New Zealand experience. There, under the inspired leadership of Roger Douglas, a social democratic labour-based party was able to modernize and rationalize the economy, in a decentralized direction. When will our home-grown socialists learn to borrow a leaf from their New Zealand counterparts? - 30- 2 IN PRAISE OF UNIONISM by Walter Block There are two possible types of unions: compulsory and voluntary. The sole difference between a legitimate and an illegitimate union is that in case of a strike, the latter will threaten to interfere with the bosses' and "scabs'" persons or property, or ask that the government do so on its behalf, while the former will refrain from these coercive activities. (A "scab" is the term of denigration applied by some, to people who are willing to accept employment conditions rejected by strikers. In a truly free society, such employment contracts would be considered as valid as any other; in a truly just society, no tinge of impropriety or immorality would attach to such workers.) A union which forcibly prevents the factory owner from hiring a strikebreaker is like a husband who divorces his wife — and then threatens to beat her up, and any prospective suitor as well — if she tries to remarry. But a union that will not threaten or initiate the use of force (except, of course, in self defense against physical abuse) is entirely legitimate. It has as much right as any other respected institution in society. It can provide great benefits to its members, and to the general public as well. As the great economist Henry Hazlitt said: "The central function unions can serve is to improve local working conditions and to assure that all of their members get the true market value of their services." For the competition of workers for jobs, and of employers for workers, does not work perfectly. Neither individual workers nor individual employers are likely to be fully informed concerning the conditions of the labor market. An individual worker may not know the true market value of his services to an employer. And he may be in a weak bargaining position. Mistakes of judgement are far more costly to him that to an employer. If an employer mistakenly refuses to hire a man from whose services he might have profited, he merely loses the net profit he might have made from employing that one man; and he may employ a hundred or a thousand men. But if a worker mistakenly refuses a job in the belief that he can easily get another that will pay him more, the error may cost him dear. His whole means of livelihood is involved. Not only may he fail promptly to find another job offering more; he may fail for a time to find another job offering remotely as much. And time may be the essence of his problem, because he and his family must eat. So he may be tempted to take a wage that he believes to be below his "real worth" rather than face these risks. When an employer's workers deal with him as a body, however, and set a known "standard wage" for a given class of work, they may help to equalize bargaining power and the risks involved in mistakes." With regard to such legitimate unions, I have nothing but praise. They are an integral part of society, and should be protected to the fullest extent of the law. To this end, prohibitions against the closed shops (based on the fallacious "right to work" doctrine) should be repealed. A union and an employer can come to a voluntary agreement whereby all workers must be . members of the labor organization as a precondition of employment. This is a contract between consenting adults, and must be upheld in the same manner as all other commercial agreements. Outside workers have no more "right to work" for an employer who has signed such a contract than does the "other woman" have a "right to marry" an already married man. Nor should such legitimate unions be precluded from engaging in boycotts, whether primary, secondary or even tertiary. Part of the system of consumer sovereignty, of which we are so justly proud in the Western democracies, is the right not to buy. If a person may properly refuse to purchase an item for whatever reason, so may others, even if they act in concert. We must never forget that union members are citizens too, and do not give up their rights as consumers when they join a labor organization. Jews and Hindus boycott pork; vegetarians refuse all meat; Greenpeace members do not buy fur coats; athiests reject religious implements; reformed alcoholics do not purchase booze. Where is the justice in singling out unions, and requiring that they alone not be allowed to boycott? And in like manner, compulsory labor arbitration is an affront to organized working men and women. To force people to work for wages and under conditions they find unacceptable is a step down the road toward slavery. Compulsory labor arbitration and the involuntary servitude it breeds must be opposed by all men of good will. However, and this is a giant caveat, this analysis does not apply to unions which either use physical violence against "scabs," or urge that the government do so in its behalf. (The Wagner and NLRB Acts make it an "unfair labor practice" and hence illegal, to hire (permanent) replacements for striking employees.) Such unions, unfortunately the overwhelming majority nowadays, are coercive, involuntary and hence illegitimate. Any good effects they might conceivably have on society such as outlined above are as nothing, compared to . the monumental evil of initiating physical aggression against those who have not first engaged in physical aggression: the employer who is trying to "divorce" his union, and the "other woman," or workers who are willing to accept the terms rejected by the striking workers. But what of the claim that "unions raise wages?" Is this not a great benefit brought about by unionism, whether legitimately or not? Price Gouging It is easy to see why prices of many goods and services would rise in cities holding sports or civic spectaculars, such as the Olympics or Expo. With tens and even hundreds of thousands of tourists suddenly descending upon a city, the demand for goods and services severely outpaces the supply. Especially affected are items normally utilized by out-of-towners: hotel rooms, taxi cabs, rental automobiles, parking, bed and breakfast emporiums, and restaurants. Such increases in prices usually offend local politicians, who object on two grounds. First, they feel that price rises are somehow unfair and improper. This sentiment is quite understandable. No one likes to be taken advantage of, and price gouging during a time of great demand would appear to be quite underhanded. Nevertheless, price rises have a role to play in a market economy. They signal an abrupt increase in the importance placed upon a good or service. If prices spurt upwards in Vancouver during a world exposition, this is a signal to all entrepreneurs. It is akin to a cry for help. It provides the knowledge that there is a sudden need for more goods and services there, at the same time it also provides, through the prospect of greater profits, the incentive to satisfy that need. To the extent that increased supply is thus called for, the original price increase will be tamped down. If local politicians forbid price gouging, they cut off this vital information and sever the incentive to "rescue" the beleaguered visitors. If politicians are really concerned with the plight of consumers, instead of worrying about price gouging they would do better by eliminating some of the laws they themselves have enacted which have the effect of reducing the supply of goods and services that can be offered to the market. For example, they could relax the laws which retard the operation of the bed and breakfast industry, which interfere with street peddlers of food, which prohibit alternative taxi services, and which prohibit the location of recreational vehicles and campers in certain areas of the city. But there is a second objection to price gouging. It is felt that such behavior reflects badly upon a city, and that although tourists may put up with it while they visit for the special event, a bad taste will be left in their mouths which will make a return visit unlikely. However, as we have seen, if markets are free and if the gouging calls forth additional supplies, price rises will be moderated. As well, if prices cannot ration limited supplies to an excessive number of would-be buyers, other institutions favouritism, graft, first come first served^— will have to do so, and these have drawbacks of their own. Even worse, these alternative arrangements do not encourage a solution of the problem through increased supply. W.B. RED INK AT BCRIC by Walter Block Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute British Columbia Resources Investment Corporation is swimming feebly in a sea of red ink. It has lost a whopping $5.7 million in the first six months of 1984. This was equivalent to 9c per share, and compares unfavourably with earnings of an identical $5.7 million for the same time period in 1983. Part of these losses were due to a shortfall of $1.7 million by Westar Timber, BCRIC's forest products subsidy, in the second quarter of this year. According to the President of the corporation, Bruce Howe, the cause of this financial setback is high interest rates and falling lumber prices. Says Mr. Howe, "We expect improved results for the last half of 1984, despite higher interest rates. Westar Mining's increased marketing efforts, particularly in Europe, will bring higher revenues in the second half." But for the moment, the BCRIC empire rests on a shaky foundation. And as far as I'm concerned, that's just great. Not that I am not filled with as much of the milk of human kindness as is the next economist. I am just as concerned with the plight of BCRIC shareholders as I am with the problems of the private owners of any other investment in Canada. But that is just the point. B.C. Resources shares are now owned privately. All those who now hold a position in BCRIC have done so voluntarily. No one has been forced, willy-nilly, to bear any of the risk associated with the rise and fall of the value of this enterprise. In the bad old days of Crown corporation status, in contrast, the economic fate of all of us was helplessly enmeshed with that of BCRIC. Whether we liked it or not, when BCRIC was mismanaged, or suffered from high interest rates or low resource prices, we all lost out. Now, only voluntary entrepreneurs bear the risk. And this is exactly as it should be. When BCRIC does well, as may happen once again, only its stockholders will benefit. Now that it is in the doldrums, only these owners will register losses. As a beneficial sidelight, the trials and tribulations of BCRIC are no longer hot political issues. Politicians no longer wax eloquent about BCRIC losses, apoplectically calling for expensive white papers, enquiries, and public hearings at every snafu. The recent losses, for example, were reported deep within the bowels of the business section of most newspapers, themselves discreetly and properly hidden on page 39, somewhere. Formerly, BCRIC's slightest hiccup was red banner front page news. How do you spell relief? A privatized BCRIC. August 22/84 - 30 ^ii ^(e-3! Rent Control: A tale of two Canadian cities by Walter Block The rental housing experiences of Vancouver and Toronto serve almost as a laboratory test of the effects of rent control legislation. Consider their histories. British Columbia enacted province-wide rent controls in 1972, under the N.D.P. government of then Premier Dave Barrett; the phasing out process began on July 1, 1983, and ended on July 1, 1984 at the behest of then Premier Bill Bennett and the Social Credit Party. Ontario began its experiment with government central housing planning in 1975 under the supposedly Progressive Conservatives of Bill Davis, and still retains them to this day with David Peterson and the Liberals at the helm. What occurred in the two rental housing markets as a result? There are many possible ways to trace the effects: rent levels, units of new construction, housing maintenance or deterioration, homelessness, etc. But the easiest and best variable is that of vacancy rates. These are objective, easily calculated, and interact with all the others. E.g., the lower the vacancy rate, other things equal, the higher die rents, the greater the homelessness, etc. They are published twice annually, in April and October (in June and December up until 1974), so reasonable coverage for each year is provided. Let us first consider the vacancy experience of the two cities from October 1984 to October 1988, the time during which Vancouver no longer had rent controls, but Toronto did. As the accompanying chart makes clear, for each and every one of the nine observations during this epoch, Toronto had a lower vacancy rate than Vancouver. This indicates a tighter market in Ontario, with higher rent levels, more difficulty in finding an apartment suite to rent, less new rental construction, etc. Nor are the differences only marginal. Over this short '84 to '88 time period as a whole, the average Toronto vacancy rate was a minuscule 0.34%. The comparable figure for Vancouver was a relatively healthy 1.53%, fully 350% higher. Nor can it be objected that Vancouver "traditionally" has a higher vacancy rate than Toronto, or has always had one. A perusal of the earlier years shows ;i mixed record, with the vacancy rate sometimes higher in one city, and sometimes in the other. Over all, for the period June 1972 to April 1984, Toronto actually had a slightly higher vacancy rate at 1.18%, than Vancouver at 0.90%. A wealth of evidence showing the dismal effect of controls on rental housing was presented in the Fraser Institute's best selling 1983 book, Rent Control: Myths and Realities. But as this study makes abundantly clear, rent controls are a subtle andinvidious piece of legislation. For not only will the law itself lead to rental housing disarray, even the threat of it will tend to do the same, as would-be landlords seek greener, freer, less controlled options for their investment dollar. It is no accident, for example, that Vancouver's vacancy rate for October 1988, at 0.4%, was the lowest it had ever reached since controls were repealed. Given the inevitable time lags in such matters, this coincided with the fall from grace in the public opinion polls of Premier Bill Vander Zaim and his Social Credit government. Why should this matter? Because those with money to invest in rental housing reasoned that if the Socred government falls in the next election, the overwhelming probability is that Mike Harcourt and the N.D.P. will sweep in, bringing rent controls in their wake as they did in 1972. And who wants to put his hard-earned money up for ransom under such conditions? This somewhat convoluted scenario may appear to some people as unlikely in the extreme. But consider the fact that we have just witnessed an ominous parallel on the federal scene. Every time John Turner and the Liberals rose in popularity, the Canadian dollar plunged. And when the Mulroney forces improved in the public opinion polls, the value of our dollar increased. This was attributable not to some sort of disembodied Capitalist System speaking out in favour of free trade, but rather to the trust, or lack of it, placed in the Canadian economy on the part of millions ol investors from all around the world. Investors in Canadian rental housing can also read the lips of the various political leaders. Self Dealing by Walter Block for the Financial Post Ottawa has recently allowed the takeover of Genstar Corp. (the owner of Canada Trust, the nation's seventh largest financial institution), by Imasco Ltd., the Montreal-based tobacco and retailing conglomerate. But it did so only after imposing severe restrictions on the merger. According to Minister of State for Finance Barbara McDougall, self dealing shall be prohibited, the management and boards of directors of Canada Trust and Imasco will remain forever separate, and Imasco will not be able to acquire other financial institutions. As if this were not a sufficient protection of the public interest, the junior finance minister reserved the Government's right to partially or fully reverse the takeover, or to force Imasco to divest all or part of its holdings in Canada Trust, in possible subsequent legislation. The reason for this latest large scale government intervention into the economy would appear to be the fear of an alliance of a financial institution and a non-financial business corporation, and the self dealing thereby made possible. Self dealing has been defined, variously, as a process where a conglomerate uses its trust company to unfairly benefit related firms even though this unduly risks its depositor's money, or where a parent company uses capital from its subsidiary to finance its own dealings regardless of the best interests of the subsidiary's depositors. Based on the opposition to the merger vociferously made by both opposition parties, and even by numerous Progressive Conservative backbenchers, there would appear to be something particularly objectionable about a merger between a financial and a non financial corporation. But there are several difficulties with such a contention. First of all, the concern is too general and overstated. Any merger may conceivably result in one party misusing the assets of another. There is thus no reason for the state to limit its misgivings to just those corporate purchases which combine financial and non financial holdings. Of course, if two nonfinancial corporations form one larger one, no depositor's funds are put at risk; but there is as much of a public interest in protecting the property of shareholders as there is in protecting the property of depositors. Secondly, the concern is biased. Mrs. MacDougall and the other critics of the Imasco purchase were visibly troubled by the prospect of the conglomerate pillaging the depositor's property. But the reverse, which they ignore, is equally plausible. The history of economics is littered with sorrowful tales of bank failures. Who is to say that in order to ward off such an occurrence in future no financial institution would engage in a raid on the non financial membership of its conglomerate? Thirdly, the property of depositors may be ravaged not only by the take-over of a non-financial conglomerate, but by one shareholder in the trust company or bank who attains a measure of control. For example, a 60% owner could arrange to lend $100, based on dubious collateral, to his grandmother. When the loan goes bad, he benefits by the full amount (his grandmother turns over to him the entire $100); true, his company loses all this money, but as a 60% owner he is out of pocket by only $60. Thus he gains a profit on the deal of $40 -- at the expense of the other members of the financial institution. In order to obviate just such a scenario, government has enacted legislation limiting control over banks to 10%, and has enmeshed trust companies in a welter of restrictions which limit the ability of owners to engage in this sort of fraudulent "sweetheart" deal. However, the government has also organized a scheme of mandatory deposit insurance (de jure, this is limited to a coverage of only $60,000, but de facto there has been no such limit in recent times). This sharply diminishes the creditor's incentive to insist upon the writing of efficient contracts to preclude such fraudulent behaviour. As a result, market institutions to accomplish this task have atrophied, or never came into existence at all. In the absence of deposit insurance and other government activities which retard marketplace incentives, if the investment community felt that a merger between financial and non financial corporations would unacceptably increase the risk of self dealing, the depositors would desert any such trust company or bank in droves. This would make it unfeasible to engage in such a merger in the first place. Were markets allowed to work, there would be no need for any special government vigilance in behalf of the depositors against a merger with a non financial business concern. One solution is to recognize that legislation which presently protects the depositor from other would-be predators within the financial corporation will presumably serve as well against any threat from a non-financial source. More radically, public policy should contemplate the removal of the first unwise government regulation, subsidized deposit insurance, which deludes marketplace participants into thinking they are safer than they actually are. Since we have seen that there is nothing unique about a financial - non financial corporate merger, the brou-ha-ha about self dealing which emerged in the Imasco-Genstar purchase may thus be interpreted as a general criticism of the propriety of mergers in the private sector. The Fraser Institute has recently published a book, Reaction: The New Combines Investigation Act, which subjects to intense scrutiny Bill C - 91, Federal Consumer and Corporate Affairs Minister Michel Cote's recently tabled attempt to amend Canada's present competition law. In the analysis of the fourteen eminent contributors to this study (half economists, half legal scholars), the visible hand of the Canadian government is far less able to protect the public against harmful and untoward mergers than is the invisible hand of the free marketplace. May 12, 1986 Selling False Creek Condos in Hong Kong by Walter Block Victor Li has recently arranged to sell 216 condominium units he is building in the False Creek neighborhood of Vancouver directly to a group of Hong Kong residents. No big deal, you say? Nothing to get all excited about? Certainly not newsworthy? Think again. This issue has hit Lotus Land by the Sea like a ton of bricks. Every pundit, politician and general busy body for miles around has been waxing indignant about this sell out of holy Canadian soil. The problem? Mr. Li has had the effrontery to sell these properties directly to Hong Kong buyers, without first offering this deal to the local citizenry. How dare he? seems to be the response of numerous apoplectic journalists. Foremost amongst these, at least in terms of bitterness decibels, is North Shore News columnist Doug Collins, who is calling for B.C. politicians to "raise public hell about people being shut out of their own city by Hong Kongers." This response, however, leaves much to be desired. Whatever can it mean, for example, to say that people are being shut out of "their own" city? For surely it is Mr. Li himself, not the people purportedly being "shut out," who is the real, rightful and legitimate owner of the property in question. Vancouverites do not at all "own" Vancouver; they own only those bits of it whose deeds bear their names. Suppose that Mr. Li had indeed made his offering to all and sundry, and not just to inhabitants of Hong Kong. And suppose further that he sold to the highest bidders, presumably the richest people, and that they just happened' to be Canadians of Chinese extraction. Would this scenario have satisfied the racists who fear the "Yellow Menace"? Further, the wailing and gnashing of teeth at the False Creek sale is now being undertaken by ostensible proponents of the free enterprise system. Mr. Collins himself is seen by many as an advocate of free markets, private property, and limited government. But surely a basic element of any system deserving of the honorific "free enterprise" is that property owners are allowed to sell their resources to whomsoever they please, at any mutually agreeable terms. This wrath, then, comes with particular ill grace from free market advocates. Indeed, there is an element of hypocracy. Collins, as well, poses as a critic of affirmative action. He has publicly and properly taken offense at all number of governmentally imposed reverse discrimination programs which favour women, the handicapped, native persons and visible minorities. But opposition against condo sales to Hong Kongers is merely a disguised call for affirmative action, or quotas, this time in behalf of Canadians. Thus it would appear that Collins does not oppose quotas in principle; it all depends upon whose ox is being gored. Think for a minute of what the economy would look like if our opposition to "closed" sales were generalized. That is, what kind of life would we lead if a law were passed that prohibited the sale or purchase of anything to anyone without first making this offer to all other people. People could no longer just call up a specific baby-sitter, plumber, carpenter; they would have to make such an offer publicly, and take formal bids. Ontario magazines could no longer target their advertising at residents of Ontario; they would have to make their pitch all over the world. I could no longer offer the present column the newspaper in which it now appears; I would first have to make this offer to all possible publishers. Small neighborhood groceries, bakeries, butcher shops would be illegal: they sell to a far too narrow clientele. Mr. Li sold directly to the people of Hong Kong in an attempt to obtain the highest prices for his property there, with the lowest selling costs. Like all businessmen, he was trying to maximize his profits. The alarums of the racists notwithstanding, we would do well to ignore Mr. Li and his condominium sales, and tend to our own businesses. As we learn from Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations, the best way to promote Canada's prosperity is to allow merchants such as Li to commercially interact with whomever they wish. SPARE BODY PARTS Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for The Financial Post In the days of yore, there was no &quotcrisis" in spare body parts. Organ transplants were an utter impossibility, the stuff of science fiction. Only Dr. Frankenstein and his literary ilk had any need for live organs. But nowadays, thanks to the magnificent discoveries and new techniques of modern medicine, these possibilities are upon us. At present, it is now possible to transplant hearts, kidneys, blood and corneas. People who would have been consigned to death, or lingering, tenuous and painful lives only a few short years ago, can now avail themselves of these medical miracles and lead healthy, happy, productive lives. All is not well, however, on the organ transplant front. Instead of being the occasion for unrelieved rejoicing, these new breakthroughs have brought in their train a whole host of problems. First of all, there is a shortage of body organs suitable for transplant. It is claimed that some are diseased, and that others would be rejected by the recipient because of incompatible blood types. This had led to a set of problems which have strained what passes for medical ethics in this country to the breaking point. For, given the limited supply of donororgans, our doctors have had to pick and choose — on no criteria whatever other than their own arbitrary whim — which of the many needy recipients shall have this life-giving aid, and which of them shall be denied. The difficulty here, is that our legal-economic system has not kept up with advancing medical technology. The law has prohibited people from using the property rights we each have in our own persons and bodily parts. Specifically, it has banned trade, or a marketplace in live spare body parts. We shall claim that deregulation of this market is the solution to the transplant problem. But before we explain how free enterprise would work in this connection, let us lay a few fears to rest. ' Yes, it is gory, disgusting and very uncomfortable to discuss allowing profit incentives to work in this field. The very idea involves images of grave robbers, Frankenstein monsters, and gangs of &quotorgan thieves" stealing people's hearts, livers and kidneys in the manner described by several novels of Robin Cook. It seems cruel and unfeeling to discuss the market for used body parts in much the same manner as we might describe the used car market. But this is only because in our present society, while we can appreciate the miracles of modern medicine without necessarily comprehending them, we have such a poor understanding of the miracles of the marketplace, and cannot even begin to appreciate them without this knowledge. So let us sit back, and relax, and calmly and dispassionately consider this idea on its own merits, all pre-conceptions and biases to one side. Let our only criteria be not our prejudice, but our assessment of whether this idea will really increase the number of donors, save lives, and free doctors from the onerous decision of picking which needy people shall be saved, and which consigned to a lingering and painful death. Having said this, let us now consider the economics of the situation. As any first year student in economics can tell you, whenever a good is in. short supply, its price is too low. And the case of spare body parts is no exception. On the contrary, it is a paradigm case of this phenomenon. For our laws on this question, in prohibiting a marketplace in human organs, have effectively imposed a zero price on these items. But at a zero price, it should not occasion any surprise that the demand for human organs would vastly outstrip the supply. This, after all, is one of the most basic laws in all of economics. If the price were allowed to rise to its market clearing level, there might not be too great a change in the number of used body parts demanded. This is called by economists "inelastic demand". All it means is that if you need an organ transplant at all, price, no matter how high, within limits of course, is not likely to deter you. No. The main effect of a free market in used bodily parts will be on the amount supplied. How would a marketplace in human organs actually work? While it is never possible to fully anticipate -the functioning of an industry now prohibited by government edict, the following scenario will do as well as any other in describing one possible option. We know that the major source of preferred organ donations will come from young healthy people who are cut down in the prime of life. This can occur in the case of traffic fatalities, murder victims, perhaps, soldiers who die in war, people who die quickly of a disease such as a heart attack, which leaves their other organs intact. Were the industry to be legalized, new firms would spring up. Or perhaps insurance companies, or hospitals would expand their bases of operation. These companies would offer thousands of dollars to people (who met the appropriate medical criteria) who would agree that, upon their demise, their bodily organs would be owned by the firm in question. Then this company would turn around and sell these organs, for a profit, to people in need of an organ transplant. In addition these new firms would operate, as at present, to try to obtain consent from the -4relatives of newly diseased persons, for use of their organs. Only now, under economic freedom, these firms would be in a position to offer cash incentives — as well as the chance to save another human life. The main effect of such a program would be to vastly increase the supply of donor organs. Certainly, many people in Canada and in the third world as well would be happy to take advantage of this opportunity. No one who objected on religious grounds, for example, would have to cooperate with the venture. As a result, no longer would potential recipients have to make do without transplants. We need not even fear that those who engaged in this practice would earn &quotexhorbitant" profits. For any such tendency would call forth new entrants who would act so as to increase supply even further and reduce profits to levels which could be earned elsewhere. Let us allow free enterprise to work in this field, and save us a lot of pain, sorrow, suffering and tragedy. -303anuary 20, 1984 Replacing Ray Spaxman as Vancouver City's Planning Director/ by Walter Block Ray Spaxman handed in his resignation as Vancouver City's Director of Planning after a 15 year stint on the job, citing his inability to get along with the city council as chief among his reasons for departure. The commentary on this event emanating from the local pundits, politicians and public policy analysts has so far centered on the qualifications needed by his replacement. For example, Alderman Libby Davies has called for a tough minded planner who can see the big picture. In her own words, "the city ... need(s) an iron-fisted planner who can visualize Vancouver's skyline in 20 years rather than swaying with the comings and goings of elected councils." In contrast, Mayor Gordon Campbell said he was searching for a person who would serve as a resource to city council. "I think we want someone who is independent and aggressive and yet knows how to provide council with the information it needs to make the right decisions." Should the vision of the new planner be elevated beyond that of the elected city council? Surely this is an anti democratic perspective; why go through the expensive process of voting in the ballot box if the decisions of our political representatives are to be subordinated to civil servants and bureaucrats. On the other hand, the presumption is that the planner, whoever he or she turns out to be, will bring some measure of professional expertise to bear on the questions of zoning and other land use problems. Why accord the primary role in such decision making to a committee of ex-used car salesmen, merchants, teachers, lawyers, unionists, etc? The problem with this entire debate is that it could easily be taking place in the pre-Gorbachev Soviet Union. For that is pre-eminently the country which engages in long and bitter controversies (sometimes fatal ones) over how best to centrally plan the economy. But even the Russians have learned, through bitter experience, that central planning leads to economic chaos. It is the signal contribution of Mikhail Gorbachev that the decentralized marketplace may actually be a better method of organizing economic activity than bureaucratic control. His proposal of perestroika is nothing if not a plan to free up the economy from the controls that have long been exercised by a Ray Spaxman, and would be undertaken by any replacement. Adam Smith, of course, said much the same thing. It is a sad reflection of the intellectual tradition now reigning in Canada that a Soviet dictator is now a more credible authority than a Scottish philosopher in some circles. But given this reality, and given the importance of placing greater reliance on markets, not public managers, we could do worse than apply perestroika to Vancouver city planning; that is, allow this job to go unfilled. But there are those who take the view that city planning is different. They claim that while central planning cannot rationally be applied to agriculture, or mining, or steel making or forestry, it is necessary in order to determine where housing, commerce and industry shall be located. After all, we don't want high rises all over the place; we don't want cement works in the business district; we don't want pickle factories in residential areas; we don't want filling stations located in cul-de-sacs. But there is a fundamental mistake made by these people. They think that if society is to be rationally planned in this manner, there must be an actual person— a Ray Spaxman clone - to do the planning. They fail to reckon with the "invisible hand" of Adam Smith. They do not understand that downtown real estate values are simply too expensive to allow for cement works; that a pickle factory would bankrupt itself trying to buy into Shaughnessy; that placing a gas station in a cul-de-sac is an invitation to economic ruin. Yes, it is hard to visualize how a city the size of Vancouver could grow and develop without anyone at the helm. Fortunately for those lacking in this type of imagination, there is a real world example of a similarly sized city which functions quite nicely thank you without any zoning or central planning: Houston, Texas. Its. story, and the general case against zoning and land use controls, may be found in the; Fraser Institute publication Zoning: Its Costs and Relevance. Stop the Drug Profiteers??? by: Walter Block, The Eraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Once upon a time, in a land far, far away, there was a golden goose. It would lay golden eggs - one per day. But this was the source of the problem: the owner wanted to get rich quick, so he killed the golden goose and we all know what happened after that. Or do we? This is highly questionable that we have learned our lesson, at least in view of some of the problems recently encountered by BurroughsWellcome Co., the producers of the AIDS drug AZT, and the modern day equivalent of the golden goose. Last month several AIDS activists chained themselves to the visitors gallery at the New York Stock Exchange, in protest against a pricing policy for AZT, which translates into an annual cost of $8,000 per year per patient. But this is only the tip of the ice-berg. For years self-styled moralists, clergymen, pundits and editorialists have charged that it is unethical to profit from the plight of sick people. Since AIDS sufferers are as desperate as can be imagined, the incessant complaints of these and other know-nothing busybodies have began to be applied to AZT. In this vein, U.S. Senator David Pryor has held hearings, examining the pricing policies of Burroughs-Wellcome. Congressman Henry Waxman, a long-standing critic of drug industry pricing, maintains that "Congress has the responsibility to ensure that this life saving drug is available to everyone ... and through a reasonable price to all." Possibly as a result of all this brou-ha-ha, AZT prices have been reduced from the $8,000 per year level to $6,000. But this makes as much sense - from the point of view of finding a cure for AIDS - as killing the proverbial golden goose. What kind of signal is this sending out to all potential discoverers of an antidote for this dreadful disease? Will it encourage them to keep the laboratory lights burning all night? Will it lead them to invest more money to this end? Will it push the next generation of scientists and medical researchers into this field, or dissuade them from it? Far from trying to reduce profits in this industry. AIDS victims and their supporters should urge the very opposite course (if action. They should hold ticker-tape parades for Burroughs-Wellcome executives and employees. They should carry them on their shoulders around town. as we do for winning spirts figures. Instead of attacking its bottom line, they should be donating money to this heroic company. Profit controls are like regulations limiting the decibels with which campers lost in the woods can cry out for rescue. If we are to wrestle the deadly AIDS virus to its knees, and are for socialist ideological reasons intent upon using price and profit controls, it would be much better to interfere in this way with every other industry under the sun except for pharmaceuticals. In that way, funds would flow from other sectors into drug research. Pryor, Waxman and the gay community have their priorities exactly backwards. There is one way, however, that AZT prices can be sharply reduced without endangering the quest for an AIDS solution. The average cost of developing a new drug and getting it past Food and Drug Administration hurdles is about $70 million. Eliminating Phase-3 tests alone would reduce this by some 30%. Better yet, disbanding the PDA entirely would reduce drug prices even more. If the crucially important task of certifying the safety of drugs were privatized, sick and dying people would be able at long last to exercise their rights of free choice. Information about drug reliability would be supplied more cheaply and accurately by private enterprise, organized into a competitive industry in order to accomplish that task. Remember, the FDA is the institution responsible for keeping AZT off the market while many AIDS sufferers had to go without, and for giving its imprimatur to thalidomide. Surely a competitive private drug testing industry could do far better than that. Taxi Medallions by Walter Block - 30- New York City has done it again. Always the biggest, and sometimes the best, the Big Apple has just set another sort of record. For the first time in its history, a taxi medallion has been sold for a cool $100,000.00. This is in U.S. currency, of course, which is worth over $135,000.00 in Canadian dollars. (The situation in this country is serious but not as critical -- the value of medallions in our cities is still far less -- so perhaps there is still some time to learn from the mistakes committed south of our border.) The reason for this startling event in Gotham is not too difficult to explain. The number of medallions, or licences to drive a cab in New York City, has remained frozen at 11,787--ever since 1937! But in the last 50 years Gotham has grown quite a bit; with increased affluence, the taxi-riding public has increased by even more. As a result, the value of a legal permit to pick up and deliver passengers on the streets of New York has skyrocketed, and has now reached its present six-figure height. This situation is highly problematic, and for several reasons. First of all, the consumer -- especially when it rains, or during the late evening and early morning hours -- is oft-time forced to go without this service. This phenomenon, no doubt, is in large part responsible for the jokes New Yorkers tell about the difficulty of finding a cab when you want one. (But it is not much of a joke for the city's minority group members, who are often discriminated against by cab drivers, of all races and nationalities.) Secondly, there is the plight of the would-be new entrant to the taxi business. Imagine the, barrier he faces. Not only must he be able to purchase an automobile, and keep its gas tank full, he must somehow come up with an even $100,000! This, of course, all but rules out any immigrant, young person, or minority group member. At best such people can get jobs in the industry, driving the cabs owned by others, but ownership of their own taxi business is simply beyond the means of all but the very rich. New York's feisty Mayor Ed Koch has come up with a plan to increase the number of medallions by 1,200, or some 10 percent of the total. But the taxi interests, and the major banks which hold the mortgages on these permits, have howled in anguish and outrage, and it is not hard to see why. If we assume that all taxi licences could sell at this new price, then the total book value of the 11,787 medallions is $1,178,700,000, or almost $1.2 billion dollars. Any large scale increase in the number of cabs permitted on the streets would eat into these values, and create vast losses for many in the industry. What, then should be done? The status quo defends the property values of the medallion owners, but it violates the public interest, inconveniences the consumer, freezes out new entrants, and enhances discrimination against minority group members. No matter what decision is finally arrived at, the interests of at least some people will thus be harmed. The same, of course, could be said for the ending of slavery. Certainly, the slave-owners were out of pocket on that great and glorious day when all the slaves were freed. And this points us in the direction of what must be done today, for the taxi industry. Increasing the medallions by 10 per cent, or by any other amount, might slightly alleviate some of the symptoms of the problem, and so is on that ground a reasonable compromise. But it would only perpetuate a patently unjust system. The only just solution is to end the system of entry barriers to taxi driving, and in one fell swoop. This could be done by announcing that henceforth, no medallions are necessary for taxi ownership. Anyone can own and drive a cab, provided only that safety and insurance requirements are met. This would ensure that customers were supplied with cabs, and that all those wishing to own and drive cabs would at last have this opportunity. But wouldn't this be unjust to all those who in "good faith" purchased the now worthless taxi medallions? Not a bit of it. It would be no more unfair to the present cab owners than was it unjust to free the slaves, without compensating the slaveholders. The slaveowners, too, bought their slaves in "good faith," but are not thereby entitled to any special consideration. Legislative sittings have been called "futures markets in stolen property." The point is, anyone who makes a purchase in this "futures market," such as the owner of a taxi medallion or of a slave, deserves to lose his entire investment when the scheme is finally exposed as the theft it is, and is repealed. Another common objection to a completely free market in taxi cabs is that there will be too many such vehicles on the road under such a system. If anyone is free to enter, goes the argument, why then everyone will. But this objection misunderstands a basic premise of economics. Profit tends to equalize across all industries. If so many cabs entered the field such that none of them could move, much less make a living, then many would be forced to leave. This would occur until the remuneration that could be earned behind the wheel tended to equal that which could be earned elsewhere, with due consideration given to the skills needed, the working conditions, etc. Thus we see that the market has its own system of checks and balances. Government is hardly needed to ensure that there are not too many participants in any one industry and too few in another. Teen Suicide by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute According to two recent studies reported on in the prestigious New England Journal of Medicine, television news stories and dramas about suicide have been responsible for an increase in the suicide rate amongst teenagers. Paradoxically, this unfortunate effect has resulted even from programs which were ostensibly designed to increase public awareness of the problem -- in the hopes of reducing it. According to the psychiatrists who undertook the research, the young people in question ignored the message being broadcast to them, and instead engaged in "imitative suicidal behaviour". The television networks which were involved in these episodes issued immediate challenges to the findings. One spokesperson sharply denied that any causal relationship had been established between the T.V. shows and an upsurge in teen suicides. However, the scientists had studied 38 such shows which were broadcast between 1973 and 1979, and found an average increase of 2.91 suicides in the following eight day period -- a result which could not be explained through normal statistical variance. Let us not argue over the facts of the case. Instead, let us assume for the sake of argument that the finding of a causal relationship between these programs and subsequent suicides is correct. What follows, if anything, from such a stipulation? In the view of some public policy analysts, there would then be a clear case for banning all television treatments of suicide. (This, at least, would be the reasoning of those who urge that pornography be prohibited on the ground that it leads to rape). The difficulty with this stance is that it can interfere with not only the free speech rights of the media, but also with scientific research. Take the studies reported in the New England Journal of Medicine themselves as an example. It is more than likely, given the intellectual precociousness of the younger generation, that many teenagers read this material. Given the assuming, the probability is that at least some of these young scholars have committed suicide as a result. But the situation is even worse than that. If the mere mention of suicide can bad impressionable youngsters to indulge in this behaviour, and if pornography can induce rape, then we may easily suppose that the depiction of detective stories will cause crime, that the study of history will encourage war, and that courses in chemistry and physics will result in the widespread creation of thermonuclear devices. More to the point there is an element of truth in each of these allegations. There is an element of risk involved in all of knowledge, including threats. However, if all such activities were therefore prohibited, it would man a virtual end to culture as it has developed over the course of the last few dozen centuries. Paradoxically, if art, culture and science have had a civilizing effects on the human animal, then banning it in the name of saving lives may actually result in more death, not less. The moral of the story should be clear. People have a right to do whatever they wish, as long as it does not involve the invitation of force against others. We cannot stop the onward and upward march of knowledge and culture just because some impressionable young people may be adversely affected. - 30 550 words The Franchiser by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The complaints against the franchiser are many and varied. Such companies as McDonald's, Burger King, and Wendy's are accused of presiding over a form of industrial organization which has had no productivity growth whatsoever for the last two decades employs a nonunion workforce composed mainly of teenagers who are forced to perform repetitive tasks at high speed for low wages creates visual eyesores which is a blot on our civilization. Further, these fast food chains are only the tip of the ice-berg. Competitors include Kentucky Fried Chicken, White Spot, Denny's, Mr. Mike's, Dairy Queen, Carvel, Dunkin Donuts, Pizza Hut, Arby's, Taco Time and a whole host of others of that generally nefarious ilk. Nor has this peril been confined to the "plastic" food industry. Nowadays the disease has spread to automobile repair (Midas Muffler, Aamco Transmissions, Speedy Muffler), hotels (Holiday Inn, Best Western, Motel 6), and even to such hitherto staid occupations as financial consulting (H&R Block), real estate (Century 21), and medical and dental operations (the new denizens of the almost equally objectionable shopping malls.) Altogether, this relatively new type of business enterprise has sounded the death knell for individualism. Our towns and cities have become homogenized; mom and pop stores of great variety have been consigned to the dust bin of commerce. Happily from the point of view of those who yearn to turn back the clock to an earlier, simpler more pastoral time, a strong reaction has set in. There are numerous cases on record of local community zoning boards refusing to grant permission for a new McDonalds to be opened. As well, dirigisme professors, academics and intellectuals are girding themselves up to combat this menace. This, at least, is the case against the franchiser made by his numerous and vociferous detractors. In point of fact, however, the objections are of no moment. Franchising is as honorable and beneficial a form of enterprise as any other. In view of the many complaints against it, we do well to consider its defence. First of all, franchising represents a voluntary commercial act between consenting adults. There is agreement on all sides: between customer and retailer, retailer and franchiser and customer and franchiser. The reason this mode of operation has become so popular is because in the opinion of millions of people, their lives have been rendered richer and happier by the advent of this mode of operation. They scarcely would have patronized these outlets in the vast numbers they have, had this not been so. Secondly, they have done so in order to promote their own safety and security. Say what you will about heterogeneity, but in the previous epoch unscrupulous fly-by-night frauds had been able to inculcate themselves in amongst the legitimate mom and pop firms. In patronizing the franchisees, the public may well have lost some variety, but they have gained the assurance that quality standards are being maintained. And in their view, the trade was worthwhile. Thirdly, the franchise represents not so much a radical departure from past business practices as a continuation of the market's long standing efforts to continually upgrade the quality of the offer made to the customer. Earlier milestones along this road were the development of department stores, and before that, brand names. As for there being no productivity improvements in industries covered by franchising for the past 20 years, this is patently false. Were there a scintilla of truth in this claim it would be impossible to account for their success. The fast food concerns do indeed employ young people for unchallenging tasks at low wages, but better this than consigning them to many years of forced unemployment. Teenagers have to start somewhere, and in any case are deliriously happy to have these jobs, as shown by the alacrity with which they apply for them. And last but not least, beauty is in the eye of the beholder. Yes, there may be those with tender and heightened artistic sensibilities who are aesthetically outraged by neon signs, and they are free to withhold their patronage from these businesses. But in a free society, they are not at liberty to prevent the rest of us from making choices for ourselves. - 30 July 4, 1988 THE TOOTH FAIRY by Walter Block, Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Like death and taxes, tooth decay was part of the human condition--somethingwe suffered from and could not avoid. Happily, however, this may be part of our past. There has been no movement on the death and taxes front of late but there are indictions that we are about to turn the corner on tooth decay. Evidence for this contention abounds. According to the Canadian Dental Association there has been a 45 percent decrease in cavities in the last 10 years; fully one-third of the U.S. population under 17 years of age is completely cavity free; and those who still suffer from this affliction have 50 percent fewer cavities than a decade ago. What is responsible for this dental liberation? There are those who credit the tooth fairy but our more pedestrian scientists point to fluoridated drinking water, better commercial toothpastes and improved dental technology. Whatever the cause,. this medical miracle has had several serious sociological implications. For one thing, there have been serious repercussions upon the profession of dentistry. Not to put too fine a point on it, with fewer cavities and the long-term prospects for none at all, there has been a falling off in the demand for practitioners. As a result, Canadian centres of higher learning such as the University of British Columbia, the University of Toronto, and the University of Western Ontario have had to cut back heavily in their first-term enrolments in dentistry school. Not being able to enter the field is a disappointment to many would be dentists but it is a personal, professional and economic tragedy to those in their fifties who 2 have devoted their whole lives to the care of teeth and now find that their services are no longer needed. Should public funds be used for their retraining? Not a bit of it. In the market, investors in capital, whether human or physical, pay their money and take their chances. If they succeed, they reap the rewards. (When was the last time a prosperous dentist offered to share some of his income with you?) But if they fail, as in this case, it is they who must bear the burden. This phenomenon also sheds some light on a doctrine recently popularized by the advocates of equal pay legislation. In their view, the worth of a job depends upon such objectively quantifiable characteristics as training, job responsibility, and working conditions. Well, all of these things have remained constant in the last little while yet the pay received by dentists on the market has been plummeting. So much for the view that jobs have intrinsic values. - 30 November 1985 THE TUBE MADE ME DO IT by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute This fall NBC presented a made-for-T.V. movie "The Burning Bed". Starring Farrah Fawcett, it told the story of Francine Hughes, a woman who had been beaten by her husband for 13 years. Finally, the battered wife soaked her husband's bed with gasoline, and while he was asleep, burned him to death. Right after the broadcast of this movie, violence occurred in three separate cities in the U.S. In Milwaukee, 39 year old Joseph Brandt waited for his estranged 37 year old wife Sharon in her driveway. When she pulled up, he doused her with gasoline and threw a lighted match at her. In Quincy, Massachusetts, a husband became enraged by the show and beat his wife to a bloody pulp. According to the director of the shelter that took her in, the husband told her he wanted to get her before she got him. And in Chicago, as if to feed the fears of this Quincy husband, a battered wife watched "The Burning Bed", and shot her husband with a pistol. Nor was this the only case of life imitating art. In Portsmouth, Virginia, a man watched the movie "Revenge of the Ninja", a story about a Japanese assassin. Depressed over his families' eviction from their home, Gregory Eley, 24, donned oriental garb and battle stars, armed himself with a submachine gun, two crossbows and a hand gun, and murdered a woman who had sued him over a business deal. A question not unnaturally arises. Should society ban movies which feature themes of death and destruction, which may lead people to emulate them? It is easy to advocate censorship, for had these two movies not been shown, several people who were killed might today still be alive. 2 But a moment's reflection casts doubt on such a public policy decision. If we banned movies, we would have to ban books, stories, paintings, plays, operas, etc. Even children's fairy tales -- Jack and the Bean Stalk, Little Red Riding Hood, Chicken Little, Hansel and Gretel -- are replete with mayhem and murder. Down this path lies the end of culture and art as we know it. But there is an even more basic objection to censorship and prior restraint. The human being is a creature of free will. People, whether they like it or not, are responsible for their own acts. "The Burning Bed", and all other artistic endeavours which depict violence, are not to blame for the acts of those who chose to emulate them. Only the criminals themselves are to blame. The Travails of Mervyn Levigne by Walter Block Mervyn Levigne, with the support of the National Citizen's Coalition, has just won a signal victory in the Ontario Supreme Court. Mr. Levigne teaches at a college which is covered by an agreement negotiated through the Ontario Public Service Employees Union. He isn't a member, but pays dues under the Rand formula, on the ground that since he benefits from the labour organization, he should pay for its collective bargaining activities. But the court drew the line at forcing Levigne to underwrite the union's political program: support for such things as the N.D.P. and abortion. It held that this violated the college teacher's rights of association under the Charter of Rights. At a superficial level, this finding would appear to be a blow for freedom and human rights. But by looking beneath surface appearances, we can see several disquieting aspects of this court opinion. . The chief stock in trade of unions is their ability to restrict the entry into the labour market of would be competitors. They do so by initiating not only threats, but actual force against strikebreakers, and others who oppose them. They are virtually the only ones in society who can with legal impunity initiate violence against other citizens. It is thus problematic that the court in the Levigne ease failed to make this more basic criticism of organized labour. . It is by no means clear that unions really benefit the work force. The best available evidence indicates that organized workers earn some 15% more than they would have otherwise in the absence of their union, but this is accomplished by exacerbating unemployment on the part of non union members. (Nor would it help if al^ employees were unionized. For the way these organizations raise wages is by restricting entry. In order for the process to work, someone has to be frozen out.) As well, in many cases, unions become so greedy that they choke off the lives of the firms they live off, in the manner of parasites unaware of their ^' best interests. If on net balance unions are not of benefit to employees, then the Rand formula, approved by the court, can hardly be justified. . But even if it were true that unions benefit workers in general, it still does not follow that they should be allowed to charge those employees who are unwilling to join up for this privilege. For many groups in our society benefit non-contracting third parties, without being able to bill them for their gains. For example, my lot in life is vastly improved if you wash your car, or mow your lawn, or bathe regularly, or smile at me as we pass by each other on the sidewalk. Yet what would we think of a government that allowed you to charge me for these undoubted advantages, against my will. But this is precisely what the Rand formula allows to unions. It should be struck down if for no other reason than this. - 30 THE TUBE MADE ME DO IT by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute This fall NBC presented a made-for-T.V. movie &quotThe Burning Bed". Starring Farrah Fawcett, it told the story of Francine Hughes, a woman who had been beaten by her husband for 13 years. Finally, the battered wife soaked her husband's bed with gasoline, and while he was asleep, burned him to death. Right after the broadcast of this movie, violence occurred in three separate cities in the U.S. In Milwaukee, 39 year old Joseph Brandt waited for his estranged 37 year old wife Sharon in her driveway. When she pulled up, he doused her with gasoline and threw a lighted match at her. In Quincy, Massachusetts, a husband became enraged by the show and beat his wife to a bloody pulp. According to the director of the shelter that took her in, the husband told her he wanted to get her before she got him. And in Chicago, as if to feed the fears of this Quincy husband, a battered wife watched &quotThe Burning Bed", and shot her husband with a pistol. Nor was this the only case of life imitating art. In Portsmouth, Virginia, a man watched the movie &quotRevenge of the Ninja", a story about a Japanese assassin. Depressed over his families' eviction from their home, Gregory Eley, 2^, donned oriental garb and battle stars, armed himself with a submachine gun, two crossbows and a hand gun, and murdered a woman who had sued him over a business deal. A question not unnaturally arises. Should society ban movies which feature themes of death and destruction, which may lead people to emulate them? It is easy to advocate censorship, for had these two movies not been shown, several people who were killed might today still be alive. But a moment's reflection casts doubt on such a public policy decision. If we banned movies, we would have to ban books, stories, paintings, plays, operas, etc. Even children's fairy tales -- 3ack and the Bean Stalk, Little Red Riding Hood, Chicken Little, Hansel and Gretel -- are replete with mayhem and murder. Down this path lies the end of culture and art as we know it. But there is ^an even more basic objection to censorship and prior restraint. The human being is a creature of free will. People, whether they like it or not, are responsible for their own acts. &quotThe Burning Bed", and all other artistic endeavours which depict violence, are not to blame for the acts of those who chose to emulate them. Only the criminals themselves are to blame. UBC: Second to noneby Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The University of British Columbia has recently published its "mission" statement. Entitled "Second to None," the document is a blueprint showing how U.B.C. could accomplish its goal of achieving excellence as a centre of higher learning. And how will this premier university proceed? By concentrating on graduate, not undergraduate programs, and by limiting its student intake to only the very best of the applicants. In the words of one spokesman, "Choosing the students most likely to succeed results in more efficient use of the very special resource this province has in its flagship university." But what of the students who would otherwise be accepted for admission, under a less elitist procedure? UBC accepts the notion that under this plan 10,000 to 15,000 students will be left high and dry, but has embarked on a course of specialization and division of labour: this institution will take on only the best and brightest students, leaving the others to the tender mercies of the provincial post secondary system. The bottom line is that openings must be rationed on some basis or other. This is true whenever demand is greater than supply, and that certainly holds in this case. Given this necessity, there are very few people who would fault UBC for employing a criterion of intelligence, or ability to withstand the rigours of its purposefully distinguished course of study. According to its academic vice president and provost, "When places in an academic program must be rationed, it would be quite wrong to ration them on any other basis." But the ethics of the matter are by no means so clear and straightforward. On the contrary, there are grave moral pitfalls in such a stance. In order to see them, we must reflect carefully upon the financing of the University of British Columbia. In point of fact, the funds necessary for the running of this great university do not all come from the best and the brightest, the people with the highest I.Q.s, or the most distinguished academic accomplishments. On the contrary, they are derived from the entire citizenry, through compulsory taxes. What kind of morality is it then which requires all people to financially support an institution, and yet restricts the benefits to those (i.e., the most intelligent) who can profit from it the most, to be sure, but who are likely to need it the least? The problem, here, is that most of the people forced to pay for the academic standards to which the professorate and students at UBC would like to become accustomed could never in a million years pass the entry requirements. There is of course no problem with attempting to become a world class institution of higher learning -- on a private basis. People are presumably free to do as they wish with their own funds, and if they desire this goal, and are willing to pay for it, no one should stand in their way. But once a university enters into the morally disputatious area of the public sector, and thereby obtains access to the public trough, it is highly unethical to discriminate against some taxpayers and in favour of others. What mode of rationing, then, would be morally appropriate for a public university to adopt? One thing is clear at the outset: any entrance requirement based on intelligence, or ability to do the scholarly work, let alone UBC's extremely rigourous standard, is clearly unjustified. For they all preclude from entrance those who have paid for the service. It would appear that the only legitimate criterion would be taxpayer status. Let he who pays the piper call the tune. Given a shortage of space, perhaps the fairest admission policy would be one of a lottery. Let all those taxpayers who wish to apply be given a lottery number, with the winners to be drawn in some random way. Then, the university could tailor itself to suit its constituents: high level classes for those able to do the work at one end of the spectrum, as at present, remedial reading or writing for those at the other end of the spectrum, and courses of intermediate difficulty and challenge for those in the middle. Many will regard this "modest proposal" as ridiculous. The absurdity emerges, however, not from the idea itself, but from a system which forces people to contribute to the institutions of higher learning they cannot reasonably hope to attend. - 30 August 3, 1988 Unilateral Free Trade -- or a Negotiated Settlement by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute A unilateral declaration of free trade on the part of Canada is hardly on the top of the agenda of the Mulroney Government, but it may be of interest to examine this public policy alternative in any case. If the "fast track" negotiations continue to splutter along at their present furious clip, or, more to the point, never get underway at all, lost in a tragic escalating tariff war, this country shall be faced with a dilemma down the road a piece: an end to trade barriers may be in our national interest, but will be out of reach no matter how desirable. A unilateral end to all tariffs, quotas and other such interferences has at least the advantage that it could be attained without the cooperation of the inward looking Americans. (To say that it will be difficult to convince Canadians of the merits of such a move, however, would be the understatement of the century). Moreover, it would undoubtedly bring great benefits to this country. Under a regime of this sort, Canadian consumers would be able to avail themselves of goods at hitherto unimaginably low prices. This alone would be a magnificent spur to our standard of living, and would probably do more for the well being of the poor in this nation than all the welfare programs on the books put together. Further, this boon to consumers would likely spill over to our export sector. For the additional funds spent in the U.S. would eventually return to this country, in the form of domestic purchases. And this could not help but spur additional employment opportunities in Canada. In fact, a unilaterally declared end to trade barriers is such a good idea that it might make sense to adopt this policy right now, and forget all about the negotiation route. This holds true except for one small point: better even than a unilateral declaration would be a mutual agreement between our two countries (or better yet, between Canada and the rest of the world) to fully open our common borders to commerce. We can in effect gain a smaller amount right now, for sure, under unilateralism (if we could but agree amongst ourselves to take this step), or wait it out, and possibly attain a greater amount later on, if the negotiations succeed, through mutual agreement. Given this situation, two questions present themselves for analysis. First is the question of whether a "bird in the hand" is worth more than "two in the bush." Economic theory alone, unfortunately, cannot answer this, because we do not know the size of the immediate (unilateral) payoff, the larger size of the later (negotiated) gain, nor the rate of discount through which one may be meaningfully compared with the other. Secondly, we must ask whether seizing the "bird in the hand" shall increase or decrease the likelihood of our ever capturing the second which is still lurking "in the bush." That is, will a unilateral declaration of free trade enhance or retard the chances of the U.S. agreeing to end their own trade restrictions? According to one theory, if we go it alone, we can shame them into following suit. If we blaze the path toward free enterprise, we can expose their otherwise hypocritical allegiance to the marketplace, and thus force them into a golden era of mutual free trade. According to another theory, they are unembarassable. Commercial relations between countries are a matter of pure brute bargaining power, in this view. If we throw away our chips (their access to our markets), they will just laugh at our hope or expectation that they will throw away their chips (our access to their markets). Unfortunately, again, there is nothing in the realm of economics that can provide a definitive answer to this puzzle. Nevertheless, the "dismal science" may be of some use regardless. For one thing, it clearly exposes and categorizes our ignorance. This helps us to know where and how we must seek additional information. For another, it indicates that there may well come a time when the certain but smaller benefits of unilateralism will start to outweigh the larger but ever receding gains of waiting for a negotiated settlement. This, it must readily be admitted, seems rather counterintuitive. It amounts to saying that were we ever fully convinced that the Americans would not under any conceivable circumstances negotiate a free trade agreement with us, we should then declare our borders open to their commercial incursions. It appears uncomfortably close to advocating that we turn the other cheek, trade-wise. Yet, for all of the superficial implausibility of the idea, it is sound public policy. Canadian industry would benefit from stepped up exports, from the ability to increase specialization, to join in an international division of labour, and from the added economies of scale that this would make possible. The domestic consumer, too, as we have seen, would gain from a unilateral dismemberment of trade barriers. It may seem unlikely, but it is comforting to know that our economic lives are not fully in the hands of the Americans. It would be vastly preferable to be able to negotiate free trade with the colossus to the south. But should things ever come down to such a pass, this country would benefit from a unilateral declaration of economically open borders even if the U.S. failed to follow our inspired lead. UNIONISM by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver B.C. A strange adventure recently befell Patrick McDermott, the 27 year old son of Canadian Labor Congress president Dennis McDermott. Young Patrick was innocently riding a bus in suburban North York when he witnessed a beating in the street. A woman, Dianne McIntyre, aged 42, was being assaulted by a man -whereupon our hero jumped off the bus, came to the rescue of the damsel in distress, and for his pains was wrestled to the ground by four other men, colleagues of the hoodlum battering Mrs. McIntyre, and was kicked and punched while he was down. "No big deal" you say? "Happens every day?" Well, yes, unfortunately; street violence seems to be part and parcel of modern day life, not only in the U.S., but increasingly in this country as well. But this case was exceptional. For the victimized woman was crossing a picket line at the main Visa credit card centre for the Imperial Bank of Commerce, and the five bully boys were bank workers, engaged in a labor strike against this financial institution. What a position to be in for Patrick McDemott, a staunch union supporter in his own right, and son of the outgoing president of the CLC! But Mr. McDermott the younger tried to remain loyal to his principles. That is, to both of them: chivalry and unionism. Although suffering from an arm injury, bruised ribs and a split lip in his confrontation with the minions of organized labour, he stated that he still believes "in the strike and the cause, but when it comes to goons hitting defenceless women, it's got to stop. That guy should be thrown out of the union." This, however, is too facile, by half. Unionism as practiced in Canada is intrinsically a violent, confrontative and physically aggressive institution, and young Mr. McDermott cannot have it both ways. He must either renounce the "cause," or give up on his principle that goons should not be able to beat innocent persons. Why is this? How can it be that a widely respected institution, organized labour, necessarily initiates violence against non-agressing people? The reason is straightforward. Actual union practice, and the labour codes of the land which underly it, are predicated on the assumption that competition, no matter how well it works elsewhere in the economy, is simply inappropriate for the labour market. But not only inappropriate. Deserving of legal penalties as well! Labour enactments in Canada mandate that the employer "bargain fairly" with a union, when what he may want to do most of all is ignore his striking employees entirely, and hire competing workers (i.e., "scabs") in their place. Some provinces (i.e., Quebec) prevent management from hiring temporary replacements for the duration of the labour dispute; others allow this, but insist that the firm not deal more favourably with these labourers than with its unionized work force. If the employer declines to be bound by these restrictions, he is liable to fines or even jail sentences -- which is certainly equivalent to visiting violence against a person, the employer, for doing no more than encouraging competition in the labour market. It is perhaps for this reason that the police and courts turn a blind eye -- or even a sympathetic one -- to situations where union violence is directed against the employer, or, in the case of Mrs. McIntyre, against those who support scab workers by crossing picket lines. "If the government will physically prohibit labour market competition anyway, why penalize organized labour for doing the same thing?" seems to be the prevailing opinion. A moment's reflection will convince us that this practice -union violence or government violence practiced against employers and/or scabs -- is completely unjustified. The non-employed competing workers (scabs) have every bit as much right as the striking unionists to compete for jobs offered by the employer. Any other conclusion would set up two classes of people -- unionists, scabs -- with different types of rights. But all Canadians have the same human rights to compete for employment, without being victimized by physical violence, whether from unionists or policemen. As for the assault and battery perpetrated on Patrick McDermott and Dianne McIntyre, a union spokesman termed the incident "minor," and said there were no plans for disciplinary action against the pickets who injured them. And of course the police did nothing to quell this violence in our streets, even though they, and all Canadians would have been outraged had this situation occurred in any context other than that of a labour strike. - 30 UNIONISM by Walter Block, The Eraser Institute, Vancouver B.C. A strange adventure recently befell Patrick McDermott, the 27 year old son of Canadian Labor Congress president Dennis McDermott. Young Patrick was innocently riding a bus in suburban North York when he witnessed a beating in the street. A woman, Dianne Mclntyre, aged 42, was being assaulted by a man -whereupon our hero jumped off the bus, came to the rescue of the damsel in distress, and for his pains was wrestled to the ground by four other men, colleagues of the hoodlum battering Mrs. Mclntyre, and was kicked and punched while he was down. "No big deal" you say? "Happens every day?" Well, yes, unfortunately; street violence seems to be part and parcel of modern day life, not only in the U.S., but increasingly in this country as well. But this case was exceptional. For the victimized woman was crossing a picket line at the main Visa credit card centre for the Imperial Bank of Commerce, and the five bully boys were bank workers, engaged in a labor strike against this financial institution. What a position to be in for Patrick McDemott, a staunch union supporter in his own right, and son of the outgoing president of the CLC1 But Mr. McDermott the younger tried to remain loyal to his principles. That is, to both of them: chivalry and unionism. Although suffering from an arm injury, bruised ribs and a split lip in his confrontation with the minions of organized labour, he stated that he still believes "in the strike and the cause, but when it comes to goons hitting defenceless women, it's got to stop. That guy should be thrown out of the union." This, however, is too facile, by half. Unionism as practiced in Canada is intrinsically a violent, confrontative and physically aggressive institution, and young Mr. McDermott cannot have it both ways. He must either renounce the "cause," or give up on his principle that goons should not be able to beat innocent persons• Why is this? How can it be that a widely respected institution, organized labour, necessarily initiates violence against non-agressing people? The reason is straightforward. Actual union practice/ and the labour codes of the land which underly it, are predicated on the assumption that competition, no matter how well it works elsewhere in the economy, is simply inappropriate for the labour market. But not only inappropriate. Deserving of legal penalties as well! Labour enactments in Canada mandate that the employer "bargain fairly" with a union, when what he may want to do most of all is ignore his striking employees entirely, and hire competing workers (i.e., "scabs") in their place. Some provinces (i.e., Quebec) prevent management from hiring temporary replacements for the duration of the labour dispute; others allow this, but insist that the firm not deal more favourably with these labourers than with its unionized work force. If the employer declines to be bound by these restrictions, he is liable to fines or even jail sentences -- which is certainly equivalent to visiting violence against a person, the employer, for doing no more than encouraging competition in the labour market. It is perhaps for this reason that the police and courts turn a blind eye -- or even a sympathetic one -- to situations where union violence is directed against the employer, or, in the case of Mrs. Mclntyre, against those who support scab workers by crossing picket lines. "If the government will physically prohibit labour market competition anyway, why penalize organized labour for doing the same thing?" seems to be the prevailing opinion. A moment's reflection will convince us that this practice -union violence or government violence practiced against employers and/or scabs -- is completely unjustified. The non-employed competing workers (scabs) have every bit as much right as the striking unionists to compete for jobs offered by the employer. Any other conclusion would set up two classes of people -- unionists, scabs — with different types of rights. But all Canadians have the same human rights to compete for employment, without being victimized by physical violence, whether from unionists or policemen. As for the assault and battery perpetrated on Patrick McDermott and Dianne Mclntyre, a union spokesman termed the incident "minor," and said there were no plans for disciplinary action against the pickets who injured them. And of course the police did nothing to quell this violence in our streets, even though they, and all Canadians would have been outraged had this situation occurred in any context other than that of a labour strike. 30 - UNIONS - I An Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for C30R Radio There have been labour difficulties between union and non-union firms at the Pennyfarthing construction site in False Creek. And there may be more in the offing regarding Expo 86, where unions are refusing to work alongside contractors employing non-union labour. The construction unions are determined to maintain the $26 per hour union pay scales, as against the $17 paid by Kerkhoff Construction Co., the non-union firm now working in False Creek. The argument used by unionists is that all attempts to undermine their organization with non-union labour should be resisted. Otherwise, according to this view, the working people will soon find themselves back in a nonunionized sweat shop type of economy, where wages would fall to barely supportable levels. How would this work? Well, if non-union firms paying $17 per hour are allowed into Expo 86, and other large scale operations, they will be able to outcompete the union shops. With the alternative of unemployment staring them in the face, the unions would have to take wage cuts down to the $17 level, thus allowing their firms to contend with the non-union builders. But the process wouldn't stop here. With a defanged labour movement, according to this argument, there is simply no reason why Kerkhoff and his colleagues should continue to pay $17. No, with unionism on the retreat, non-union construction firms might now offer as little as $10 per hour. K they did so, they would again be able to underbid union firms for construction jobs. And this would push union scales down once more, in an attempt to compete. Where the process would end, no one knows — somewhere in the dark ages of sweat shop employment, according to this view. What a horrifying scenario! But it is entirely false, and based on mistaken assumptions. Wages dont rise because unions pull them up. Real wages were rising for centuries before unions first came into being in the late 1800s; they continue to rise nowadays in countries with little or no organized labour, and in the non-union sectors of nations with a labour movement. Why, then, do wages in the marketplace rise? It is not because of the benevolence of non-union firms like Kerkhoff that his employees receive $17 per hour. It is because of their productivity. If Kerkhoff didn't pay them what they were worth, say, if he paid them only $10 per hour, some other firm would snap them up at $12, earning a cool $5 profit per man-hour. But Kerkhoff, facing a loss of his workforce, would have to up the ante. That's why he pays $17. Productivity. And competition in the labour market. And this would remain the same in the absence of featherbedding unions, which have priced themselves out of the market at $26 per hour. The sooner the unions come to their senses, the better off they, and all the rest of us, will be. This is Walter Block for Vancouver AM. Time: 3:25 Script #5 April 12/84 UNIONS - m An Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for C30R Radio In the past two days, we were discussing the increasingly bitter animosity of the construction unions toward firms which employ non-union labour. We stated that this animosity — which has taken the form of violence, egg and rock throwing, tire slashing — has no moral justification, and no economic justification either. The unions feared that if non-union firms such as Kerkhoff Construction Co. were able to under bid for contracts, that not only would their own puffed up inflated wage scales of $26 per hour be put at risk, but even the more realistic $17 paid in the non-union sector would be threatened. We showed that Kerkhoff pays $17 because of the productivity of his non featherbedded workers, that the main danger to the unions was the $26 per hour with which they had prices themselves out of the market. We indicated that unrealistically high unionized construction pay scales were a source of unemployment, and that fears of a return to sweat shop conditions were only a red herring. Today we consider another topic on the labour front: the recent Vancouver city council 7-U- vote to hire a union contractor to build a sewage pumping station - instead of a non-union firm which was the lowest bidder. Interland Contractors Ltd., the unionized company, put in a bid for $1^9,963 to build the station, and this was accepted, even though Phased Construction Ltd., a non-union concern, put in a bid for $14^55 - $5,508 less. Now an extra $5,000 or so won't break the city budget. Although $5,000 here and $5,000 there can add up. As well, the next time city council takes a higher unionized bid, it might amount to more than $5,000 or so. But money isn't the only concern. There is also a little matter of principle. There is simply no moral justification for the duly elected government of the City of Vancouver to discriminate in favor of some of its citizens, and against others. It was elected by all voters, some of whom are in unions, others not. There is no difference in principle between such discrimination in favor of unions and discrimination in favour of white people, or men, or the non-handicapped. This decision is an affront to fair play, to equal treatment, and to the human rights of individuals who do not happen to belong to labour unions. It should not happen, never ever again. This is Walter Block for Vancouver AM. Time: 2:54 Script #7 April 12/84 UNIONS - II An Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for C30R Radio This is the second in a series of commentaries concerned with the labour difficulties now plaguing the B.C. construction industry. Last time out, we discussed the Pennyfarthing Development Corporation's Harbour Cove condominium project on False Creek in Vancouver. Over bitter union opposition, the non-union 3.C. Kerkhoff & Sons Ltd is now engaged in building on that site. Incidentally, at a top salary paid of $17 per hour, this non-union shop has been able to save the owners a cool $3.5 million, in contrast to union firms forced to pay wage scales of $26 per hour. We suggested that the construction unions come down to reality, and stop creating their own unemployment by pricing themselves out of the market. Organized labour in B.C. would do well to borrow a leaf from the construction unions in the U.S. In Washington, D.C. for example, the unionized share of the $3 billion per year construction business fell from 75% to 10% of the total in the last few years. As a result, a majority of the unions in the Washington Building and Construction Trades Council have agreed to wage cuts which will allow a 20% reduction in labour costs. In addition to less take home pay, they have agreed to wage freezes, use of lower-paid helpers, streamlined work rules, straight pay on Saturday make-up days to cover rainouts, and even shorter coffee breaks. This pattern, moreover, is based on one set by AFL-CIO affiliates in Little Rock, Milwauke, Knoxville and Cincinati. But British Columbia construction unions are instead digging in their heels, and demanding that the status quo on wages and benefits be maintained. They are opposed to working alongside non-union firms, like Kerkhoff, on the construction of Expo 86. They insist, as a precondition to any such coopeation, that instead of lowering their own pay scales of $26 per hour, the non-union workers be brought up to this unrealistic level from their present $17 per hour. But this would worsen matters, not improve them. Instead of creating more jobs for union workers — it would destroy them in the non-unionized sector. This idea, moreover, has been put forth on moral grounds. But what is so ethical about threatening the imposition of wage scales that would put at risk the entire project? How can it be considered moral for the unions to attempt to dictate non union pay scales — especially ones which would create havoc in the non union sector, as they have already done for organized labour. This is Walter Block for Vancouver AM. Time: 3:10 Script //6 April 12/84 U.S. TRADE PROTECTIONISM & COMMUNIST CHINA by Walter Block Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute The United States, the land of the free and the home of the brave, is supposed to be the bastion of free enterprise. Especially under President Ronald Reagan, who croons about the "magic of the marketplace" in solving economic problems and bringing prosperity to all, the U.S. in theory is a living embodiment of the principles of Adam Smith. The People's Republic of China, in contrast, is presumably anything but a country which supports economic freedom. Its official ideological position is some variant of Marxism or other, and it is thus not expected to be open to the arguments for free markets and free trade. So much for the theory. In the real world things can be far different. A case in point is the recent trade dispute over textiles that has erupted between the Communist Chinese and the capitalist Americans. Peking is threatening to retaliate against Washington over U.S. protectionism interferences with textile trade. According to the official Chinese news agency Xinhua, Chinese Ambassador Zhang Wenjin is unhappy with the new U.S. "country of origin" rules. This measure means that U.S. customs agents will reject clothing manufactured in Hong Kong, based on materials and semi-completed garments originating in mainland China. Mr. Zhang is protesting against this rule, which he says will threaten $2.2 billion worth of textile exports to the U.S. He said that "hundreds of factories and about 60,000 jobs would be harmed in (his country's) southern provinces alone, and that this would be a grievous blow to China's industry, employment, trade and economic development." 2- In point of fact, as opposed to theory, the U.S. is a rather protectionist country. In recent months it has clamped down increased tariffs, or set up quotas on goods and products such as motorcycles, steel, autos, and now Chinese textiles. As well, for a while it was threatening to deal more harshly with Canadian forestry products, but did not carry through. Lip service to the ideals of free markets is not enough. Actions speak louder than words. If the Reagan administration wishes to benefit its own citizens, and those in the rest of the world, it should begin dismantling the tariff walls it has been erecting around itself -- and with all due deliberate speed. For trade barriers needlessly diminish economic welfare. If the peoples of the earth cannot join with one another in friendly trade, they will all miss out on the benefits of specialization and the division of labour. Why not produce those things we are good at, and then trade for the products of other nations which can produce them more efficiently than ourselves? Adam Smith must be spinning in his grave. Imagine, a country devoted to the principles of capitalism and free markets erecting barriers to trade and the Communists protesting. August 23/84 - 30 VINCENT CHIN An Editorial CommentaryPrepared by Walter Blockfor The Financial Post The story is a pretty sick one. Vincent Chin, a Chinese-American living in Detroit, was about to be married. The 27-year-old draftsman was at his bachelor party when he was attacked with baseball bats (how all-American can you get?) by a Chrysler foreman named Ronald Ebens, and his stepson, Michael Nitz. They blamed Japanese automakers for Chrysler's problems, and beat Vincent Chin to death. It didn't matter that their victim was of Chinese, not Japanese ancestry. Presumably all Orientals are alike, to people of this sort. They screamed, "It's because of you we're out of work," and they beat him to death with a baseball bat. Sound horrible? There is worse to come, if you believe in justice. Wayne County Circuit Court Judge Charles Kaufman sentenced these cold-blooded murderers to three years of probation and fine of $3,780 each. At the trial, mockery that it was, he said of these men, who had no prior criminal records, "(They are) not the kind of people you send to prison." Well, if these killers are not the kind of people you send to prison in Detroit, who is it that really deserves incarceration? I shudder to think. Perhaps this is why they call Detroit the murder capital of the United States. Fortunately, however, cooler heads prevailed, ultimately. The federal authorities moved in, and Ebens and Nitz were indicted on charges carrying maximum sentences of life imprisonment. You say this can't happen in Canada? Well, maybe not. But this kind of sentiment against the Japanese, and by extension, all Orientals, is alive and well in Canada as well, unfortunately. When and if a murder of this type takes place here, it will be done with a hockey stick, not a baseball bat, but come it must, if such anti-Oriental prejudice is continually whipped up in Canada. Our much vaunted federal authorities, who are supposed to be humane, fair-minded, and concerned with human rights are now busily negotiating with the Japanese about cutting down their exports of cars to this country. This cannot possibly but exacerbate anti-Japanese feeling in this country. In point of fact, however, the unimpeded import of Japanese cars is of great benefit to Canadians. Tariffs can only harm us. How can we maintain this when as a result, there will be the loss of thousands of jobs in the automobile industry in Canada? First of all, it is by no means a foregone conclusion that absent tariffs, the Japanese will always be able to out-compete us. Where there is the will there may be a way; as long as free competition is allowed, western auto producers may one day be able to assert their previous preeminance. But lets suppose they do not. Let us stipulate, that is, that were tariffs removed, the Japanese auto manufacturers are much more efficient than Canadians. So much so that under these conditions, Japanese cars, selling at a fraction of the price of our own, would sweep all before them. Even under such a scenario, all is not yet lost. The Japanese may open up and run factories of their own here, employing Canadian workers, in order to cut costs even further by economizing on transportation expenses. Alternatively, Canadian firms may prosper and even grow, working as suppliers of spare parts, or accessories, for a greatly expanded Japanese operation. But again, let us suppose that even this does not come to pass. That the Japanese, under a regime of complete free trade, would organize auto production entirely on a domestic basis--not using Canadian manufacturers even as suppliers. Then, and only then, would our own auto industry vanish without a trace, at the cost of tens of thousands of jobs. Even so, such a state of affairs would still be in the best interest of Canadians. Why? Suppose that the Japanese are so efficient that Canadians can now purchase an automobile of given quality of $5,000, one which cost $15,000 when produced domestically under the old regime of tariffs. Well, then, the first indisputable effect will be that Canadians, all those who purchase cars, will have an extra $10,000 worth of loose change jingling around in their pockets. What, pray tell, will they do with all this suddenly new-found wealth? This is hard to answer. Some of it will go for increased domestic consumer purchases, revitalizing those industries, whichever they are, and creating additional employment there. Some of it will be saved, lowering interest rates, making it easier to start new concerns and to expand old ones--creating employment throughout the economy. And if some of this is merely socked away into mattresses, under pillows, and in tin cans buried in the front yard, this will have similar effect--prices will be lowered, making it easier to expand present businesses and to start new ones, and helping other consumers to make purchases. And what about the $5,000 purchase price of the automobile? This, of course, goes to Japan, ultimately, in payment for the car. What will the Japanese do with this money? Why, turn around and spend it on items which we produce more effectively than they, such as wheat or barley, or coal, or lumber, or oil, or natural gas, or maple syrup or any of dozens of other products produced on farm, forest, or mine. This, needless to say, will again create more employment all throughout the economy. And not just any old kind of employment. Rather, jobs that are highly productive. After all, the path to wealth, and the way to fight poverty, is by allocating labour to its most productive uses. And there are few better ways of accomplishing this than by specializing in what we do best, allowing the Japanese to do the same, and then exchanging our best efforts for theirs. But suppose the Japanese refuse to spend this $5,000 here. Will the Canadian economy be somehow cheated of the jobs that could have been created thereby? Not a bit of it. First of all, it is exceedingly unlikely that the Japanese would do any such thing. They didn't achieve their preeminent position in matters commercial by exporting goods, and refusing to accept imports in return. But suppose that they, ostrich-like, just refuse to spend this money, anyway. Far from hurting us, this will be of great benefit to our economy! If the Japanese send us cars, and refuse to use the money we pay them to buy our goods, it is as if they are giving the cars away to us for free. And no economy in the history of the world was ever hurt by gifts of this kind. So far we have been assuming that Japan has an advantage in the production of cars, Canada can out-produce it when it comes to products of forest, farm and mine. It is now time to relax this assumption. Let us assume, then, that not only is Japan a better producer of automobiles, but can out-do us with regard to every other product under the sun as well. It still does not follow that Canada would be better off with protective tariffs. (I hate to sound like a broken record on this, but the truth is the truth.) The point is, Japan may be able to undercut Canada in all product lines, but in some of them she is far more efficient than we, while in others, she may barely be able to beat us out. Suppose, for example, that with given resources, she can produce 10 times as many cars as us, but only twice as much wheat. Well, then, when she sells us the first batch of cars, and we pay her, our Oriental trading partners will purchase wheat, not cars, for even though Japan has an absolute advantage over us in all products, we have a comparative advantage in wheat. This may sound outrageous, but it is the merest of common sense. Consider an attorney who is the best lawyer in town, and also the best typist. Now if attorneys make $200 per hour, and typists earn $10 per hour, does it pay for the lawyer to hire a typist, or to do both jobs himself? Of course he is better off sticking to his comparative advantage, and specializing in the practice of law. In just the same way, even if the Japanese can produce more cars and wheat than Canada, unlikely as this is, they will still find it in their own interest to specialize, and trade with us. Mr. Lumley, let not Vincent Chin's death have been completely in vain. Stop this senseless negotiation of "voluntary" trade barriers with Japan, if only in the name of human rights, if not for the economic reasons we have presented above. January 20, 1984 WHERE'S THE BEEF? An Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block Everyonce in a great while, an ad or slogan or jingle comes along that is a milestone in advertising's Hall of Fame. For example, who can ever forget Avis' "We're 1e2; we try harder". Or American Express' "Don't leave home without it". Or Coca -Cola's "It's the real thing". Or "Nothing spells relief like Rolaids".. Or "Try it, you'll like it". Or "It's Miller Time". Or "This Bud's for you". Or "You have a friend at the Chase Manhattan Bank". But now, along comes an ad campaign, or rather just a single ad, which threatens to shove many of these golden oldies down the memory hole. It's for Wendy's Hamburgers, and it features three old ladies staring balefully at a gigantic hamburger bun, with a tiny meat patty. "Where's the beef?" rasps out one of them, and in the space of a few short weeks, this woman, Clara Peller, has become something of a cult figure. "Where's the beef?" products now include dolls, games, hats, records, cards, t-shirts, a record album, baseball hats, cups, wastebaskets, and, it would appear, anything and everything else produced by man upon which such a slogan can be written. Indeed, a veritable mini industry has sprung up around "Where's the beef?" Clara Peller has already made appearances at all the top entertainment shows, and even has a fan club. Wendy's is still number three behind McDonalds and Burger King, but is closing in fast with a 15% spurt in sales in January 1984 alone. Why am I going on and on about this advertising phenomena? What does "Where's the beef?" have to do with economics? Well, in addition to creating a new industry out of the very thin air, "Where's the beef?" shows the advertising industry for the vibrant, productive, creative, economic endeavor that it is. For too long 2 we have been under the intellectual sway of those who see advertising as basically parasitical, as creating nothing of value. In a static unchanging economy, there is perhaps less need of advertising. With everything the way it was in grandfather's time, who needs a catchy jingle to introduce a new product or new way of doing things? But as economist Joseph Schumpeter has demonstrated, we live in a dynamic, progressive economy, one in a continual flux. Here, advertising serves a vital role. If we are to adopt new techniques, new options, new items, we must sometimes be informed and perhaps cajoled and enticed. And what more pleasant a way than advertising? Advertising is a multi billion dollar industry. It creates goods and services and it creates happiness, it oils the wheels of our splendidly developing economy. Let's hear no more nonsense about how unproductive is advertising. - 30 MEDICAL CARE FINANCE AND THE LICENSING OF PHYSICIANS by Arnold Aberman, MD. and Walter Block, Ph.D. When individuals pay directly for medical care, an increase in the supply of physicians is always to the benefit of the public, since it maintains downward pressure on medical fees. However, although the individual fees will be lower when competition is permitted, the total amount of money spent on medical care may rise. This will happen if the increased number of services performed add more to costs than do the lower fees decrease costs. (In technical economic parlance, this applies if the elasticity of demand for medical services is greater than unity). But that is of no concern whatsoever to the individual as long as the price he pays for a given amount of medical services decreases. Price per unit of medical service may decrease because advertising, for instance, allows more efficient delivery of services. -More generally, economics teaches us that the greater the supply of good or service, the lower will be its price, other things equal. But this does not necessarily mean that doctors will earn less, since each one may perform more services. But the individual consumer of health care will save money at the lower price. He will also gain if the amount of services performed increases. This must be a benefit since consumers would not be forced to change their buying patterns. So, as usual, the market, if allowed to operate, benefits both consumers and producers. Of course, it is true that the physicians who cannot satisfy consumer preferences will lose out. This fear of failure may have led physicians organizations to try to limit entry into the health care field. They have done so in two ways: by trying to limit the scope of alternative practioners, such as acupuncturists, chiropracters, etc., and by attemping to reduce the numbers of medical students, and immigrant doctors to this country. (Canadian Medicine: A Study in Restricted Entry, a new book published by the Fraser Institute, and written by Professor Ronaid Hamowy of the University of Alberta, documents this sorry aspect of Canadian history). However, nowadays the government pays doctors, and this situation brings about several complexities. For one thing, when government pays the entire bill it has little interest in price per service. It is mainly concerned with the total cost of medical care. If the patient paid directly for medical care, one way to diminish total cost might be to increase the price per service and thus reduce the number of services performed. But since the government pays for the entire price of medical care and provides it to patients for "free", it cannot decrease the number of medical services by raising price. A second way to cut total cost would be to radically reduce the fees paid to doctors. Since patients are already receiving care for "free", this would not lead to increased utilization. But the government could not slash fees without greatly angering the doctors and possibly leading to serious repercussions. So the only way to decrease number of services and thus total costs is by restricting the number of licensed physicians. Thus regulations are enacted that retard free movement of physicians between provinces, immigration of doctors to Canada is discouraged, and licenses are granted to newly graduated doctors only with added difficulties. And, of course, since not increasing the number of physicians is in the economic interest of licensed physicians, the government have a natural ally in currently practicing doctors. This is where the Hamowy book comes in. Professor Hamowy has shown persuasively that the actions of the various medical regulatory bodies, made on the basis (pretext!) of protecting the public interest, has had the opposite effect. Whether purposely or otherwise, medical licensing has protected the financial interests of licensed physicians by restricting supply, limiting competition, and reducing the spread of market information by outlawing advertising. It is interesting to read the arguments of spokesmen for physicians made in the 19th and early 20th century amassed by Hamowy. They are very similar to the arguments used today -not only by physicians, but taxi drivers, trucking companies, lawyers as well. Such positions by various professional associations are common. After all, why should doctors not act to protect their financial interest (as they see it)? The real problem is that governments have the power to bow to the selfish demands of the doctors (and other such groups). Today government regulatory bodies, for example agricultural marketing boards, openly and without any evasion, act to restrict production and set prices. If a group of doctors wanted to decrease their fee schedule and advertised that fact, (in order to increase total income), the government (acting through the College of Physicians and Surgeons) would not allow them to do so. Of course, in a market situation, the physicians could lower fees, patients would pay less, more services would be consumed (a reflection of consumer preference), and the doctors would make more money, to the benefit of all concerned. The notion that the total amount of money spent on medical care must not be allowed to increase is nonsense. For example, let's consider computers. Everyone knows that the price of computers has decreased markedly over the past five years. But the amount of money spent on computers has gone up. Now suppose that government had to pay for the entire cost of computers. If so, it would want the price of computers to stay high if this would decrease the total cost of computers. But it is even more complicated than that. To make the analogy complete, we must assume that the government gives computers away for "free". In that case the only way the government can reduce the total cost of computers is to limit the number of computer manufacturers (like decreasing the number of doctors). Aren't we lucky that governments do not pay for computers? If they did, we would be reading in the newspapers how the cost of computers has gone up in the past few years, that this is a danger to the public weal, and that something must be done (a government restraint program?). In the interests of patients, our medical care financing ought to be re-oriented in the direction of individual responsibility. People ought to pay directly for health services (with the exception, perhaps, of catastrophic medical insurance) and not indirectly through taxes, "for free", which only encourages overoptimal utilization. As well, as shown by Canadian Medicine A Study in Restricted Entry, our laws ought to be revised so as to lower the barriers to entry into the medical profession. Air Canada Wants to Stay Young According to the Federal Court of Appeal, a finding by the. Canadian Human Rights Commission against Air Canada was justified. The airline refused to hire pilots over the age of 27, and this practice was rejected under the Canadian Human Rights Act as discriminatory. Air Canada had nothing against the ages of the five complainants -ranging from 32 to 41 in 1983, the time of the tribunal hearing. Many of its active pilots are in their thirties and early forties. It objected only to initial hiring at this age, since it operates a policy of mandatory retirement for pilots as they reach their 60th birthday. The court, however, ordered the crown-owned airline to base its safety policies on the flying capabilities of its pilots as individuals, rather than as a member of a class, or age category. Such a policy, of course, is designed to make distinctions between pilots. It would not, therefore, be unfair to a particularly robust and capable pilot in his 60s -- or even older. While very few type I errors might be made (firing elderly employees who are still capable), there is now the added risk of comm itting some type II errors (failing to ferret out elderly incompetents who somehow manage to pass the test). The strategy imposed by the court on the airline thus increases the risks of flight hazards. Ramon Sanz, one of the five rejected would-be Air Canada pilots whose application for employment was given a sharp boost by the Federal Court of Appeal, ~\ reacted thusly: "We won; that's good news." This decision was welcomed by Sanz, but there may be, in the coming years, air passengers and their families who will rue this judicial decision. Nor is it merely a matter of human rights having to take a back seat to air traffic safety when there is a conflict. (Although it would be eminently common sensical to make an exception in cases of this sort). There is also the point that the testing of pilots on an individual basis adds to the costs of the enterprise. And these costs must be passed on somewhere. Were Air Canada a private profit- making venture, extra costs could only be visited upon the paying customer. But given Air Canada's crown corporation status, the long suffering taxpayer will be called upon to shoulder the extra costs. Some, of course, may be able to do so, but there are likely to be many others for whom this will be a heavy burden. Black Students by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C Do you think that societal discrimination against black students is responsible for their poor showing at school? If you do, think again. According to a study p-eleased by Professor Signithia Fordham, a major cause of the gap between white and black students is a fear on the part of the latter that they will be taunted for success in school. In fact, achievement in class, and accomplishment on standardized tests is widely derided in this community as "acting white." Strong peer pressure is directed against those who study hard and succeed. In many ghetto high school graduations, the honors ceremonies have to be held separately; only those special students, and their parents, are invited. This is because when these rituals were held before the entire school, anti scholarship riots broke out. The anthropologist from the University of the District of Columbia intensively interviewed 33 students from an unnamed high school in Washington D.C. with an enrollment which is 99% black. According to one pupil, who fears being called a "brainiac," smart students who know an answer in class will sit back and refuse to answer. Another, a football player who early on earned a series of As and Bs, began purposefully failing tests when his friends called him "Mr. Advanced Placement." With an environment that is not only unscholarly, but so strongly antischolarly,it is clear that black education is in for hard times. Throwing more and more money at the problem -- the liberal's entire stock in trade -- will only promote a poisonous atmosphere in more plush surroundings. What is needed is a moral and spiritual reawakening, and a sense of responsibility. It was not always this way in the black community. For most of this century, until only a decade or so ago, academic pursuits were highly admired, as they are by most people. Parents would slave away, often at very menial tasks. taking on extra jobs, in order to put their children through school, to earn advance degrees. There was for many years the common expectation that the top ten percent in terms of abilty and accomplishments would lead the black underclass into the middle class. Why is it, then, that this intellectual ennui has overtaken young black students? Part of the reason is undoubtedly the fact that the path of higher eduction is no longer so alluring. Yes, doctors, lawyers, engineers and businessmen still earn very comfortable salaries. But these pursuits in most cases take years of intensive study, and to many ghetto youth there appears to be a far more easier and softer way-involvement in the drug trade. Here, the payoffs are far more substantial, and what may be even more important, immediate. Why be a sissy or a momma's boy and go to school for many years, when one can enter the crack, smack cocaine or heroin trade, and in a matter of months attain the life's earnings open to the more traditional professions? Anyone who does so is a fool, and deserves no respect, it is widely thought, in this subculture. One indirect solution to the problem of black anti-intellectualism would thus be the legalization of drugs. Such a step would, at one swell foop, eliminate the astronomical profits to be earned in these endeavors. And in doing so, it would invest scholarly, business and professional activities with the esteem they once unquestionably held. Fortunately, there are several black leaders able to provide inspirational examples to such tragically deprived youth; for instance, scholars such as Stanford's Thomas Sowell, and George Mason's Walter Williams. They have labored long and hard through their scholarly work to show that blacks are as able as anyone else to make their mark in the intellectual world. They have been in the forefront of the movement to show that many well intended government programs, such as welfare, minimum wages, affirmative action -- and drug prohibitions -- have boomeranged, and harmed the very groups they were supposed to help. Unfortunately, since these scholars are all champions of free markets, and opponents of an enlarged welfare state, they are all but ignored in the nation's media. It is a tragedy that journalists are open only to blacks who favour increased welfarism and dependency, the very programs which have brought us to our present precarious state. - 30August 10, 1988 G I Real Canadian Superstore by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute There has been much wailing and gnashing of teeth in British Columbia labour circles in recent weeks. Real Canadian Superstore (RCS) has contracted with a new local of the United Food and Commercial Workers for a wage and benefit package that many pundits and editorialists are calling a "sweetheart" deal. Traditional labour leaders are apoplectic. Hopping with rage are B.C. Federation of Labour president Ken Georgetti, Confederation of Canadian Unions president Jess Succamore and IWA-Canada president Jack Munro. They feel betrayed because the new bargain significantly undercuts union scales previously negotiated with RCS competitors Overwaitea, Save-an-Foods and Safeway. And these companies, instead of cheering on the interloper local #777, or, even more in keeping with their traditional and expected role, calling for an outright end to unionism in their stores, have joined in an unholy alliance with Georgetti, Succamore and Munro in condemning the newcomers. What is going on here? Is this just some sort of springtime eccentricity perpetrated by Lotus Land on the rest of the country, or is there something of real economic significance now taking place in British Columbia? In order to understand this phenomenon, we must delve into some of the more arcane mysteries of the dismal science. One of the most fundamental and basic axioms in all of economics is that wages tend to equal the productivity levels of the workers. If 'compensation is lower than the contribution made by the employee, he will likely quit, and seek greener pastures elsewhere. Alternatively, if the wage and benefit package surpasses on the job productivity, the employer will tend to lose customers, market share and profits to competitors who can lower pay scales toward actual productivity levels in the industry . .. But the entry of new competitors is the key. If excessive earnings are to be pared down to conform to productivity, new firms must be able to enter the market, bid less for employees, and pass along the savings to the consumers. How else can they attract customers from existing businesses? This is what the B.C. grocery dispute is all about. RCS, for example, pays cashiers a starting salary of $7.50 per hour. Other major stores, in comparison, offer $11.02 on an hourly basis. When health coverage, holiday, and other fringe benefits are factored into the picture, the RCS package comes to about $10.00. This is estimated to be 30% to 50% less than the full compensation offered by Overwaitea, Save-On-Foods and Safeway. RCS, in other words, is betting that the wage package paid by the established firms is generous to a fault; that by succumbing to union pressure, these grocers have actually shortchanged their less well organized customers. In a fully free market, RCS would not have to work through a labour organization which has the legal power to disrupt its commercial activities. In the real world, it felt it had to. This is why, presumably, it dealt with a union, but insisted upon a four year no strike clause. As well, RCS offers a buyout payment in the form of a Registered Retirement Savings plan worth up to $2,500, which encourages workers to quit before reaching top salary scales, and thus attaining seniority status. This, too, can be interpreted as an attempt to head off the labour disruptions all too often concomitant with unionism. Critics, however, have complained that the contract between RCS and Local 777 amounts to an unfair "tilt." But why should we assume that the playing field is already level? According to our analysis, it is the present system of labour contracts that is inequitable; because of past union pressure, established supermarket employees are overpaid, compared to other wages and to the contribution they make to the consumer. On the contrary the new contract is a movement toward equity and economic rationality. Another complaint is that of "predatory pricing." It is alleged that as soon as RCS drives it competitors out of business, it will raise its prices to astronomical levels. A more likely scenario, however, is that the new competition will force down all supermarket prices. Certainly experience with RCS in other cities gives no support for this critical contention. Last, how can we account for the opposition of the entrenched large scale grocers to the new development. This is only a paradox for those who believe that businessmen always and ever favour free markets, or who do not distinguish between what is best for a particular firm, and what is good for the economy as a whole. Businesses often attempt to fix prices, but competing firms can always be counted upon to bring these schemes to nought -- unless of course new entry is limited by government. - 302 CARDINAL CARTER &: THE TORONTO BUS STRIKE I by Walter Block Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute Gerald Emmett Cardinal Carter, head of the Toronto Diocese, has a problem. Pope John Paul is scheduled to visit suburban Downsview on his visit to Canada, and over 300,000 people are expected to trek out from Toronto to attend the mass he will give there. However, and this is a big however, the unionized employees of Toronto's public transit system are poised, ready to go out on strike for better pay. Cardinal Carter, archbishop of Toronto, fears an internationally embarrassing situation should this strike occur during the papal visit. He has offered to mediate the labour dispute, and spoke out as follows: "It would be an embarrassment seen in full living colour throughout the world, an embarrassment not only to the church, not only to the municipality and the province, but also to Canada at large. To say that I am concerned about this possibility is an understatement. In fact, I am most distressed. " And well might he be distressed with the prospect of a transit strike during the papal visit. Should it occur, it would bring great misery and confusion to the people of Toronto. But is this not also the case in every city-wide transit strike? True, the papal visit will add complications in this one instance, but every such occurence interferes with the lives of the poor, the elderly, commuters, and millions of ordinary citizens. We should not, then, limit our concern to a Toronto transit strike during the papal visit, but generalize to all such cases. And tomorrow we shall do just that. August 23/84 - 30 CARDINh2 CARTER &: THE TORONTO BUS STRIKE II by Walter Block Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute Yesterday, we were considering the plight of Torontonians desiring to travel to meet the Pope on his upcoming visit. Due to a threatened transit strike this task might become very difficult indeed. But we said that every city wide transit strike brings great inconvenience in its wake, and are now ready to analyze the general case. Strikes in the urban transportation industry create havoc for two reasons. First, in the modern era, practically all transit systems are run by government, and on a monopoly basis. That is, there is only onerapid transit system, and if it goes on the fritz, there is no real viable alternative for the masses of commuters. The answer to that is easy. Transit systems -- buses, trolleys, subways, rail lines -- should all be privatized, as most were, when first built, and private business concerns should be allowed to compete with one another for the commuter dollar. Then, in the case of a labour dispute, alternative means will be available to Secondly, our labour codes must be radically amended. For a strike actually implies two things: a) that the unionized workers will am leave the job site enmasse,and b) that they will forceably prevent others from taking these jobs. Now the first is completely justified. Compulsory labour is simply incompatible with a free society. But the second is entirely unjust. By what right do organized workers forceably prevent others from accepting pay scales and working conditions spurned by the union? If Cardinal Carter were interested in preventing transit disturbances over the long haul, and not in just this one instance, he would champion competition in the labour market, as a replacement for our present Collective bargaining arrangements. August 23/84 - 30 I CIDA and "Foreign Aid" by: Walter Block The Canadian International Development Agency has spent hundreds of millions of dollars on massive water delivery systems in the Third World. Huge dams and gigantic irrigation systems, intended to help farmers in the undeveloped countries have boomeranged, and caused great damage instead. For example, a group called Save the Soil Campaign recently protested against damage to their land created by the massive Tawa Dam, located in Madhya Pradesh in India. Part of the reason for the debacles is that the typical western engineer is more interested in replicating the Grand Coulee Dam in Africa or Asia, even though smaller more modest systems, tailored to the local scale, have actually done some good. But this bias is only the tip of the iceberg. Of more importance in that there is little accountability in government to government transfers of funds. (We reject the more common appellation "Foreign Aid" because it is pejorative; this term assumes that the money will succeed in helping the unfortunates in the underdeveloped world -- the very point in question). If it succeeds, those responsible are not automatically given more funds with which to operate; if it fails, as it most often does, those in charge are not penalized, and made to reduce the scope of their operation, as they would be in the private sector. Now that CIDA has spent hundreds of millions of dollars creating these white elephant projects, it intends to spend hundreds of millions of dollars more to restore land that has been damaged by flooding and salt deposits, which resulted from the first binge of dogooding. According to Gaston Grenier, chief of CIDA's agricultural sector, this second round will cost far less than the previous one. The problem with this statement, however, is that it is exceedingly difficult to determine the expenditure level of this organization, since Parliament does not demand financial statements. "No one has accounted for the spending on an (itemi.zed) basis since CIDA has existed," said Mr. Grenier. But even correctly engineered water projects, properly tailored to the physical environment in the LDCs is no guarantee of success, for oft-times economic variables are perverse. Irrigation schemes, even after installation, are a great financial drain on the recipient countries, since user fees pay only a small proportion of the costs. For example, in Bangladesh, this accounts for only 1% of the costs; in Thailand, 3%, in Nepal 4%, and in Indonesia 7%. As well, farmers are charged not for their actual water usage, but according to the size of their land holdings. As a result, favored agriculturalists have no incentive to economize on the scarce water, and sometimes drown their fields with two or three times as much as is necessary, leaving others with practically nothing. In addition, due to communal ownership of the pumping and storage machinery, there is little incentive to maintain it, and much to overuse it. As a result, there is great wastage of the precious water. This comes about because of the "tragedy of the commons," which shows that when property is owned by all, in common, individuals have an incentive to abuse it. This analysis was first applied by Garrett Hardin to a small town which had a field (the "commons") which would provide forage for just 1 00 cows, one each owned by 1 00 different farmers. If farmer A placed one extra cow on the field, all the cows would suffer, albeit very slightly, but he himself would benefit immensely, since he could virtually double his wealth. However, this same idea occurs to all 100 farmers. But when the field has 200 cows, they all die. In contrast, if the farmers owned the land individually, each would keep one cow on his own small plot, and all would prosper. This litany only begins to detail the trauma imposed on the underdeveloped world by well intended but unwise CIDA policy. According to a study undertaken by the World Resources Institute in Washington D.C., this agency has been responsible for the spread of disease, the displacement of whole communities, and the (J flooding and salinization of land. When improperly managed, reservoirs, canals and drainage ditches can be turned into large pools of stagnant water the home of disease spreading mosquitos. When improperly managed, dams can destroy the fish stock and river hydrology. This leads to land erosion, waterlogging and siltation. Instead of flourishing, the crops, with their oxygen cut off, tend to rot. Nor are these concerns of theoretical interest only. In India, over 20 million acres of land have been waterlogged, and over 50 million salinated. In Pakistan 25 million acres have been threatened by waterlogging, and over 10 million by excessive build up of mineral salts in the soil. Let it not be thought that the answer to all these problems is better bureaucrats, and more finely tuned programming. Government to government transfers of funds are intrinsically.injurious to the economic development of third world countries. First of all, it must not be thought that when people enter the civil service, they automatically become uniquely determined to do good for others. On the contrary, they are still the same imperfect human beings they have always been, filled with a desire to help others, for sure, but also with an interest in doing well for themselves. Any public policy that calls for saints as administrators is sure to fail. Secondly, we must realize that while "foreign aid" takes up a relatively small part of the GNP of western democracies, in most cases less than 1%, these funds represent a gigantic proportion of the earnings of the third world. It is only human nature for these people to attempt to compete for these monies. They do so by forsaking the world of commerce (the means by which the "first world" clawed its own way out of "third world" status) and embracing the public sector, the immediate source of all the largesse. The best and the brightest of the young people of these countries, then, instead of producing, trading and creating wealth in the private sector, go to government, cap in hand, and attempt to cash in on "foreign aid." In this way the entire society can become needlessly politicized. We must realize, further, that these monies do notgo to the starving children we see in those heart-wrenching pleas for money. They typically go to the third world despot, and, especially when there are different tribes in a country, this leads to warfare and bloodshed, surely the greatest enemies of economic development. Thirdly, a great portion of the funding goes toward the "Three MIs": Monuments, Mercedes, and Machine Guns. This enables the leaders of these countries -- who are largely responsible for their economic plight in the first place -- to further strengthen their strangle-hold over the people. Sometimes the monuments are merely to themselves: statues for personal aggrandizement. This is relatively harmless; the material is concrete, and after it is done, the expenses are over. Of far greater damage are the economic monuments -- the steel mills, oil refineries, automobile plants -- which cost far more to build, and then lose money every year of their existence. And not only do these funds enhance the power of the third world dictators, they also enable them to pursue the unwise domestic policies which have been so ruinous for their countries. Chief amongst these are the massive and forced collectivized farms (e.g., Tanzania) and the marketing boards and pricing policies which make agriculture an unprofitable business (e.g., Ethiopia). If government to government transfers of money are not the solution to third world economic disarray, what then is the answer? The policy that simply cries out to the heavens is one of free trade. If we could integrate the economies of the third world with our own, we would do more for their material well being than thousands of foreign aid programs. Yet the hypocracy of the Canadian government is such that while we pose as the friend of these peoples, we cut their exports off at the knees, and refuse them free access to our markets. For shame! Of course, there is a political reason for this stance. The greatest number of votes are to be found in Ontario and Quebec, the provinces with most of the inefficient industries which would tend to disappear under a regime of free trade with the nations of the third world. - And yet, most of the people in central Canada do not gain from "protectionism." On the contrary, most lose. Consider the words of Ludwig von Mises on this issue: "Granted that only those Canadians engaged in tanning hides are immediately interested in the preservation of the tariff on leather. But every Canadian belongs to one of the many branches of production. If each domestic product is protected by the tariff, the transition to free trade hurts the interests of each industry and thereby those of all specialised groups of capital and labor the sum of which is the whole nation. It follows that repealing the tariff would in the short run be prejudicial to all citizens. And it is shortrun interests only that count. This argument involves a threefold error. First, it is not true that all branches of industry would be hurt by the transition to free trade. On the contrary. Those branches in which the comparative costs of production are lowest will expand under free trade. Their short-run interests would be favored by the abolition of the tariff. The tariff on those products they themselves turn out is of no advantage for them, as they could not only survive, but expand under free trade. The tariff on those products for which the comparative cost of production is higher in Canada than abroad hurts them by directing capital and labor, which otherwise would have fertilized them, into those other branches. Second, the short-run principle is entirely fallacious. In the short run every change in the market data hurts those who did not anticipate it in time. A consistent champion of the short-run principle must advocate perfect ridigity and immutability of all data and oppose any change, including any therapeutical and technological improvement.' If in acting people were always to prefer the avoidance of an evil in the nearer future to the avoidance of an evil in the remoter future, they would come down to the animal level. It is the very essence of human action as distinct from animal behaviour that it consciously renounces some temporarily nearer satisfaction in order to reap some greater but temporarily remoter satisfaction. Finally, if the problem of the abolition of Canada's comprehensive tariff system is under discussion, one must not forget the fact that the short-run interests of those engaged in tanning are hurt only by the abolition of one of the items of the tariff while they are favored by the abolition of the other items concerning the products of the industries in which comparative cost is high. It is true that wage rates of the~~~nnery workers will drop for some time as against those in other branches and that some time will elapse until the appropriate long-run proportion between wage rates in the various branches of Canadian production will Be established. But concomitantly with the merely temporary drop in their earnings, these workers will experience a drop in the prices of many articles they are buying. And this tendency toward an improvement in their conditions is not a phenomenon only of the period of transition. It is the consummation of the lasting blessings of free trade which, in shifting every branch of industry to the location in which comparative cost is lowest, increases the productivity of labor and the total quantity of goods produced. It is the lasting long-run boon which free trade secures to every member of the market society. The opposition to the abolition of tariff protection would be reasonable from the personal point of view of those engaged in the leather industry if the tariff on leather were the only tariff. Then one could explain their attitude as dictated by status interests, the interests of a caste which would be temporarily hurt by the abolition of a privilege although its mere preservation no longer confers any benefit on them. But in this hypothetical case the opposition of the tanners would be hopeless. The majority of the nation would overrule it. What strengthens the ranks of the protectionists is the fact that the tariff on leather is no exception, that many branches of industry are in a similar position and are fighting the abolition of tariff items concerning their own branch. This is, of course, not an alliance based on each group's special group interests. If everybody is protected to the same extent, everybody not only loses as consumer as much as he gains as producer. Everybody, moreover, is harmed by the general drop in the productivity of labor which the shifting of industries from more favorable to less favorable locations brings about. Conversely the abolition of all tariff items would benefit everybody in the long run, while the short-run harm which the abolition of some special tariff item brings .t;o the special interests of the group concerned is already in the short run at least partly compensated by the consequences of the abolition of the tariff on the products the members of this group are buying and consuming." Human Action,pp. 750-752. (Mises speaks of the mythical country "Ruritania." "Canada" has been inserted instead by the present author). \ Comedy and Canadian Culture by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The "Golden Age" of Canadian comedians is upon us. It is truly a worldwide event. Laugh masters from the frozen northland have taken by storm the stages of the U.S. in particular, and many other countries as well. One can no longer tune in a television program devoted to comedy, nor attend this type of movie theatre presentation, nor for that matter peruse the front covers of national and international weekly newsmagazines, without being confronted with the hordes of Canadians who have taken part in this bit of cultural imperialism. This is not the first time that Canadian born and bred performers have tickled the world's funny bones. Top comedic actors in the past certainly include Mack Sennett and his Keystone Kops, and the "Shakespeareans" Johnny Wayne and Frank Shuster of Ed Sullivan Show fame. But this past trickle has now turned into a veritable flood. Merely to list the people who have recently vied for the title of "King of Comedy," and the organizations with which they have been associated, is to see the sheer enormity of the present day occurrence. Let us, in any case, endeavour to do just that. Any list of Canadian comedians would have to include at least the following: Howie Mandel (St. Elsewhere),Robert Boyd, Ivan Reitman, Dan Aykroyd, Mark Breslin, Rich Little, Jim Carrey, Andre-Philippe Gagnon, Lome Michaels, Hart Pomerantz, Rosie Shuster, Bob Dolman, Michael Short, Jenny Jones, Leslie Nielsen, Joe Medjuck, Daniel Goldberg, and David Steinberg. But there are even more. One of the most famous comedic television shows produced in Canada has been the Emmy award winning SCTV.(The Los Angeles Timescalled it the "best comedy show on TV - maybe the best one in TV history.")The characters of that show have taken on a life of their own, and thus might reasonably be included in any roll call of honour of Canadian comedy: "Edith Prickley" (Andrea Martin), "Earl Camembert" (Eugene Levy), "Floyd Robertson" and "Count Floyd" (Joe Flaherty), "Lola Heatherton" (Catharine O'Hara), "Johnny LaRue" (John Candy), and "Ed Grimley" (Martin Short). Perhaps most famous of all are The Great White North'sMcKenzie ("Hoser") Brothers, played by Dave Thomas and Rick Moranis. But that is only the tip of the iceberg. Other shows, programs, movies, organizations which have prominently included Canadians are: Splash, Ghostbusters, Legal Eagles, Spies Like Us, Saturday Night Live, Second City(Toronto), Yuk, Yuk's, Armed and Dangerous, Heartburn, Three Amigos, The Hart and Lome Terrific Hour, Airplane, The Canadian Conspiracy, The National Lampoon Show, Animal House, Stripes, Meatballs, Brewster's Millions, Summer Rental, The Blues Brothers, Strange Brew, After Hours,and A Fine Mess. But why are we talking about this subject at all? What does it have to do with economics, or public policy analysis? (I pass over the obvious retort that economics, and economists, are one big joke.) The connection between the success of Canadian funnymen abroad and public policy has to do with economic nationalism. Suppose the present situation were reversed. Suppose, that is, that instead of Canadian actors making inroads in the U.S., there was a raft of Americans taking this country by storm. Can you imagine the howls of dismay and outrage that would emanate from the Canadian nationalist "culture vulture" set? There is little doubt that after the obligatory spate of editorials, conferences, perhaps even picketing, an attempt would be made to enact legislation making it more difficult for foreigners to impose their "alien" culture on us. C But none of this, fortunately, is now occurring in the U.S., even while undergoing its present orgy of protectionism. This indicates two things. First, the Americans are more confident in the value of their culture than are we. So much so, that they are willing to import the best that other countries have to offer, with no embarrassing demands for "U.S. content." Secondly, their culture is a true mosaic, strengthened not only by domestic input, but by foreign as well. If we want to improve the quality of Canadian culture, we could do worse than to drop the entire nationalist agenda, and emulate the openness of American cultural institutions. - 302 The New Computer Age: threat to mankind or golden opportunity? by Walter Block It's called many things "Artificial Intelligence", "the micro-dot electronic revolution", "The Age of Robotics". Whatever the name, it can perform numerous and amazing tasks. Modern computers, coupled with silicon chip-based integrated circuits, can now diagnose lung diseases, locate mineral deposits, play chess at almost a grandmaster level,cut logs, assemble autos, and do other industrial tasks far more efficiently than human beings •.. This new breed of robot serves as the basis of the ubiquitous scanning devices n.ow. found at supermarket check-out counters, and of amechanized "arrn't .. which .aids paraplegics. Modern R2D2s can sheer sheep – in tandem with a robot-colleague which immobilizes the animals -- and human-voiced commands. The new computers can communicate with others of their ilk, repair their mechanical relatives, and even help create new units from scratch. These electronic servants, moreover, work full-time: 21+ hours a day, 7 days a week, 52 weeks a year, with no time off for coffee breaks, holidays or gossip. They never call in sick, talk back to the boss (unless programmed to do so), nor file a grievance. Wondrous and marvellous as are these accomplishments, there is, according to some, quite a large worm in the apple. Consider the following: • A robot has replaced six steelworkers at an International Harvester plant in the north east • According to the feminists, 15 million mostly female clerical, sales and service workers -- in banking, insurance, and general business offices --will lose their jobs to automatic word processors and related office automatons. The National Action Committee on the Status of Women also warned that the micro-electronic revolution would impact women more heavily than men • General Motors plans to spend $1 billion, worldwide, to install 14,000 new robots; the Japanese will invest $450 million, over the next decade, for such fifth generation, artificially intelligent machines. IBM and Bell Telephone Laboratories, Inc., have announced similar ambitious plans • The introduction of artificial intelligence is by no means limited to the western hemisphere. According to the European-based Federation of Commercial, Clerical and Technical Employees, office employment in that continent could fall by an estimated 25 per cent by 1990 • There have been widespread claims that the new automatons have increased the degree of "anomie" suffered by the human beings who work alongside them. Complaints include faUing morale, and depersonalization and alienation from the workplace. Based on these and other "horror" stories, a reaction to the new generation of computers has set in. Opponents are determined to allow the introduction of artificial Intelligence -- but only grudgingly, gradually, and accompanied by a series of "safeguards". A Task Force Report on Micro- electronics, for example, called for full re-training of workers who fall "victim" to the "chip" revolution. New national training programs are being proposed. Among other things, this would encourage women to take "educational leaves of absence, partially on the basis of being supplanted by new computer technology". As well, a recent union report called for "preventative collective action" and increased unionization, in order to ameliorate the economic havoc the new machines are feared likely to cause. Other unions want strengthened collective agreements "to ensure protection against rapid technological change". The United Steel Workers Union is aiming for cash payments equal to 10 per cent of the companies' investment in the new technology, the right to reopen collective agreements whenever such changes are made, mandatory retraining, and a two year job guarantee - - or a cash payment in lieu --for all computer-related firings. A critique of the "unilateral approach" (the failure of management to consult organized labour before introducing the new technologies) has been widely circulated which cites "distrust" and "damaged labour relations" as the unfortunate results of the new machines. And if these "reasonable" and "moderate" requests are not met, there are more extreme measures waiting in the wings, ready to erupt. In addition to growth restrictions, there is a threatened technological moratorium in the offing. Worse, a new generation of Luddites (these are the people in the 18th Century who burned recently introduced kni tting looms out of fear for their jobs) stands ready to fight the artifically intelligent computers – with sabotage. magazine bombings" . Given this spectre, a more measured response would appear to be indicated. It will thus be helpful to put this automation-createsunemployment argument into some perspective, by considering the economics of employment in some detail. First of all, employment is a means, not an end. In the best of all In this vein, a usually sedate and always responsible business warns of "anarchy, complete with hit-and-run rioting and possible worlds, mankind would be able to attain the kinds of goods and services most Americans now enjoy -- by merely pushing a button-- not as the result of working full out. If things worked this way, if robots did most of the work now being done by people, and other robots built and serviced these "worker" robots, then human beings could be freed up to try to turn their wildest dreams into realities. We could all become artists, musicians, poets, scientists, or whatever; not in order to safeguard our present standards of living, but to use this as a basis from which to build up to as yet unimagined heights. How else can we conquer cancer, explore the solar system, expand all our horizons? What is really desirable is thus not work, but productivity. In order to see this, we can ask the following: which would make society better off, a quantum leap in the amount of work we were required to do, coupled with a compensating decrease in productivity (so that we were no better off in terms of real wealth)? Or a great increase in productivity, together with an appropriate decline in the amount of work needed to accomplish this (again with an unchanged wealth position)? The answer is obvious. The first option would consign us to the economy of several hundreds of years ago, when the entire human race had to work like dogs just to stay alive; when men were forced to work 120 hours a week or more; when women worked like slaves their entire existence; when even small children were assigned to back-breaking tasks in factory, farm or mine. Truly was such a life "nasty, brutish and short". The second option, however, was the path our economy actually took, thank goodness. Instead of being forced to work by a paltry and niggardly Mother Nature, men nowadays usually work a 40.hour week or less, and there is even talk of a 4-day week; women, in many cases, no longer need add full time jobs to their already full time jobs at home; and children need not work at all. Instead, they are free to go to school. (Compulsory school attendence laws have tried to take credit for this shift, but does anyone really doubt that such legislation would have been completely ineffective a scant 150 years ago, when productivity levels could not support such a luxury?) Now, the unemployed person might be forgiven for not seeing the point that work is only a means, not an end. (As far as he is concerned, a job will not only put food on his family's table, but will also earn back some modicum of psychological well-being.) The crucial question, however, is to which tasks shall he be assigned when re-employed? To those which can be accomplished by mere machines, or to those which tax his uniquely human abilities? What of the fear that the new jobs will not arise? As long as there are unmet needs, and people willing to work to attain these ends, there will be new positions created. From the vantage point of our agricultural economy of 200 years ago, it would have been impossible to predict precisely what kind of jobs would come into existence today. In like manner, we cannot now predict which occupations will arise to take the place of those shown to be unnecessary by the new computer revolution. However, we know that they will be created, and we know why. If a robot, at both minimal outlay and subsequent maintenance cost, is real1y able to replace 1000 workers (to take the "worst" possible case) then some truly monumental results wil1 ensure, and each of them will create new employment opportunities. In the first instance, immense profits will be earned by such companies. Their shareholders (and/or private owners) will either spend or save their new-found wealth. In the former case, this will encourage the industries which receive the new stream of expenditures; in the latter case, interest rates will be driven down, creating new loan opportunities and new employment, throughout the entire economy. But such profit levels cannot long endure. In a reasonably free market system, new entrants will swarm in, to take advantage of the high profits. By purchasing additional robotic factors of production, and hence raising their prices, and by se11ing more such products at lower prices, profit levels will be soon dissipated. The former will encourage more employment in robot production, and the latter will enable consumers to purchase yet even more with a given dol1ar, thus again raising their standards of living. This will lead to stiH more employment in those areas where the new purchasing power is spent. It was through a procedure such as this that large employment shifts have taken place in the past. There is no doubt that it will work again. It was once feared that automatic spinning mills would permanently unemploy the entire hand weaving industry. Instead, the results were cheaper clothing and more jobs in cloth making. First generation computers were supposed to create a permanent "army of the unemployed" amongst office workers. Instead, companies like IBM have created literally millions of jobs throughout the economy, with lower prices and higher standards of living to boot. No less will be true of the new artificial intelligence revolution. The worm in the apple will not be a cold faceless computer-robot, taking the bread away from the workers table. Instead it will be modern Luddites, who once again threaten progress. Let's Have a Little Perspective, Here or Conflicts of Interest by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute In the last few weeks, the newspapers have been filled with stories about conflicts of interest suffered by politicians. Several British Columbian Social Credit MLAs have figured prominently in this coverage. Forests Minister Tom Waterland was forced to resign amidst conflict-of-interest charges resulting from his $20,000 investment in Western Pulp Partnership, Ltd. This is a company which owns cutting rights in the South Moresby, including the politically disputed Lyell Island, over which Mr. Waterland had been rendering judgement. Then, Energy Minister Stephen Rogers came under fire for his stake of $100,000 in WPP. Mr. Rogers does not deal directly with this forestry firm, but he is the minister responsible for B.C.Hydro, which offered discount rates on electric power to sawmills such as Western. As a result of all this brou-ha-ha, Premier Bennett inaugurated a new conflict-of-interest policy. All ministers in the Socred cabinet, plus dozens of senior mandarins, will now be forced to either put their assets in a blind trust, or to make a "full and complete disclosure" of their investments. And if the C; momentum from these political shenanigans continues apace, the day is not far off when allM.L.A.s, whether in power or not, and senior bureaucrats with executive responsibility, will have make similar disclosures. There are, however, numerous drawbacks in such a scenario. Openly acknowledging one's investment portfolio is no guarantee that the elected official or civil servant will not be able to use his public position for private gain. It may make things more difficult, but a person who is so minded may still be able to mix his public and private life in this manner. Nor is a blind trust a necessary impediment to such activity. The public figure may rely on the fact that portfolios need not be changed, even when in blind trust and may act so as to increase the value of his holdings on the day they were given over to the administrator. Such a policy may not maximize his private wealth, but, especially if the portfolio has not been radically altered, it may well enhance the value of his property. In any case, the fact that this is a possibility may divert those in public office from discharging their duties as they would had they no potential conflict of interest to contend with. But this is only the tip of the ice berg. There is also the siren song of nepotism to deflect our public servants from their steely determination to "act in the public interest." Progressive Conservative MP Sinclair Stevens recently had to resign from his Ministerial responsibilities under a cloud, not because of any charges made against him personally, but because of loans on very favorable terms made to his wife. This problem is easier to point to than it is to solve. First of all, if the activities of the wife of a government official must be scrutinized lest they cast doubt on the propriety of his own position, what about his children or his parents? What about his uncles, aunts, cousins, in-laws, grandchildren, etc. The difficulty is that there is no nonarbitrary way to draw the line. No matter where it is drawn, there will always be some (perhaps distant) relative whose business relations may cast aspersions on the legitimacy of the politician in question. Secondly, what about the rights of the relatives of politicians or leading civil servants? Must they be prohibited by law from engaging in commercial transactions? If they are, this is a clear breach of their own rights. If not, there is always the possibility that someone may treat them advantageously, in the hopes of currying favour with the principal (this seems to be the charge in the Stevens case.) Nor have we even yet completely catalogued the difficulties of conf licts of interest for public functionaries. So far, we have concentrated solely on monetary gains. But this does not go far enough, by half. For all attempts to come to grips with potential conflict-of-interest problems have so far been limited to dilemmas about money. But money, as we all know, is only one of the many things sought by human beings. In fact, this insight is so well entrenched in the social sciences that economists have even developed jargon to express it. We commonly distinguish between money income, on the one hand, and psychic income on the other, where the latter term denotes all non-pecuniary benefits, such as the gratification of sex, power, notoriety, fame, or the satisfaction of seeing one's fervently held ideology implemented. This concentration on money income in attempted resolutions of conflicts-of-interest actually discriminates against those who wish to benefit themselves financially. But what about those who wish to benefit in these other ways? We can hardly attempt to make people place their psychic sources of income in a blind trust, or force them to make "full disclosure" in this regard. These difficulties are basic, not superficial. They transcend political affiliation, jurisdiction, even national boundaries, and apply to alloffice holders and government officials. (They do not apply, however, to private enterprise. For if a corporate officer, for example, engages in a bit of nest feathering, it is in the interests of the firm to ferret out this behaviour. Business concerns may best be understood as competing not only with regard to providing their primary product, but also as regards their ability to stop employees from acting against their interests.) Conflicts of interest plague the public sector at present, and are likely to do so for the foreseeable future, or for at least as long as human nature remains the way it now is. What, then, may be done about this ubiquitous problem? The answer is simple. If there is no airtight way to avoid conflicts of interest amongst public servants, let us at least resolve to reduce their numbers as much as possible. Thus the best way to eliminate virtually all conflicts of interests amongst civil servants and public officials is to decrease the number of these positions to an irreducible minimum. There are many other good and sufficient reasons for cutting back on the public sector, but extirpating conflicts of interest is certainly one of them. - 30 Consumers Association of Canada by Walter Block, Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The newspaper headline leapt off the page at me in bold black type: Consumer group backs higher price for wheat. What is this, I say to myself. Surely, the editorialist has got the headline wrong. Shouldn't it be, instead, Consumer group backs lowerprice for wheat? Intrigued, I delve into the business page story. Much to my amazement, I find that the headline writer has indeed got it right! According to Consumers Association President Sally Hall, the Canadian consumer should be willing to pay a few cents more for a loaf of bread to help out the western grain farmers who are now facing the lowest wheat prices in seven years. If that don't beat alII What will they think of next? Government bureaucrats demanding a tax cut? Taxpayers urging a tax increase? Union leaders calling for a decrease in pay? Oil sheiks advocating that O.P.E.C. be ended? Students asking for lower grades? Bishops counselling atheism? Marxists justifying a move toward the laissez faire capitalist system? Now, none of these other miraculous events have (yet) come to pass, but the C.A.C. is indeed supporting higher wheat prices, provided that the additional money reaches farmers, and does not get stuck in the pockets of middlemen. Nor is this a case of outright traitors to the consumer cause -- or farm interests-having taken over the organization. Instead, there actually appears to be method in what might otherwise be considered the madness in this view of the consumers association. States Ms. Hall, "Canadian consumers have to be willing to subsidize and Agriculture is the No. 1 industry farmers. in Canada." Reading in between the lines, and generously interpreting the sentiment which may be behind these remarks, one can arrive at a position that makes a sort of wierd sense. This is the view that if the consumer lets down the farmer in his hour of need, by refusing to subsidize him, this will result in increased agricultural bankruptcy. If so, then with fewer producers, wheat prices will eventually rise. From this perspective, it may not be in the consumer's short run interest to promote high farm prices, but such a policy may, paradoxically, yield good results in the long run. Although this view now has the ring almost of plausibility, there are grave errors in it. First of all, the argument could be used not only by consumers of wheat, but by purchasers of all sorts of goods. If generally adopted, no longer would any buyer look for a bargain. He or she would "reason" that successful bargaining would only result in producer bankruptcies, fewer suppliers, and eventual higher prices. Instead, the purchaser would seek out the most expensive supplier, acting, presumably, to keep prices down. But how can prices be kept down by bidding them up? We must realize that this argument applies not only now, when farm prices are down, but at all times. It is alwaystrue, even when agricultural prices are high, that if consumers bid them still higher, more farmers will survive and prosper; and this, according to the argument, is all to the long run benefit of the consumer. According to this "logic," the consumer must always subsidize the farmer, out of self interest. There is a second criticism as well. While the demand side of the market does indeed benefit from an increase in the number of suppliers (and lose from a decrease), this only holds if all other things are equal. If the buyer must spend his own money to assure this outcome, then other things are patently notequal. For the whole point of encouraging more supply is to thereby obtain lower prices. But if lower prices are renounced as a sort of short run greed which always can be said to backfire, the consumer never gains. Thirdly, this argument fails to appreciate the fact that in the marketplace, profits tend to equalize in all lines of endeavor, given that due consideration is given to risk. That is to say, a situation cannot long endure where profits in industry A are 50%, profits in Bare 10%, and profits in Care -5%. Under such circumstances, everyone and his uncle will want to enter industry A, and people will desert C as rats from a sinking ship. But this reallocation of resources will reduce the revenues derivable in A, and increase the desirability of C. We may never arrive through this process at a situation where exactly the same returns are earned in each industry, but there will always be this tendency at work which keeps to a minimum the differences in profits between one industry and another. It is similar to the process which keeps the queues roughly equal at a bank, supermarket or Post Office. If any line gets too long, those at the back of it leave, and join shorter ones. Also, whenever a very short line emerges (perhaps one teller or clerk is more efficient, or has been able to serve several customers quickly), newcomers gravitate to that queue. The wait at all wickets may never be exactly equal, but neither can the time spent on one line be too far different than that spent on another. The point of this long winded exegesis of the economics of profit is this. Suppose that the advice given by the Consumers Association of Canada somehow succeeds. This would mean that housewive's present willingness to spend a few cents more on a loaf of bread results in an increase in the number of farmers who can survive, which in turn leads to lower wheat prices. Even if this unlikely series of events somehow came to pass. it would still not reduce the price of bread, as hoped and expected by the C.A.C., because when that glorious day finally emerges, and the price of wheat finally falls, this will only lead to an exodus of farmers from agriculture, in response to the falling rate of profit. If you are still with me, gentle reader, this means that the C.A.C. plan cannot succeed because of the tendency of profits to equalize in all industries. The present argument is similar to a fallacy which makes the rounds every few years in the realm of international finance. In that view, a country can benefit by giving foreign aid to other nations, if the latter must use this money to make purchases in the donor nation. To be sure, such tied aid often does benefit some segments of the donor's economy (indeed, this is why such arguments often find popular support), but it can hardly improve the wellbeing of the entire country. For giving people money, and then forcing them to use it to purchase goods you produce, is exactly equivalent to granting them the items outright; and no one ever became rich by giving away his stock in trade for free. In like manner, the consumers of Canada cannot enrich themselves by subsidizing the nation's farmers. If they follow the advice of the Consumers Association of Canada, they will only succeed in impoverishing themselves, as common sense would indicate. A far better policy would be to take advantage of the present (perhaps temporarily) low prices, and then when prices go up, grin and bear it. Or will some farmer's association dare to argue that when agricultural prices go up, the nation's food growers should subsidize the consumers with artificially lower prices, in order to promote their numbers, so that eventually farm goods will sell more dearly. Don't hold your breath. The canadian farmer, if not the consumer, is far too smart to fall for sophistries of this sort. May 7, 1986 Disband the Critical Industries Commission BY Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver B.C. Art Phillips is B.C.'s first commissioner of critical industries. His mission? To bring management, labour, banks and government together, and negotiate with them in order to rescue firms in the mining and forestry industry that would otherwise go belly-up. The bottom line of course, are the jobs that are thereby saved. Mr. Phillips is credited with reviewing the Bell Copper Mine in Granisle (250 jobs); Brenda Mines in Peachland (400 jobs); Lamford Forest Products in Sooke (200 jobs); Victoria Plywood (ZOO jobs); Stege Logging in New Hazelton (65 jobs); and Clearwater Timber Industries in Valemont (400 jobs). One of the most attractive aspects of this Social Credit program is its low cost. In this era of large scale bailouts and horrendous government deficits, the Commission has spent only one half of its $600,000 budget. Since it has kept over 1,500 people off the unemployment insurance rolls, this works out to something less than $200 per job saved. (True, tax concessions have played a role in the rescue packages negotiated by Phillips. But you can't get blood out of a stone: bankrupt companies are obviously bad tax payers, so the government did not have to forego much in the way of revenue due to these activities). These accomplishments have earned the commissioner kudos from virtually all reaches of the political economic spectrum. This is surely an anomaly of major proportions in the highly polarized rain forest. The Socreds, of course, are ecstatic. Mr. Phillips, after all, is their own appointee, and they can quite properly bask in the reflected glow of his success. But the distaff side is no less complementary. In the view of New Democrat Alex Macdonald, this policy was the Premier's best idea in all of 1985. According to a Globe and Mailreport, the International Woodworkers' Terry Smith has "nothing but a really high regard for Art Phillips". And the journalists have been combing their thesauroses in order to come up with new and better superlatives with which to describe this program. However, before we run away with ourselves from enthusiasm, we do well to reflect on a basic aphorism in social science. When just about everybody in politics and journalism has agreed upon an economic issue, it is usually a safe bet that they are all wrong. Unfortunately, the Critical Industries Commission is no exceptiun to this general rule. What, then, is the case against Commissioner Phillips? At first blush, criticizing him would appear perilously close to attacking Santa Claus. Is not Vancouver's ex-Mayor responsible for handing out a lot of low-cost goodies to over 1,500 otherwise unemployed British Co1umbians? But a moment's reflection will show the flaws in this program. Bankruptcies, in our modern mixed economy, are the result of one of two factors. First, of course, is unwise government intervention. Under this rubric we must include labour codes which allow, nay, encourage, unions to price their members at uneconomic rates; punitive taxes which penalize marginal firms and discourage risk taking; impositions of paper work, which discriminate against small business; crown corporations which compete unfairly against private enterprises, since their revenues are guaranteed through taxation; and a panoply business regulations, which sap the incentive, initiative and competitiveness of an entire economy. What can a Critical Industries Commission accomplish against these inroads of government intervention? Nothing. First of all, its mandate is now limited to forestry and mining. Due to budgetlimitations, it can only deal with less than half of the firms which apply to it; in its 10 month existence, the corporate lives it has touched upon number in only the dozens. This is truly only the tip of the iceberg. Yet the problem of business-depleting government intervention is monumental, and province-wide. If Mr. Phillips wanted to save tens of thousands of jobs, not merely hundreds, he would take his entire budget and with it bite the hand that feeds him; that is, he would turn upon his employer, the provincial government, and lobby Victoria to decrease its voluminous interference with the. market system. It is arbitrary, and discriminatory, to save only some few of the thousands of jobs lost due to unwise government economic intervention. So on this score the Commission is a failure. But there is a second source of bankruptcy. Even in the absence of unwise public policy, this would still exist. I refer, of course, to changes in consumer taste, new resource discoveries, or depletions, and new technology and innovations here and abroad which make some firms obsolescent. All of these have effects that reverberate through the economy in complex and often unknown ways. Business failures which result from such basic economic factors are, paradoxically, a healthyphenomenon. If the horse and buggy industry cannot be decently buried, if the family farm is not allowed to go the way of all flesh, if the textile industry in Canada does not make way for foreign imports, then we as a country are doomed to slide into economic decay. To be sure, jobs in these twilight industries can be "saved", but only at the cost of mis-allocating labour away from the automobiles, services, computers and spaceage technology that would otherwise undergird economic expansion. Yes, "jobs are lost" in the sometimes bewildering unveiling of a free market. But if they are artificially saved, by a well-meaning but blundering Critical Industries Commission, this only imparts a measure of arteriosclerosis to our economy. Lost jobs are like dead cells in. our body. If we prevent them from dying, no place remains for new life. Superficially, and in the short run, policy of saving the "dead cells" of the economy makes sense. But give the Art Phillips of world their way, and the ultimate result will be decay and economic strangulation • .. CROWN CORPORATIONS Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for The Financial Post Crown corporations play a great role in the Canadian economy, so it is important that their raison d'etrebe analyzed. Some economists, even those otherwise receptive to the case for the competitive system, have accepted the argument that government enterprise ought to be allowed to compete in the marketplace. In this view, there are no "natural limits" to direct government involvement in the economy whatever. It is only a historical accident that government has never entered the business of running mom and pop grocery stores, newspaper and shoeshine stands, boutiques, babysitting agencies, restaurants, massage parlours, flower shops, etc. Should government one day decide to take on these tasks in addition to its already multitudinous functions, there is no economic principle at all which could be adduced in opposition. To be sure, these economists insist that the competition be "fair". That is, the public enterprise - whether at local, provincial or federal level, government department or bureau -- should not enjoy any special privileges denied to private enterprise. No grants of monopoly privilege can be conferred, as presently enjoyed by the Canadian Post Office. (It is now illegal in Canada for private citizens to offer to deliver mail for a fee in competition with Canada Post.) No automatic underwriting. of extra budget expenditures can be undertaken, based on general government revenues. No exceptions from tax obligations can be given. All firms, Private as well as public, must pay taxes; and the tax rates should be invarient regarding the two sectors of the economy. This principle would be consistently applied even up .to, and including, bankruptcy. According to the view we are considering, if the costs of a government run Crown Corporation were not offset by earned revenues, it would be allowed to be dissolved under bankruptcy procedures, just as in the case of the failure of a private firm. Naturally, this regime could not feasibly be applied to "natural money losers," such as welfare, and to programs which are thinly disguised income transfer schemes such as health care, unemployment insurance, etc. But advocates of this philosophy are anxious to apply it to most ''traditional'' government run business enterprises which produce real goods or services, such as Crown Corporatlons.: There is no doubt that such a scheme would be a vast improvement over present institutional arrangements -- at least as far as already existing corpora- tions are concerned. No longer would they have an automatic free ride. No longer would their very existence be guaranteed, regardless of whether they pulled their weight or not. This plan, moreover, would allow for a certain flexibility and hence efficiency: if a public corporation were allowed to go bankrupt, private concerns could purchase the resources, capital goods and equipment, and manage them competitively. The drawbacks in the scheme do not concern present public enterprise. Instead, they arise in regard to the possible spread of government to fields still reserved for the private sector. One difficulty is that if government were allowed to enter anyindustry, public enterprise would be unleashed upon so many different, small and petty tasks. Even the communist regimes allow scope for some private initiative. Nor is it even possible to reply that government business would eventually fail in these new endeavours, thus paving the way for the re-entry of private firms. For with enough initial capitalization, they could be immune for long periods of time from the vicissitudes of the marketplace. Which brings us to the crucial point: initial capitalization. In the free enterprise system, the start-up investment for new firms must alsobe strictly voluntary. It may be based on individual contributions, stock flotations or bond purchases, since each of these methods involves funds invested through free choice. If putting "government enterprise on a business footing" meant raising the initial capitalization in such a voluntary way (plus an adherence to all other "fair competition provisos we have discussed), then government could truly take its rightful place alongside all other private enterprises. But in what way would they be a public institution at all? It would be indistinguishable in all respects form a private firm, and could not properly be identified with the public sector. And if public enterprise contrived to raise its initial funding not from voluntary payments but out of tax revenues, it would still retain a crucially important unfair advantage over private concerns, thus denying the "government as competitor" thesis. - 30 January 20, 1984 n Cruelty to animals by Walter Block Ecologist Dr. David Suzuki relates his own hunting experiences, as a young boy. He offers such a dramatic diatribe against the killing of animals that it is worth quoting at length: "One year I saw an ad in a comic book for a metal slingshot. I ordered it, and when it arrived I practiced for weeks shooting marbles at a target. I got pretty good, and decided to go after something alive. "Off I went to the woods and soon spotted a squirrel. I gave chase and began peppering marbles at it until finally it jumped into a tree, ran to the top and found itself trapped. I blasted away, and grazed it a couple of times, so it was only a matter of time before I would knock it down. "Suddenly the squirrel began to cry - a piercing shriek of terror and anguish. That animal's wail shook me to the core, and I was overwhelmed with horror and shame at what I was doing - solely to prove my prowess with a slingshot, I was going to killanother being. I threw away the slingshot and my guns and never hunted again." It is for reasons and emotions such as this that animal rights groups have held such strong sway in Canada. Groups such as Lynx, the Society for the Prevention of Cruelty to Animals and the League Against Cruel Sports may have limited power, but they have been able to seize the moral high ground in opposition to the killing of fur bearing animals. It is time, then, to subject their case to careful analysis. It is easy enough to oppose the brutal, sadistic and vicious killing of creatures such as that which sometimes occurs in leg-hold trapping, or in Suzuki's amateurish attempts to kill a squirrel. But the protestors take a much more radical and comprehensive approach. In their view, anykilling of fur bearing mammals is wrong; even those which are farmed, and killed humanely. This accounts for their antagonistic response to the wearing of allanimal skins. One objection to this stance is the charge of hypocrisy. That is to say, the argument can only be consistently maintained by vegetarians. It would ill behoove a meat eater to cavil at other methods of utilizing the cadaver of the once living creature. But mere vegetarianism is hardly sufficient. To be consistent, the animal rights advocate would also have to adopt the principles said to be employed by Mahatma Ghandi. He would have to refrain from killing any member of the animal kingdom, including such things as flies, rats, mosquitos, germs, etc. After all, if every life is precious, whether human or not, it does not do to make invidious comparisons between species. The logical implication of this, however, is that it would have been immoral for people to kill rats during the bubonic plague. It is likewise improper to eliminate the Anopheles mosquito in order to prevent yellow fever. What, then, of the rights of animals? Do they have any? If they are to be able to claim any rights of the sort to which human beings enjoy, they must do one of two things in order to establish some sort of cross species linkage. One possibility is that they must be able to petition for their rights, in some manner or other. There are those who claim that chimpanzees and porpoises, among others, will be able in the future to do so, or to be taught to do so. On that day, humans will be honour bound to consider their declarations. Alternatively, if animals are to have rights, they must at least. show that they respect the equal rights of their fellow creatures. That is, if the lion claims the right not to be hunted by us, then when the lion and the lamb lay down together, they must bothget up, unharmed. Why should we do more for the lion (or the bear, or others beloved by the animal "rights" organizations) than it is willing to do for the lamb? Why should we treat the porpoise any better than he treats the fish? These protestors may be vociferous, they may be numerous, they may be cantankerous, but we must deny to them the moral high ground they so desperately, and unjustifiably, claim. - 30- October 31,1988 2 Drugs and the Olympics by Walter Block, Fraser Institute Canada's Ben Johnson was stripped of his gold medal for the 100 metre dash in the 1988 Seoul Olympics. According to his coach Charlie Francis, this instance of drug taking is only the tip of the iceberg. Numerous other Canadian athletes have been implicated in the use of anabolic steroids, and world class athletes from several other countries have been implicated. The main reaction on the part of the leading sports authorities is a call for a "war" on muscle building medications. There are several shortcomings with this approach, however. For one thing, there is a matter of arbitrariness. Why is it that anabolic steroids are banned while other performance enhancing drugs, such as cortisone and Xylocaine, are allowed? Even aspirin, for that matter, is a performance-enhancing drug. For another, who gives the Olympic and sports authorities the right to ban anabolic steroids? They are widely used in Canada for patients suffering from rheumatoid arthritis and other debilitating diseases, and are available upon prescription. Ben Johnson's doctor, after all, prescribed them for him, at least according to present testimony. The case of Eleanor Holm, a U.S. swimmer entered in the 1936 Olympics is a case in point. Avery Brundage, President of the LO.C. at that time, banned her from competition because she had imbibed a glass of champagne at a ship's party on the trip across the Atlantic to Berlin. There are many who would question his right to have done so. A further difficulty is that the war against these particularperformance enhancing drugs seems almost as futile as the war against addictive drugs such as cocaine and heroin. Keeping pace with the development of newer and better body building pharmaceuticals, and often outstripping it, is the technology necessary to disguise their use. Whatever the shortcomings, there is a clear need to establish some sort of rules that everyone must follow. "A level playing field" is a much abused notion when applied to free trade, but when it comes to sports, it is vital. If there is no commonality to which sports participants must be held, the whole point of athletic competition vanishes. We might as well assign some people to the starting line, and others either 10 ya~behind, or in front. 1 The big question is, What must be equalized? In high schools and colleges, the amount of training is subjected to egalitarian considerations: team practices are limited to a specified number of weeks. This is not done in professional endeavors. In swimming there is virtually no difference in the type of equipment used. In sailboating and car racing, there are gigantic disparities. Here, the competition is as much between men as between gear. Bicycle racing could equalize the apparatus, by random assignments, but has chosen not to do so. The point is, some sort of equalization must be imposed, but its dimensions are not given to us from on high. The present scandal stems from the fact that commonality cannot now be achieved. We can impose stricter and more frequent controls, but we can only hope that the testing mechanisms will be able to overcome those which mask drug usage. A more radical solution to the present drug scandal is the suggestion that the rules be relaxed completely: allow everyone to take the muscle building drug of his choice. The problem with this is that we will no longer know of what the human body -- unaided by drugs -is capable; we will only see the result of the combination of such artificial stimulants plus training. (Yes, these materials may be harmful. But • we're talking about adults here, and they have the right to weigh the pros and cons and decide such issues for themselves.) A compromise is to urge the creation of twocompletely different sections of the Olympic games (and all other related professional sports activities). One would be an "open" division, where medications of all kinds and varieties would be allowed. The other would be a "closed" division, open only to the drug free. Every subsequent world record would have an asterisk, or not, depending upon drug usage. This is no panacea; no compromise known to man ever is. We would still face the difficulty of drug users posing as drug free athletes. But this compromise would go a long way toward resolving a most perplexing difficulty, since with two divisions, there would be less incentive to cheat. - 302 Equal Pay Legislation by: Walter Block, 'the Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The advocates of equal pay for work of equal value castigate the market for its inherent unfairness. Instead of the "anarchy" of free enterprise, they propose that all wages be set on the basis of skill, effort, responsibility and working conditions. These would be determined by boards of "experts," and tribunals of bureaucrats and civil servants, who substitute their "objective" assessments for the chaotic judgement of a system of competitive labour markets. There are many and serious objections which can be levelled against this scheme. Perhaps most important, the entire proposal is predicated upon a malefemale wage "gap" resulting from employer discrimination. Unfortunately for their case, no such phenomenon actually exists. To be sure, if the wages of all full-time, full-year employees are compared, the ratio is roughly .65. But the ensuing pay gap of 35% is more of a myth than a reality. It hides the fact that this "gap" is virtually entirely the product of differential marital status . . " Why should this make a difference? Simple. Marriage has asymmetrical effects on male and female incomes, raising those of the former, and lowering those of the latter. Fraser Institute researchers have segregated the Canadian sample on this basis, and have unearthed some startling results. Based on data generated (although not published) by Statistics Canada we have found that women who have never been married earned fully 99.2% of the incomes of their male counterparts. And a Fraser Institute book, "Focus on Employment Equity: A Critique of the Abella Royal Commission Report,"reports that the wage ratio for the nevermarrieds with a university degree was an astounding 109.8%. Indicating that females in this category actually earned 9.8% more than equivalent males. The reason for this is not hard to discern. Married males do far less of the housecleaning, shopping, diapering, child care and other household tasks than do their spouses, and this holds true even when both are employed full time. There are even cases on record of married women refusing salary boosts and job promotions on the ground that this would put at risk their primary relationship. Contrary to the self-styled feminists, there is nothing intrinsic to a job that makes it worthy of compensation. Crucial in any determination of wage rates is the \. demand on the part of consumers for the service supplied. Right now, for example, the skill, effort, responsibility and working conditions of dentists are such that they receive high compensation. But were a cure for tooth decay to be uncovered tomorrow, their wages would plummet without any diminution whatsoever in these objective measurements on the part of the practitioners of this profession. Further, any proposal which artificially raises the salaries of a given calling beyond its productivity level threatens it with unemployment. Equal pay enactments are always couched in terms of raising female incomes, never reducing those of males. As such, they threaten to price women out of the market, in a manner similar to what has already happened to young people, who have been rendered less employable by minimum wage laws. There is also the embarrassment that when boards or tribunals in the different jurisdictions have attempted to "objectively" set the value of a job, the results have varied widely. When entrepreneurs poorly estimate the worth of a job, they are automatically penalized. If they set wages too high, they risk bankruptcy; too low and they are likely to suffer severe quit rates. Unfortunately, no such automatic reward and penalty device can operate in the public sector. Equal pay legislation is a form of wage - price control. As such, wages are frozen in place, despite changing market conditions. For example, if there is a sudden need for more nurses, and fewer fire fighters, an inflexible wage system will be unable to encourage the former, and discourage the latter. Over a decade ago Canada rashly experimented with wage - price controls. It was a disaster, in the view of all people of good will. That we are seriously flirting with this unsavory idea so soon after underscores the point that those who are ignorant of history are doomed to repeat the mistakes of the past. - 302 THE FARMERS PLIGHT: BANKRUPTCY AND TEARS by Dr. Walter Block Senior Economist Fraser Institute According to the old euphemism "early to bed, early to rise, maketh a man healthy, wealthy and wise." This might hold true, in some times in some places, but certainly not for the small modern family farmer. Although he gets up at the crack of dawn, labours all the day long, sinks exhausted into his bed, and may be healthy and wise as a result -- he certainly is not becoming wealthy. On the contrary, his reward, in many cases, is only insolvency, bankruptcy, and tears. An incident occurred recently on the Eastern seaboard, a bank foreclosed on the farm and prize-winning pure-bred Charolais cattle of a 48 year old farmer. In response, and in an attempt to publicize his quest to save his farm, he dumped three dead cows in front of the Toronto offices of the foreclosing bank. He did this on the ground that the bank's refusal to carry his debt was really responsible for the death of his livestock, since without further financial support he did not have enough money with which to feed his herd. A local newspaper headlined its front page coverage of this event: "Bank seizes cattle, land of tearful farmer." (One wonders what the Society for the Prevention of Cruelty to Animals had to say about thisl) In the event, the farm was seized because of a default on a loan of $935,000 plus $123,976 in accrued interest charges. More generally, farmers are having difficult times, mainly because of high interest rates, but also because of tightening margins between feed, fertilizer and other farm costs on the one hand, and farm output prices on the other hand. What public policy ought to be followed to deal with the crisis in the small family-owned farm? Not unnaturally, the response of some people might be that "the government should do something about the plight of the farmer." Suggestions range from farm subsidies to price supports, from impeding banks from foreclosing on farms to setting up marketing boards to help the farmer. But each of these policies has serious flaws. Farm subsidies cannot be created out of the thin air. They must come from somewhere, at a cost to at least some people. If the government merely prints up additional money and presents it to impoverished farmers, the inflationary fires are stoked up. If it does the same with borrowed money, other bond sellers are crowded out of the loan market, and high interest rates -- the issue that started us off on this quest in the first place, and a problem for many other businesses as well -- are increased even the more. And if government diverts tax money to farmers, it must either increase taxes, which the public opposes, or reduce other programs. Price supports for farm produce likewise have serious defects. They have a habit of raising food prices, a particularly vicious result, in that the poor spend a far higher per centage of their household budgets on food than do the rich. Then, too, by interfering with the free play of the price mechanism, supports also reduce the accuracy of the information conveyed by the price system, and make it harder for the numerous economic actors in the marketplace to coordinate their activities with one another. Legislation which violates the right of lenders to foreclose on the property of loan defaulters will also have unforeseen and disturbing consequences. Banks are a popular target of demagogues because they usually have lots of money. But if financial institutions cannot collect the collateral put up for debts that turn bad, they will be less willing to make loans in the first place. This will reduce the incomes of savers, many of whom are people with little means. It will also increase the costs of future loans -- the interest rates charged -- and this will harm all future and potential borrowers. Nor is there any justification, at least from the consumer's point of view, for setting up agricultural marketing boards. As the best available evidence shows, marketing boards set up and/or strengthen incipient tendencies of farmers to cartelize; they raise prices to consumers for agricultural products; and they artifically and needlessly reduce the quantity of foodstuffs supplied to the market. Of course, it is unlikely that the small farmer will long endure, at least in his present state, without government aid. And this, without a doubt, will be a tragedy "- - for thousands of people, who will be forced to enter other, now more productive fields. It is important to realize, however, that such a policy will be of great benefitto the remainder of the citizens. The present spate of bankruptcies are part of the long term reduction of the proportion of the workforce on the farm. In early colonial times, the proportion of the population on the farm was well over 90 per cent. This fell regularly and precipitiously over the 18th and 19th centuries, reaching a level of 44 per cent in 1880, 35 per cent in 1910, 25 per cent in 1930, 15 per cent in 1950, and five per cent in 1970. This pattern was welcome, as it arose from great increases in farm productivity, coupled with a far less than proportionate increase in the number of mouths to feed. To compare 1880 and 1970, for example, this trend freed up fully 39 per cent of the labour force for other, and now more important work. Imagine if, somehow, just these people had to go back to the farm in order that we may still be able to feed ourselves. This would be a disaster, as we would have to do without the truly huge number of goods and services now provided by these people. So the long term trend from farm to city is to be applauded, not denigrated and artifically halted. Moreover, there is not a shred of evidence to support the much-vaunted claim that psychological, moral and spiritual benefits spill over from the small family- owned farm to the remainder of society. Supposedly, the farm is the creator of honesty, independence, thriftiness, trustworthiness, and a whole host of other boy scout-type characteristics. Now, there is no doubt at all that many people raised on farms exhibit these qualities. But this is hardly a rural monopoly. City folk, too, number amongst their offspring children with high moral qualities. So if there are any geographical moral spill overs, and this has never been scientifically shown, they are likely to be in bothdirections, not just one. We must conclude that the case for government initiatives to help the farmer is extremely weak. Based on the evidence, they are likely to add to the general rate of inflation, or to raise food prices, or to ruin loan markets or to increase farm cartelization. And if these efforts are successfulin stemming the tide from farm to city, they will reduce the rate of increase in our standard of living. - 30- \ FEDERAL BUSINESS DEVELOPMENT BANK I by Walter Block The Federal Business Development Bank, like many other financial institutions, has been hard hit by the recent recession. In fact, it has lost money for the last five years. But unlike other money losing firms, this bank has somehow managed to avoid bankruptcy. And not only that; its management is optimistic for the future, and is now exhibiting an upbeat image. For example, B.e. &: Yukon regional manager Doug Kerley is excited about FBDB's new directions. The bank will playa new match-making role, bringing together entrepreneurs and investors for a seventy-five dollar registration fee. But how did FBDB rack up so much red ink? Says Kerley, "We, like a whole lot of people, got caught up in the growth syndrome before the recession hit and, as lenders, we took our eye off the ball and made unwise credit decisions." FBDB lost f fL(. 3lii'i 3 -iy Sixty-foUl poInt ttlt'e9million dollars in fiscal n-ineteen eighty-tRree, eigt::lty fQyr, (TJ $J..'fq·8 bringing its deficit to two-."'luI"l6I"ed and ferty nine PQittst:~million.But ?;{.i? "good news" since the loss in the previous year was eightY-o~million, sixte8Rpoint se~million greater. Says Mr. Kerley, "We're headed in the right direction and we want to get there (that is, earn a profit) as soon as possible." Let's hold on a minute. Here is a bank which has registered losses totalling a quarter of a billiondollars in the last five years. They "took their eye off the ball", and made "unwise credit decisions" according to their own admissions. What are they doing now, still in existence, prattling about a rosy future? Something strange is going on. You may have guessed it by now. The Federal Business Development Bank is not a private business, but rather a Crown Corporation. Because of this privileged status, it is not subject to the laws of supply and demand, profit and loss, like all other businesses. Next time we'll see why such an arrangement is not in the interests of the Canadian public. July 30/84 - 30 FEDERAL BUSINESS DEVELOPMENT BANK I by Walter Block Last time we were discussing the economic situation of the Federal business Development Bank. We saw that the FBDB had lost a whopping quarter of a billion dollars in its last five years, due to ''unwise credit decisions" in the words of bank spokesperson Doug Kerley. And yet it continues to exist, because of its special privileged Crown Corporation status. Is this in the best interests of the Canadian public? Hardly. The purpose of a banking system is to serve as an intermediary between those who wish to earn a return on their savings and those who wish to invest funds in productive enterprise. The bank must pay a reasonable rate of interest to those who entrust their savings with it, and charge investors enough to make this possible, as well as enough to maintain itself in business with a profit for its owners. Above all, a banking concern must only lend to those who are likely to repay their loans -- with interest. Otherwise national resources will be misallocated and the savers will lose their hard earned money. It is obvious that such responsibilities can best be accomplished by the free enterprise system. For here, competition prevails. Banks which squander the funds entrusted to them on dubious projects will soon suffer losses of patronage from savers. Unless they mend their ways, bankruptcy will ensue. But with banking under Crown Corporation status, this process is shortcircuited. A Crown Corporation bank such as the FBDB is able to call upon tax revenues to make good its unwise decisions. In such a case, there is no natural, automatic, and reliable way -- similar to the profit and loss system of private t-" enterprise -- to stem the financial haem~#,ge. The Federal Business Development Bank should be privatized at once, before it can waste and misallocate yet another dime of precious Canadian resources. July 30/84 - 30 FREE TRADE & ECONOMIC & CULTURAL NATIONALISM by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver B.C. There is a lot of talk, nowadays, about free trade. But the very concept of free trade drives Canadian political leaders into such a tizzy of fear that they substitute the phrase of "freer trade" or "enhanced trade" or some such other circumlocution so that the dread name never has to pass their lips in its pure form. We the people, however, need not labour under this apprehension. Instead, we do well to understand the theory of free trade, in all its pristine glory, and realize that it is in the best interests of the great masses of Canadians, especially farmers, and those who work in agricultural-related industries. One concern of those who fear an elimination of allgovernmentimposed barriers to trade is that such a policy will lead to unemployment. They cite prospective job loss in such callings as shoe manufacture, textiles, autos, electronics, etc., where foreigners can produce the goods at a fraction of the Canadian costs. And this is indeed realistic. An end to laws which protect such industries from foreign competition will mean a wholesale cutback -- or perhaps even an entire elimination -of jobs in these sectors. But this is all to the good. For why should precious Canadian labour be expended on jobs which produce less than they might? The farmer who works at tasks that could be done as well by animal or mechanical means (plowing, hauling, lifting) will have less to show for his efforts than if he concentrated on doing things that he could do far better (running a mechanical plow, hauling by tractor, using a fork-lift). In just the same manner, and for the same reasons, Canada would be far better off if people now employed in producing shoes on an inefficient basis, shifted themselves into job slots where they could be more productive. For "any old employment" cannot and should not be our goal. Millions of farm jobs in Canada, billions of them for that matter, could be created if people used tea-spoons, or their finger nails, to dig up our rich earth. What we want, what we needas a country if we are to successfully negotiate our economic way into the 21st century, are jobs where people are freed up to do more productive things. This was the free trade message of Adam Smith, who inveighed against the mercantilists, the economic "na tionali sts" of hi s day. He saw dearly that the "wealth of nations" was dependent on productive labour, that is labour directed to its most efficient employments. And as a necessary corollarary, he demonstrated that this could only take place under a regime of full free trade, where goverment placed no obstacles whatever in the way of international cooperation, specialization, and a world-wide division of labour. We all see this cearly in the case of maple syrup and bananas. Sure, we could produce bananas in this country. All we would need are gigantic and stupendously costly hothouses. And just as certainly, the tropical countries could produce maple syrup. They could do this by erecting large scale refrigerators in which to place the maple trees. (We're talking bigrefregerators, here). The very idea is ludicrous. We all see the fallacy. Far better for us to produce the maple syrup, for them to grow the bananas, and then each to trade for the item the other specializes in. To mutual advantage. Very few people, however, see that the same principle applies to textiles, shoes, autos and electronic goods like television sets. But it does, it does. Here are the views of Ludwig von Mises on the question of free trade: Third revi sed edi tion, Henry Regnery, Chicago, 1966, (Human Action, pp 752-55) But there is one further bogey-man offered up by those who favour "protectionism" (tariffs and quotas only protect the capitalists with investments in textiles, autos, etc., and their highly unionized work forces; for the rest of us, "destructionism" is a more appropriate description of what it does to our economic prospects). And this is the spectre of loss of cultural identity, or even worse, political sovereignty. But these claims are without foundation. Consider the case for assuming that free trade will mean an end to Canada as a national entitiy. The European Economic Community (E.E.C.) was actually proposed by some of its adherents to this end. That is, they actually welcomed a single country consisting of the European nations, and saw the creation of the E.E.C. as a means toward this end. But after decades of experience with free trade, and end to individual national sovereignty is no closer than it was then at the inception of E.E.C. And the same is true of the Scandanavian countries. After generations of free trade (YJ}Q between th\em, Norway, Denmark, Sweden, Finland and Iceland and still individual going concerns, thank you. If political amalgamation has not followed economic rationalization in these cases, where the one was welcomed as a means to the other, how can this occur in Canada, where most citizens vociferously reject any loss of political soverignty? What about loss of cultural identity? This too is a bogus fear. Is Canadian culture really so precarious and fragile a plant that it needs protection from the inroads of "Dallas" and other U.S. television programs? Or Newsweekand TimeMagazine? Or from the unregulated competition from U.S. book publishers? If it really is so weak, then it would be far better to let it go, and enjoy the cultural products of America and indeed, the rest of the world. But this is nonsense. Canadians have our own cultural traditions. They serve us, and they serve us well. Let us consider in this regard an example very close to horne: the publication of Grainnewsitself. It is extremely unlikely that Grainnewswould cease to exist without government regulations impeding the importation of competing periodicals from the U.S. Certainly, this newspaper articulates the concerns of western farmers better than any emanating from thousands of miles away. But if Grainnewsone day failed in its mission, and if a periodical devoted to agriculture published in say South Dakota satisfied the needs of its present subscribers to a greater degree, then Grainnewswould deserve to go bankrupt. And the same applies to another employer of mine, the Fraser Institute. That organization creates and disseminates a wealth of public policy research and analysis dealing with economic problems which impact Canadians. Yet it does not call upon government to protect us from the competition which might develop under free trade with the U.S. Were it to do so, then it would not deserve to be considered a legitimate part of Canadian intelectual and cultural life. But what of all those artistic, musical and literary organizations which are positively frothing at the mouth at the prospect of competition from abroad? To the degree that they fear a loss of business attendent upon the lowering of cultural trade barriers -and to the degree that these fears are realistic -- to that extent they are not really part of Canadian artistic life, but rather welfare recipients posing as artists. - 30 Government Aid The big economic news in the western provinces is Ottowa’s announcement of a $1.2 billion aid package. According to Prime Minister Brian Mulroney, these funds will be spent on a western diversification program in B.c., Alberta, Manitoba, Saskatchewan. The money will not be spent on a per capita basis, but rather on the merits of each proposal, in the view of Bruce Rawson, deputy minister of the Western Diversification Office, to be housed in Edmonton, Alberta. All four of the western provinces have welcomed the new initiative, and spokesperson for business and labour have expressed cautious optimism. There have been some criticisms expressed, but these have nothing to do with the idea of government subsidies to business. Rather, they focus concern on the amount of money allocated for this purpose. For example, Richard Allen, chief economist of the B.c. Central Credit Union has questioned whether the money will in whole or part merely replace reduced department of regional industrial expansion (DRIE) funds, or whether they will be a net addition to western spending. According to his analysis, it all depends on the bottom line: the more expenditure, the better; the less, the worse. However, there are some more basic criticisms to be levelled at such government aid programs. First, and most basic, is the fact that this expenditure is not government money at all. Instead, it belongs to the hapless taxpayers, who were forced to cede these funds to the state. Government, in and of itself, has no money whatsoever; all its wealth must come, directly or indirectly, from the people. So, far from Ottawa "giving" anything to the people in the western provinces, it is merely returning to them their own money. Secondly, there is the issue of diversification. True, many graduate schools of business have been for years urging this policy on all and sundry, but this is by no means always optimal. The person who bought IBM stock at the right time -- and only IBM stock -- did not diversify at all. All yet he is laughing, all the way to the bank. On the other hand, diversification does, undoubtedly, reduce risk. The question is not whether to diversify, but to what degree should this be done. And there is no reason to believe that the bureaucrat is in a better position to determine this than the taxpayer. Further, if real diversification is desired, surely it will be more effectively achieved by allowing each taxpayer to make his own investment decisions, than by giving it all to the bureaucrats and inviting them to parcel out the money in no more than $20 million bits, as they have planned to do. Thirdly, who is in a better position to determine the "merits" of any given proposal? The bureaucrat who has not earned the money in the first place, and who will not suffer its loss if he miscalculates, or the average citizen, who earned it with the sweat of his brow and will suffer its loss from unwise investment? Surely, the answer is obvious. And so is the public policy recommendation which follows: give the money back to the taxpayer, and let him decide how to spend it. Or better yet, don't take these funds, which are not needed for the proper running of government, away from him in the first place. Charity: Hansen - Vander Zalm By: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute British Columbia's newest Premier has promised to donate at least $15,000 of government funds the amount pledged by Nova Scotia, to Rick Hansen's Man-in-Motion wheelchair tour. Further, with an air of righteousness, avidly aided and abetted by the Province's media, Mr. Vander Zalm has challenged the other eight Premiers to contribute generously toward the wheelchair athlete's goal of raising $10 million for spiral cord research, and demanded that the federal government match the entire package. On the face of it, the B.C. Premier cannot be faulted for supporting this medical research. He comes to office under a cloud of being a "wildman" rabid free enterpriser. There would appear to be no better way to live down this reputation than by getting behind the Hansen world tour, and thus establishing his credentials as a warm caring person and a humanitarian. But there is a better way, one which has the added advantage of not contradicting his supposed free enterprise principles. Mr. Vander Zalm could, as a very high profile private citizen, make a very well publicized personalcontribution to Rick Hansen's efforts. Instead of challenging his fellow Premiers, and the Prime Minister, to follow suit, he could ask this of the entire Canadian citizenry. Why rely on the government to bail us out of all our problems? The State, as is well known by all free market advocates, is inefficient, cumbersome, irresponsible and unresponsive. Excessive government intervention into the affairs of a free people is not the solution -- it is the problem. Rick Hansen's world tour is itself an exercise of private, not public initiative. The problem with making charitable contributions out of public coffers, even to worthy causes, is that not all taxpayers will agree to this expenditure of their money. As the Merv Lavigne case has recently established, it is improper to force people to support causes against their will. So let us call upon Mr. Vander Zalm to remain true to his free enterprise views, to retract his offer of financial support to Rick Hansen on behalf of the entire Province; and instead to lead a privateinitiative toward this very worthy end. 367 words - 30 James M. Buchanan wins the Nobel Prize in Economics by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute "Hello, I'm a government bureaucrat, and I'm here to help you." This statement has become a classic one liner, a joke which ranks right up there with other entries in this genre such as "The check is in the mail ," and "Yes, I'll respect you in the morning." Anyone who takes these statements at face value will believe anything. Yet, while most members of the general public clearly see the bureaucrat for the pest he is, there is one academic discipline, economics, which for many years had as a basic premise the view that the government, for all intents and purposes, was basically to be seen as a benevolent institution. How did economists, who are otherwise highly intelligent people, paint themselves into such a tight corner? Simple. They were enthralled to a theory called "market imperfections." In this view, the marketplace, if left to its own devices, was "imperfect." Economists were quite clever in dreaming up all sorts of bizarre examples to show this: externalities, the dependence effect, unequal bargaining power, neighborhood effects, social cost, monopolization, "imperfect competition," the list goes on and on. Given, then, that the market was imperfect, it seemed to follow, for these benighted economists, that government action would improve matters. Now to anyone with an I.Q. above his age level, this would appear as the obvious non-sequitur that it is. Even were it true that the market were imperfect, it by no means follows that bureaucratic involvement would correct the situation. Indeed, it might well worsen it -- the usual occurrence in the experience of people who do not wear ideological blinders. Into this morass enter Dr. James Buchanan, southern farm boy, graduate of Middle Tennessee State University -- and winner of the 1986 Nobel Prize in economics. Like the child in the fairy tale who kept insisting that "the Emperor wears no clothes," this George Mason University professor developed a Public Choice School of Economics which insisted upon telling the truth about these matters, notwithstanding the great popularity of the contrary view within academia. The common sensical core of this theory is that people do not somehow magically transform themselves when they leave the private sector for jobs in government. They are not converted from selfish profit maximizers, questing after the unholy buck, into selfless moralizers, intent only upon promoting the "public interest." On the contrary, people are people are people. They have roughly the same motives whether in the public or the private sector: and this includes the desire to get ahead, to improve their own situations, to make gains in their own salaries, prestige and living standards. "No big deal," you say? "Anyone could have arrived at this insight? It's just a matter of common sense and logic?" Maybe so. But in point of fact, before Buchanan, no economist had systematically applied the logic of profit maximizing behaviour to the political, legal, and juridical realms. Using the tools of modern economic analysis hitherto limited to business and markets, Buchanan was able to shed new light on voting patterns, constitutions, legislatures, pressure groups, and much much more that had formerly been the province of sociologists and political scientists. Along with his colleague, friend and co-author Gordon Tullock, the most recent Nobel Prize winner has inspired a whole generation of gifted younger economists to look at our political institutions in a jaundiced, but far more realistic manner. Thanks to Buchanan, it is no longer credible for an economist to point to "market failure" as evidence for state aggrandizement; the modern retort is that "government failure" is at least as serious, and probably more so. Because of these efforts, the choice of Jim Buchanan by the Swedish Nobel selection committee has been roundly and shrilly condemned. For example, left leaning economist Robert Lekachman has deplored the award for what he describes as "Mr. Buchanan's rather modest achievements." Liberal commentator Michael Kinsley called him "an obscure right-wing eccentric." The influential Washington Postcastigated him as "extreme, and his adherents as a fringe element." Columnist Coleman McCarthy expressed "shock and surprise" that Buchanan's views should be dignif ied wi th a Nobe 1 Prize. And these quotes are only the very tip of a veritable iceberg. This outpouring of abuse and vilification is not easy to understand. Part of it, a major part, undoubtedly arises because the Public Choice School has been influential in Washington D.C. under President Reagan, in providing a justification for cutting back on excessive government operation. But this phenomenon cannot be entirely explained by reference to the pro free market implications of Jim Buchanan's work. For Friedrich Hayek, Milton Friedman and George Stigler are also outspoken defenders of economic freedom, and also highly influential in public policy decision making. Yet their awards of Nobel Prizes were not met with such tumultuous criticism and such howls of outrage from the liberal community. This can only be conjectural, but one explanation might be that while Hayek, Friedman and Stigler all made it part of their life's work to show how the invisible hand of the marketplace works to the betterment of society, Jim Buchanan's role is commonly seen as basically negative. True, he also supports free enterprise, but the quintessential element of his research is that the institution of government, beloved of socialists above all else, is fatally flawed. Although the Nobel Committee did not mention Buchanan's appreciation of Ludwig von Mises in its deliberations, I should like to close this review on just that point. (Please don't get me started on the question of why Mises never won the Nobel Prize, or the popularity and adulation meted out to other economists. That is the story for another day.) In hi s 1969 book Cost and Choice: an Inquiry in Economic Theory,James Buchanan singled out Mises, and his main disciple, Hayek, for special praise for their work on opportunity or subjective costs. Buchanan quite rightly saw Mises' insights in this regard as an integral part of the critique of socialist planning models. The point is that costs are not objective, and thus able to be calculated by the outsider, the bureaucrat, or the socialist central planner. Rather, they represent the next best opportunity foregone when a decision, any decision is made. For example, the true cost of reading this article is not the money paid for a subscription to Grainews.It includes that, to be sure, but it also includes the cost of foregoing the next best alternative that you could have engaged in, but did not, because you are busy reading this testimonial to James Buchanan. What is this? Well, it1s exceedingly hard for me, or for anyone else, to say. It could be the pleasure of watching a soap opera, or plowing the lower 40, or teaching your children, or repairing the tractor, or eating lunch. How can anyone else know how you would have spent your time, were you not now engaged in reading? The answer is, they cannot. And thus Jim Buchanan, along the lines set out by Mises in the 1940's, hammers in yet another nail in the coffin of intrusive government. - 30 4 THE FINANCIAL POST December 3, 1983 Commented/by Walter Block Labor Laws unfairly restrict employers’ rights 'The stnke is an attack on competing workers' IN THE NEXT few months, several provinces will be re-examining their labor codes with a view to revising them. In the past, such attempts have been superficial. Our legislative representatives must go to the heart of the matter this time out, for the health of the Canadian economy depends upon it. This analysis will entirely concern itself with the ideal labor code, with how things should be. In the field of labor relations, the most important issue is the strike. Actually, this is a misnomer, as it refers not to one act, but to two. A strike is, first, a withdrawal of labor in unison from an employer, on the part of the relevant organized employees. To this, there can be no objection. If a single individual has a right to withdraw labor services, or to quit a job, he does not lose it merely because others choose to exercise their rights simultaneously. There is a second aspect of the strike, however. And this element is pernicious, insidious and entirely improper. I refer here to the union practice of making it impossible for the struck employer to deal with alternative sources of labor. The businessman must convince the Labor Relations Board that he is "bargaining fairly" with those who have left his employ (even though what he most desires is to ignore them, and to deal with others instead); he must give special considerations to those who have left him in the lurch by striking. Fantasy One argument of organized labor is that its present powers - or something like them - are responsible for past wage increases, and are needed if wages are to continue to rise in the future. But this is fantasy. Gains in labor productivity - because of better skills, improved capital equipment and industrial peace - are the causes of gains in take-home pay. This is proven by relatively declining wages in the heavily unionized "smokestack" industries, compared with increased salaries in the far less unionized computer, microchip and other information and service industries. As well, there is the fact that real wages have been rising for centuries, while the earliest unions appeared only in the late 19th century. So-called "unequal bargaining power" thus has nothing to do with the matter. Another argument for the status quo is that the "scab" is stealingthe job of the striker. But this is also the sheerest nonsense. A job is an embodiment of an agreement between two consenting parties - employee and employer. It cannot be the possession of only one of them. A properly revised labor code, then, would allow strikes in the sense of mass refusals to work, or quits in unison. It would entrench this behavior as a basic element of the rights of free men. But it would limit union activity to this one option. It would thus prohibit all interferences with the rights of alternative employees ("scabs") to compete for jobs held by union members. It would end picketing, and other such forms of threatened or actual violence. Although many people think pickets are aimed at the struck employer, they are actually an attack on competing workers ("scabs"). And just as our laws should not allow business firms to picket the premises of suppliers, competitors or customers, no group of workers should be able, by picketing, to forcibly prohibit another group of workers - almost always poorer - from bidding for jobs. A proper labor code would thus define a "legitimate union" as one which strictly limited its actions to organizing mass resignations. Were this one basic change in labor relations to be made, then society would have to rethink a whole host of unjust and unwise elements now embodied in present labor legislation. • Right to work provisions: These would be an infringement upon the rights of employers and legitimate unions to sign mutually beneficial and consensual agreements. Under the ideal labor code, there would be no "right to work." • Wage restraints: Should be ended. These would be an unconscionable interference with the rights of legitimate unions to engage in collective bargaining. • Boycotts: Of whatever type, they are simply a refusal to deal with certain people. But everyone has the moral right to choose his friends and business associates. Any attempt to stop such behavior would be a severe violation of our human rights. And this goes for the secondary boycott as well. • Applying anticombines legislation to unions: A favorite of union bashers, this, too, would be inapplicable for legitimate unions. • Imposing "democracy" on unions: It would be no more justified to subject legitimate unions to "democracy" than it would be to impose the secret ballot, government supervision of voting procedures, or limited political activism on any other voluntary organization such as the corporation, the faculty club, or the Roman Catholic College of Cardinals. • Back to work orders: This would be an infringement upon the right of free men to withdraw their labor services. Fines, jail sentences for labor organizers, imposed loss of check-off privileges would be a completely unwarranted interference with the only tactic at the disposal of legitimate unionism. (WALTER BLOCK is senior economist at the Fraser Institute, Vancouver.) Mandatory Retirement It may sound overly dramatic to say so, but mandatory retirement is the mirror image of slavery. Under the slave system, its victims were compelled to work, against their will; with compulsory retirement, elderly people are prohibited from working, whether they wish to continue or not. The Canadian system of forcing a segment of our population to quite the work force is now under attack, thank goodness. Ten doctors and one teacher, in two separate suits, have launched cases in our courts against being turfed out of their jobs. This policy would appear to be a blatant legislated discrimination against people above 65 years of age, and thus in violation of the equality section of the Charter of Rights. There are two arguments put forth in defense of this despicable practice. One has been made in an editorial of a major Canadian daily newspaper, which states, "In a broad sense compulsory retirement is a socially useful practice: it provides relief from a lifetime of toil for elderly workers." This is easily disposed of, however, for if our senior citizens were really seeking a respite from their labours, all they need do is take advantage of the voluntaryretirement provisions in their contracts. Forced retirement is hardly needed. But there is a second response: coerced retirement clears the decks, and provides job openings for younger workers. This is far more insidious, because even though it is as fallacious as the other ~he mistake is harder to see. The error lies in the implicit premise that there is only so much work in the world to be done. If the old folks hog some of it up, in this view, why then there will only be that much less left for everyone else. But this is the philosophy of an economic crack pot. The blatant fact of the matter is that the world's work is never done, and is limited only by the visions and aspirations of mankind, which are endless. As long as people want more economic goods and services than are now available to them, and are willing to work for them -- and this includes 99 and 44/ 1 OOs percent of all people who have ever lived -- then there will be jobs to fulfill, more than enough to keep us all fully occupied at least for the next few thousands of years. Why, then, do we now have so much unemployment, especially for teenagers and other young people? This is because government has seen fit, for a variety of !"C reasons, to pass legislation which has the effect of pricing unskilled persons out of the job market. There is union legislation, "fair wage" enactments, the minimum wage law, all of which stipulate that people must be paid at levels which are often beyond the productive capacity of young people. Hence, unemployment. Marian Regional High School Closing by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, a.c Now that the closing of the Marian Regional High School in Vancouver has receded from the front pages, it might be appropriate to more carefully consider the implications of this occurence from a public policy perspective. The decision to suspend the operations of this Catholic school for girls has been widely condemned. The schoolgirls themselves have engaged in a highly publicized protest at this action. The Catholic Secondary School Teachers' Association has asked the Industrial Relations Council to call a halt to this plan. According to a high profile leader of organized labour, the man responsible for this determination, Archbishop James Carney, is guilty of "the basest form of union busting." A locail Vancouver newspaper columnist has gone so far as to characterize Catholics who support their church in this regard as unthinking sheep who blindly follow orders. "The church has long taught good Catholics their place. Good Catholics belong on their knees," were the exact words. It doesn't seem to have occurred to many people that such a description could easily be interpreted as purposefully spreading hatred against an identifiable group, behaviour condemned by the anti hate-mongering Section 281.2 of the Criminal Code under which several now well known bigots were charged. Criminal or not, such a characterization, were it uttered against a group such as Sikhs, Jews, natives, blacks or any other minority, would be instantly condemned by all people of good will. Judging from the absence of protest about these intemperate words, it would appear to be open season on Catholics. For shame. Why was this exceedingly unpopular decision made? According to an announcement made by Archbishop Carney, the school was closed because the church had lost confidence in the teachers' ability to provide a Catholic education. But there would appear to be more to this than meets the eye. After all, when one loses confidence in one's employee, one does not commonly close down one's domicile or place of business; one merely fires the unreliable or unsuitable person, and hires another. When a someone loses confidence in his attorney, it would be ludicrous to think that his only option consists of giving up the lawsuit. Obviously, the more rational alternative is to dismiss that lawyer, and retain a replacement. Why then did not the Archbishop, having lost confidence in the seventeen Marian High School faculty members, simply fire the lot of them, and hire a replacement crew? The reason is not hard to discern: the B.c. Labour Code hung like a sword of Damocles above his head. The law compels him to "bargain fairly" with a group of people he wished to have nothing further to do with. In a word, it would have been deemed an "unfair labour practice" for him to replace the seventeen teachers with people he could trust to set a good example for the students, on a 24 hour per day basis. The ordinary businessman who loses confidence in his work force rarely closes up shop. Instead, he grits his teeth and carries on. Perhaps this is what the Archbishop might have done had the work force in question consisted of painters, electricians, plumbers or custodians. But when it came to the molders of young minds (these children, remember, were ultimately his responsibility), he could not tailor his beliefs to conform to the niceties of the labour code. Archbishop Carney was unwilling to compromise or "bargain." He has, at least from his own perspective, no less than a sacred mission, which leaves no room for negotiation. So, instead, he chose the only honorable course open to him, which was to close down the school. There are many who are quite understandably unhappy with this situation. But they should seek the root cause of the Archbishop's decision in an unwise, rigid and inflexible legal code, not as an arbitrary whim of the man himself. By in effect closing down a Catholic school which otherwise would have remained open, union legislation contravenes religious freedom. By forcing employers to deal with workers who no longer have their trust, the British Columbia labour code also violates the law of free association. True, rarely in our society does this denial of basic human rights result in such an altercation. But then, rarely do we find in public life a man of strong principle such as Archbishop Carney. - 30Market Failure by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. Many professional economists subscribe to what might be called the argument from market failure. In this perspective, the market is imperfect, and therefore the government is justified in intervening in commercial activities, in order to improve matters. But this view has not gone unchallenged. First of all, any attempt to "justify" government regulation of business on this ground violates a distinction which is axiomatic in economics, that between the normative and the positive. Justification is by its very nature a normative, i.e., value-laden procedure; but economics is a value free subject. The point is, there is nothing in the value free corpus of economic science that could possibly justify anyone doing anything. Economics as such is limited to describing, explaining, understanding and perhaps predicting; the justification of action is entirely outside its realm. Second, even if there were any such thing as "market failure," and even if economics could somehow justify acting so as to obviate such a phenomenon, it by no means follows that its mere existence would justify state activity. For there is such a thing as "government failure" (the inability of state bureaucrats to act efficiently, due to a lack of the proper profit and loss incentives) and in. any given case the latter might outweigh the former. That is, in ordinary parlance, the cure might be worse than the disease. Third, there has been no definitive demonstration that there exists any real world example of market failure. The major candidates put forth by the proponents of this doctrine include monopoly and pollution. Let us briefly consider each. Trusts, or combines, or monopolies are said to misallocate resources, when they attain too great a degree of control over a given industry. But economists cannot even unambiguously define an industry. There may be only one widget producer in a given city, but if the whole province, country or the entire world is defined as the relevant market the concentration ratio (the proportion of sales, employment or profits accounted for by the top few firms) can be made to appear very low. Similarly, the more all inclusive the definition of the good in question, the less "control" there can be. That is, one is far more likely to find "monopoly" in the industry limited to colas, then in the ~ne which includes all beverages, and yet there is no unambiguous way to define the industry. As well, the misallocative or dead weight losses described by some economists are solely a product of their narrowly constricted "blackboard" economics. Firms depicted in these models are timeless and static, while those which earn a living in the real world are forced to act in a dynamic setting. Nor is there an independent criteria (the perfectly competitive result, beloved of the blackboard economist) against which to measure the actual operation of a business concern which might run afoul of combines legislation. Rather, the proponent of such legislation must claim the contrary to fact conditional that were such an industry to exist, it would have arrived at a different pricing and quantity decision than the defendant accused of restraining trade. But here the firm finds itself in a "Catch 22" no-win situation. For if it charges more than its competitors, it can be found guilty of monopolizing or profiteering; if its prices are lower, it can be fined for "cutthroat or predatory competition." It cannot escape even if it proves it did neither: for then it stands condemned of engaging in collusive behaviour. Pollution is claimed as another instance of "market failure." The charge, here, is that the business firm need only calculate the costs of its inputs -- land, labour and capital -- and can safely ignore the costs of smoke, wastes and pollution, since these are imposed on others. It is for this reason, claim the critics, that the capitalist system is earmarked by excessively dirty air and water and by noise inundations. There is of course a failure of some sort that must be used to explain these unfortunate circumstances. But it is not "market failure." On the contrary it is "government failure," in this case the neglect of the courts to carefully define and assiduously protect the property rights of those victimized by polluters. Were the state to have awarded injunctions to the plaintiffs in the early 19th century pollution or nuisance cases (as they were called then), our entire experience with smoke prevention devices and technology would have taken a far different turn than it has, and our environment would have been far more adequately protected. (For a Fraser Institute perspective that challenges the view that market failure is responsible for our poor ecological conditions, see The Environmentalists versus the Economy.) There may well indeed be market failure in the sense that commerce is conducted by flesh and blood creatures who are of course imperfect, and hence given to error. But no one has shown the existence of any "market failure" in the real world, apart from the fallibility of human beings. - 30MARXIST PRIESTS I by Walter Block Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute As Canada prepares itself for the visit of Pope John Paul later this month, it might be appropriate to reflect on the relationship between the Roman Catholic Church and a philosophy called Liberation Theology. What is Liberation Theology? Liberation Theology is a view, held by some Catholic priests and other clergy, that the poor may best be helped by combining the teachings of Jesus Christ and, are you ready for this, Karl Marx? Strange bedfellows indeed, but not to these ecclesiastics. Marxist dogma such as immiseration and exploitation theory is used by Liberation Theology to show how capitalists must of necessity take advantage of their workers, rape the land and its resources, and impoverish the poor. But Liberation Theologians do more than merely weave theoretical apologetics for Marxist-oriented revolutionary groups in the third world. In addition to this intellectual aiding and abetting, they have gone so far as to use their moral stature to support the active use of arms. However, it looks as if the days of the Liberation Theologians are strictly numbered. A report has recently been issued by Joseph Cardinal Ratzinger, Pope John Paul's chief heresy fighter. It contained so blistering a condemnation of Liberation Theology that one newspaper headlined its account: "Vatican blasts Marxist priests". Tomorrow, we shall reflect closely on this report. This is Walter Block. September 4, 1984 - 30 MARXIST PRIESTS II by Walter Block Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute Last time we were discussing Liberation Theology, the view of some Marxist- oriented priests that socialism, not capitalism, is in the best interests of the poor people of the world. On the eve of John Paul's visit to Canada we were reflecting on a condemnation of Liberation Theology written by Joseph Cardinal Ratzinger, the Pope's chief heresy fighter. According to the report itself, it was written to "draw the attention of pastors, theologians, and all the faithful to the deviations, and risks of deviation…. that are brought about by certain forms of Liberation Theology which use, in an insufficient manner, concepts borrowed from various currents of Marxist thought." This may come as something of a surprise to Liberation Theologians right here in Canada. They have been loudly maintaining that the Roman Catholic Church has been tilting to the left in recent years. The Ratzinger reports continued "Let us recall that atheism and the denial of the human person, his liberty and his rights, are at the core of the Marxist theory". The Church is of course still on the side of the poor, and in this publication underlined the importance of becoming involved "in the struggle for justice freedom and human dignity". It warned that ideological deviation, such as Liberation Theology, tends inevitably to betray the cause of the poor. And it is so important that this message be heard by all concerned with poverty in the third world. For as research by Fraser Institute author Professor Peter Bauer of the London School of Economics has shown, free enterprise, not socialist central planning, is the last best hope against the starvation and human degradation now taking place in the third world. This is Walter Block September 4, 1984 - 30 Medical Economics by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute A late breaking medical story is of great relevance to economics. It has to do with strategies to defeat the AIDS virus, and it teaches us an important lesson in economics. Based on a conference of researchers held at Tamarron, Colorado, there are two approaches in the war against AIDS. The first is called random testing. Already existing drugs, whether they have failed at, or succeeded in, overcoming the diseases for which they were originally designed, are pulled off the shelves and tested randomly for traits that could destroy the AIDS virus. AZT, for example, is a drug which was initially intended to cure cancer. It failed at that task, but after languishing for 20 years, it was reintroduced, and is now credited with extending the lives of about 50% of AIDS' victims. The second technique is the creation of new drugs. This is often through gene splicing, in an attempt to attack the weak link in the life of a microbe. A hot topic at the convention in Colorado was CD4, a hybrid that combines human protein with an antibody, in order to better protect itself against the ability of the AIDS virus to overcome either element on its own. What is the relevance to economics of all of this chemical and pharmaceutical mumbo-jumbo? It is this. There is a widely held doctrine amongst the dismal scientists called externalities. In this view, private enterprise is unable to function, or is able to do so only very imperfectly, if firms find themselves in a situation where they cannot charge fully for benefits conferred on others. Then, according to a variant of this doctrine called external economics, businesses are supposed to refrain from producing these goods or services in the first place, or to do so in insufficient quantities. This being the case, governments are justified in taking up the slack with interventionistic policies, in order to make good on this failure of free enterprise. Telling the world at large of one's AIDS' research, however, certainly confers benefits on others; mainly, in the present case, on one's competitors. According to this received economic "wisdom," then, conferences of this sort are not supposed to take place at all. But they certainly do, and on a massive scale. At the conference in Colorado, for example, Genetech Inc. presented a slide show on CD4, for the intellectual edification of such competitors as SmithKline Beckman Corp., Biogen Inc., Ortho Pharmaceutical Corp., and GeneLabs Inc. Nor are these others backward in presenting the results of their own research at this and many other such conferences. How, then, can we explain this orgy of altruistic behaviour on the part of some of the largest, richest and most profitable corporations in the world? Have the profit-seeking moguls of the pharmaceutical industry been converted en masse to altruism by the likes of Mother Mary Teresa? Not at all. As Adam Smith saw so clearly, even if many of his would-be intellectual descendants do not, one can best promote the general good by seeking one's own selfish interest. How then does the drug industry, and its allies in the university community, benefit by pooling information on AIDS' research? These people gain in a myriad of ways. Publicity for one. Genetech share prices, goodwill, product acceptance etc., all undoubtedly rose with the announcement of its important new CD4 findings. This cannot help but impact that firm's bottom line in a positive manner. Further, even if this firm C. is not the ultimate discoverer of the cure, its public announcement may help it obtain a share of the patent. Nor is it difficult to see self-seeking at work with regard to academic researchers, who depend on the publish or perish syndrome for tenure promotions, academic credibility and even Nobel prizes. If ever there were a refutation of the operation of the externalities doctrine, this is it. - 30 2 The New York Timeson Minimum Wages by WalterBlock When -nived in New York City, I was an avid and faithful reader of the NewYork Times.Sitting down with this newspaper was a daily ritual for me. More, it was a central part of my intellectual life. Like a sort of Rock of Gibraltar in reverse, I could always count on the New York Timesto take a stand, from my perspective, on exactly the wrong side of all economic issues. Whenever there was a question of government intervention into the economy, there was the Times,urging greater and greater centralized control. Nowadays, as a resident of Vancouver, I only peruse this periodical in fits and starts. Imagine my surprise and amazement then, when the following editorial headline jumped out and hit me right between the eyes: "The Minimum-Wage Illusion." Not only had these editorialists finally, at long last, come out on the correct side of an economic issue, but their analysis was both rigorous and professional. So much so, that it is worth quoting at length: "It's small wonder that politicians like the idea of raising the minimum wage: improving the lot of the lowest-paid workers seems virtuous, at no apparent cost to the public. But the rationale is half-true at best, and the free price tag is false .... "Without question (the minimum wage level of) $3.35 an hour is not a living wage for a family.... A person working full time at the $3.35 rate in 1986 would have earned $4,600 less than the poverty level for a family of four. The question is whether legislating a higher minimum would improve life for the working poor. "It definitely would -- for those who still had work. But by raising the cost of labor, a higher minimum would cost other working poor people their jobs. The (U.S.) Department of Labor estimates that each 10 percent increase means that 100,000 to 200,000 jobs would be eliminated or not created." Here, the New York Timesputs its finger directly on the Achilles Heel of the minimum wage argument: it creates unemployment amongst the very people who are, ostensibly, its main beneficiaries. This law is notlike an elevator floor which rises, pulling all along with it, on an upward wage path. If we need a physical analogy, minimum wage legislation is more akin to cutting off the bottom rungs of the employment ladder; it consigns those whose productivity happens to fall below the level mandated by law to an life of unnecessary idleness. A moment's focus on the logic of this enactment can dramatically illustrate the point. If an increase to $4.65 (the level now being contemplated by the U.S. House Education & Labor Subcommittee) will help the poor, why not go full out and raise it to $46.50? Everyone knows full well that such a step would not only create havoc amongst the present working poor, it would disemploy most skilled tradesmen as well. Take the case of the middle class employee with a productivity level of $30.00 per hour. Under our imaginary law, any employer foolish enough to hire him would suffer an hourly loss of $16.50, the difference between the minimum wage and the worker's productivity. But if this is true, it applies as well to the present wage minimum of $3.65 per hour. Although relatively modest, this level, too, restricts from employment all those unfortunates (teenagers, school drop outs, the physically and mentally handicapped, etc.) whose productivity attainments fall short of $3.65 per hour. Thus, the Times,if it wanted to be even more correct, would not content itself with merely opposing an increasein the minimum wage level; it would call for the repeal of this pernicious legislation, root and branch. But if the New York Timesdid so, there are many of us who might have a heart attack. As it is, it is almost too much to bear. Imagine, the Timestaking a perfectly reasonable and responsible (if somewhat moderate) view on matters economic. Is nothing sacred any more? If we can't rely on the New York Timesto print all the economic error that is fit to print, upon what can we rely? - 302 The Financial Post The Economy August 17, 1985 Minimum Wage law no help to the unskilled By Walter Block VANCOUVER TERRY SEGARTY, British Columbia's minister oflabor, has a problem, and is resolved to do something about it in the fall. British Columbia has the lowest minimum wage rate in the country $3.65 per hour _ and tremendous pressure has been placed upon him to raise it at least to $4 per hour, the average level obtaining in the other nine provinces. At first blush, this would seem like a good idea, even one that is long overdue. If, as its name implies, the minimum wage law can boost wages up to whatever level is prescribed, that is to say set a floor under incomes for the poor, then why not? But a moment's reflection will show that this is a mirage. For example, if prohibiting Compensation below some arbitrarily determined level can really enhance salaries, why stop at the paltry, mean and niggardly level? Why not go for, say, $40 per hour, or even better yet, really reach for the stars and demand that no employee be paid less than $400 per hour? The answer is obvious. To mandate that a skilled craftsman with a productivity level of $25 be paid $400 is to invite disaster. Any employer who complied would rack up $375 per hour in red ink. Even at the more modest $40 per hour, any such firm would still lose $ 15 per hour and thus be forced into eventual bankruptcy. No, the reason wages are as high as they are has nothing whatever to do with legal compulsion. It is because productivity is relatively great in this country and because salaries tend to be equal to productivity levels, that we enjoy our relative prosperity. True, a minimum wage level of$4 would not threaten the livelihood of the person who can produce $25worth of goods and services per hour, but it certainly can put at risk the jobs of people with lesser skills. For example, the employment of a person who can only create goods valued by the market at $3.25 per hour would be obliterated by a minimum wage level of $4 per hour. How can we test the economic principle that high minimum wage levels lead to relatively increased unemployment rates for unskilled workers? /-J Manitoba . Saskatchewan . Ontario . New Brunswick . Nova Scotia . Quebec . Newfoundland . British Columbia Alberta . Prince Edward Island Unemployment rate for 20 - 24 year olds as % of rate for those 25and over % 289 257 251 237 213 206 204 190 182 N.A Minimum Wage $ 4.30 4.25 4.00 3.80 4.00 4.00 4.00 3.65 3.80 3.75 One way is to calculate the unemployment rates of youthful Canadians as a percentage of those of the more highly productive adult employees, and compare them with the minimum wage levels in each of the provinces. (For our table, we choose workers between 20 and 24 as our control because this is the youngest group subject to the "adult" minimum wage law,) The results afL\painfully obvious. Manitoba, with the highest minimum wage level ($4.30) has an unemployment rate for its young workers that is 1.9 times as high as that for the rest of the population. Saskatchewan, with the next greatest level ($4.25), weighs in with the second biggest relative unemployment rate for youth - I .6 times as high as the rest of the population. And at the bottom of the pick in terms of the disenfranchisement of their young people, come British Columbia and Alberta with two of the country's lowest minimum wage levels. Are you listening Mr. Segarty? WALTER BLOCK is Senior Economist/or the Fraser Institute, Vancouver . .. SATURDAY, JANUARY 111986 It hurts those it would help MINIMUM WAGE PRICES THE YOUNG OUT OF JOBS WALTER BLOCK ... senior economist with the Fraser Institute, a Vancouver economic think tank. Economists well know that such laws exacerbate unemployment for teenagers. A recent survey by the prestigious American Economic Review showed that members of the profession agreed, by an 87.7 per~nt to 12.3 per~t margin'L with the proposition that "a minimum wage increases unemployment among young and unskilled workers." \ _---------~~~-~ :t)f . , '5 This finding has ~olated very w..®into the economic mainstream ~ within ~ univers~ the business world, and the thinktank community. Even introailcf6iytextbooks, no matter what the "'political bias of their authors, typically include a diagram showing that when wages are set by law at a level above equilibrium, unemployment for the less skilled will ensue. But the knowledge of the deletrious effects of mandated minimum wages has not yet seeped into the consciousness of the public. Ministers, high school teachers, journalists, social workers, editorialists, and other well-meaning folk have been appalled at the fact that the minimum wage level is so low. In Canada, it ranges from $3.65 in B.C. to $4.50 in Saskatchewan, and the reaction of many people is: 'How can anyone live on such low pay?" If we probe a bit more deeply, however, the case against this legislative enactment becomes easier to see. Por the minimum wage law does not compel an employer to hire a worker at any given wage rate. Rather, it only stipulates that an e"mployee cannot be put on the payroll unless he is paid at least a certain specified hourly wage. The loophole is wide enough to drive a truck through: if the law commands that a low-skilled person be paid, say, $4 per hour, and his productivity level is only $3 per hour, all the firm need do is take on several highly skilled employees (and some sophisticated machinery) instead, and avoidfloilc(! tin FIA~'Wthe unskilled workers it would otherwise have hired. How can the economists' contention about the effect of minimum wage laws be tested in Canada? One way would be to compare the unemployment rates in each province with the\minilTlu~ ;-vage levels in force. This is done in . ." columns (2) and (3) of the accompanying table. M·,"fl/ACtc.: Mc;,\.\\,-l!,V \. h \,-v,}-.\r<... But it is very difficult to comprehend the concern of the eco£omists 110m this data.For example, Saskatchewan and Manitoba, vJV\.'v -with the highest minimum wage levels in the country ($4.50 and- ;$4.$0 per hour), have the lowest rates of unemployment (both-Jl:t 5.7 per cent), whi~British Columbia and New Brunswick, with the nation's lowest minimum wages ($3.65 and $3.80 per hour) register some of the highest rates of unemployment (13.3 per cent and 13.9 per cent in October 1985). There is a grave problem with this test, however. The unemployment effects of minimum wage legislation is visited almost entirely on the unskilled.l~~t, young people. The victims are teenagers, especially males, people in their early twenties, school drop-outs, those with little formal education, and those lacking the years of on-the-job experience that alone can make up for this deficiency. In contrast, the unemployment that attacks an entire province is the result of a complex welter of phenomena: export markets, government spending patterns, seasonality (given present unemployment insurance institutional arrangements), regional imbalances, and so on. If the minimum wage levelis doubled from $4 an hour to $8 an hour, this will have very little effect indeed on a person earning $22 an hour. Wit, shoald-it?1. Ct0l' But think ofwhaiijiil do toa relatively unskilled laborer who can produce at the rate of only $5 an hour. If the firm is forced to pay $8 an hour, it will lose $3 for every hour the worker is on the payroll. .----.c~ L. This is therefore the equivalent to a sort of black death for th~t prospects of very young people. Attempting to discern the effects of minimum wage levels based on the overall unemployment rate in a province is thus like trying to gauge the effect of smoking on the health of the total populace. The problem is that just as the evils of tobacco usage are limited to those who suffer from cancer, emphysema, and other disorders of the lungs, ~ have .lillIe or nothing to do with QlllilF iRQl:lIgenee in ttthietie eSHtests, QF aging, gr mgtgF vehicle .acOoi'Olelllii, QF etHer SWQA Q?Jlfi@S ef~othe unemployment effects of minimum wages are all but confined to young people, and have virtually nothing to do with the joblessness of their elders. How can we fashion a test of the Canadian data that takes cognizance of the fact that young people, not the entire population, are victimized by a minimum wage, enactment? This is done in, columns (3) and (4) of the table. In column (4) we calculate the proportion of unemployment suffered by males aged 20-24 - the youngest age group subject to the adult minimum wage level listed in column (3) _ relative to those 25 years and older. And here the results of minimum wage legislation is clear for all to see. Those provinces that mandate the highest wage levels ($4 and above) impose the greatest unemployment burdens on their young people, while those with the lowest legislatively enacted wage levels (Alberta, New Brunswick, and British Columbia) have the three lowest unemployment rates for those in their early twenties. Source: Statistics Canada, Labor Department, October 1986 Throwing out the moneylenders Almost 2,000 years ago, when the moneylenders were thrown out of the temple, it was done bodily, according to published reports of the time. Nowadays, when religious leaders plan to emulate the deed, physical force will not be utilized; rather an attempt will be made to outcompete and undersell them. The modern equivalent of the moneylender is the tax discounter, who gives the citizen the tax refund due him -- on demand. With this service, no waiting for the slothful Revenue Canada is necessary, but the discounter charges a fee of 15%. It is this payment which sticks in the craw of Rev. John Cash ore, minister at First United Church in Vancouver. According to this spiritual leader, churches and charitable organizations should band together to provide tax discounting services, and do it for free! With the help of volunteer accountants and other office workers, the Cashore plan would offer the poverty-stricken taxpayer half ~ refunds immediately, and the other half after the revenooers get through picking the bones of the tax return. There are two flaws in Reverenj Cashore's attempt to undercut the moneylending tax discounters. First, why offer only 50% of the refund immediately? Why not match the 100% given by commercial enterprises? This drawback makes the church initiative less attractive to the poor than it need be. (Of course, it protects the viability of the plan, as it requires on;:go% of the funding.) But the second difficulty is far more basic. On what logical grounds can tax discounting be distinguished from all other goods and services provided on the marketplace? That is to say, why toss only moneylenders out of the temple? Consistency requires that church leaders who share Reverend Cashore's ideology oppose allcommerce. For example, if it is objectionable to "take advantage of the poor" by giving them only 85% of what they would in any case receive in due course, is it not also "exploitative" for the middlemen to mark up prices? For the retailer -- especially in a poor neighborhood -- to raise prices to the consumer far above those he must pay to the wholesaler? For the landlord to charge rents to those who cannot really afford them? This being the case, will the First United Church go into competition with middlemen, retailers and landlords? Perhaps with real estate agents, stock market speculators and commercial advertisers. For make no mistake about it: Reverend 'I Cashore's mission, it you scratch its surface, is really an attack on the free enterprise system -- the one responsible for a standard of living and welfare despera tely desired by the rest of the world. Newfoundland Labour Strike by Walter Block The labour scene in Newfoundland is heating up once again. This time it is the Newfoundland Association of Public Employees (N.A.P.E.) which finds itself on the barricades. This 1,700 member union is engaged in a struggle with the Newfoundland Transportation and Public Works Department over a demand that their $6 to $8 an hour wages be lifted to match those which prevail in other provincial ministries. The organized workers are also campaigning against Bill 59, a law which declares essential (and therefore prohibits from striking) a proportion of all public sector bargaining units. The altercation over these issues has turned bitter. The strike has been declared illegal, and several N.A.P.E. officials have already been jailed for persisting in it. The likelihood is that more imprisonments will follow. John Fryer, president of the 250,OOO-strong National Union of Provincial Government Employees, vows that his group will fully support the local union. A member of the Canadian delegation to the International Labour Organization, Mr. Fryer has characterized Bill 59's strike limitation provisions as a "threat to the rights of free people in a free society," and intends to raise this issue with the LL.O. Tempers are short, and all that is needed for a "made-in-Canada" version of the Arthur Scargill led British miners strike, is a spark hitting the dry tinder. This Newfoundland labour fracas raises an important question which has application far beyond its provincial borders. If we sit back and look at the issue with a some historical perspective, we can see that this episode does not really fit the classical economic model wherein business and labour meet in head-on confrontation. In that scenario, the capitalist was presumed to be a profit maximizer, and therefore unwilling and his employees. The government was thus brought play an unbiased and intermediary role. But in the present Newfoundland controversy, business has no part at all. We rather find the forces of unionism in confrontation with government, the institution presumed by the classical theory to be above the labour-management struggle. It is almost as if one hockey team were now trying to overcome not its opponent, but rather the referee, and the latter, instead of insisting that its role be respected, has entered the fray with alacrity. In such a case, who can act as the non-partisan umpire? The answer is, No one! (The courts and even unable to deal fairly with into the picture, in order to judges in this country are correctly seen as part and parcel of the government which pays their salary, and through whose good offices they are appointed.) This is why labour strikes against government are so threatening to the very social fabric upon which civilization rests, in a way that business-union quarrels are not, and can never be. What can be done about this? We must first recognize that the classical theory was predicated upon the state truly being above the fray, apart from the hurley burley world of commerce. But once the modern government entered the realm of business, with its panoply of crown corporations and product-oriented ministries, a fatal contradiction arose. It was as if the hockey referee picked up the stick, and tried to knock the puck into one (or both) of the goals, all the while insisting that he be allowed to keep the whistle between his lips, and that the two teams respect his position as umpire. The point is, the two roles are simply incompatible. Government can be the referee (the classical-liberal definition of this institution), or government can be a player, but it cannot (successfully) be both. One or the other must go. When put into these terms, it is painfully obvious which way our society must move. There is only one choice if we are to avoid the chaos involved in having either no referee at all, or what is almost worse, a referee who 'is not respected because correctly perceived as party to the altercation. And that of course is a move toward privitization: government must be encouraged to sell off crown corporations in a wholesale manner not yet even contemplated ~he ~sent admjnistr~±on;the public sector must divest itself on a massive scale of its lands, businesses, commercial undertakings, and those ministries involved in competing with the private sector; the apparatus of the state must cease and desist from attempting to provide goods and services whose manufacture could be organized through the marketplace. Then, secure in the knowledge that it can at last play a truly judiciary role in labour management relations, government can in good conscience ban public sector unions. (This would not mean that individual c~vil servants could not quit, or even that they could not quit, or threaten to do so, en masse; it would only mean that society would no longer grant to these institutions special privileges to picket privileges denied all other citizens.) First of all, there would no longer be much of a public sector left for unions to organize. And what of those functions which would still remain even after a wholesale privitization (police, fire, army, courts, welfare, etc.)? Here, we could at last approach the classical model where government, could be sharply distinguished from business enterprise: the latter might be seen by some as having interests diametrically opposed to organized labour, but this would no longer apply to the former. In this way respect for the refereeing process in Canada could be resurrected. In this way, and only in this way, can our nation be spared some of the agonized labour Strife suffered by many of our neighbors. - 30 North Van Chickens The district council of North Vancouver, a bedroom community for B.C.'s largest city, has just dealt a low blow to 16 year old student, MartIn Wouters. This young man, a budding farmer now, and perhaps a world-A agriculturalist in the future, has been raising chickens in his home as pets. So far, his "flock" amounts to a grand total of eleven birds. But young Mr. Wouters has reckoned without the district council, which has ordered him to get rid of his burgeoning enterprise. The young criminal, it would appear, has had the effrontery to run "a fowl" of North Vancouver's far-sighted and well-conceived zoning by-laws whitf'l prohibit, among many other things, the raising of farm animals. Well, actually, the law under which this juvenile delinquent was first prosecuted was ruled by a provincial court as "too ambiguouS!...(i So council had to get back to its drawing board and come up with a legislative enactment aimed specifically at this youthful malefactor, Martin Wouters. And, by 5-2 vote they did that, ensuring that no chickens can be kept anywhere. (These politicians, in a sort of Keystone Kops fiasco, may have gone too far. For according to Mayor Marilyn Bake, a supporter of Martin's endeavours, the law as it now stands would prohibit the municipality's own Maplewood Childrens' Farm - a district enterprise which, horrors!, features cows, goats, rabbits, and numerous - including the always dangerous aforementioned chickens.) What's behind all this barnyard furor? Would North Vancouver, an elite community where an undistinguished bungalow on a teeny lot commonly sells for well in excess of $IOO,OO~be overrun with farm animals but for this zoning bylaw? Is district council like the boy with his finger in the dike, preventing North Vancouver from vanishing below thousands of tons of animal excrement? In a word, No. indeed, the very idea is ludicrous. The marketplace imposes a sort of zoning of its own, making the contrived political variety unnecessary. As shown by the Fraser Institute study, Zoning: Its Cost and Relevance,low valued uses can never bid away land from highly valued ones. It is the very intensive land uses, for housing, which always push around the extensive ones, like farming. It is never the other way around. When Martin Wouters grows up into a full fledged chicken rancher (assuming that his run-in with Big Brother hasn't soured him forever) he would be daft to even try to locate in North Vancouver. The land costs would simply be too expensive. He would do far better to locate in the less well populated ares of the province __ where all the other farmers can be found. That is, of course, if he can afford to purchase not only the birds and coops, etc., but the necessary government permits. But this is another story, entirely. (One that has been covered in, The Egg Marketing Board!,-;;;.blishedby the Fraser Institute. Olympic Standings: What do they mean? by Walter Block, Fraser Institute Many people in the west have been emotionally cast down by the results of the Seoul Olympics. They see the final standings as an indication of the success of the political economic systems of the various countries which were represented, and they do not like the implication that the communist regimes of the U.S.S.R. and Eastern Europe seem to be more viable than those of North America and Western Europe. It was bad enough that the Soviets trounced the U.S. team. Even worse was the fact that the relatively small country, East Germany, also nosed out the Americans. To add insult to injury, The Bulgarians, Chinese and Romanians outperformed the British, French, Australians and Canadians, and others who are part of the western ambit. One way to confront this wailing and gnashing of teeth is to realize that the Olympics Games are just that: games. As such, they do not at all amount to an objective assessment of the accomplishments of a nation, and the desirability of living there. If proof be needed of this obvious point, one need do no more than compare the results of the two Germanys. The East Germans, although far fewer in numbers, garnered 102 medals compared to the 40 earned by their counterparts in the West. Yet any comparison of the two societys, on the basis of living standards, freedom, G.D.P. etc., will show the West to be vastly preferrable to the East. It was not the Federal Republic which built the Berlin Wall to keep their people locked up inside, after all; on the contrary, this "honor" belongs to the so called Democratic Republic of Germany. There are no people who flee from West to East at great risk of life and limb; no, the one way traffic is all the other way. The poorer showing of the western industrialized democracies may also be explained by the hypocritical "amateur" rules which, although on the way out, and good riddence to them, still continue to bedevil the Olympic games. According to the popular mythology, there are no Soviet athletes who are professional, and thereby excluded from the games. But the same does not obtain in the U.S. Is there any doubt that were such top flight American professional athletes as Mike Tyson, Sugar Ray Leonard, Michael Jordan, Larry Bird, Magic Johnson, Reynaldo Nehemiah allowed to compete, that the American totals would have been higher, and those of the Soviets and East Germans correspondingly lower? As well, there is a great bias in the choice of sports represented at the Olympics. The U.S. is preeminent the world over in football and baseball, and yet these activities were not represented in Seoul at all. The worst team in the N.B.A. would blow the representative of any other country off the court, and yet this sport accounts for only one set of medals. In contrast, there are many minor sports with virtually no adherents in the U.S., which offer literally dozens of medals. There is yet another sense in which medal standings are a poor indication of the athletic prowess to be found in the nations of the world; they have not been controlled for population. This is absolutely crucial to any appreciation of the true accomplishments of a nation in this regard. For little credit should be given to a large country which piles up many victories -- but only through sheer force of numbers. In the accompanying table, the medal harvest of each country has been divided by its population. The number of medals per population is given in column 2, and the new ranking in column 3. Columns 4 and 5 show the actual number of medals won, and the ran kings derived from these figures. Column 6 shows the number of ranks higher ( +) or lower (-) a country moves as a result of comparing the adjusted to the unadjusted medal count. A perusal of this table yields some surprising results. East Germany still retains its rank as the second most prolific athletic country in the world, but the Virgin o Islands, not the Soviet Union, has captured the to}? spot. Other small countries vaulting into the top ten include Netherlands Antilles, Djibouti, Surinam and Norway. The U.S.S.R. still outshines the U.S., but both of them appear in the middle of the pack, in 25th and 28th places, respectively. So much for the vaunted athletic positions of both these two super powers. Games, it would appear, have very little mdeed to do with the armed might of a nation. Besides these two, other major losers in terms of ranking are the relatively large countries China, Japan, Brazil, Poland, U.K., Italy, Belgium, Turkey, Mexico, Spain and Canada. All have lost at least 10 ranking places from the new system. Adjusting the medal count is also in keeping with the common sense notion that people from similar and neighboring countries tend to have comparable sports prowess. In the adjusted ranking scheme, the South American countries of Chile, Argentina, Peru, Brazil, Colombia and Mexico are all grouped in the 40th to 46th ranks. Similarly, the Scandinavian nations of Sweden, Norway, Finland and Denmark are all to be found within the 9th to 16th positions. The Iberian countries Spain and Portugal occupy similar ground (37th and 39th positions) and are closely Joined by other European souther Meditaranians such as Greece (38th), France (30th) and Italy (31st). Likewise, we can see that the inferiority complex that Canadians have long held with regard to the U.S. is entirely unjustified. These countries are alike as two peas in a pod, holding down positions 28th and 29th. The Implications that follow from this analysis are sharp and dramatic. There is simply no reason for either superpower to invest millions of dollars in a quest for athletic excellence -- at least if their goal is a demonstration of the superiority of their respective systems. They are the leading two countries of the world in terms of armaments, and one of them has an economic system the other is now in the flattering process of copying. But as far as athletics are concerned, both are at best mediocre. '. Medals Po Per Ca ita Actual e Rank .±.L ulation Rank Medal Country Vigin 1030.9 Islands East German 610.5 y N. 431.0 Antilles New 409.3 Zealand Bulgari 401.0 a Djibouti 384.6 Surina 284.0 m Hungar 214.7 y Sweden 132.2 Norway 122.2 Romani 111.3 a Australi 96.0 a Jamaica 95.4 South 88.1 Korea Finland 83.5 Denmar 78.0 k Netherl 68.9 ands West German 65.9 y Switzer 62.8 land Mongoli 62.6 a Kenya 58.7 1 1 45 +44 2 102 2 3 1 42 +39 4 13 16 +12 5 35 5 6 1 47 +41 7 1 37 +30 8 23 10 +2 9 11 10 5 18 24 +9 +14 11 24 8 -3 12 14 15 +3 13 2 31 +18 14 33 6 -8 15 4 26 +11 16 4 25 +9 17 9 20 -3 18 40 4 -14 19 4 28 +11 20 1 49 +29 21 9 20 -1 Yugosla 53.5 via Costa 53.4 Rica Czechos 52.3 lovakia U.S.S.R. 50.2 Poland 45.6 U.K. 42.9 U.S. 41.2 Canada 41.0 France 29.4 Italy 24.7 Belgiu 20.3 m Senega 19.7 l Morocc 14.7 o Austria 13.2 Japan 11.9 ~ain 10.6 reece 10.2 Portug 10.1 al Chile 8.8 Argenti 7.1 na Peru 5.8 Brazil 5.0 Colom 4.7 bia Turkey 4.4 Mexico 2.9 Iran 2.9 China 2.7 Thailan 2.2 d Philip 2.0 pines Pakist 1.1 an Indone .6 sia 36 37 38 22 12 17 -5 23 1 39 +16 24 8 22 -2 25 132 26 16 27 24 28 94 29 10 30 16 31 14 1 12 9 3 19 11 13 -24 -14 -18 -25 -10 -19 -18 32 2 33 +1 33 1 44 +11 34 3 29 -5 35 1 14 4 1 35 14 27 48 -22 -10 +10 -3 39 1 36 40 1 38 -2 41 2 32 -9 42 43 1 6 43 23 +1 -20 44 1 46 +2 45 46 47 48 2 2 1 30 34 41 7 49 1 52 +3 50 1 51 +1 51 1 50 -1 52 1 40 28 POETIC JUSTICE? February 18. 1986 Dr. Milton Avol, 61 years old, was forced to live in one of his own Los Angeles tenement buildings. He was ordered to take up 30 day residence in a slum dwelling by L.A. municipal Judge Veronica McBeth -- as -15 -12 -6 -41 -12 punishment for repeatedly failing to clear up building and safety violations on his property. Hundreds of landlords have been "punished with fines and by jail sentences for similar acti vi ties. But the plight of this California neurosurgeon was deemed newsworthy because the penalty had the appearance of imposing poetic justice on the perpetrator. What could be more fitting than to force a slumlord to live in one of his own rodentinfested buildings, amidst the peeling plaster, leaky plumbing, broken glass, and other accoutrements of substandard housing? Actually, Judge McBeth had offered Dr. Avol his choice of "house arrest" for a month, or 30 days in jail. When he hesitated, the judge chided him, and asked if his rented units were really worse than the penitentiary. Although it may appear to many that the slumlord received his just deserts in this case, that conclusion is far from obvious. First of all, would we really be willing to generalize from this example? That is, does society really wish to similarly penalize the purveyors of other second-hand, shoddy and shabby goods and services? Examples which immediately spring to mind are used cars, old clothing, secondhand books. Even people who administer food banks are guilty of dealing in low quality merchandise. The answer is obvious. It is ludicrous to even suggest that any of these other dealers in second-hand goods be subjected to legal harassment. .•. Yet by singling out .slumlords, we discriminate against the seller of only one kind of service. Secondly, the result of this law, and of quality control legislation in general, is to reduce the supply of the item in question. If fines ~nd jail sentences are imposed on second-hand clothes dealers, or if they were forced to wear there own products, it is easy to see that they would have every incentive to leave the business. In this regard we may ask, is the slumlord, on net balance, a benefit or a detriment to his tenants? Clearly, he is a benefactor. People are willing to patronize the establishment of a Dr. Avol only when this represents their best opportunity, given their resources. If these tenements, and their landlords with them, somehow vanished in a puff of smoke, the tenants would certainly be worseoff. Under such an assumption, they would have to settle for those opportunities previously rejected in favour of the slum dwelling they had originally settled for. They may have to deal with landlords of the ilk of Dr. Avol because of their straightened circumstances. But the owner of slum property is hardly responsible for their poverty. And last but not least, the rental agreement between Dr. Avol and his tenants represents a "capitalist act between consenting adults". It is a form of paternalism, deeply offensive to the personhood of bothparties, to set this contract asunder through quality control legislation. We do not have so little substandard housing in the western industralized democracies because of such enactments. All the laws in the world -- in the 18th century -- could not have achieved modern housing conditions. We are now so well-housed because our system of economic freedom allows for growing income and wealth. This is why most of us can afford spacious, well-built and maintained dwelling space. Not because of legislation under which Dr. Avol was subjected to "house arrest". \ Pravda, Canadian Style Did you ever hear the expression "Don't toot your own horn?" All it means is that one should not brag about one's own efforts, but rather leave the telling of the glad tidings to others, who may be a bit more objective. This particular truism hits home with a vengeance in British Columbia, where )\" s the Social Credit government/\ engaged in an unseemly bout of self-congratulation, by publishing the back-patting "B.C. Government News". This newspaper is chock filled with such critical and probing articles as "A Budget for Renewals," "Major Highway Projects," "Excitement Building for Expo," and "Good News for Forestry." According to Provincial Secretary Jim Chabot, this venture into journalism was necessary because Vancouver newspapers have failed to present the "true facts" about government in B.C. to the people. In Chabot's view, the people have the "right to know" how marvelous their government is. Since the local newspapers have not yet quite seen fit to present the situation in quite this light, government must intervene into the newspaper market. Case closed. But this arrant nonsense was exposed by MLA Gordon Hanson (Victoria), the New Democratic Party's provincial secretary critic, who for once in his life opposed a government foray into the private sector. Said Hanson, "In a democracy, we do not want an official organ like Pravda." Precisely. The media performs a watchdog role in a free society. A government newspaper may not be a contradiction in terms, but it is surely in violation of the principle that one not be one's own judge. ~ But this logic can be carried on much further. If the ~~. Government N r. ([t) ". ". f . h h h (S d' ) bi d ews IS an exer cise In presenting In ormation t roug t e ocre s own lase r•.... ----------------------------_._._--_ .. 2 political filter," to use Mr. Hanson's very wise words, then how much more true is this of the Canadian Broadcasting Company: CBC, too, is a government owned, managed and controlled media institution. As such, it too is an abomination in a democracy. If we oppose the "B.C. Government News" in Lotus Land, and Pravda in the Soviet Union, and we should, we should, then we must as well express our dismay at CBC as the official voice of the Canadian Government. The sooner CBC is disbanded, root and branch, and salt sowed where it once stood, the sooner can Canada once again enter the family of democratic nations. "Primum non nocere" by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. The basic premise of all modern medical practice is the latin expression "Primum non nocere." It means "First do no harm." This is an astoundingly important maxim, and it is indelibly etched onto the thought processes of all medical students. It urges doctors and all health professionals to be prudent and conservative with the patients in their care. Physicians must of course take risks. And being only human, they must of necessity fail from time to time in their efforts. But the principle of "Primum non nocere" still stands like a moral beacon, imposing a level of behaviour on doctors that would otherwise simply not be there. The same, unhappily, cannot be said for politicians, civil servants, judges, bureaucrats and regulators. They, too, are often capable of achieving great benefits for the public. After all, without government, life would be "nasty, brutish and short," in the words of Thomas Hobbes. There would be a war of all against all, and the weak, and even many of the strong, would perish. But the state can also impose great harm on society. There are hundreds of instances where government acts in diametric opposition to the basic laws of economics -- or perhaps even worse, as if they did not exist. For example, it is a basic staple of economic analysis that the setting of price maxima leads to a shortfall in supply, and to excess demand. This insight has even percolated down into the introductory textbooks on the subject, where rent control is often used to exemplify the evil. The point is, when rents of residential dwelling units are precluded from reaching their market levels, business firms will tend to divert their investments elsewhere: to commercial or industrial real estate, to home ownership units, to shopping centres, or to fields even further removed. As a result, shortages, low vacancy rates and even homelessness occurs, coupled with excess store and office capacity, where rent controls do not apply. Sometimes a rent control provision exempts new construction, but this posture too is fraught with difficulties. First of all, already existing buildings (which comprise the overwhelming majority of units at any given time) deteriorate as the landlord's incentives to make repairs diminishes. This process can take decades to ruin a city's housing stock (i.e., the South Bronx) but once it is put into motion it is exceedingly difficult to stop. Secondly, if rent control is such a good idea, how can its proponents advocate its limitation? If they really believed in this legislation, they would urge expansion, not contraction. And thirdly, investors are usually too canny to be taken in by a city's protestations that controls will not apply to new stock. They have been burned in too many places, on too many different occasions, for this provision to appear credible. Notwithstanding the above considerations, numerous provinces in Canada (e.g Ontario, Manitoba) still maintain their antiquated system of rent controls. Another violation of the "Primum non nocere" rule is minimum wage legislation. Here, a price floor, not a ceiling, is set. Several provinces have set $4.00 per hour as the minimum allowable pay scale; others have gone higher. At first blush, this would appear to be a beneficial legislative enactment. Many people think it will actually raise the wages of ill-paid workers. However, as elementary price theory suggests, the effects are deleterious. For the law does not mandate that anyone must be hired at a wage of $4.00 per hour. On the contrary, it only requires that an employer will be subject to fines and/or a jail sentence if he pays an employee less than this hourly rate. Consider the plight of a worker whose productivity level is $3.00 per hour. It is extremely unlikely that such a person will be hired, or be able to maintain his job slot -- for the employer will lose $1.00 for every hour he is on the shop floor. Rather than _ raise this person to the $4.00 level, the minimum wage law will likely preclude him from employment in the first place. If this is hard to see, imagine the effects of a minimum wage law requiring an hourly payment of $40.00, not $4.00. (This might be "justified" on the ground that if by mere dint of legislative pen, salaries can be pushed up to $4.00, why not continue to the process to $40.00, or even beyond?) It is clear, however, that any province enacting such a law would soon suffer almost total and complete 100% unemployment. Virtually all employers would leave, and one the ones who remained would be forced into bankruptcy. But this is no less true for lesser skilled workers. As elementary economics makes clear, setting a price above market value will only succeed in creating a surplus. This is called unemployment, and it is largely for this reason that teenage joblessness is twice as high as the adult average. Were economic planners to be bound by the rule of "Primum non nocere," our society would not now be burdened with by rent controls and minimum wages laws. - 30Privatize Social Security by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. Several important anniversaries have occurred during 1989. This year is the bicentenary of the French Revolution and the demicentenary of the start of World War II. With all the public attention focused on these two dates, another important event has slipped by virtually unnoticed. It was in 1889 -- 100 years ago -- that a public sector pension plan was first implemented. In the spring of that year Prince Otto von Bismarck, the Iron Chancellor of the old German Reich, introduced a compulsory insurance pension scheme to the Bundestag, or parliament. It was enacted in the summer, and a reign of paternalism was borne, one from which the world has not yet recovered. There are several important differences between governmental social security plans and the private variety. For one thing, the latter is voluntary, but not the former. In the one case, people are treated as adults, able to make decisions for themselves, to learn from them, and to take on themselves the responsibility for their actions. In the other case they are treated as children -- to be ordered about, for their own good. In some sense, it may be no accident that this scheme was first introduced in Germany. For it is entirely incompatible with the traditions of democracy and liberty upon which western civilization is predicated. If people cannot be trusted to make pension arrangements with private insurance firms, or to save for their own old age, how can they be relied upon to act as mature citizens? It is entirely illogical to claim, on the one hand, that people are too morally and intellectually feeble to take care of themselves, but able, somehow, to elect leaders who will make up for these manifest deficiencies. Another drawback is that governmental social security amounts to no more than a vast Ponzi scheme. Pension payments nowadays are made not with money derived from the contributions of the recipients when they were young, wisely invested and hence augmented as in the case of market plans; rather, they are based on funds mulcted from new workers. If these new entrants somehow were able to refuse to join the plan, there would be no money with which to pay the retirees. Then. the fraudulent nature of the plan would be exposed for all the world to see. When Ponzi schemes are run through private channels, the government brands the perpetrators as criminals, and summarily claps them into jail. Is not sauce for the goose sauce for the gander? To encarcerate private citizens for acts allowed to government bureacrats is surely to bring about disrespect for law and order in general. As well, dependency on the state is engendered by public social security, and the breakup of the extended family encouraged. In the good old days before the statist Bismarck began his sorry career, parents gave to their children in the well founded expectation that their progeny would care for them in their twilight years. This pattern of support was the bulwark of the extended family. But when the state thrust this ill-conceived plan upon society, incentives became all turned around. Why support our elderly parents when the all-loving government will do it, with our own tax money? Anyone who persevered in this tradition would pay twice: once for his own relatives, through voluntary contributions, and another time for the parents of other people, through taxes. In contrast, private social old age retirement insurance has none of these problems. People are not artificially encouraged to join them, at the point of a gun. Nor are they "for free," that is, financed from compulsory tax payments. It is only when the benefits of these plans outweigh their out-of-pocket costs that people will join. So let us "turn back the clock" to a more just age and repeal this pernicious system. At the very least, let us resolve to follow Barry Goldwater's advice and make the system voluntary. Then and only then will adult citizens of the realm be treated like the responsible people we would like them to be. - 302 Recycling . by: Walter Block The packaging industry has come under fire from outraged ecologists. Their complaint? While the purveyors of bags, boxes, bins and other wrappings have created products which serve the retail market adequately, these materials are an environmental disaster when it comes to disposing of them. Styrofoam, for example, is cheap and convenient, but it is not easily biodegradable. And the same goes in spades for plastics of all varieties, sizes, dimensions, and manners of construction. How to deal with the problems of solid waste disposal? There are two schools of thought on the matter. According to the first, the problem is caused by greedy capitalists, who maximize their profits in sublime indifference to the well being of society. They produce the styrofoam, bottles, cans and wrappers, which subsequently litter our landscape. Since the manufacturers are concerned only with producing the packaging, and thereby drumming up more retail sales, and not with the ultimate destination of this material, they are unconcerned with the ecological problems they leave in their wake. The answer, from this perspective, is more Government Regulation and Control. Compulsory deposit legislation and outright prohibitions of plastics, styrofoam and other non "ecologically friendly" materials are included in the panoply of responses from this quarter. As well, there is as always the old standby, "throwing money at the problem." To this end, plans are being bandied about to require a "voluntary" payment of some $100 million, to be made by the packaging industry. These funds would be used by the government for researching ways to combat the rising tide of solid waste. The basic objection to this throwing of massive amounts of money at the problem is that it is totally misdirected. In the view of the second school of thought on the issue, the reason for the problem has nothing at all to do with greedy capitalists. On the contrary, it is a result of the fact that garbage disposal has been organized through the public sector. Government waste disposal is the very factor which accounts for the seeming irresponsibility of the packagers. It is the phenomenon responsible for the fact that packagers now choose materials with no consideration for the difficulties of their ultimate disposal. How would a fully private garbage pick up industry function so as to solve the present impasse? While it is always a difficult task to anticipate the market, we now have enough experience with privatization (See: Privatization: Tactics and Techniques, Fraser Institute, 1988) so as to be able to predict, at least in broad brush stroke outlines, how such an industry might conduct its business. To begin with, there would be a complete separation of solid waste sanitation and state. People would make arrangements for garbage removal with profit seeking business firms on their own behalf. This task would be as private as any other paradigm case of market operation, for example as that of the provision of restaurant food, toys or newspapers. It is likely that sanitation firms would set up a sliding scale, charging more for unsorted waste material than for sorted. As well, there would likely be a sliding scale for refuse in terms of its "ecological friendliness." So much for easily recyclable material; more, proportionately, for plastics or styrofoam, or for orange juice "tins" which contain several different types of material which are more expensive to separate. This will have a profound effect on the packaging industry. For consumers, knowing that they will later have to pay higher sanitation fees for harder-to-disposeof materials, will tend to shun them. Or they will only purchase them if their prices are low enough to defray the additional removal costs. For the first time, the system will be rationalized. Packagers will no longer be able to impose costs on the (public) sanitation service. Whenever a packager contemplated adding a new line of very attractive but non biodegradable material to his offerings, he would now be faced with customers who would look askance at it. They would ask something like the following of themselves: "This looks good, but how much will it cost me to get rid of it?" With a consumer in that mind set, the ecological problem of solid waste management would soon tend to evaporate. - 30Recycling by: Walter Block The packaging industry has come under fire from outraged ecologists. Their complaint? While the purveyors of bags, boxes, bins and other wrappings have created products which serve the retail market adequately, these materials are an environmental disaster when it comes to disposing of them. Styrofoam, for example, is cheap and convenient, but it is not easily biodegradable. And the same goes in spades for plastics of all varieties, sizes, dimensions, and manners of construction. How to deal with the problems of solid waste disposal? There are two schools of thought on the matter. According to the first, the problem is caused by greedy capitalists, who maximize their profits in sublime indifference to the well being of society. They produce the styrofoam, bottles.scans and wrappers, which subsequently litter our landscape. Since the manufacturers are concerned only with producing the packaging, and thereby drumming up more retail sales, and not with the ultimate destination of this material, they are unconcerned with the ecological problems they leave in their wake. The answer, from this perspective, is more Government Regulation and Control. Compulsory deposit legislation and outright prohibitions of plastics, styrofoam and other non "ecologically friendly" materials are included in the panoply of responses from this quarter. As well, there is as always the old standby, "throwing money at the problem." To this end, plans are being bandied about to require a "voluntary" payment of some $100 million, to be made by the packaging industry. These funds would be used by the government for researching ways to combat the rising tide of solid waste. The basic objection to this throwing of massive amounts of money at the problem is that it is totally misdirected. In the view of the second school of thought on the issue, the reason for the problem has nothing at all to do with greedy capitalists. On the contrary, it is a result of the fact that garbage disposal has been organized through the public sector. Government waste disposal is the very factor which accounts for the seeming irresponsibility of the packagers. It is the phenomenon responsible for the fact that packagers now choose materials with no consideration for the difficulties of their ultimate disposal. ( 1 •• How would a fully private garbage pick up industry function so as to solve the present impasse? While it is always a difficult task to anticipate the market, we now have enough experience with privatization (See: Privatization: Tactics and Technigues, Fraser Institute, 1988) so as to be able to predict, at least in broad brushstroke outlines, how such an industry might conduct its business. To begin with, there would be a complete separation of solid waste sanitation and state. People would make arrangements for garbage removal with profit seeking business firms on their own behalf. This task would be as private as any other paradigm case of market operation, for example as that of the provision of restaurant food, toys or newspapers. It is likely that sanitation firms would set up a sliding scale, charging more for unsorted waste material than for sorted. As well, there would likely be a sliding scale for refuse in terms of its "ecological friendliness." So much for easily recyclable material; more, proportionately, for plastics or styrofoam, or for orange juice "tins" which contain several different types of material which are more expensive to separate. This will have a profound effect on the packaging industry. For consumers, knowing that they will later have to pay higher sanitation fees for harder-to-disposeof materials, will tend to shun them. Or they will only purchase them if their prices are low enough to defray the additional removal costs. For the first time, the system will be rationalized. Packagers will no longer be able to impose costs on the (public) sanitation service. Whenever a packager contemplated adding a new line of very attractive but non bio-degradable material to his offerings, he would now be faced with customers who would look askance at it. They would ask something like the following of themselves: "This looks good, but how much will it cost me to get rid of it?" With a consumer in that mind set, the ecological problem of solid waste management would soon tend to evaporate. - 30October 31,1988 2 I Recycling by: Walter Block The packaging industry has come under fire from outraged ecologists. Their complaint? While the purveyors of bags, boxes, bins and other wrappings have created products which serve the retail market adequately, these materials are an environmental disaster when it comes to disposing of them. Styrofoam, for example, is cheap and convenient, but it is not easily biodegradable. And the same goes in spades for plastics of all varieties, sizes, dimensions, and manners of construction. ,) How to deal with the problems of solid waste disposal? There are two schools of thought on the matter. According to the first, the problem is caused by greedy capitalists, who maximize their profits in sublime indifference to the well being of society. They produce the styrofoam, bottles, cans and wrappers, which subsequently litter our landscape. Since the manufacturers are concerned only with producing the packaging, and thereby drumming up more retail sales, and not with the ultimate destination of this material, they are unconcerned with the ecological problems they leave in their wake. The answer, from this perspective, is more Government Regulation and Control. Compulsory deposit legislation and outright prohibitions of plastics, styrofoam and <.~ other non "ecologically friendly" materials are included in the panoply of response -2) from this quarter. As well, there is as always the old standby, "throwing money at bolflclkc:1 the problem." To this end, plans are being b~. about to require a "voluntary" payment of some $100 million, to be made by the packaging industry. These funds would be used by the government for researching ways to combat the rising tide of solid waste. The basic objection to this throwing of massive amounts of money at the problem 1 ire is that it is totally misdirected. In the view of the second school of thought on the issue, the reason for the problem has nothing at all to do with greedy capitalists. On the contrary, it is a result of the fact that garbage disposal has been organized through the public sector. Government waste disposal is the very factor which accounts for the seeming irresponsibility of the packagers. It is the phenomenon responsible for the fact that packagers now choose materials with no consideration for the difficulties of their ultimate disposal. How would a fully private garbage pick up industry function so as to solve the b present impasse? While it always a difficult task to anticipate the market, we now "" have enough experience with privatization (See: Privatization: Tactics and Techniques, ,~ , -, .. / !~ Fraser Institute, 1988) so as to be able to predict, at least in broad brushstroke outlines, how such an industry might conduct its business. To begin with, there would be a complete separation of solid waste sanitation and state. People would make arrangements for garbage removal with profit seeking business firms on their own behalf. This task would be as private as any other paradigm case of market operation, for example as that of the provision of restaurant food, toys or newspapers. It is likely that sanitation firms would set up a sliding scale, charging more for unsorted waste material than for sorted. As well, there would likely be a sliding scale for refuse in terms of its "ecological friendliness." So much for easily recyclable material; more, proportionately, for plastics or styrofoam, or for orange juice "tins" which contain several different types of material which are more expensive to separate. This will have a profound effect on the packaging industry. For consumers, knowing that they will later have to pay higher sanitation fees for harder-to-dispose2 of materials, will tend to shun them. Or they will only purchase them if their prices are low enough to defray the additional removal costs. For the first time, the system will be rationalized. Packagers will no longer be able to impose costs on the (public) sanitation service. Whenever a packager '( contemplated adding a new line of very attractive but non bi~egradable material to his offerings, he would now be faced with customers who would look askance at it. They would ask something like the following of themselves: "This looks good, but how much will it cost me to get rid of it?" With a consumer in that mind set, the ecological problem of solid waste management would soon tend to evaporate. - 30October 31, 1988 3 , ',-" Rent Control Reconsidered by Walter Block Recently, a new twist has been added to the argument in defense of rent control legislation. According to this perspective, it is far too "simplistic" to assert, in a straightforward manner, that rent control leads inexorably to various types of housing dissarray. (The traditional economic analysis concludes that rent control causes low vacancy rates, retards repairs and upkeep, and decreases the building rate of new rental units.) No, we are now told, reality is far more "complex" than that. In the real world, we are given to understand, it is impossible to generalize about rent control at all! This is because different types of controls will lead not to the same conclusion, but to very different results, depending upon which specific types of controls are implemented. In the words of one of these "new" critics, "different regimes of rent control will quite clearly differ in their effects," We must, however, reject the point that it is not possible to generalize about rent controls at all. Even those who make this claim cannot consistently uphold it. By the mere fact of calling all schemes to limit the amount of money tenants must pay "rent controls," these critics themselves have generalized about them. Their claim is thus rendered self-contradictory. But this view does more than affront logic and common sense. It is in violation of numerous empirical studies of the effects of rent control. Certainly, all instances of these legislative enactments have something more in common than a mere name -- it is for that reason they are all given a common nomenclature. What, then, do all cases of rent control legislation have in common? They all mandate that rents be legally forced below the level which would otherwise have been obtained in the absence of such an enactment. What common effects will all such laws have? They will all make investment in residential rental units a less attractive proposition than otherwise. This, in turn, will retard new building, promote housing deterioration, reduce vacancy rates, encourage racial and other discrimination, decrease labour mobility -- the traditional arguments against rent control. (The evidence for these assertions may be found in a Fraser Institute book entitled Rent Control: Myths & Realities, which studies the experiences of eight different countries with this legislation over the past halfcentury.) True, the strengthof these effects will vary with the strictness of the control in question, but from this fact it does not at all follow that rent controls -- all instances of them -- have nothing in common. Taking this "new" position is like saying that since being punched in the mouth by my eight year old son is very different in effect from being punched in the mouth by Shawn O'Sullivan, it is therefore impossible to generalize about being punched in the mouth. Surely a dubious proposition. There is little doubt that imposing rent control on a city is very much akin to "punching in the mouth" its stock of residential housing units. The only question that remains is one of determining how strong a blow has been struck in any given case. New York City's early form of rent control, for example, was a real knock out punch. It did not provide for any rental increases whatsoever, nor even for vacancy decontrol. True, it has moderated in recent years, and rent "review" has come to take the place of rent "control" for many thousands of housing units, but the Big Apple's 45-year experiment with rent limitations, by whatever name, has spelled the death knell for hundreds of thousands of people's homes. Toronto, too, has unwisely passed rent control legislation. It is not as strict as New York's used to be, and it has only been in effect for about a decade -- too short a time to provoke a South Bronx-style response. Recently, changes in this law have been made. Unfortunately, however, in the wrong direction. In a new enactment brought down by the Liberals, the permissable rent increase was reduced from 6% to 4%. This is akin to punching out the housing stock of Hogtown at a significanly higher rate. But this is all beside the main point. It deals only with the degreeto which different regimes of rent control will attack the rental unit stock. On the fact that this will be so, these can be no question. Even eminent socialists, economists who have called for government intervention on numerous other occasions, have pulled back in the case of rent control. For example, states Nobel Prize Winner Gunnar Myrdal, an important architect of the Swedish Labour party's welfare state: "Rent control has in certain Western countries constituted, maybe, the worst example of poor planning by governments lacking courage and vision." And in the view of socialist economist Assar Lindbeck: "In many cases rent control appears to be the most efficient technique presently known to destroy a city -- except for bombing." In fact, the proposition that "a ceiling on rents reduces the quantity and quality of housing available" was supported by an overwhelming 98.1% of economists polled in a recent survey reported by the prestigious American Economic Review.Of the 27 public policy issues probed in that analysis, the one on the effect of rent controls met with the least disagreement. Let's face facts. Rent control is an assault on the rental housing stock, and the sooner this elementary postulate of economics is recognized, the better the future housing conditions for Ontario tenants. - 30December 30, 1988 1 Seat Belt Refuser Seat Belt Legislation -- and Socialized Medicine by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, n.c. Many people regard seat belt legislation as a personal affront, as an interference with their rights as citizens, and as adults, to conduct their affairs exactly as they wish. One argument on behalf of such restrictions is that in the advent of socialized medicine, people don't really bear the ultimate responsibility for their own actions. That is, if someone fails to employ a seat belt, and thereby suffers an injury, it will not be he who will have to pay the ensuing doctor bills. Rather, this will come out of general tax revenues. Under such a system, it is argued, we are all our brother's keepers; we have a right to insist that other people take good care of themselves. Carried to its logical conclusion, this philosophy could also justify laws mandating compulsory teeth brushing, the ingestion of leafy vegetables (ugh!), and the avoidance of beer, wine, sugar, alcoholic beverages, tobacco, stock car racing and skiing. Yet, hypocritically, the government is actually engaged in the production for sale of some of these latter items, and taxes them all, heavily. In any case, why is it that seat belts are mandatory only in privatemotor vehicles? Why not carry through consistently, and require their use in publicconveyances such as buses, trains, trolley cars and subways? Could it be that, in the judgement of politicians and bureaucrats, this would be too great an inconvenience and too costly? If so, why not enact a law compelling only dignitaries active in government to wear seat belts? After all, they are our most precious human resource, aren't they? No. The answer is not to do away with our remaining freedoms, but to call into question the pernicious system of socialized medicine which puts them all at risk. Even now, Great Britain, which has travelled down the garden path toward socialized medicine for many more years than we, is an example of how the system can unravel. In that country, there are long waits for doctor's service, and people who must avail themselves of the most modern medical techniques are forced to go elsewhere (sound familiar?) Things have come to such a pass that a private for profit hospital industry has sprung up along side the "free" one -- which is not, of course, free at all, but rather paid for through taxes. And, to add insult to injury, unions have lately been actively negotiating for inclusion in this private system. Nor are the reasons for this debacle hard to understand. It is only human nature (economists call this "moral hazard") to demand more of a service, to use it rather carelessly, when it is "free." But this puts great demands on the system, which then has a harder and harder time responding to non frivolous needs. - 30 SEX IN ADVERTISING An Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for The Financial Post There is a storm of opposition a-brewing over the use of women as sex objects in advertising. Magazines as disparate as Maclean's, Vogue,and City Womanhave been accused by two media watchdogs of using pictures of sexy women to enhance their advertised products. The first committee is headed up by Lynn McDonald, New Democratic Party MP for the Broadview-Greenwood riding in Toronto. According to this spokesper-son, women are increasingly used as sex objects in print and electronic advertising. And unless broadcasters and advertisers do something to turn this situation around, this committee shall lobby the Canadian Radio-television and Telecommunications Commission to impose new government regulations. The second committee has been struck by the advertising industry itself. Called the Advertising Advisory Board, its mission is to act as a sex-role educational watchdog, trying to induce the industry as a whole to make changes on a voluntary basis. The A.A.B. has called for a more realistic portrayal of women, as well as men, in commercial advertisements. Specifically, it has asked advertisers not to exploit sexuality purely for attention-getting purposes. Rather, their presence should be relevant to the advertised product. For example, the Advertising Advisory Board is trying to stop the use of sexy women in irrelevant situations, such as draped over the hood of a tractor, in a commercial for farm equipment. As admirable as these efforts may appear to some, they are fraught with difficulties. First of all, there is a little matter of the rights of free speech and free association. If the advertiser can pay the female model an acceptable wage, and likewise induce the voluntary cooperation of photographers, copywriters, artists and all other necessary personnel, then to prohibit this ad campaign is an interference with all their rights of free speech and association. Secondly, the A.A.B. puts it finger on the essence of advertising: grabbing the attention of the consumer. People, nowadays, are subjected to a bewildering array of conflicting and competitive messages. The advertiser who can grab the attention of the consumer is a step ahead of the competition. There is a joke about mule training. There was a particularly intractible animal, the bane of his trainers. An expert was called in, and promptly hit the <; mule a resounding clunk on the head with a sledgehammer. When asked to explain this rather bizarre behaviour by the amateur mule trainers, the expert explained, "Well, I had to get his attention first." Precisely. This is why advertisers have to be so clever. And, students of human nature, they have learned that nothing grabs the attention of the jaded Canadian consumer as the inclusion of a half undraped attractive model. Of course these contrivances are not merely humdrum descriptions of the product. Only amateur advertisers limit themselves to telling of price, quality, product specifications, directions, operations, etc. The professionals, like the expert mule trainer, grab the consumer's attention first. Strictly speaking, much of good advertising can most-C9~l:Iredl be interpreted in this manner: testimonials from actors and athletes, catchy musical jingles, headlines and eye-catching layout in the print medium. And there is a third effect as well. If the essential ingredient of advertising is removed, this de-fanged industry will no longer be in a Position to contribute to the consumer welfare. Now many people have swallowed whole the view of the critics such as John Kenneth Galbraith, Vance Packard and Ralph Nader. For them, the advertising industry makes no contribution to the common weal anyway, and thus de-fanging it will be a loss to no one - except possibly to a bunch of thieving, dollar-chasing, exploiting advertisers and capitalists and they deserve whatever is done to them anyway. But there are grave problems with this view. If advertising were limited to the cold-hearted creation and dissemination of information -- price, warrantees, product specification and the like - it would, paradoxically, impart far less information than it does at present. For the brute fact is that most people tune out such boring messages. When I used to teach economics at university, many moons ago, one of the most important lessons I learned for instructing my freshman classes was to keep the students awake. If they weren't awake - actively listening, not just staring at me, zombie-like, with their eyes glued wide open -- if they weren't awake, I say, then nothing I said, no matter how brilliant, would ever get through. In like manner, the dissemination of commercial information is wellnigh impossible unless one has first captured the attention of the consumer. A defanged advertising industry cannot possibly accomplish this crucial task. And without the smooth and easy flow of information, our economy would lose much of its vitality. So the advertiser, derided, excordated and put down though he may be, plays an essential role in our economy. In contrast, consider these busybody do-gooders who would handcuff his efforts with a welter of prohibitory legislation. If they succeed, they will reduce our economic well-being, by attacking our economy in a vulnerable spot -- our information flow. Opponents of such advertising, of course, have the right, in our free enterprise system, to promulgate their own views. They may do this by creating competitive messages, and by engaging in boycotts. To borrow a leaf from a well-known commerical advertisement: How do you spell ''relief''? Notwith the Advertising Advisory Board, or with MP McDonalds'C committee on advertising, the other media advertising watchdog group. - 30Sexist Advertising and the Feminists by: Walter Block, the Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The war between the sexes is still raging. The city council of Kamloops, British Columbia placed an ad in its tourism brochure featuring an attractive bikini-clad woman kneeling at the feet of a businessman who was reclining in a beach chair. Accompanying the ad is the message "WHERE BUSINESS AND PLEASURE COME TOGETHER .... IN SUPER, NATURAL HIGH COUNTRY. KAMLOOPS, B.C." According to the local woman's resource centre, the ad clearly implies that the barely dressed female represents the sexual pleasure, while the almost fully dressed male is mixing a little business with his pleasure. But Kamloops Mayor John Dormer is having none of that. "To me, it's a non issue and I don't think members of the general public would be offended either. It's tastefully done, and the complaints about it are ridiculous. II And a majority of the aldermen are hanging tough, too. They like the ad because it is "eye-catching," although a minority, including the lone female member of council find it II offensive. II It is of great interest to contrast this case with a superficially similar one which took place in Vancouver only a scant few years ago. At that time Eaton's department store had placed an exhibit in its sidewalk window that was also deemed sexist by spokespersons for the local feminist movement. (It featured a male doctor manikin holding a probe aimed at the crotch of a female patient manikin.) But in the aftermath of the protest, all similarity between the two cases dramatically disappears. Eatons' management, instead of stonewalling, and insisting upon maintaining its vision of propriety, caved in with alacrity. Within a matter, literally, of hours, the offensive exhibit was withdrawn, to the accompaniment of profuse apologies. How can we explain the two very divergent reactions? At first glance this would appear to be exceedingly difficult, since both protests were undertaken by much the same people, feminists, and in each case they were objecting to essentially identical occurrences. The difference lies not in the offense, nor in the identity of the protestors, but in the people against whom the complaint was made. In the Kamloops case the perpetrators of the transgression are part of the public sector, in Vancouver, they were a private business. As such, they are confronted with very different incentives: the Kamloops Mayor and City Council do not have to face any voters in the polling booth for another few years; Eaton's, in sharp contrast, had to face its "dollar" voters the very next day, and every day thereafter. . on that far off day when the politicians shall finally be called upon to defend their actions, they will be judged not only by how well they acquitted themselves in this one case, but by how well they collected the garbage, filled the pot-holes, ran the recreation centres, distributed patronage, conducted library services" etc. In addition, if they are telegenic, or particularly well spoken, they will effortlessly be able to explain away their acts. . in sharp contrast, the shoppers could easily focus their entire dissatisfaction on the businessmen they held responsible. Nor could they squirm out. All the protesters needed to do was to patronize a competitor. This potential threat was more than enough to quickly bring to heel the capitalists who owned Eaton's. The point of this little civics lesson is that we as consumers are able to exercise a far greater degree of control over private businesses even though we do not own them, then we can exert over politicians, despite the fact that we are theoretically their employers, and they ostensibly act in our behalf. Paradoxically to some people, the marketplace is far more responsive to our needs and desires than is the ( cumbersome and inefficient political system. (And at least the politicians are eventually accountable to the citizenry; imagine if this decision had been made by bureaucrats!) We can easily see from these two cases that if feminists truly had the interests of their constituency at heart they would urge a greater role for the private sector. Instead, their biases run toward more government intervention. This is highly unfortunate from the perspective of those of us who favour the goals of the women's movement, if not their means. - 30THE SKY TRAIN VANDALS by Walter Block In recent weeks there has been a spate of destruction, hooliganism and vandalism aimed at the Sky Train, a.k.a. Automated Light Rapid Transit. ALRT wiring has been tampered with, cars have been defaced, and garbage has been thrown on to the road bed. This last technique succeeded on one occasion in laying waste to several hundred yards worth of tracks, as the computers have not yet been programmed to deal with this sort of hazard. What philosophy could possibly justify these deeds of destruction launched against the Vancouver Sky Train? It could not be the free enterprise perspective, which might well object to unwarranted government intervention in the transportation industry. But if that were the case, w would have seen similar attacks on buses, Via Rail, ferries, the sea bus, Air Canada, C.N.R., B.C. Rail, to say nothing of Expo '86. Nor could these acts be based on socialism -- protesting against the supposed capitalist acts of Bill Bennett's administration of the province. First of all, there are precious few of these; secondly, if this were so, these acts of hooliganism would have taken place several years ago, during the so-called restraint period, not now when Socred spending is back to normal, and certainly not against a government enterprise such as SkyTrain. Although this can only be a guess, one possibility is that there are some misgivings with the first letter of ALRT, with the"A", which stands for "automated". Had there been a human conductor of the train on board and in charge when some extraneous material was thrown in its path, he could easily have stopped it; in this case, a flesh-and-blood person behind the controls would have prevented almost a quarter mile of track from being chewed up. As a result of this vandalism, a guard has been put on duty; this may not have been a total victory for the view which opposes machinery "taking jobs" away from people (presumably a conductor, not a guard, was wanted), but it must be considered at least a partial triumph. The philosophy which hates and fears new technology on the ground that it creates unemployment is called Luddism. It is named after one Ned Lud, who went on a rampage in England in the last century, burning knitting looms because one person, with this new equipment, could do the work of 20. Ned Lud was clearly well-intentioned. Who, after all, wants to see 19 people unemployed, even if the 20th can thereby increase his productivity? This would be no less than a tragedy economically, morally, spiritually and socially. In like manner, the philosophy underlying the Sky Train vandalism may well be benevolent in origin, even if its goals leave something to be desired. It, too, may fear that unemployment rates have risen, at least compared to the situation where each ALRT train had a human driver. In this view, these machines have supplanted several hundred job slots, the number of train conductors who might otherwise have been used. But a moment's reflection will convince us that an automated Sky Train system has not lost us these jobs, nor, indeed, any at all. First of all, additional employees, skilled at computer technology, were needed to construct the equipment at the outset. Secondly, there are the salaries for human motormen that will not be paid. These monies can be used instead for other purposes: for creating still more "robots," in order to accomplish new and additional tasks which would have been otherwise impossible to finance, or for extra consumption of already existing goods. Whichever of these options is chosen, it will mean increased employment in these other fields. But the core fallacy here is the assumption that there is only so much work to be done in the world. Sometimes called the "lump of labor" fallacy, this economic view holds that the peoples of the world only require a limited amount of labor in their behalf. When this amount is surpassed, there will be no more work to be done, and hence, there will be no more jobs for the workers. In this perspective, making sure that automatic equipment is not employed is of over-riding importance. For if these machines do too much, they will ruin things for everyone. By "hogging up" the limited amount of work which exists, they leave too little for human beings. It is as if the amount of work that can be done resembles a pie of a fixed size. If robots are allowed to seize some of it, we homo sapiens will have to make do with less. If this economic view of the world were correct, there might indeed be something to be said for the philosophy of vandalism. At least, there would be some justification for insisting that machines like ALRT not be put into operation. However, there is as much work to be done as there are unfulfilled desires. Since human desires are, for all practical purposes, limitless, the amount of work to be done is also unlimited. Therefore, no matter how much work the robot completes, it cannot possibly exhaust or even make an appreciable dent in the amount of work to be done. If it does not "take work away from people" (because there is a limitless amount of work to be done), what effect does ALRT computer technology have? Its effect is to increase production. Because of the efforts of the Sky Train robots, the size of the pie increases -- the pie that will then be shared among all those human beings who took part in its production or who benefited from its use. Consider in this regard the plight of a family shipwrecked in the tropics. When the Swiss Family Robinson sought refuge on an island, their store of belongings consisted only of what was salvaged from the ship. The meager supply of capital goods, plus their own laboring ability, will determine whether or not they survive. The Swiss Family Robinson faces an unending list of desires, while the means at their disposal for the satisfaction of these desires is extremely limited. If we suppose that all the members of the family set to work with the material resources at their disposal, we would find that they can satisfy only some of their desires. What would be the effect of having a robot at their disposal in such a situation? Suppose that with the aid of technology the family becomes able to produce twice as much per day as before. Will this be the ruination of the family, "take work away" from the other family members, and wreak havoc upon the mini-society they have created? It is obvious that this is not so. On the contrary, the machinery will be seen as the benefit it is, since there is no danger that the increased productivity it brings about would cause the family to run out of work to do. If the new technology can produce ten extra units of transportation services, it may become possible for other members of the family to be relieved of such chores. New jobs will be assigned to them. Clearly, the end result will be greater satisfaction for the family. In like manner, because of robotics, society as a whole will move towards greater and greater satisfaction and prosperity. Thus, the reasoning underlying the philosphy of vandalism is flawed. There are indeed problems with a government initiative such as ALRT, but the lack of human motormen is not one of them • •. SkyLink by Walter Block Federal Transport Minister Don Mazankowski has just turned down an application by Skylink Airlines to operate a new commuter air service. Had this bid been approved, it would have allowed regularly scheduled service between Skylink's home airport of Boundary Bay, in the city of Delta on the lower mainland of British Columbia, and Seattle's Seatac Airport. This decision is a disaster, from several perspectives. First of all, it is a further repudiation, not that any was needed, of any claim this Progressive Conservative Government may have once had to the mantle of the free enterprise system. The Mulroney-ites may have been swept into power while offering fundamental change to our economic system, but in the event, the long train of similar abuses and usurpations. Secondly, it is a violation of the new Charter. For surely it is now a human right to engage, with other consenting adults, in commercial ventures for purposes of mutual gain. And yet, by his decision not to overturn a Canadian Transport Commission denying Skylink this new route, Don (Free Enterprise) Maszankowski has undermined the right of the people in this firm to earn an honest living. Thirdly, this ruling is really an attack on the consumer. As the airline deregulation movement in the U.S. has shown, it is the air traveller who has gained the most, in the form of reduced price air tickets, from allowing a measure of competition into this industry. If Canada does not follow the pattern establised by our neighbour to the south, it will only further reduce the living standards in our nation. This decision, moreover, comes at a particularly unfortunate time and place, given the opening of EXPO in Vancouver. Travellers from Seattle need more options if they are to be able to attend this event. But it is not merely a matter of a public authority having made a determination which is so obviously and blatantly contrary to the public interest. The question arises, Why should there even be a Canadian Transport Commission, or for that matter, a Federal Ministry of Transport? Cannot the free enterprise system, together with the laws of the land, as administered by the judiciary, suffice in this regard? Something to think about. -30- SPARE BODY PARTS Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for The Financial Post In the days of yore, there was no "crisis" in spare body parts. Organ transplants were an utter impossibility, the stuff of science fiction. Only Dr. Frankenstein and his literary ilk had any need for live organs. But nowadays, thanks to the magnificent discoveries and new techniques of modern medicine, these possibilities are upon us. At present, it is now possible to transplant hearts, kidneys, blood and corneas. People who would have been consigned to death, or lingering, tenuous and painful lives only a few short years ago, can now avail themselves of these medical miracles and lead healthy,. happy, productive lives. All is not well, however, on the organ transplant front. Instead of being the occasion for unrelieved rejoicing, these new breakthroughs have brought in their train a whole host of problems. First of all, there is a shortage of body organs suitable for transplant. It is claimed that some are diseased, and that others would be rejected by the recipient because of incompatible blood types. This had led to a set of problems which have strained what passes for medical ethics in this country to the breaking point. For, given the limited supply of donor- organs, our doctors have had to pick and choose -- on no criteria whatever other than their own arbitrary whim -which of the many needy recipients shall have this lite-givlng aid, and which of them shall be denied. The difficulty here, is that our legal-economic system has not kept up with advancing medical technology. The law has prohibited people from using the property rights we each have in our own persons and bodily parts. Specifically, it has banned trade, or a marketplace in live spare body parts. We shall claim that deregulation of this market is the solution to the transplant problem. But before we explain how free enterprise would work in this connection, let us lay a few fears to rest. Yes, it is gory, disgusting and very uncomfortable to discuss allowing profit incentives to work in this field. The very idea involves images of grave robbers, Frankenstein monsters, and gangs of "organ thieves" stealing people's hearts, livers and kidneys in the manner described by several novels of Robin Cook. It seems cruel' and unfeeling to discuss the market for used body parts in much the same manner as we might describe the used car market. But this is only because in our present society, while we can appreciate the miracles of modern medicine without necessarily comprehending them, we have such a poor understanding of the miracles of the marketplace, and cannot even begin to appreciate them without this knowledge. So let us sit back, and relax, and calmly and dispassionately consider this idea on its own merits, all pre-conceptions and biases to one side. Let our only criteria be not our prejudice, but our assessment of whether this idea will really increase the number of donors, save lives, and free doctors from the onerous decision of picking which needy people shall be saved, and which consigned to a lingering and painful death. Having said this, let us now consider the economics of the situation. As any first year student in economics can tell you, whenever a good is in short supply, its price is too low. And the case of spare body parts is no exception. On the contrary, it is a paradigm case of this phenomenon. For our laws on this question, in prohibiting a marketplace in human organs, have effectively imposed a zero price on these items. But at a zero price, it should not occasion any surprise that the demand for human organs would vastly outstrip the supply. This, after all, is one of the most basic laws in all of economics. If the price were allowed to rise to its market clearing level, there might not be too great a change in the number of used body parts demanded. This is called by economists "inelastic demand". All it means is that if you need an organ transplant at all, price, no matter how high, within limits of course, is not likely to deter you. No. The main effect of a free market in used bodily parts will be on the amount supplied. How would a marketplace in human organs actually work? While it is never possible to fully anticipate the functioning of an industry now prohibited by government edict, the following scenario will do as well as any other in describing one possible option. We know that the major source of preferred organ donations will come from young healthy people who are cut down in the prime of life. This can occur in the case of traffic fatalities, murder victims, perhaps, soldiers who die in war, people who die quickly of a disease such as a heart attack, which leaves their other organs intact. Were the industry to be legalized, new firms would spring up. Or perhaps insurance companies, or hospitals would expand their bases of operation. These companies would offer thousands of dollars to people (who met the appropriate medical criteria) who would agree that, upon their demise, their bodily organs would be owned by the firm in question. Then this company would turn around and sell these organs, for a profit, to people in need of an organ transplant. In addition these new firms would operate, as at present, to try to obtain consent from the relatives of newly diseased persons, for use of their organs. Only now, under economic freedom, these firms would be in a position to offer cash incentives -- as well as the chance to save another human life. The main effect of such a program would be to vastly increase the supply of donor organs. Certainly, many people in Canada and in the third world as well would be happy to take advantage of this opportunity. No one who objected on religious grounds, for example, would have to cooperate with the venture. As a result, no longer would potential recipients have to make do without transplants. We need not even fear that those who engaged in this practice would earn "exhorbitant" profits. For any such tendency would call forth new entrants who would act so as to increase supply even further and reduce profits to levels which could, be earned elsewhere. Let us allow free enterprise to work in this field, and save us a lot of pain, sorrow, suffering and tragedy. - 30January 20, 1984 • Species Extinction by Walter Block Dr. David Suzuki, perhaps Canada's best known self-styled environmentalist, waxes eloquent about the needless extinction of species. He states: "Today, 40 million years of evolution embodied in the rhinoceros is being snuffed out in decades for no other reason than profit and human vanity (rhinos are slaughtered for their horns to make Arabian dagger handles or aphrodisiacs for Chinese men.) Our inability to stop before the species extinction is appalling. It is horrifying to reflect on the impoverished work that our children will inherit compared to the one we knew in our youth." This, indeed, is a vexing problem; and for pointing this out so dramatically, we are all in debt to Dr. Suzuki and his like-minded colleagues. However, his understanding of the causes of the problem are virtually 180 degrees away fr0I!1 the truth, and his public policy recommendations, if followed, would worsen the problem, not improve it. In Suzuki's view, the villains of the piece are "profit," "development," and "a limitless demand for an increase in consumer goods." His solution? Cut down on excessive and frivolous consumption, and end our reliance on the private property and profit systems. In actual point of fact, however, the reason that many species are brought almost to the edge of extinction, and some, unfortunately, past this point, is for the very opposite of reasons. It is not for too great a reliance on property rights, but for a lackof private property rights. Consider the buffalo and the cow in this regard. Biologically, these are very similar animals. And yet it is only fortuitous that the buffalo, which for many years was allowed to run free, unowned by man, was saved from extinction. In sharp contrast, the cow has been domesticated for millennia; it has been owned,and thus cared for, by farmers and herdsmen from biblical times and even before. Why the unequal treatment of "equals"? Economists call what (almost) happened to the buffalo the "tragedy of the commons." If no one is allowed private property rights over the buffalo, then it does not pay anyone to let any of these animals that one could capture run free. Things came to such a pass that hunters would often kill a buffalo -- to eat only its tongue. When a buffalo died -- in the non private property days of "home, home on the range," and "don't fence me in" -- no one lost any money, thereby. As can be expected, no one acted so as to prevent such occurrences. Hence, the virtual elimination of the buffalo. The case of the cow furnishes a sharp contrast. When a cow dies, its owner suffers, in the pocketbook. He has an incentive to stay up all night with a sick or pregnant cow, and to call in the services of a veterinarian, if need be. It is the understatement of the century to assert that the cow never even came close to extinction. It is the same with the rhinoceros. The reason they are being driven to the vanishing point is not because of "greed." It is because the countries of the world in which the rhino can flourish have made it all but impossible for farmers to domesticate this animal, and raise it in large herds for purposes of profit. (Similarly, the Canadian government has placed legal impediments in the way of those who wish to domesticate and raise such "wild" animals as elk and reindeer.) The fact that the rhino can be used for dagger handles or aphrodisiacs is an explanation for its perishing, but only under institutional arrangements whereby herdsmen cannot domesticate the animal. If no legal barriers were' placed in their way, these factors would make this beast more valuable.People would have even more of a profit incentive to care for the rhino, to make sure that it was fed, watered, sheltered, etc. Dr. Suzuki, then, has it exactly backwards. If he really wishes to see the rhinoceros population prosper and grow, he would be a staunch advocate of private property, profits and markets. Since he opposes these things, he is really on the side of extinction of these animals, his protestations to the contrary notwithstanding. - 30October 31,1988 2 ;,"-=--", , ...:...I J Species Extinction by Walter Block 'y;\\\\J Dr'1'-~~zuki, perhaps Canada's best known eloquent about the needless extinction of species. self-styled environmentalist, waxes He states: "Today, 40 million years of evolution embodied in the rhinoceros is being snuffed out in decades for no other reason than profit and human vanity (rhinos are slaughtered for their horns to make Arabian dagger handles or aphrodisiacs for Chinese men.) Our inability to stop before the species extinction is appalling. It is horrifying to reflect on the impoverished work that our children will inherit compared to the one we knew in our youth." This, indeed, is a vexing problem; and for pointing this out so dramatically, we are all in debt to Dr. Suzuki and his like-minded colleagues. However, his understanding of the causes of the problem are virtually 180 degrees away from the truth, and his public policy recommendations, if followed, would worsen the problem, not improve it. In Suzuki's view, the villains of the piece are "profit," "development," and "a limitless demand for an increase in consumer goods." His solution? Cut down on excessive and frivolous consumption, and end our reliance on the private property and profit systems. In actual point of fact, however, the reason that many species are brought almost to the edge of extinction, and some, unfortunately, past this point, is for the very opposite of reasons. It is not for too great a reliance on property rights, but for a lackof private property rights. Consider the buffalo and the cow in this regard. Biologically, these are very similar animals. And yet it is only fortuitous that the buffalo, which for many years was allowed to run free, unowned by man, was saved from extinction. In sharp contrast, the cow has been domesticated for millennia; it has been owned,and thus cared for, by farmers and herdsmen from biblical times and even before. Why the unequal treatment of "equals"? Economists call what (almost) happened to the buffalo the "tragedy of the commons." If no one is allowed private property rights over the buffalo, then it does not pay anyone to let any of these animals that one could capture run free. Things came to such a pass that hunters would often kill a buffalo -- to eat only its tongue. When a buffalo died -- in the non private property days of "home, home on the range," and "don't fence me in" -- no one lost any money, thereby. As can be expected, no one acted so as to prevent such occurrences. Hence, the virtual elimination of the buffalo. The case of the cow furnishes a sharp contrast. When a cow dies, its owner suffers, in the pocketbook. He has an incentive to stay up all night with a sick or pregnant cow, and to call in the services of a veterinarian, if need be. It is the understatement of the century to assert that the cow never even came close to extinction. It is the same with the rhinoceros. The reason they are being driven to the vanishing point is not because of "greed." It is because the countries of the world in which the rhino can flourish have made it all but impossible for farmers to domesticate this animal, and raise it in large herds for purposes of profit. (Similarly, the Canadian government has placed legal impediments in the way of those who wish to domesticate and raise such "wild" animals as elk and reindeer.) The fact that the rhino can be used for dagger handles or aphrodisiacs is an explanation for its perishing, but only under institutional arrangements whereby herdsmen cannot domesticate the animal. If no legal barriers were placed in their way, these factors would make this beast more valuable.People would have even more of a profit incentive to care for the rhino, to make sure that it was fed, watered, sheltered, etc. Dr. Suzuki, then, has it exactly backwards. If he really wishes to see the rhinoceros population prosper and grow, he would be a staunch advocate of private property, profits and markets. Since he opposes these things, he is really on the side of extinction of these animals, his protestations to the contrary notwithstanding. - 30October 31, 1988 (j , Strange Bedfellows? Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Whoever said that politics makes strange bedfellows must have been thinking of Doug Collins and Harry Rankin. On the one hand, we have a man with impeccable left-wing credentials. An ex Committee of Progressive Electors Vancouver alderman, a stalwart supporter of the N.D.P., a card carrying member of the B.C. Civil Liberties Association, lawyer Harry Rankin yields to no one in his devotion to left-wing causes; radical environmentalism, feminism, government controls over the economy, peace marches, economic nationalism, he has fought for them all. On the other hand, there is a man with equally impeccable rightwing credentials. Doug Collins is a long time west coast columnist, now writing for the North Shore News. A rejected candidate for the newly-formed Reform Party (by leader Preston Manning after the local constituency had nominated him), Collins has been highly visible as a witness for Mr. Zundel, at their hate literature court trials. Drawing his ire are feminists, multi-culturalists, the immigration law and radical environmentalists. What on earth could these two very different political animals have in common-apart from the fact that they happen to reside in B.c.? Both have recently criticized the purchase of Vancouver real estate by foreign investors from Hong Kong. In the words of Mr. Rankin, "When money floods in from individuals buying four or five houses for investment purposes instead of for living in, you heat up and inflate the economy. "We have to check the source of the inflation -- the foreign speculators -- by not allowing anyone other than Canadians and landed immigrants to purchase residential property." In chillingly similar language, Mr. Collins strongly objects to the practice of the Block Bros. real estate firm in "taking out whole-page ads in the Hong Kong press inviting Hong Kongers to buy homes on the North Shore. "Recently," he stated, "a woman in Woodcroft was offered a fancy price for her apartment by an Asiatic. When she asked him why he wanted her place, he told her he had already bought every other apartment on that floor. "Regulations to prevent the mass selling of residential real estate to foreigners would not be unusual. The Australians have already put the clamps on such sales. So have some other jurisdictions, including P.E.I. and Hawaii." 1 These statements are very objectionable, even frightening. They harken back to the discredited and discreditable era of the "yellow menace" and "yellow peril." One would have hoped that never again would a presumably civilized society such as ours have been subjected to such carryings on, but it appears that we are not to be spared. Adding insult to injury, there is a small matter of hypocrisy. Collins is himself an immigrant to Canada from the U.K., while Rankin's forbears hail from Europe. It comes with particular ill grace, then, for these two gentlemen to engage in blatant foreigner bashing. Further, it is simply untrue, as both imply, that Hong Kong investments in Canada will harm the inhabitants of this country. When a person of Chinese descent (or any other, for that matter) purchases a home in B.C. he offers considerations which, in the eye of the seller, are worth morethan the property in question. For example, if a British Columbian sells a domicile to a resident of Hong Kong for $300,000, it must be true that the vendor values the money he receives more highly than the residence he gives up. Otherwise, he would scarcely agree to the sale! Collins and Rankin go wrong in that they liken the foreign investment to a takeover of real estate. As a moment's reflection will convince us, the Hong Kong Chinese are not seizing property; they are trading for it. As for the similarity of belief way out on the fringes of the left-right spectrum, this is only paradoxical to those who do not realize that both extremes, not just one or the other, fail to comprehend the subtleties of voluntary social arrangements. Both, unfortunately, are all too willing to call for the coercive power of government to do their bidding, to impose their will on the rest of society. - 302 Student Free Enterprises? Sound the trumpets! Toot the horns! Free enterprise is alive and well in Canada, courtesy of several provincial governments! Pioneered by Ontario, and now a policy of the B.C. government as well, the new student venture capital program grants an interestfree loan of up to $2,000 for the purpose of launching these young people into the world of entrepreneurship. And the newspaper accounts of this journey into capitalism are uniformly glowing. They wax eloquent about all the newly coined gardening firms, tee shirt emporiums, and yogurt shops which have been set up with the money. Woop-de-do. There is only one fly in the ointment. The program is an abomination, a travesty of free enterprise, and will do more to undermine the philosophy of Adam Smith than it will support it. For the essence of the capitalist system is that people save up their ~ hard-earned dollars, invest them, and then bear the risk of their decisions. If government gives the WOUld-be businessman the wherewithal to start up the process, or lends it 'to him interest-free, it undermines the whole enterprise. Government can no more make a young person a capitalist through such a procedure than it can award a chess grand mastership to a neophyte player and expect this action to make even the smallest iota of difference. For free enterprise is predicated on the willing cooperation of all market participants. This holds true at the consumer level, in the labour and raw materials stage, and throughout the series of trades which comprise the structure of production. This voluntarism most assuredly includes the start up process as well, where capital is attracted to a new venture by the promise of profits and interest payments. The problem with the government program is that the initial start up funds come not from willing investors, but courtesy of the tax system. And, say what you will about taxes, their inescapable characteristic is that they are anything but voluntary. On the contrary, they are coercive, as is readily known to all those who have refused to pay. This government student venture capital program is thus destructive of capitalism. It undermines the ethic of free enterprise. Worse, if possible, it misleads students, and is thus a violation of the canons of education as well. This program should be ended with all due deliberate speed; that is, forthwith • .. Government subsidies for scientists? by Walter Block Dr. David Suzuki is a well known environmentalist, and opponent of the free enterprise system. In his weekly column in a major Canadian newspaper, he often engages in special pleading in behalf of one of his favoured special interest groups: scientists. Let us consider the case he makes. In the market place, claimants for our hard earned assets can only obtain a portion of them with our consent. This can be done directly, as in the purchase of a consumption item. It can also take place through the intermediation of an entrepreneur, who risks his own money on the supposition that he can thereby earn profits (i.e., create something which consumers will value more highly than the production costs.) That is to say, businessmen engage in research and development funding in the hope that its eventual fruits will more than repay them. But Dr. Suzuki is no fan of the free market system. Not for him the nicety of asking people for their money on a voluntary basis, of convincing them that their earnings are well spent on scientific endeavours. He wishes to short circuit this system, and take by force, through taxes, the funds the people would not have given by their own free will for this purpose. Despite Suzuki's elitism, there is not much of a case that can be made on economic grounds for this dubious public policy. For one thing, government subsidies to research may be objected to on the ground that they encourage the undertaking of wasteful projects; with public sector involvement, the political agenda tends to supplant the purely scientific one. As well, it skews research procedures compared to the optimal allocation which would occur on the market. If there is any case for governmental interference with the market, it is in regard to basic, not applied research, because the investor may not be able to capture the full benefits of his labors. The so called "unenlightened" short-changing of Canadian scientists, has been criticized by some economists on this ground. As against that, government, too, can "fail," and thus market imperfections do not in and of themselves justify public sector activity. However, even this case for government intervention is questionable, since many of these spill overs can actually be captured by the pure research scientist, in the form of Nobel prizes, prestige, tenure, the respect of their peers, etc. Since it is impossible to know or measure the value to society of different R&D strategies, it is unwarranted to maintain that there would be in the absence of government intervention an underallocation of funding to basic scientific research. There is, thus, no economic evidence which indicates that, in the absence of public subsidies for the activity, it would be too small. Dr. Suzuki is especially irate at the fact that the U.S., Japan, and several western European countries spend some 2.5-2.8 per cent of their G.N.P on scientific research, while their Canadian counterparts have lavished on them funding at only approximately one half of this rate. This penury has led to a brain drain: "That's why so many world-class scientists have left Canada to work in other countries." But where is it engraved in stone that Canada must have a world class scientific community, especially given that this is contrary to the wishes of its citizenry? It is simply illogical to expect so small a country as ours to be well represented in all areas of human accomplishment. In the U.S., for example, the scientific community is geographically segregated. Scientists are huddled in small areas of the country, such as those surrounding Boston and "Silicon Valley" in California. But this leaves truly vast stretches of the country - far larger than all of Canada without any scientific community at all. If places like New York, or Indiana, Ohio and Pennsylvania have little or no scientific establishment, why should Canada bankrupt itself to keep up with the Joneses? This would be especially unwise, given the fact that scientific papers written south of the border appear in English, and are highly accessible to Canadians at little or no cost. Why not be free riders on U.S. investment? - 30October 31,1988 '---- ' 2 Government subsidies for scientists? by Walter Block Dr. David Suzuki is a well known environmentalist, and opponent of the free enterprise system. In his weekly column in a major Canadian newspaper, he often engages in special pleading in behalf of one of his favoured special interest groups: scientists. Let us consider the case he makes. In the market place, claimants for our hard earned assets can only obtain a portion of them with our consent. This can be done directly, as in the purchase of a consumption item. It can also take place through the intermediation of an s entrepreneur, who risk his own money on the supposition that he can thereby earn "profits (i.e., create something which consumers will value more highly than the production costs.) That is to say, businessmen engage in research and development funding in the hope that its eventual fruits will more than repay them. But Dr. Suzuki is no fan of the free market system. Not for him the nicety of asking people for their money on a voluntary basis, of convincing them that their earnings are well spent on scientific endeavours. He wishes to short circuit this system, and take by force, through taxes, the funds the people would not have given by their own free will for this purpose. Despite Suzuki's elitism, there is not much of a case that can be made on economic grounds for this dubious public policy. For one thing, government subsidies to research may be objected to on the ground that they encourage the undertaking of wasteful projects; with public sector involvement, the political agenda tends to supplant the purely scientific one. As well, it skews research procedures compared to the optimal allocation which would occur on the market. If there is any case for governmental interference with the market, it is in regard to basic, not applied research, because the investor may not be able to capture the full benefits of his labors. The so called "unenlightened" short-changing of Canadian scientists, has been criticized by some economists on this ground. As against that, government, too, can "fail," and thus market imperfections do not in and of themselves justify public sector activity. However, even this case for government intervention is questionable, since many of these spill overs can actually be captured by the pure research scientist, in the form of Nobel prizes, prestige, tenure, the respect of their peers, etc. Since it is impossible to know or measure the value to society of different R&D strategies, it is unwarranted to maintain that there would be in the absence of government intervention an underallocation of funding to basic scientific research. There is, thus, no economic evidence which indicates that, in the absence of public subsidies for the activity, it would be too small. /3)~Suzuki is especially irate at the fact that the U.S., Japan, and several western European countries spend some 2.5-2.8 per cent of their G.N.P on scientific research, while their Canadian counterparts have lavished on them funding at only approximately one half of this rate. This penury has led to a brain drain: "That's why so many world-class scientists have left Canada to work in other countries." , But where is it engraved ¢n stone that Canada must have a world class scientific community, especially given that this is contrary to the wishes of its citizenry? It is simply illogical to expect so small a country as ours to be well represented in all ) areas of human accomplishment. In the U.S,for example, the scientific community is geographically segregated. Scientists are huddled in small areas of the country, such as those surrounding Boston and "Silicon Valley" in California. But this leaves truly vast stretches of the country - far larger than all of Canada without any scientific community at all. If places like New York, or Indiana, Ohio and Pennsylvania have little or no scientific establishment, why should Canada bankrupt itself to keep up with the Joneses? This would be especially unwise, given the fact that scientific papers written south of the border appear in English, and are highly accessible to Canadians at little or no cost. Why not be free riders on U.S. investment? - 30L October 31, 1988 3 TAX SUBSIDIES - PART I BY Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute Does the government subsidize the people of the country by neglecting to tax them on all their earnings? That, in a nutshell, is the essence of the dispute over tax deductions, tax credits, tax concessions, tax expenditures, loopholes, preferences, and tax shelters. There are two schools of thought on this issue. According to one viewpoint, whenever government fails to collect a tax that would otherwise be due (under an alternative law) it is equivalent to a subsidy. For this oversight reduces its revenues -- its tax take falls by this amount -- and this is the same, in effect, as if the government had first taxed the money away from us, and then given it back in the form of a subsidy. Take the exemption for charitable donations, for example. Mr. A contributes $100 to the XYZ Foundation, and, because of his tax bracket, he can save $25 from his total tax bill. What is that, according to the line of thought, but a government grant of $25 to Mr. A (and indirectly to XYZ)? Had government not allowed the exemption, it would have cost Mr. A roughly $125 to donate the same $100 to XYZ. The difference? A subsidy from all the taxpayers, ultimately to XYZ. It is just as if government had given away $25 of its revenues. Nor are we talking peanuts here. According to the Finance Department which publishes an annual accounting of such tax expenditures, the cost of loopholes in the personal income tax alone was $23.4 billion, for 1980. And the following statistics are reported by W. T. Stanbury and John L Howard in Probing Leviathan(Vancouver: The Fraser Institute, 1984): Corporate tax concessions were 67% of all such taxes collected in 1973, 75% in 1974, and 69% in 1975. Based on these findings, Stanbury and Howard estimate that had cash subsidies been used instead of foregone tax revenues, the federal budget would have been almost 50% larger than it was in 1979. But there is a second school of thought on the question of tax expenditures, and we shall consider it next time. February/85 TUNAGATE AND BUFFALOGATE by Walter Block The Canadian reputation for probity and reliability in matters commercial has recently been dealt a double death blow. In the tuna industry, a million cans of this product had to be recalled in September after New Brunswick Premier Richard Hatfield and the then Federal Fisheries Minister John Fraser (Vancouver South) overruled government evaluaters, and insisted , that rancid fish be put on the market despite its failure to pass the appropriate tests. In December, another 32,600 tins of tuna had to be taken off the supermarket shelf, because several dozen were found to contain "slimy," "off-odour," and "decomposing" fish. This was a small amount compared to the gigantic fiasco of September, but coming hard on the heels of that event it all but destroyed what was left of the reputation of the company involved, Star-Kist, an affiliate of H.J. Heinz of Pittsburgh, Pa. In the beef industry, a similar occurrence took place in late 1 985. Meat from diseased buffalo that could not under present treaties have been either exported from or imported into this country, was nevertheless approved by federal inspectors for domestic human consumption. So-called experts from the Department of Agriculture -- which had passed on the slaughter of the tubercular animals -said that there was "basically no danger" to consumers, but the whole event, pardon the pun, left a bad taste in the mouth of most people. What have we learned from this unfortunate concatenation of events? Many pundits have concluded that government must pull itself up by its bootstraps , so to speak, and endeavour to do a better job in its certification quality of food we eat. Indeed, the present Fisheries Minister Tom Siddon (Richmond-South Delta) intends to review and tighten the inspection procedures of his department. But the problems run far deeper than that. If a little bit of ministerial belt-tightening were all that was needed to rectify the situation, this presumably would have been done in the past and we would not now be faced with our present crisis of confidence. Nor is the problem even that of front line people engaging in mistaken assessments, nor yet that of their superiors rejecting correct evaluations made from below, as is alleged to have occurred in Tunagate I. No. All of these errors are unfortunately the lot of humankind, and will presumably plague us, and continue to do so, as long as we still occupy real estate on the wrong side of the Garden of Eden. The real difficulty is that whenever incorrect behaviour occurs in the public sector, there is no automatic response which tends to be self-correcting. In the private sector, in contrast, errors tend to be dampened down, because those who indulge too frequently are penalized by losses of profits, and by eventual bankruptcy. How might the benefits of the free enterprise system be brought to bear on the problem of assessing the quality of (tuna) fish or (buffalo) meat or other such foodstuffs? Were the marketplace, not government, given this vital responsibility, there would presumably be numerous firms which would enter the industry of quality certification. Each would undertake to weigh, measure, test, and in other manners certify the quality of products for their clients. If ever it were later learned that an error in judgment had been made, the very life of these independent testing laboratories would become forfeit. THeir eOreputations, their life expectancy would depend on minimization or even complete elimination of error. Perhaps even more important, the prsonal fortunes of the owner of these firms would hang in the balance. Compare, if you will, the internal mental states of a federal fisheries minister, with the owner of a private certification laboratory, which specializes in a clientele mainly composed of fish processors. The minister, to be sure, will be determined to do a good job. His prospects for advancement in government may depend upon it. But if he or one of his underlings succumbs to less than perfect behaviour, his losses are relatively minimal. He can still remain as an MP. His own income is thus secure. Nor is his personal fortune at risk. He may even rise to cabinet again, although likely in another ministry. His counterpart in private industry will suffer far more grievously, however. There are numerous competing firms, ready, willing and able to pounce down on him in an attempt to win away his clients. As we have seen, his entire commercial life is dependent upon the success of his firm. Where a fisheries ministry may check and check once again, the owner of an independent testing laboratory may install far more elaborate fail-safe mechanisms. He is likely to test larger samples aof the given universe, the better to minimize error. And in all likelihood this better process will be given to the consumer at a lower cost than the taxes which now go to support such ministries. This is because free enterprise traditionally accomplishes tasks at one-third to one-half the cost endemic to government. Again, the explanation for this is the profit and loss system: it rewards and penalizes entrepreneurs to the extent they can produce a service at a minimal cost. Some well meaning people may recoil from this proposal. ~ They may be aghast at the spectre of the marketplace being asked not only to produce our foodstuffs, but to certify their quality as well. They will splutter, "This is too important a task to be left to private individuals." On the contrary, this is too vital a role to be entrusted to the well-meaning but blundering hand of government. Would you really trust the folks who mismanage our post office to the allimportant job of maintaining quality standards of food? If you would, have you ever heard of Tunagate, or Buffalogate? Then there is the objection that private testing laboratories would be subject to bribery. This is a very serious charge, since if such activity occurs, it will completely undermine the case for a private sector initiative in this regard. Might it be likely that a guarantor of the quality of tunafish might accept a large bribe to certify as acceptable a flawed shipment of this product? We cannot say this is impossible. stranger and more heinous things have happened in the history of mankind. But remember: we need not prove that private enterprise is "perfect". No institution composed of real live human beings can ever be so. The case for the market is not that it is without flaw, only that it is likely to commit fewererrors than the public sector. For bribery is not unknown in government. (Understatement of the century). In some countries the practice of bribery is so widespread it has reached epidemic proportions. It is a way of life. Even in our own country it is not unknown for "public servants" to be diverted from their duty with the promise of filthy lucre. The question is, under which system of certification, public or private, is bribery more likely to take place? And the available evidence seems to support the view that bureaucrats are more likely to be ? than the employees of private firms. Again, we return to our comparison of the Fisheries Minister and the owner of the independent testing laboratory. Each has reasons and incentives to resist the bribery of his employees. But which one will lose more from a successful penetration of his enterprise by bribers? As we have seen, it is the private owner, not the minister, who has more at risk and thus a greaterincentive to combat the blandishments of bribery. We must thus conclude this analysis with a call for greater private sector involvement. No, future tunagates and buffalogates will not thereby be completely eliminated. But all indications point to the more modest conclusion that such fiascos will be reducedin future in this manner. B.C. construction picketers prove harassment is the key -k N b VANCOUVER ARE YOU READY for the latest carfuflie on the B.C. labor front? Ironworkers' Union local 712 recently rejected _ by a small 86 to 79 vote - an offer from Dominion Bridge. It was to employ 750 workers at a new steel fabrication plant to be built near Nanaimo. If successful, this project could have been the entering wedge to an industry aimed at supplying steel products for the burgeoning oil refinery business in Alaska. Yes, the wages offered by Dominon Bridge were somewhat below those called for in the overblown and unrealistic contracts negotiated by the Ironworkers union in past better days. But unemployment is a fact of life in British Columbia today, and people are far better ofT employed at the $12.85 per hour offered than not at all. L When he heard about this latest instance of the union movement shooting the labor force in the foot, Industry Minister Don Phillips responded by creating special union-free economic zones in the province. A union-free economic zone is only one variant of an idea that is now sweeping the world. In the general case, a freeenterprise zone is a special geographical area in a country within which the usual prohibitions, red tape, regulations, intervention and bureaucracy do not apply. Government involvement is limited to providing for the public safety _ protecting the persons and property ofthe inhabitants. As well, there are Iimited-free-enterprise I zones, where only one or a few industries are freed of government interference. For example, there are free banking zones, free insurance zones, free gambling zones, free trade zones, where tariffs do not apply, and union-free zones, the type advocated by Phillips, where unions are not allowed. What are the advantages of union-free economic zones? Simply this. They will help create •• additional employment. The major economic cause of unemployment is government-mandated wage rates in excess of productivity levels. If the union demands $17 . per hour, but the worker can only produce goods and services worth $13 per hour, something has to give. Either the employer will refuse to comply in the first place, as in the case of Dominion Bridge, or will eventually be driven bankrupt. But this is perhaps the entire raison d'etre of labor unions. To drive wages up and up, in strict disregard for productivity levels - where wages would otherwise be set. The people of British Columbia, and of the rest of Canada as well, thus owe Don Phillips a debt of gratitude. If he can succeed in creating union.free zones, he will have taken a great step toward the reduction of unemployment. . Our union legislation was enacted in the first place because many people thought that without unions, wages would be set at levels dictated by employers. In point of fact this is untrue. Wages are determined by employee productivity, and competition between employers, not at the whim ofthe boss. We know this, because we cannot otherwise account for rising wages in times before the advent of unions in the late 19th century, in industries untouched by organized labor _ such as domestic service, legal secretaries, computer programmers - and in places such as Hong Kong, the Phillipines and the southern and southwestern states in the U.S., where unions are weak or nonexistent. September 29, 1984 * • * Hardy souls Were union-free economic zones instituted, those who favored unions would merely stay away. Outside these zones, they would still be able to avail themselves of the benefits they percieve are afforded by unions. In contrast, only those hardy souls who were willing to take their chances in a geographical area where present labor codes did not apply would enter the union-free zones. But B.C. Federation of Labor President Art Kube claims -free trade or free enterprise zones exist only in the Third World, in "countries which have dictatorships or something close to it, and which suffer from extreme poverty." In fact, this claim is at complete variance with the facts. Free enterprise zones of one variety or another are by no means limited to the impoverished nations of the Third World. On the contrary, there are hundreds located in Europe, the U.S. and the- Far East. According to a study on this subject published by the Fraser Institute entitled Free Market Zones, as of 1980 there were roughly 90 st-ch zones in Europe, 80 in Latin America, 60 in the U.S., 50 in Africa, 35 in the Far East -nd 20 in the Middle East. And this was only as of 1980. Since then the numbers have grown ever more. For example, the People's Republic of China had four zones in 1980, and has just announced the creation of 14 more. --Canada is practically alone in not having even one free-enterprise zone. This is particularly regrettable, given their success elsewhere in the world. WALTER BLOCK is senior economist at the Fraser Institute. Vancouver. Canada's National Journal of Business, Investment and Public Affairs C tlb ~ It BI k Union-free zones could relieve unemployment ,~~ ThE MINIMUM WAGE LAW DISCRIMINATES AGAINST YOUNG WORKERS prepared for the "Financial Post" by Walter Block, Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B. C. B.C. Labour Minister Terry Segarty has a problem, and is resolved to do something about it in the fall. The Province of British Columbia has the lowest minimum wage rate in the nation -$3.65 per hour - and tremendous pressure has been placed upon him to raise it at least to $4.00 per hour, the average level obtaining in the other nine provinces. At first blush, this would seem like a good idea, even one that is long overdue. If, as its name implies, the minimum wage law can boost wages up to whatever level is prescribed, that is to say set a floor under incomes for the poor, then why not? Surely the presently wobbling economy in Lotus Land could use a shot in the arm of that sort. But a moment's reflection will show that this is a mirage. For example, if prohibiting compensation below some arbitrarily determined level can really enhance salaries, why stop at the paltry, mean and niggardly $4.00 level? Why not go for, say, $40.00 per hour, or even better yet, really reach for the stars and demand that no employee be paid less than $400 per hour? The answer is obvious. To mandate that a skilled craftsman with a productivity level of $25.00 be paid $400.00 is to invite disaster. Any employer who complied would rack up $375.00 per hour in red ink. Even at the more modest $40.00 per hour, any such firm would still lost $15 per hour .and thus be forced into eventual bankruptcy. No, the reason wages are as high as they are has nothing whatever to do with legal compulsion. It is because productivity is relatively great in this country, and because salaries tend to be equal productivity levels, that we enjoy our relative prosperity. True, a minimum wage level of $4.00 would not threaten the livelihood of the person who can produce $25.00 worth of goods and services per hour, but it certainly can put at risk the jobs of people with lesser skills. For example, the employment of an individual who can only create goods valued by the market at $3.25 per hour, would sure to be obliterated by a minimum wage level of $4.00 per hour. How can we test the economic principle that high minimum wage levels lead to relatively increased unemployment rates for unskilled workers? One way is to calculate the unemployment rates of youthful Canadians as a percentage of those of the more highly productive adult employees in this nation, and then compare this figure with the minimum wage levels which apply in each of the provinces. (We choose workers between 20 and 24 as our control because this is the youngest group subject to the "adult" minimum wage law). Unemployment Rate for 20-24 year olds Provincial relative to employees Minimum Wage aged 25-i. Level 204% $4.00 213% $4.00 237% $3.80 206% $4.00 251% $4.00 289% $4.30 257% $4.25 182% $3.80 190% $3.65 n.a. $3.75 Newfoundland Nova Scotia New Brunswick Quebec Ontario Manitoba Saskatchewan Alberta British Columbia Prince Edward Island Source: Statistics Canada, Labour Department, May 1985 The results are painfully obvious. Manitoba, with the highest minimum wage level ($4.30) has the largest unemployment rate for its young workers, relative to the general population (289%). Saskatchewan, with the next greatest level ($4.25), weighs in with the second biggest relative unemployment rate for youth (257%). And at the bottom of the pack in terms of the disenfranchisement of their young people, come B.C. and Alberta with two of the country's lowest minimum wage levels. Are you listening, Mr. Segarty? Water by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. "Water, water, everywhere, but not a drop to trade." That, except perhaps for water in containers, seems to be the Canadian policy on the matter. Says International Trade Minister John Crosbie, "We're not going to let the Americans have any of our water. That's our policy." And according to Flora MacDonald, "We have introduced a water policy with regard to diversion of water in this country - prohibiting it." Nor is this strategy a partisan one. On the contrary, to the extent that Canadians are unified on anything, this would seem to apply to this one issue. Liberal Leader John Turner has been peppering the Tories for assurances that large scale diversions of fresh water not be allowed, and NDP trade critic Steven Langdon has gone so far as to call for emergency legislation on this matter. As can be expected, this sentiment is highly popular, too, in the environmentalist community. Mel Clark of the Rawson Academy of Aquatic Science has demanded that the U.S.-Canada free trade agreement be amended specifically to exclude water. And Waterwatch Canada has released a Gallup poll which indicates that seven out of ten Canadians don't want water, snow or ice exported to the U.S., and would be less likely to support a political party that allowed such occurrences. Water was named as our most essential natural resource in this survey, followed, distantly, by farmland and forests. Virtual unanimity of opinion, however, hardly guarantees common sense. It may only indicate that people tend to think in the same tired ruts. And this, unfortunately, applies to the present case. Among the disquieting elements in the present discussion is that it doesn't seem to have occurred to anyone to determine the price we might be offered in return for our precious but renewable, water resources. All participants act almost as if the question were one of giving this fluid away, for free. But trade is precisely that. It is not the unilateral making of a gift; it is, rather, an exchange of commodities. And under voluntary exchange, the presumption is that both parties gain; if they did not, there would hardly be mutual agreement to engage in it. Suppose, then, that our neighbors to the south were to offer us $10.00 per quart for this "vital bodily fluid." (This is how the commodity was referred to in the movie "Dr. Strangelove.") Is there any Canadian who would not be deliriously happy to sell water to the U.S. on these conditions? Why, by sending them a few trillion gallons under these conditions -- a mere pittance in terms of the astronomical availabilities- we could all be rich beyond our wildest dreams. Naturally, no one would rationally offer such an exalted price under today's conditions. Perhaps on the moon, or Mars, one day far in the future, not here and now. But the point still holds: crucial to a determination of whether it is in the interest of Canadians to sell water is what we would be offered in return. Without knowing that, we are not in a position to accept or decline such an offer. What if the price offered were more reasonable? Say, one penny per barrel? Then, the advantages and disadvantages might be more evenly balanced. Perhaps the best result under these stipulated conditions would be to meet part of the demand, in an attempt to obtain still more advantageous terms of trade. There is a great difficulty, however, in any such scenario. Water, unlike other natural resources, is not privately owned. Rather, it is possessed on much the same basis as are commodities in the preperestroika Soviet Union. That is, the government owns them. Under the inspired leadership of Chairman Gorbachev the Russians are battling valiantly to overthrow almost a century long dependence on central economic planning. Unfortunately, at the very time the Communists seem to be embracing the teachings of Adam Smith, politicians, pundits and professors in the west are urging a move in the very opposite direction. (The reactions against free trade, privatization and deregulation are cases in point.) It will not be easy to privatize water resources. Indeed, the very idea will appear ludicrous to many. But if we are to put water exports on a business basis, if we are to become international "drawers of water" at a time of drought, no less must be undertaken. - 302 The Exploitation of Women's Fashions According to American podiatrist William Rossi, writing in the Journal of the American Podiatry Association ("High Heels - the Agony and the Ecstasy"), women should not give up their high heeled shoes because they are sexy as all get out. Even though they're uncomfortable, and sometimes hurt like hell, "the high heel may well be the most potent aphrodisiac ever invented" said the good doctor. "When worn by women, the high heel sensuously alters the whole anotomy -- foot, leg, thigh, hip, pelvis, buttocks, breasts, etc." Strange sounds, indeed, emanating from the respected journal of the American Podiatry Association, usually devoted to more medicinal concerns. One would be temped to dismiss this article as the personal musings of a single disturbed foot fetishist -- were it not for the howls of outrage and dismay sent out by the anti-capitalist, radical feminist chorus. Based on this reaction, it would appear that the purpose of high heels is not at all to make women more sexually attractive to men. No, they have a far more insidious function -- to solidify business control over ladies fashions, the better to raise profits. According to this viewpoint, firms in the fashion business can manipulate ladies clothing styles, hem lengths, materials, colours, shoulder styles, frills, and certainly heel heights. They make sure that each season requires changes in one or more of these features, so that clothes bought last year are no longer in style, and new ones must continually be purchased. This is the way in which the outburst by Dr. Rossi can be explained, according to the radicals: the warehouses must be overflowing with boxes of high heeled shoes, and the podiatrists of the nation have been sent out to flog this unsold surplus. There are several flaws in this analysis, however. If the barons of clothing and footwear really exercise such control over women's purchasing habits, how is it that warehouses full of unsold goods ever develop? Why do bankruptcies ever occur in the fashion industry? Why does such manipulation occur only in women's styles, not men's? (Here, except for slight changes in lapel or tie widths, it is extremely difficult to tell if a suit is out of fashion.) Is it because the clothing and shoe moguls are sexists? How then to account for the fact that many of the leaders and innovators in women's clothing design are females? And why, pray tell, is there such fast, ferocious and furious competition in designer jeans, perfume, jewelry, and between the department stores which sell ladies fashions? Moreover, how can such monopoly-like control be wielded by so many tiny firms, who are far too numerous to even consider colluding? Some of the lowest industrial concentrations are found amongst the shoe and leather glove factories, hosiery and knitting mills, and in the fur goods industry. Women's clothing factorie~ and women's clothing contractors have the lowest, and the next to lowest four-firm concentration ratios, 6.3 per cent and 7.1 per cent, respectively, of all the almost two hundred different industries covered in this regard. (A four-firm concentration ratio is the proportion of the industry's sales, profits, capitalization, or in this case, value of shipments, accounted for by the largest four firrns.) No. it is impossible to sustain the thesis of a malevolent capitalist plot whose sole aim is to profiteer by making women physically uncomfortable in their clothing and shoes. An alternative explanation might run along the following lines: each year, the fashion designers hold their regular seasonal showings, where they exhibit their new lines -- and then advertise like mad in order to gain public acceptability. But the department shoe buyers -- the intermediaries, or agents, for the women who will make the actual final purchases -- exercise a thumbs up or thumbs down approval or disapproval role. If women accept uncomfortable shoes, or clothing -- whether motivated by a desire to appear attractive to the opposite sex, or as a result of custom, or for whatever other reason -- it is a result of their own free will. They always have the option of wearing non-fashionable styles, and paying whatever psychic cost this entails. Most men, too, might prefer to wear jeans, loafers, sports shirts and other leisurewear to business and formal occasions rather than neck-constricting ties, dress shirts and suits. They often take the uncomfortable path, just like women, not because they are puppets pulled on strings wielded by vicious sexist capitalists, but for a myriad of cultural, social and psychological reasons. - 303 I^A^ l^ Capitalism, Old and New by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute Critics of the free market have recently taken to distinguishing and old and a new version of capitalism. In their view, the capitalist pigs of yesteryear weren't really so awful after all, at least compared to the businessmen of today. The old timers may have abused our economy, but at least the robber barons of the 19th century left us a legacy of railroads, steel mills, automobile assembly plants, oil refineries, mines, steamships, and much, much more. They created meaningful goods, services and jobs on a massive scale. But what do the modern paper-pushing junk-bonding yuppie take-over artists leave in their wake? Nothing. Unlike their forebears, this new breed of capitalist adds no wealth to our nation. This attack on contemporary capitalism appears well taken, but only on the surface. First of all, not all capitalists in years gone by were actually involved in the production of physical goods or tangible services. Then, as now, market participants provided such "intangibles" as insurance, accounting, banking, intermediation, arbitration, etc. Second, one has only to mention recent consumer breakthroughs to realize that we have benefitted from a whole host of new-fangled products in the present era: computers, VCRs, bigger and better televisions, electronic games, air travel, more and more sophisticated telephones and other communication devices, etc. And the future, with robotics, genetic engineering, new medical discoveries, bodes well to provide us with even more of the same. In order to see the fallacy of this challenge, we must realize that the capitalist is, at bottom, an entrepreneur. All entrepreneurs have in common an ability to predict future demand, and to mobilize land, labour and capital to best meet consumer needs, especially those that have not yet become apparent. In order to do this, the entrepreneur engages in two sorts of speculations: through time and through space. In the latter case, he perceives that the market price of an item in two different areas deviates by more than transportation costs alone could account for. He purchases in the cheaper market, and sells in the dearer, thus transferring material from those who value it less to those who value it more. In the process, he of course enriches both, otherwise neither would have cooperated with him. In the former, the entrepreneur thinks he notices a discrepancy between factor and final goods prices, in this case to an extent greater than that which could be accounted for by the rate of interest. In other words, land, labour and capital (and this includes new ideas) are now trading in some markets below the prices that the ultimate goods shall be able to be sold for, when finally produced. So the entrepreneur takes a risk. He purchases these items, and ofttimes mobilizes them for entirely different and better purposes. But he never physically creates material goods, even in the "good old days" of capitalism. He merely takes factors of production that otherwise would have ended up, say, in the horse and buggy industry, and diverts them to other alternatives. Although this new critique of the market has a veneer of freshness, it is actually as old as the hills. Can't you just picture one cave man telling another that although exploitative, at least the old hunting system produced real red meat; in contrast, the present "gathering stage" of grubbing for roots and berries does not add anything substantial to the economy. Or a Luddite complaining that only farming is a legitimate economic activity; in comparison, the machinery of the "robber barons" is superfluous and superficial. (Actually, this is very similar to the message of the ^•1) physiocrats, an early school of economics.) In recent history, we have passed through the agricultural to the manufacturing stages. We have now arrived at the informational revolution. Sometime in the future, perhaps, we will move toward an economy based on something altogether different, perhaps space exploration. And then, the interventionist of the day will muse that the informational stage at least provided computers; space exploration will be just a waste of time, in his opinion, adding nothing to the well being of those still on earth. THE DEALER IN SPARE BODY PARTS I by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute Baby Fae with a transplanted baboon heart; Dr. Barney dark, with a transplanted artificial heart; hundreds of heart transplants, starting with those performed by the famed Dr. Christian Barnard of South Africa; these are amongst the episodes that have seized the headlines, and captured the imaginations of millions of people. But behind the headlines, there are numerous other medical procedures which have substituted diseased organs with healthy ones on an interpersonal basis. For example, liver, bone marrow, blood, cornea, eyes, and kidney. The Organ Donor Association of the U.S., however, reports that only X people have signed the donor card, which gives permission for the various body parts to be taken and used in medical procedures upon the sudden demise of the grantor. In Canada, the figure is Y. The Red Cross, moveover, reports a blank shortage of blood supplies, especially (Walter, the insert for page 2 that goes here does not make sense.) The reason Baby Fae had to make do with a baboon heart, and Dr. Barney dark with an artificial one, was that there was not a sufficiency of human hearts available for transplant. The problem with present institutional arrangements is that the free enterprise system is not fully allowed to operate. To be sure voluntary organizations — such as Z Associations — are allowed to do their good works and these, along with all other non-governmental initiatives must be considered part of the marketplace. But commercial concerns, buying up spare body parts and reselling them at a profit, are prohibited in most places in the world, and where they are not prohibited outright, their blank is severely limited. And with good reason, in the view of many people. The very idea conjures up visions of ghoulishness, Frankenstein experiments, grave robbing. Count Dracula gone beserk, Robin Cook plots, and other unsavory scenarios. Imagine. Allowing the evil merchants of profit to get their grubby hands on such an enterprise! By its very nature, these people contend, bodily transplants must be left to the voluntary private sector, or perhaps made a responsibility of government. But there are problems with this view. The voluntary organizations, as we have seen, have not produced the &quotgoods", at least in sufficient quantities. And there is always the danger that the government, the embodiment of force in society, will use compulsion to attain the goal the voluntary sector could not accomplish. The spectre of the state compelling people to sign these donor cards, despite their religious or ethical beliefs to the contrary, is one that we can do without, thank you kindly. How would a marketplace in used body parts function? It is impossible to ever fully anticipate the actions of 100's of profiteering entrepreneurs, each reading for an end (a sufficient quantity of raw material for transplants) beyond their intention (profit). However, a few general principles become clear upon consideration. One possibility, for example, would be to continue the present policy of signing donor cards, only now these commercial firms could offer money to those who signed. This could not help increase the numbers of donors. And if it did not do so sufficiently to supply all those in need of organs, the firms would have to raise prices paid until it did. In the case of blood, the Red Cross does, of course, pay for its supply. But its prices are too low, as shown by the fact that only insufficient quantities are brought forth. As well, it has failed to adopt a policyof differential prices, to reflect the relative shortages of the various types of blood. And there is no reason to believe that these private companies would not be able to increase the supply of this &quotfactor: in accord with demand. Entreprenuers in every other field of endeavour known to man — some mundane, some exotic — have been able to accomplish this task with no fuss or fanfare. But this would mean, would it not, that organ receipents would have to pay for these items. And isn't that unconscionable? Shouldn't people have the right to receive these vital items, necessary for life itself in many cases, free of charge. To make this claim is to laugh. Why should people receive bodily parts for free? These items have value. To mandate that recipients have them at no cost is to prohibit the donors, and the middleman - facilitaters, from being paid. After all, we do not prohibit the farmer, or the miller, baker, retailer, from earning money from the sole of bread, even though bread (and other food) is also necessary for life. If we did, we would find bread to be in short supply, just hike human organs. Under the present system of prohibited or controlled payments, many potential organ recipients thus cannot receive them. Surely they would be better off having them, even for a fee, than being forced to do without, with the dubious privilege of not being required to pay for what they cannot in any case have. Suppose that under these conditions, some intrepid entreprenuer were willing to start up a black market service in this field. That is, he would offer large sums of money to those willing to sign organ donor agreements with him, and would charge even larger amounts to doctors in need of these items for purposes of transplant. (We assume away the insuperable legal difficulties that would confront our organ businessmen at both ends of the transaction). The question is, would such as underground badily parts company be a benefit or a detriment? One argument for the latter view is that the firm, if successful, would tend to undermine respect for law and order. It would be thumbing its nose at the duly constituted authoriteis, who have so far remained adamant in declaring such 'ghoulish" sales and purchases illegal. As against that, it could be argued that any legal code which in effect if not by intention consigns innocent individuals to death (heart failure, for example) or to lives of misery (kidney dialysis machines) richly deserves to be ignored. But one point is clear. Our black market &quotghoul" will benefit organ donors, by offering them financial renumeration, as well as the satisfaction of knowing that the organs they may donate upon their devise will enable others to live. By doing so, it will, as we have seen, increase the number of organs made available, and this will be of inestimable benefit to those who might otherwise have been forced to go without. Now let us consider a case that really does have ghoulish attributes. Let us suppose that a marketplace in used body parts could not only work with donor cards, where the organ transfer takes place after the death of the donor. Let's assume that there would also be a market where live donors give up parts of their body — and then go on living. A heart transplant would be out of the question, but people could give up one (or even two) eyes(s), or one kidney, etc. Naturally, the price for a bodily part on this basis would tend to be higher than for that supplied only upon the death of the donor. But still, both parties to the transaction would benefit. True, the donor would give up a precious part of his body, at great inconvenience and rist, but the price he receives would more than compensate him for this onerous renunciation, otherwise he would not agree to do so. And of course the recipient would not agree to pay the outrageous expense unless the recipient of the organ was worth even more to him. But what about the case where the recipient was a old ne'er-do-well, lazy, shiftless millionaire heir, and the donor a young, healthy, brilliant, hard working person who had the misforturn to be born desperately poor, and needs large amounts of money for food to keep his family alive. Wouldn't an organ transplant from the latter to the former be exploitative? Anti thetical to public policy and the general good? The very idea seems replusive to most people. Part of the unsavoriness, however, arises from the nagging suspicion that it is unfair that the ne'er do well is fabulously wealthy, while the hard worker is desperately poor. Let us banish this from consideration, though. It is extrinsic to the case in point. Given the justice of their initial endowments of wealth, it is easy to see that both parties gain from the exchange, in that neither would enter into this commercial venture in the absence of such an expectation. And the experience of the Ethiopian famine of 198^ should underscore this point. If one of these unfortunates had been willing to give up a bodily part, so that he and his fellow sufferers could live, then any law enjoining such a possibility would not only be a grave injustice, but would consign these people to death. DEVIL MUSIC by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute A California teenager short himself in the head while lying in a bed he had just made -- an action urged in a suicide song by Ozzy Osbourne, a heavy-metal British rock star, brought to us courtesy of CBS Records. A part of the lyrics states: "... made your bed, rest your head, but you lie there and moan, where to hide, suicide is the only way out." As a result, the father of the young man, Mr. Jack McCollum, is suing CBS Records, the distributor. Jet Records, the recording company, Ozzy Osbourne the singer, plus two songwriters. He is seeking compensatory and punitive damages which could amount to millions of dollars. He is doing so, according to lawyer for the plaintiff Thomas Anderson a bornagain Christian, because under California law it is a felony to encourage anyone to commit suicide, "and this is exactly what these records do." In addition to the gory details, the case is buttressed by a finding in the coroner's report that the young McCollum committed suicide "while listening to devil music." There are several logical difficulties with the suit, despite this official report. First of all, it is a free speech issue, Mr. Anderson's views to the contrary notwithstanding. Impressionable people might be "driven" to suicide by all sorts of artistic offerings, besides the lyrics of rock music. If plaintiff wins his suit, there will be a chilling effect on novels and plays as well. Will any author dare include a scene in which one of the characters commits suicide? Further, there will be the risk that serious discussions of the phenomenon, even such as the present one, will some day be held liable for leading to untimely self-afflicted death. Secondly, there are grave philosophical problems with the proposition that one person can cause another to commit suicide, whether directly through exhortation, or indirectly, via movies, plays, or in our case, songs. This view flies in the face of the doctrine of free will, upon which our entire criminal code is predicated. If people are not responsible for their own acts, how can it be just to punish them? And if they are, how can we hold one person guilty for the suicide of another? The plaintiff's argument in this case deserves to be rejected. Further, he should be made to pay the defendant's expenses, and charged for bringing a frivolous and harassing suit. - 30 - 410 words Drugs and the Olympics by Walter Block, Fraser Institute Canada's Ben Johnson was stripped of his gold medal for the 100 metre dash in the 1988 Seoul Olympics. According to his coach Charlie Francis, this instance of drug taking is only the tip of the ice-berg. Numerous other Canadian athletes have been implicated in the use of anabolic steroids, and world class athletes from several other countries have been implicated. The main reaction on the part of the leading sports authorities is a call for a "war" on muscle building medications. There are several shortcomings with this approach, however. For one thing, there is a matter of arbitrariness. Why is it that anabolic steroids are banned while other performance enhancing drugs, such as cortisone and Xylocaine, are allowed? Even aspirin, for that matter, is a performance-enhancing drug. For another, who gives the Olympic and sports authorities the right to ban anabolic steroids? They are widely used in Canada for patients suffering from rheumatoid arthritis and other debilitating diseases, and are available upon prescription. Ben Johnson's doctor, after all, prescribed them for him, at least according to present testimony. The case of Eleanor Holm, a U.S. swimmer entered in the 1936 Olympics is a case in point. Avery Brundage, President of the 1.0.C. at that time, banned her from competition because she had imbibed a glass of champagne at a ship's party on the trip across the Atlantic to Berlin. There are many who would question his right to have done so. A further difficulty is that the war against these particular-performance enhancing drugs seems almost as futile as the war against addictive drugs such as cocaine and heroin. Keeping pace with the development of newer and better body building pharmaceuticals, and often outstripping it, is the technology necessary to disguise their use. Whatever the shortcomings, there is a clear need to establish some sort of rules that everyone must follow. "A level playing field" is a much abused notion when applied to free trade, but when it comes to sports, it is vital. If there is no commonality to which sports participants must be held, the whole point of athletic competition vanishes. We might as well assign some people to the starting line, and others either 10 yards behind, or in front. The big question is, What must be equalized? In high schools and colleges, the amount of training is subjected to egalitarian considerations: team practices are limited to a specified number of weeks. This is not done in professional endeavors. In swimming there is virtually no difference in the type of equipment used. In sailboating and car racing, there are gigantic disparities. Here, the competition is as much between men as between gear. Bicycle racing could equalize the apparatus, by random assignments, but has chosen not to do so. The point is, some sort of equalization must be imposed, but its dimensions are not given to us from on high. The present scandal stems from the fact that commonality cannot now be achieved. We can impose stricter and more frequent controls, but we can only hope that the testing mechanisms will be able to overcome those which mask drug usage. A more radical solution to the present drug scandal is the suggestion that the rules be relaxed completely: allow everyone to take the muscle building drug of his choice. The problem with this is that we will no longer know of what the human body - unaided by drugs -- is capable; we will only see the result of the combination of such artificial stimulants plus training. (Yes, these materials may be harmful. But we're talking about adults here, and they have the right to weigh the pros and cons and decide such issues for themselves.) A compromise is to urge the creation of two completely different sections of the Olympic games (and all other related professional sports activities). One would be an "open" division, where medications of all kinds and varieties would be allowed. The other would be a "closed" division, open only to the drug free. Every subsequent world record would have an asterisk, or not, depending upon drug usage. This is no panacea; no compromise known to man ever is. We would still face the difficulty of drug users posing as drug free athletes. But this compromise would go a long way toward resolving a most perplexing difficulty, since with two divisions, there would be less incentive to cheat. - 30 - The Economics of the Parole System by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. In 1971 Allan George Foster brutally raped and murdered his 18 year-old sister-in-law. He was caught, sentenced and served 10 years of his jail term. He was released in 1981 on full parole, having been "rehabilitated," at least in the opinion of the so-called expert psychiatrists responsible for rendering this decision. The parole officers were unequivocal in their positive assessment of Foster. Said Vasha Starrie, his case management officer at Agasiz Mountain Prison: "I thought he had dealt with the (1971) offence and had developed character features that made him open and reliable." Further "He is one of the sanest people I have ever met ... a highly sensitive and intelligent person." According to psychologist Clifford Ratzlaff, who subjected Foster to an intensive battery of tests, "He appears to have overcome the life stress that caused him to flip out (in 1971) and take the life of another person." Late last yenr. however, this sane well-adjusted person struck again. This time the victims were his common-law wife Joan Pilling, 34, her daughter Linda Brewer, 12, and Brewer's school friend Megan Sue McCleary, also 12. Luckily for society, he committed suicide after this outbreak, because this second series of ghastly crimes would have allowed him yet another parole after 25 yearsprovided he could have convinced another set of dogooding experts of his intrinsic goodness. What does this gory tale have to do with economics? The murderer's own assessment of his situation was apropos to this point. Said Foster: "There is only one thing crazier than me and this is the society that let's me do what I do." But it is possible to pinpoint more exactly the precise locale of the craziness in 49 society. First and foremost it is a system which severs the connection between action and responsibility. The psychological experts, and the parole board members who rely on them make decisions that affect the rest of us in crucial ways. Yet, they are neither rewarded when they correctly assess these prisoners, nor, more important, are they penalized in any way when they are tragically wrong. Adam Smith stated so eloquently that it is not from benevolence but from self interest that the butcher and the baker provide their wares for us. But if these entrepreneurs had as little selfish interest as do the parole boards, we would all starve. Secondly, we must note that the Foster case is symptomatic of government failure. The state bureaucracy necessarily lacks the magic of the marketplace, and the supurb incentive system imposed by the lure of profits and the fear of losses. Incarceration of prisoners and parole are now responsibilities of the public sector. Given this state of affairs we must look toward privatization of these roles as a means of improving matters. Government is clearly derelict in its duty; and intrinsically so. It is thus difficult to see how private enterprise could do anything: but bring us a more socially responsible parole system. EXPO Walter Block The Fraser Institute Expo has gone out a blaze of glory, with a gigantic fireworks display accompanied by a Provincial-wide orgy of mutual self congratulation. In the afterglow of this splendid occurrence, critics can scarcely expect tci be heralded. However, certain aspects of the World's F'air need to be examined so that we do not draw the wrong public policy conclusions from it. That there were successes, no one can doubt. The original plans called for some 13 million visitors; in the event, over 20 million showed up, courtesy of good weather -- and heightened terrorist activities in Europe. In addition, EXPO was expected to lose a cool $310 million although the final and definitive iJigures are not yet in, it looks as if the shortfall will be significantly below that figure. In fact, the triumph was so great that the Social Credit party was able to rely heavily on this factor for its recent electoria1 win at the po11ing booths. But there were neqative aspects as well, and when these are balanced against positives, it is unclear that the people of British Colurctbia really turned out to be beneficiaries. Expense Let us first consider the large loss of money involved. This was an expenditure of huge proportions. While ordinary private businesses do ofttimes indeed suffer financial setbacks, they are never undertaken on purpose, nor contemplated with equanimity in advance, as was done in this case. And the reason is simple. People don't usually intend to lose their own hardearned cash. Those who do so, usually end up with little or nothing to show for their efforts. Had Jimmy Pattison treated revenues earmarked for EXPO s his own, for example, it is unlikely in the extreme that he would have spent them in this way. There is a social .justification for this phenomenon as well. Business losses imply that the revenues spent on the product by the entrepreneur were not valued as greatly by the paying customers. If EXPO ends up losing $300 million, we can deduce from that fact alone that the public valued the resources spent on this World's Fair precisely this much more than the benefits derived therefrom. This means that consumer welfare would have been $300 million higher had these monies been allowed to stay in the hands of their original owners, instead of being taken from them in the form of taxes. Had these dollars not been allotted to the public sector, they could have been spent in the ordinary way-- on toasters and skateboards, radios and cabbages, videos c-ind furniture -- and the people of the province would have been better off to the tune of some $300 million. A Party One argument in behalf of EXPO, intended to defend it against the charge of losing money, is that this event "was one vast party in behalf of all of British Columbia, and like it or not, parties cost money." True, all too true. Festivities are indeed indeed expensive, and the bigger and more lavish they are, the more they cost. But gala events are usually put on, and paid for, by the party giver. The invited quests may bring a present (although this is never mandatory) , but they are not forced to pay an admission price at the gate, nor to make up any shortfalls through increased taxes which would otherwise not have had to have been collected. If the leading politicians of B.C. had really wanted to give a party, and to do so in the manner in which most people engage in this activity, they could have invited anyone they had wanted to, but paid for it with their own money! Tourism A more serious attempt to defend the vast EXPO losses is to claim that they were really an investment in tourism for the province. But this, too, is problematic. If promoting future visits from out of towners were the goal, why build EXPO? Why not just subsidise their travel costs to Vancouver? After al1, it was recognised by everyone that EXPO would not last forever. The fair was seen only as the bait through which hordes of foreigners could be induced to see the many natural beauties of our province. But surely we could have enticed many more people to the lower mainland by paying their way here, than by setting up a world's fair, and charging them for the privilege of viewing it. Even this criticism does not go deeply enough. It accepts as given the desirability of subsidizing the tourist sector, and argues only that EXPO was an inefficient means toward that end, But we can ca1l into question the premise that it makes good public policy sense for government to artificially promote tourism. Once the issue is posed in this manner, it is not clear that there is a case for taking the revenues of the populace as a whole and diverting them into any one industry. First of all, why tourism? Why not forestry, or mining, or real estate, or farming, or frisbee production, for that matter? All of these employ thousands of people (or perhaps could, with a heavy enough subsidy), and are fine upstanding industries in their own right. Why is their claim to government largesse any the less than that of tourism? Secondly, if the EXPO ploy succeeds and the tourist sector does indeed receive a shot in the arm, the owners of the individual hotels, motels, trailesr camps, restaurants, gift shops, etc, are the ones who will mainly benefit. Why should they be allowed to recoup, based on the investment funds derived from the entire populace? Is it fair to ask all British Columbians, many of whom are far poorer than the businessmen in the tourist sector to finance investment aimed to help the latter? Such perverse income redistribution is hardly in the public interest. Further, in the free enterprise system, it is the consumer, not the producer, who is presumably sovereign. Money is not funneled into firms or industries at the behest of businessmen anxious to enhance their revenues, by government bureaucrats, who desire to control other people's property. On the contrary, disbursements are based solely on the desires of the paying customer. Given this system, there is no warrant to take money from all the people, and simply give it to the tourist industry (in the form of EXPO), since had consumers wished for this occurrence, they were perfectly free to re-order their priorities on their own accounts. Every penny spent on EXPO, it must be remembered, was a penny that could not be utilized for other goods and services. And in the view of the consumer, welfare was enhanced by spending it his own way, not in the manner designed by the well-intentioned government in Victoria, for a World's Fair. Lottery Had EXPO been financed through tax revenues, the case against it would have been simple, complete, and airtight. People would have been forced to pay through taxes for an item they could have supported through the stock market, but their funds were never solicited in this manner. However, the losses from this event have been funded not through the Finance Ministry, but out of the revenues of the B.C. lottery system. This completes the analysis, since it can no longer unambiguously be contended that the citizenry was forced to yield up revenues against its will, as would be true for the tax system. Despite this complication, there is still a case to be made against the financing of EXPO. For one thing, there is a curtailment of full free choice involved here: while the public can indeed choose whether or not to buy a lottery ticket, options have been circumscribed by the fact that only the government may legally offer to provide such a service. Apart from this, the monies raised from the lottery could have been used to defray the provincial deficit, or to 1ower other taxes. This would have benefitted the public, given that the people are able to spend their money in a way that can better promote their interests than can governement expenditures. As a result, even if no taxes at all are used to pay for the EXPO losses, taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been but for this event. The world's fair thus cannot be justified as a gigantic provincial party, nor as an "investment" in tourism, or excused on the basis that it was not supported by tax revenues. If anything, EXPO most resembles the bread and circuses given to the populace by the Roman emperors two millennia ago. And it certainly cannot he defended on these grounds, at least not in the modern era. Flag Burning by Walter Block In the libertarian philosophy, free speech rights are interpreted as but an aspect of the more basic rights to private property. For example, if someone breaks into my house at 3:00 A.M., and starts reading in a loud voice the sonnets of Shakespeare, he may not properly object if I toss him bodily out onto the street that I have violated his rights of free speech. He has no rights of free speech -- on my property. He has such rights only on his own property, or on that (a hall, auditorium, newspaper advertisement, etc.) which he has rented from someone else. - 30 December 27,1989 The Financial Post Opinion March 28, 1981 19 Column by Walter Block There is evidence foreign aid can often be counterproductive The prime minister's recent whirlwind globetrotting trip on behalf of a closer NorthSouth dialogue makes it a good time to review Canadian foreign aid policy. At first blush, aid to underdeveloped countries seems noble, humanitarian, and serendipitously, in our own national interest as well. After all, Canadian aid to the less fortunate nations surely must save people from starvation, encourage the development of primitive economies, increase our exports and enhance freedom by forestalling the spread of communism. There is much evidence, however, showing aid programs to be questionable means toward these worthy ends. Further, there are indications that private trade and investment, currently shackled and hampered by tariff and import barriers in the Western industrial countries, may be more efficacious than intergovernmental transfers. Economic development Food grants arc a major part of foreign aid, and Canada is the world leader here, meeting about 30% of its bilateral commitments in this form. (Canada funnels 70% of its total donations bilaterally; 30% is given through multilateral channels such as the Organization for Economic Co-operation & Development.) Foodstuffs are obviously basic, because the malnutrition which unfortunately prevails in many less developed countries is one of the blocks to economic betterment. But compelling humanitarian requirements in cases of actual famine aside, even this sort of aid is fraught with danger: massive gifts can take the profit incentive out of local agriculture; with fewer farmers and less land under cultivation, this can paradoxically worsen, not improve, the long-term prospects of food production and hence safety from future starvation. Capital grants are likewise destructive to long-term productivity. Although the ancient Egyptian pyramids were an extraordinary instance of capital accumulation, they resulted in no economic gain in the basic sense of contributing to the well-being of the great masses of people. Even more wasteful are the modem equivalents of such monument-building made possible by foreign aid: the steel mills in Egypt, the modem chemical plants in India, the tractors given to aboriginal peoples who cannot operate them, the automobile assembly plants scattered widely throughout the Third World (which are the result of protective tariffs on automobile imports as well). These are wasteful because the products fabricated in this highly technological manner actually cost the underdeveloped countries more to manufacture themselves than they could have paid by importing the finished product from more developed countries. Many people deduce from the fact that the rich countries have much capital and the poor ones little that what is required is vast capital infusions. But this wet-sidewalkscause-rain reasoning points to almost the exact opposite of what is really needed. Capital, in and of itself, does not create wealth. It is rather the result of a process of economic development that also includes, as complementary factors, such things as the willingness to work, the skill and education of the labor force, and relatively free and private markets protected by a stable code of laws. One indication of the importance of these other phenomena is the fact that a large proportion of the very limited capital generated in the poor countries is actually invested in the more advanced nations, where private property rights are far more secure. Then there is foreign aid in the form of technological and other education. Canada ranks third among the donor nations in this category, behind only France and New Zealand, meeting just over 15% of its bilateral commitments to the underdeveloped world in this form. But the difficulty is that in the absence •of such facilities as fully equipped laboratories, libraries, computer centres, and without the mutual support of thousands of other similarly educated scientists and technologists, such aid cannot be efficiently utilized. And the proof can be seen in the immigration patterns of the educated classes in the Third World a "reverse brain drain," toward the more advanced countries. Foreign aid of whatever variety — food, capital, technology or outright. cash grants — moreover sets up a welfare-like dependency status on the recipient country. In much the same manner as domestic welfare programs sap the economic ambition, vitality and progress of their local clients, so do programs on international levels have similar effects. Canadian self-interest If foreign aid is unlikely to help the recipient, can it at least help the donor? (Note: the focus here is on economic, not military aid, which must be justified on entirely different grounds.) Pragmatic considerations would seem to support this view. For one thing, the Canadian International Development Agency requires that about 80% of its bilateral disbursements be spent on Canadian goods and services. But behind the bookkeeping legerdemain, this amounts only to a free gift of goods and services from Canada to other countries, with no offsetting returns. No one is foolish enough to •suppose that West German reparations to Israel actually benefited the economic selfinterest of West Germany — even though much of it took the form of exporting domestic items. Nor does the defendant in a civil case rejoice in his new-found wealth when he is forced by a court decision to compensate the plaintiff— even in the form of goods Ie himself produces. Will Canadian aid to other countries at least make it more likely that they will choose the path of democracy and market institutions rather than fall into the communist and collectivist ambit? Unfortunately, not only will Western foreign aid not attain this end — it is likely to undermine it, and instead to encourage socialism and totalitarianism :in the Third World. First of all, Canadian aid is traditionally in the form of govcmmcnt-to-gov-emment grants. This strengthens the role of the public vs the private sector in the underdeveloped countries. But political freedom is a delicate and precious flower, it cannot live where the bulk of economic activity is carried on in the public sector. Second, Canadian foreign aid has been given to countries that have made explicitly socialist avowals in their centralized economic plans — and our largesse has in no small degree shielded them from the repercussions of such policies and allowed them to continue unchecked down this path. For example, we find in the five-year plan of India, a country which continues to receive strong Canadian support, the view that "planning should take place with a view to the establishment of a socialistic pattern of society where the principal means of production are under social ownership or control." The alternative Of far greater benefit to the nations of both North and South is a policy of free trade and unregulated international flows of capital. This will greatly benefit the Canadian standard of living, as we can purchase many goods such as clothing from the* less developed world for far less than it costs to make them ourselves. But of far greater importance, such policies will truly lead to Third-World economic development — and to tighter integration with our own economy. How, then, to account for the hypocrisy of a nation whose leaders loudly proclaim their interest in economic development for the poor countries and yet remain steadfast in their determination to maintain protective tariffs, quotas and other impediments to economic intercourse with the Third World? walter BLOCKis senior economist at the Eraser Institute, Vancouver. A FREE MARKET IN KIDNEYS? by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute According to recent reports, the black market value of a kidney which can be transplanted is some $13,000 -- which translates to roughly seven times its weight in gold. Such an occurrence may occasion all sorts of references to King Midas -- who was supposed to have been turned into a statue of sold gold, but behind this rather dramatic way of characterizing the value of human organs lies in a story of untold and tragic human suffering. There are hundreds and even thousands of Canadians whose lives could be vastly improved could they but have the use of a healthy kidney. Paradoxically, there are other thousands of people who die each year, taking perfectly healthy kidneys to the grave with them, who have no financial incentive at all to bequeath these organs to those in need. Why, it may well be asked, cannot potential donors presently be given a pecuniary reward for doing the right thing? That is, what precludes a businessman from purchasing the future rights to a kidney from potential donors, and then selling these items to those suffering from kidney disease? The problem is, it is illegal to harness marketplace incentives in order to encourage kidney donors. Anyone who set up a business of this sort would be summarily imprisoned. Instead, our society must resort to all sort of inefficient stratagems toward this end. Famous personages have exhorted us, in the event that we suffer untimely death, to make a posthumous gift of these organs. Medical schools coach their students on the best techniques for approaching next-of-kin; the difficulty is that they must ask permission at the precise time when they are least likely to be given it -- upon the sudden demise of a loved one. As a result, all of this has been to little avail. While potential recipients languish on painful kidney dialysis machines waiting ghoulishly for a traffic fatality which may spell life for them, the public has refused to sign cards in sufficient numbers giving permission for automatic posthumous donor status. Things have even come to such a pass that there are grotesque and fascistic plans now being bruited about which would allow the government to seize the kidneys of accident victims unless they have signed cards denying such permission. The free enterprise system, were it allowed to be operated in this instance, might well be a God-send to the unfortunates who suffer from diseased kidneys. A legalized marketplace could encourage thousands of donors. Would you sign a card donating your kidney after death for 13,000 big ones, right now, in cold hard cash? There are very few people who would turn up their noses at such an offer. And if sufficient supplies were still not forthcoming at this level, prices would rise even further until all demand was satisfied. Given free enterprise incentives, pardon the pun, we would be up to our armpits in kidneys. This is the tried and true process we rely on to bring us all the other necessities of life: food, clothing and shelter. After all, we do not depend for the provision of these goods and services on voluntary donations. We know this to be a relatively unreliable system -- notwithstanding the fact that it is flogged by numerous opinion leaders in the case of organ transplants. There is no doubt whatsoever that those presently responsible for preventing a free market in kidneys take these actions with the noblest of motives. To them, legalizing the purchase and sale of human organs would be the ultimate in degradation. Far better, from their viewpoint, that people donate their bodily parts for free so that thousands of kidney disease sufferers may live normal lives. However, no matter how benevolent the intentions of the prohibitionists, it cannot be denied that the effect of their ill-conceived actions is to render it less likely that those in need shall be served. It is time, it is long past time, for our society to put aside its archaic and prejudicial opposition to the marketplace, so that we can relieve the suffering, and in many cases, lift the death sentence we have inadvertently placed on as hopeless and hapless a group of citizens as ever existed. 30 October 28, 1986 The Free Trade Agreement and Job Creation By Walter Block Nowhere in the debate over the Free Trade Agreement has more economic confusion been allowed to run rampant than with regard to the question of job creation. According to the Economic Council of Canada, 250,000 net new jobs - that is, the total number created minus the total number lost - are likely to come into being as a result of the FTA. Brian Mulroney, perhaps the nation's number one cheerleader for the deal, hasten quoting this figure at the drop of a hat. Other pro free trade forces have not been slow on the uptake to parrot these figures. The opposition has been claiming that net job creation will be lower or even negative - more will be lost than generated -- or contenting themselves with the claim that such employment opportunities which arise will be of the hamburger flipping variety. The truth of the matter is that no permanent job creation whatsoever will occur as a result of free trade. Nor is this a /controversial matter within the profession of economics. The puzzle is that a group of reputable economists, such as presumably form the staff of the Economic Council of Canada, could have committed such a basic and elementary fallacy. Not that this is all to the bad: anything that promotes free trade will improve the lot of the average Canadian, and sometimes even falsehoods, as in this case, can prove beneficial. But there is a higher calling than mere economic prosperity for Canadians, and that is the pursuit of the truth, where ever it leads us. It is in view of this latter, more important goal that it behooves us to pierce the veil of ignorance surrounding the Council's claim, and to set the record straight. Why is it that the FTA will not create jobs, not a single one of them? The reason for this is simple. Free trade has nothing at all to do with employment. Its only effect will be on the kind of jobs available, not with their number. In order to see this quite clearly, we have to go back to fundamentals; we must reflect on what jobs are, why people want them, what are their economic purposes. Please excuse this voyage down memory lane, back to the introductory economics studied a decade or more ago, but with a fallacy as basic as this one that is our only option. A job is defined as something we would not do for its own sake. Those of us who earn a salary doing something we would be happy to do without compensation are really engaging in "play." The rest of us working slobs do so but because of the wages we are given in return. Why work at all, even for pay? We do so because we live in an environment of scarcity; that is, there are goods and services we cannot have unless we create them, and working is the way in which we produce things. If all sorts of manna continually rained down on us (food, clothing, shelter, VCRs, medical cures, sportscars), and no one wanted anything that was not in this way given to us, then no one would work. We would all play. Some of the "play" might be interesting and important-research, exploration, the arts - but it would still not be work in the technical economic sense. Why do employers hire people to work for them? Because of the productivity given to them by their employees. If a worker could not add to the value of the product created by the firm, he would be unemployable. And the wage he is paid in the market tends to reflect the value of his contribution. Given the importance of work in the real world, why do we have unemployment? There are all sorts of reasons, but most of them amount to government insisting that workers be paid more than their productivity levels. On the micro level, enactments such as minimum wages, fair labour standards, union legislation in effect price potential suppliers of labour out of the market. As well, unemployment insurance and generous welfare payments create joblessness by subsidizing it. On the macro level, government interference with the money supply, interest rates, stock markets and business decisions can render the economy unstable, and lead to recessions and depressions. Joblessness, however, can also occur in the free unfettered market. Frictional unemployment ensues when people are searching for situations; they are in between jobs, or are looking for a first job, or are rejecting present offers in the hope of better ones in future. How many jobs are there in an economy at any given time? As many as there are people willing to work. That is, as many as there are people who want more material goods than they have, and value these items more than the leisure they must forego when they become employed. New jobs are not something vouchsafed by governments upon a grateful citizenry, although ofttimes governments like to take credit for this process ("We created 4.2 million jobs over the last decade.") The fact that most new jobs are created by small businesses is irrelevant; if there were no small businesses, the jobs would emerge in large businesses or in self employment. Ra,ther, new employment slots occur automatically in the market, whenever people want them. When millions of new immigrants came to the U.S. at the turn of the century, no one had to create the millions of new jobs for them. They were created because these newcomers wanted to purchase goods and services, and were willing to trade their labour power in order to do so. And the same applies to the demobilization of millions of soldiers at the end of the war, and to the rise in labour force participation of women in the past few decades, or any other sudden onset of a need for more jobs. These people, too, achieved employment status, not through government, but through the magic of the marketplace. If jobs are limited only be people's desire to work, how then can a free trade agreement increase employment? The answer, it should now be clear, is that an end to tariffs and other such barriers cannot raise the number of a nation's jobs. The only thing that can increase employment slots is an additional number of people seeking work. All free trade can do is multiply the efficiency with which individuals labour. That is, instead of producing rice ourselves, directly, we can trade for rice produced in Texas or Louisiana with, say, maple syrup. Since Canadians are poor rice producers, but wise in the ways of all things having to do with the maple tree, we can, paradoxically, have more rice for the same amount of effort expended not by producing it ourselves, but by first gathering the syrup, and then trading it for rice. In similar manner, the carpenter can get more piano lessons, and the piano teacher more kitchen cabinets, not by doing the work of the other, but by sticking to one's own specialty, and then exchanging for the expertise of the other. Even were it possible, it is not advisable to raise the number of jobs that need to be done. We could, for example, increase employment opportunities merely by prohibiting railroads, and demanding that the cargo they used to haul be transported, instead, by people carrying 50 pound sacks on their backs. This could create work for literally trillions of people! But the important point to realize here is that we would not thereby necessarily expand the number of jobs available. Remember, people are already working to their desired extent (except for governmentally created unemployment - and there is no reason to expect that this rate will change as we embrace free trade); if we abolish railroads, the same number of people will still be working. Only now more of them, many, many more of them, will be needed to transport goods; consequently, fewer will be available to do other more important work. Society would suffer, poverty would increase, but joblessness need not change by one iota. The Gap between Science and Public Policy by Walter Block Our scientists and engineers are able to create automobiles capable of safely doing 150 miles per hour, at least on the straightaways. In the event, however, these cars do 10 m.p.h. in bumper to bumper rush hour traffic, courtesy of a public policy mired in the horse and buggy days. Our doctors are now capable of transplanting organs from one person to another. This is an art which would have been inconceivable just a few short years ago. Indeed, even today it still seems magical. But do not rejoice too quickly. Thanks to legislative ineptitude, there is a shortage of available kidneys, eyes, livers, hearts and lungs. Because of technology, we now have airplanes at our disposal that can cross the continent, a distance of some 3500 miles, in a matter of six hours or so. And yet all too often, before we even start out, there is a delay of several hours; and when we arrive, we are all too likely to find ourselves stacked up in a parade of airplanes waiting to touch down. Because of breakthroughs in building construction, it is now possible to create sufficient low cost housing for all Canadians. And yet in Ontario, presently the most prosperous of all the provinces, there are long queues of people futilely searching for rental suites. Why is it that physical scientists are able to supply society with such miraculous accomplishments on a seemingly endless basis, while our public policy, the domain of economists, is in such disarray that we are often precluded from the full enjoyment of what might otherwise be available to us? The short and simple answer to this question is that the findings of economics, are all too often completely ignored in public policy making. Take the four problems mentioned at the outset. They are all cases where public policy has failed to come to grips with the concept of supply and demand. According to this elementary bit of economic analysis, if a price minimum or price floor is placed on a good or service, there will be an excessive demand; more will be desired by the public than can be offered. With rent control, landlords are limited in the rents they may charge. Hence, new investors avoid this market like the plague. Tenants not only find it difficult to obtain housing, but paradoxically must even sometimes pay more for it than if incentives to build rental suites were not cut off at the knees. Present law prohibits the sale of human organs for transplant purposes. This, effectively, sets a zero price on such transactions. As a result, potential donors have less incentive than they would otherwise have to sign pledge cards, and many recipients are consigned to inferior medical techniques (e.g., kidney dialysis machines) and even to death, the ultimate degradation. Road and airport congestion are examples of the peak load problem. The demand for such services rises at certain times of the day. But unless there is a flexible pricing system in place which reflects the demand alterations, excessive demand, or crowding, are the inevitable result. . So the economic answers to all these problems are obvious and easy to operationalize: repeal rent control to end the housing shortage; allow commercial transactions in human organs, and alleviate the suffering of recipients who must now do without; and inaugurate a peak load pricing system to cure highway and airport congestion. "Easier said than done," is one possible response to these modest proposals. "Forget it," is the more likely assessment of those in charge of public policy planning. Which leads us to ask why the advice of economists is often ignored, while that of physical scientists is almost always implemented. There appear to be two main reasons. For one thing, self interest. Powerful people have much at stake with regard to economic arrangements; very rarely do special interests have anything to gain or lose in a dispute over theories in physics or chemistry. For another, very few non economists have much humility when it comes to questions of economics. People will often say, "I'm not an economist, but..." and then proceed to rhapsodize about their theories of economics. But no one says "I'm not a physicist, but..." and then articulates his views on this arcane science. The importance of German private property - 30 1. 3 Dr. Block is an economist with the F raser Insfifllt~_ uring and after the Second World War thousands of Germans fled their homes. They migrated to the four comers of the earth: Australia, South America, Western Europe, the U.S. In our own country, they formed the backbone of what is now the German-Canadian community, one known for its work ethic, its strong family orientation, its stick-to-itiveness and its intellectual brilliance. Now that East Germany has united with its western counterpart. its government has decided, quite appropriately, to take on the trappings of capitalism. Foremost amongst these is the institution of private property rights. In this regard it has embarked on a program of returning land. farms, homes and factories to their rightful owners. a policy for which it should be heartily congratulated. And it is one that should be emulated by all of the countries that formerly suffered behind the Iron Curtain. This visionary and courageous program, however, has run into several difficulties. First of all, the government has decided to exempt from the plan all property seized between May 8, 1945, and October 6, 1949, prior to the founding of the late-but-not-lamented German Democratic Republic. This is intolerable. Just because people emigrated does not mean it is legitimate to seize their property. There is simply no legitimate statute of limitations on justice. As long as the property owners have proof of titJe-photographs, letters, records. etc.-it should not matter whether their homes and farms were expropriated before. during or after the aegis of any particular government. There is a second problem as well: the irresolution of the government. Stated Petra Speyrer, vice-consul for Germany in Vancouver: "It will take years and years. I am sure. to resolve (the land ownership issue). First of all, you have to find out whether to give property back or compensate with money. If money, then how much? How do you find out the value of the land? I am sure there will be a lot of lawsuits because people will wan! their land back and not JUS! money. It is very complicated:' With all due respect, the issue is not complicated at all. On the contrary, it is exceedingly simple. Of course it is the land and physical property that should be returned-nothing else. If the rightful owners want money instead, they are free to sell their holdings for whatever the market dictates. "How much" should be no business at all of a state run under the principles of free enterprise. (It is only in the case of property destruction-which does not in any case apply to land, certainly not to its site value-that such thorny problems could conceivably arise. But this is a small part of the privatization effort.) There is another reason besides pure justice for returning property to its rightful owners: pragmatism. In most advanced economies, labour accounts for some 75C;C of the Gross Domestic Product. The rest-rent, interest, profit, etc.-is created by the other factors of production. The entire land of a nation, according to most responsible estimates, is responsible for less than 10%. The property in question in what was formerly East Germany is a tiny fraction of even this amount. So in returning it all to the foreign nationals of German extraction who are its rightful owners, Germans will lose very little indeed. But they will gain immeasurably. For what these economies lack at present more than anything else in the world is the entrepreneurial spirit. And there could be no better demonstration of the fact that not only is entrepreneurship welcomed in these countries. it is treasured, than to give back the land-all of it, without any strings attached-to irs rightful owners. The countries of Eastern Europe are crying out for investment. What do you think will occur if they make a clean break with the past and return this stolen property? The likelihood is that the new owners will return for at least part of the year--bringing with them millions of dollars of investment funds, and, far more important, their skills and talents. Down that path leads Germany and Eastern Europe to industrial peace, material prosperity and a true market economy. If these countries persist in their stinginess in the return of stolen property, they may keep for themselves a few additional thousands of acres of land, but these holdings will never become very valuable, because without a free and vibrant economy none of the factors of production amount to very much. D BRITISH COLUMBIA REPORT, MARCH 11, 1991 i3 Private German Property by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. Thousands of Germans fled their property during and after World War II, from what was then East Germany. They migrated to all four corners of the earth: to Australia, to South America, to Western Europe, to the U.S. In our own country, they formed the backbone of what is now the German-Canadian community, one known for its work ethic, its strong family orientation, its stick-to-itiveness and its intellectual brilliance. N ow that East Germany is on its way to a life of freedom, forming once again a united country with its western counterpart, its government has decided, quite appropriately, to take on the trappings of capitalism. Foremost amongst these is of course the institution of private property rights. In this regard they have embarked upon a program of returning land, farms, homes and factories to their rightful owners, a policy for which they should be heartily congratulated. It is one which should be emulated by all of the countries which formerly suffered behind the Iron Curtain. This visionary and courageous program, however, has run into several difficulties. First of all, the government has decided to exempt from this plan all property seized between May 8, 1945 and October 6, 1949 prior to the founding of the late but not lamented and so called German Democratic Republic. But this is intolerable. Just because people emigrated, does not mean it is legitimate to seize their property -- and this applies regardless of the official auspices under which such acts were undertaken. There is simply no legitimate statute of limitations on justice. As long as the property owners have proof of title -- pictures, letters, records, etc. -- it should not matter whether their homes and farms were expropriated before, during or after the aegis of any particular government. There is a second problem as well: the irresolution of the government. Stated Petra Speyrer, vice-consul for Germany in Vancouver: "It will take years and years, I am sure, to resolve (the land ownership issue). First of all, you have to find out whether to give property back or compensate with money. If money, then how much? How do you find out the value of the land? I am sure there will be a lot of lawsuits because people will want their land back and not just money. It is very complicated." With all due respect, the issue is not complicated at all. On the contrary, it is exceedingly simple. Of course it is the land and physical property which should be returned -- and not anything else. If the rightful owners want money instead, they are free to sell their holdings for whatever the market dictates. "How much?" should be no business at all of a state run under the principles of free enterprise. (It is only in the case of property destruction -- which does not in any case apply to land, certainly not to its site value -- that such thorny problems could conceivably arise. But this is a small part of the privatization effort). There is another reason besides pure justice for returning property to its rightful owners -- all of it, not merely that seized at any particular epoch: pragmatism. It most advanced economics, labour accounts for over 75% of the G.D.P. The rest-rent, interest, profit, etc. -- are created by the other factors of production. The entire land of a nation, according to most responsible estimates, is responsible for less than 10% of G.D.P. The property in question in what was formerly East Germany accounts for a tiny fraction of even this amount. So in returning it all to the foreign nationals of German extraction who are its rightful owners, Germany lose very little indeed. But they will gain immeasurably. For what these economies lack at present more than anything else in the world is the entrepreneurial spirit. And there could be not better demonstration of the fact that not only is entrepreneurship welcomed in these countries, it is treasured, than to give back the land, all of it, without any strings attached, to its rightful owners. The countries of eastern Europe are crying out for investment. What do you think will occur if they make a clean breast of the past and return this stolen property? The likelihood is that its owners will come back to stay for at least part of the year -- bringing with them millions of dollars of investment funds, and, far more important, their entrepreneurial skills and talents. Down that path leads Germany and Eastern Europe to industrial peace, material prosperity and a true market economy. If these countries persist in their miggardliness in the return of stolen property, they may keep for themselves a few additional thousands of acres of land, but these holdings will never become very valuable, because without a free and vibrant economy, none of its factors of production amount to very much. So the choice is clear. The peoples of Eastern Europe have nothing to fear. from the market system and everything to gain from it. But free markets can only be predicated on just titles to property. Return the property. All of it. And as soon as possible. - 30- Private German Property by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. Thousands of Germans fled their property during and after World War II, from what was then East Germany. They migrated to all four corners of the earth: to Australia, to South America, to Western Europe, to the U.S. In our own country, they formed the backbone of what is now the German-Canadian community, one known for its work ethic, its strong family orientation, its stick-to-itiveness and its intellectual brilliance. N ow that East Germany is on its way to a life of freedom, forming once again a united country with its western counterpart, its government has decided, quite appropriately, to take on the trappings of capitalism. Foremost amongst these is of course the institution of private property rights. In this regard they have embarked upon a program of returning land, farms, homes and factories to their rightful owners, a policy for which they should be heartily congratulated. It is one which should be emulated by all of the countries which formerly suffered behind the Iron Curtain. This visionary and courageous program, however, has run into several difficulties. First of all, the government has decided to exempt from this plan all property seized between May 8, 1945 and October 6, 1949 prior to the founding of the late but not lamented and so called German Democratic Republic. But this is intolerable. Just because people emigrated, does not mean it is a legitimate act to seize their property -- and this applies regardless of the official auspices under which such acts were undertaken. There is simply no legitimate statute of limitations on justice. As long as the property owners have proof of title -- pictures, letters, records, etc it should not matter whether their homes and farms were expropriated before, during or after the aegis of any particular government. There is a second problem as well: the irresolution of the government. Stated Petra Speyrer, vice-consul for Germany in Vancouver: "It will take years and years, I am sure, to resolve (the land ownership issue). First of all, you have to find out whether to give property back or compensate with money. If money, then how much? How do you find out the value of the land? I am sure there will be a lot of lawsuits because people will want their land back and not just money. It is very complicated." With all due respect, the issue is not complicated at all. On the contrary, it is exceedingly simple. Of course it is the land and physical property which should be returned and not anything else. If the rightful owners want money instead, they are free to sell their holdings for whatever the market dictates. "How much?" should be no business at all of a state run under the principles of free enterprise. (It is only in the case of property destruction -- which does not in any case apply to land, certainly not to its site value -- that thorny problems arise. But this is a small part of the privatization efforts). There is another reason besides pure justice for returning property to its rightful owners -- all of it, not merely that seized at any particular epoch: pragmatism. It most advanced economics, labour accounts for over 75% of the G.D.P. The rest-rent, interest, profit, etc. -are created by the other factors of production. The entire land of a nation, according to most responsible estimates, is responsible for less than 10% of G.D.P. The property in question in what was formerly East Germany accounts for a tiny fraction of even this amount. So in returning it all to the foreign nationals of German extraction who are its rightful owners, Germany lose very little indeed. But they will gain immeasurably. For what these economies lack at present more than anything else in the world is the entrepreneurial spirit. And there could be not better demonstration of the fact that not only is entrepreneurship welcomed in these countries, it is treasured, than to give back the land, all of it, without any strings attached, to its rightful owners. The countries of eastern Europe are crying out for investment. What do you think will occur if they make a clean breast of the past and return this stolen property? The likelihood is that its owners will come back to stay for at least part of the year -- bringing with them millions of dollars of investment funds, and, far more important, their entrepreneurial skills and talents. Down that path leads Germany and Eastern Europe to industrial peace, material prosperity and a true market economy. If these countries persist in their miggardliness in the return of stolen property, they may keep for themselves a few additional thousands of acres of land, but these holdings will never become very valuable, because without a free and vibrant economy, none of its factors of production amount to very much. So the choice is clear. The peoples of Eastern Europe have nothing to fear from the market system and everything to gain from it. But free markets can only be predicated on just titles to property. THE GROSVENOR Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for C30R Radio - 30- Radio Station C30R has made Its home in the basement of the Grosvenor Hotel .for 52 years, but now this grande dame of Vancouver hostelries is scheduled for the wrecker's ball. The upper floors have been closed off, the furnishings have been sold, and all is in readiness for the demolition team. The other day as I approached the front door of the hotel in order to do my regular broadcast for C30R, I was met by an elderly lady. With tears in her eyes, she said "How could they do this? How could they knock down such an elegant building, filled with memories of a bygone era?" Many people empathize with these feelings. It is sad that yet another bit of Vancouver's history will vanish in a cloud of dust and rubble. But such is progress. If we are to grow and expand, to succeed and prosper, to take our places as one of the foremost cities in the world, build we must. Uneconomic structures, which occupy expensive downtown real estate, must be allowed to make way for even more valuable buildings. It is only in this and other similar ways thai our economic prospects may be enlarged, our standards of living improved, and the scourge of poverty wrestled to the ground. But there is a small but highly organized and influential group of people who are trying to force their views on aesthetics down the throats of the rest of us— whether we like it or not. I refer to those vociferous busy bodies who try to impose historical landmark status on old and decaying buildings in the central city. These people are usually highly educated, sophisticated and cultured. They want to indulge their own upper class tastes, and protect the older buildings that people such as they particularly enjoy. But this is at the expense of the tens of thousands of people who might benefit from the jobs and homes that could be created if modern office towers or large apartment blocks were erected on those sites instead. If these people want to save the buildings, well and good. Let them buy these heritage structures themselves—like they do in the case of their antiques and vintage cars. But it is entirely unfair to force other people, many of them poorer, to pay for this particular enjoyment. Historical Monuments / Judging from the quantity, quality, and high prices fetched for antiques, Canadians are a people who relish their history. Paradoxically, economics has a part to play in this enjoyment of the past: the price system tends to promote optimal preservation of past relics. If too few relics from the past had been saved, the price system could be counted upon to remedy this situation. Extremely high prices would encourage people to forage around in hopes of uncovering more marketable antiques, hence meeting the great demand. The movement would be toward discovery and increased supply. This is readily understood. But it is no less true that an oversupply of artifacts would also create problems. If our homes were too burdened with antiques, then there would be less room tor the modern conveniences we also enjoy. If such a situation were somehow to arise, many antiques would lose value and would be summarily thrown out. Neither of these scenarios is remotely likely. Indeed, the proof that the price system is working well is that both are ludicrous: there is no antique "problem." Things are entirely different, however, with regard to historical monuments and buildings. The market has all but been banished and zoning has instead held sway. Consequently, there are serious problems. Were a price system in effect for time-honoured buildings, some of them, those worth more in situ than demolished, would be preserved. But without a market the costs of maintaining such structures in pristine condition are ignored. There is no way of telling which are worth more as is, and which are more valuable for the space they release for new construction. A Price System How would it work? Why would the owner of an antique building preserve it, when he could sell it for millions to a developer? Given that this particular edifice is one that deserves preservation, consumers must value it more for its historical character than for the space it could cede to a skyscraper, (we assume away the possibility of moving the entire building to a cheaper site as too costly). If so, then the revenues the owner could extract via admission charges, plus his own psychic enjoyment, should more than offset alternative revenues. Why are so few historical buildings preserved, on the market? For one thing, cost" are relevent to present economic decisionmaking: this explains why small relics from the past have a greater chance of being preserved, other things equal, than larger ones. Old stamps and coins, jewelry and children's toys can be preserved at less cost than can automobiles, locomotives, sailing ships and buildings. Consequently, unless the larger artifacts are more valuable in proportion to the cubic space they occupy (abstracting from additional maintenance costs) fewer of them will be saved for posterity. Externalities But there is another difficulty posed for a market solution to the historic building question: externalities. There may not be any feasible way for consumers .to see the inside of the building without paying for the privilege, but the main attraction may be the facade, and all passersby can enjoy this without charge. How could the entrepreneur internalize this externality, and convert the outside of the building into a paying proposition. The problem arises because not ati elements are part of the competitive market. The streets are government controlled. If they were privately owned, one aspect of thu externality problem would disappear. The owners of the historic building and of the surrounding streets and sidewalks would presumably come to some agreement concerning the sharing of the revenues collected from the passersby. Possibly one would buy the other out There would remain the question of the surrounding skyscrapers. Their owners might well charge admission to their windows or roof - for the purpose of viewing the neighboring attraction. This, of course, could severely hamper the monument owner's efforts to maintain it as a paying proposition. Large Fences But there are several counter measures he could adopt. He could erect (or so threaten) a large fence around the building to cut off a view from the lower floors; or a large shield above the roof so that noone from the upper storeys could enjoy the vista. Given these possibilities the surrounding skyscraper owners might be willing to negotiate a payment for the viewing rights. Alternatively, the historic and the surrounding structures might come under the same ownership: from one landlord selling to the other, or both to a third party. In any of these eventualities, the externalities would be no more; they would be internalized. The facade of the building, as well as the inside would be brought into the economic nexus. Both could be charged for thus allowing people to register the importance they placed upon it. The antique monument would thus remain so, as long as market value is more than any alternative. It is important to realize that not all external benefits need be internalized. Many, if not most viable commercial establishments release external benefits for which they are unable to collect. People benefit from the knowledge alone of certain amenities in their city, such as the Canadian symphony orchestra even if they never patronize them. The owners of these establishments cannot of course send a bill to a1"l those who merely appreciate their existence, but they can still earn enough profit to stay in business despite this "failure." It is not necessary to ensure that each and every person who enjoys a historic monument pay for it. All that is necessary for its continued existence is that more $ be collectable from it than from alternative uses. Advertising There is always the possibility, if there are anough "free riders" anxious to see the monument, but not to pay for such a privilege, to use it for advertizing advantage. The most obvious way would be to erect bill boards on and about the edifice. But this might well detract from its beauty, or historic character. Alternatively, the commercial message could be delivered far away from the structure: on radio, T.V. or in print. Landmark Preservation Under Zoning Under zoning when property felt to be of historical interest is declared a landmark, it may not be altered, improved or demolished. Although it is (or was) private property, the owner has been relieved of valuable rights. Costs, or the alternative uses of the space occupied by the building, are not considered. Sufficient antiquarianism is the only criterion. Unlike antiques on the market, such monuments need not be more valuable as relics than put to other uses; they need only have some worth from a historical perspective in order to be saved. Thus there is little likelihood that consumer welfare will be increased by landmark zoning. Instead, a small group of antiquarian elitists can ignore the desires of the rest of the population, and impose the preservation of an excessive number of historical buildings. Perhaps one reason Canadians accept such policy is that it is difficult to discern the "what-might-have beens." The historic landmark is physically there: people see it, enjoy it, photograph it, touch it. It is more difficult to appreciate the factory that might have taken its place; to envision the extra employment its construction would have meant; or the lower-priced consumer goods it could have produced. These possibilities are no less important despite the present difficulty of recognizing this. Labour Code Revision by Walter Block The present Labour Code of British Columbia has is its objective the protection of wage rates for the working men and women of the province. Its basic philosophy is based on the view that there exists an unequal bargaining power between employer and employee -- vastly to the advantage of the former. The methodology of the B.C. Labour Code is one of promoting collective bargaining - in order to balance the scales of power in favour of the latter. While well-motivated and based on the best of intentions, the Labour Code has had widespread negative unintended consequences. Under its rule, the union movement has obtained great powers, but, paradoxically, this has not benefited many working people, nor the population of the province as a whole. Thousands of person-hours have been lost as a result of strike activity. Bitterness and acrimony have afflicted labour relations; all the EXPOs in the world will not convince foreigners to bring their persons (tourism) or property (investments) to this province, into an atmosphere of strife and conflict. Worse for the labour force, unemployment has risen. Let us take Canada as a whole (this is a reasonable procedure, since the labour codes of the other province are much like those of B.C.), and compare it with the United States in this regard. [n 1961, the unionization rates in both countries were very similar, at 30 per cent of the labour force. By 1985, the rate in Canada had risen to 40 percent (45 percent in British Columbia), but fallen to below 20 per cent in the U.S. As a result, real wages n this country rose by 35 percent between 1965 and 1985, while they fell by 5 3ercent south of the border. - 30- LABOUR CODE REVISION by Walter Block In the next few months, several provinces will be re-examining their labour codes with a view to revising them. In the past, such attempts have been superficial; they have placed bubble gum, band aid, and scotch tape solutions on a corpus in need of major surgery. Our legislative representatives must go to the heart of the matter this time out, for the health of the Canadian economy depends upon it. This analysis will entirely concern itself with the ideal labour code, with how things should be. This is crucial, for as Yogi Berra put it &quotIf you don't know where you're going, you probably won't get there." In the field of labour relations, the most important issue is the strike. Actually, this is a misnomer, as it refers not to one act, but to two. A strike is, first, a withdrawal of labour in unison from an employer, on the part of the relevent organized employees. To this, there can be no objection. If a single individual has a right to withdraw labour services, or to quit a job, he does not lose it merely because others choose to exercize their rights, simultaneously. There is a second aspect of the strike, however. And this element is pernicious, insidious and entirely improper. I refer here to the union practice of making it impossible for the struck employer to deal with alternative sources of labour, who are anxious to compete for the jobs the strikers have just vacated. This entry restriction can be accomplished in several ways. In the days of yore, organized labour would first brand their competitors as &quotscabs," or &quotstrike breakers" and then use threatened or actual physical intimidation (mass picketing, trespass, sit down strikes, violence, arson) to make it impossible for the employer to hire replacement workers. Anyone who thinks that mass picketing is merely an exercize of free speech rights is confusing de jure with de facto. In theory, union picketing is an information generating exercise in free speech. In fact, it is an active threat of physical intimidation; it is harrassment, pure and simple. In the modern era, unions have added to this tactic a plethora of legislation which also effectively drives a compulsory wedge between employer and &quotscab." The businessman must convince the Labour Relations Board that he is &quotbargaining fairly" with those who have left his employ (even though what he most desires is to ignore them, and to deal with others instead); he must give special considerations to those who have left him in the lurch by striking. One argument of organized labour is that its present powers — or something like them -- are responsible for past wage increases, and are needed if wages are to continue to rise in the future. But this is fantasy. On the contrary, gains in labour productivity — because of better skills, improved capital equipment and industrial peace — are the causes of gains in take home pay. This is proven by relatively declining wages in the heavily unionized "smokestack" industries, compared to increased salaries in the far less unionized computer, microchip and other information and service industries. As well, there is the fact that real wages have been rising for centuries, while the earliest unions appeared only in the late 19th century. So-called &quotunequal bargaining power" thus has nothing to do with the matter. Another argument for the status quo is that the &quotscab" is stealing the job of the striker. But this is also the sheerest of nonsense. A job is an embodiment of an agreement between two consenting parties - employee and employer. It cannot be the possession of only one of them. A worker no more owns &quothis" job than does a husband own &quothis" wife. A striking union which forcibly prevents the employer from hiring a replacement is like a husband who divorces his wife — and then threatens to beat her up, and any prospective new suitor as well — if she tries to remarry. Just as one spouse may now divorce the other for any reason or for none at all, the employer should be able to fire an employee without being compelled to show &quotcause." Our laws do not force the worker to justify a decision to quit his job, and the employee-employer relationship should be an entirely symmetric one. A properly revised labour code, then, would allow strikes in the sense of mass refusals to work, or quits in unison. It would entrench this behavior, as a basic element of the rights of free men. But it would limit union activity to this one option. It would thus prohibit, to the full extent of the law, any and all interferences with the rights of alternative employees (&quotscabs") to compete for jobs held by union members. It would end, forevermore, all picketing, and other such forms of threatened or actual violence. Although many people think that pickets are aimed at the struck employer, they are actually an attack on competing workers (&quotscabs"). And just as our laws should not allow business firms to picket the premises of suppliers, competitors or customers, no group of workers should be able, by picketing, to forcibly prohibit another group of workers — almost always poorer — from bidding for jobs. A proper labour code would thus define a &quotlegitimate union" as one which strictly limited its actions to organizing mass resignations. A &quotlegitimate union" would eschew picketing, violence, and all other special advantages — legislative or otherwise —vis-a-vis its non unionized competitors. This would end, once and for all, the legal fiction that workers who have left their jobs can yet retain any right to employment status in those positions. Were this one basic change in labour relations to be made, then society would have to re-think a whole host of unjust and unwise elements now embodied in present labour legislation. o Right to work provisions. These would be an infringement upon the rights of employers and legitimate unions to sign mutually beneficial and consensual agreements. Under the ideal labour code, there would be no &quotright to work." o Wage restraints should be ended. These would be an unconscionable interference with the rights of legitimate unions to engage in collective bargaining. o Boycotts of whatever type are simply a refusal to deal with certain people. But everyone has the moral right to choose his friends and business associates. Any attempt to stop such behavior would be a severe violation of our human rights. And this goes for the secondary boycott as well. o Applying anti combines legislation to unions. A favorite of union bashers, this too would be inapplicable for legitimate unions. o Imposing &quotdemocracy" on unions. It would be no more justified to subject legitimate unions to &quotdemocracy", than it would be to impose the secret ballot, government supervision of voting procedures, or limited political activism on any other voluntary organization such as the corporation, the faculty club, or the Roman Catholic College of Cardinals. o Back to work orders. This would be an infringement upon the right of free men to withdraw their labour services. Fines, jail sentences for labour organizers, imposed loss of check off privileges would be a completely unwarranted interference with the only tactic at the disposal of legitimate unionism. -30LABOUR CODE REVISIONS By Walter Block, Senior Economist The Fraser Institute For The Financial Post Things are not going well for organized labour, as these incidents from around the world will attest: . In New Zealand, Prime Minister Robert Muldoon has just amended his nation's labour code, banning closed shops. Despite the fact that nearly half the countries' labour force is unionized, leaders of the Labour Party opposition see this as an election ploy! . In England, the birthplace of industrial unions, the barons of organized labour have been forced to call off a threatened shipyard strike. This was to have been in protest against employer demands to stremline work methodsimposed by some 17 different unions, to the virtual ruination of British shipbuilding. This industry, once the envy of the world, and responsible for building 80 per cent of all merchant shipping, is now a shadow of its former self, only half as efficient as its main European rivals. As well, a widely publicized "national day of protest" came to nought. This was the response to the Conservative Government's plan to ban unions at Communication Headquarters (in charge of national security intelligence gathering) in Cheltenham. . In the United States, the Supreme Court has just ruled union succession rights to be unconstitutional. Now, when a company becomes bankrupt, or undergoes reorganization through other transformation, the prior union contract no longer prevails. And what, pray tell, of the labour relations scene in Canada? In lotus-land by-the-sea, the labour movement is shooting itself in the foot. It shows signs of breaking up through internal dissension, while plunging the province of British Columbia into chaos. The situation is this. The International Woodworkers of America (IWA) had recently signed a three-year labour contract after much dissension with management. Because of this, and also due to recession-created economic hardships, they were only now beginning to draw full paycheques on a steady basis. At this point the 7,600-member Pulp, Paper and Woodworkers of Canada (PPWC), and the 9,000member Canadian Paperworkers Union (CPU), rejected a contract similar to the one signed by the IWA, and were locked out by their employers on February 2, 1984. Whereupon the PPWC and the CPU set up secondary pickets at IWA workplaces—which were crossed, despite Labour Relations Board approval, in violation of the most sacred taboo of the labour movement, by members of the latter union. Now the fur realty began to fly. Fist fights, and worse, broke out between the various bands of unionists. Townspeople and non-union truck loggers entered the fray. Due to the violence and chaos, the RCMP was unable to protect the locked-out workers, and the picket lines had to be abandoned. As a result of all this. Art Gruntman of CPU and Jim Sloan of PPWC have called for the resignation from the B.C. Federation of Labour of IWA president Jack Munro, who had publicly supported his members' actions. B.C. Labour Minister Bob McLelland had long been reputed to be considering changes in the province's Labour Code, widely regarded as among the most favourable to unionism in all of Canada. If so, he has been handed, on a silver platter, ample reason for doing just that. Specifically, secondary picketing, with its interference in plants where there are no present labour grievances, would appear to be highly unpopular with the long-suffering B.C. citizenry. If this one practice could be prohibited, or at least made more difficult, then one burr under the saddle of labour-management, relations will have been removed. But while we are talking about secondary picketing, we might reconsider the role of primary picke. ig as well. In theory, and as a matter of law, this type of picketing serves only informational purposes. It advises all and sundry that the organized employees are at variance with their employer. But the facts are often far different. Instead of merely notifying the public about a labour dispute, picketing serves as a threat to all those who might be interested in competing for the jobs and salary spurned by the union. Since all Canadians have, or at least should have, a right to compete for any given employment opportunity, such a practice is a de facto, although not de jure violation of liberty. A more accurate interpretation of picketing (whether primary or secondary) is as a nuisance or harassment. This is precisely how it would be regarded were it to take place in any other commercial or personal arena. Suppose, that is, that a person vacates the premises of landlord A, and patronizes landlord B instead. Surely the courts would cast a baleful eye on A, if he, together with his family, cronies, and business associates, began to picket the tenant for being &quotunfair." Or take another case. Suppose that a man divorces his spouse, and then along with all his friends "pickets" the home of his exwife, warning off possible suitors. Would this be considered an informational exercise in free speech rights? Hardly. On the contrary, it would be clearly seen for the harassment it is, and be summarily prohibited by any court in the land. Can we as a nation afford any less rigorous a definition of justice in labourmanagement relations? -30March 9, 1984 Gabriel Bruce: The Liver Transplant Boy by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute According to recent reports, the black market value of a kidney which can be transplanted is some $13,000 -- which translates to roughly seven times its weight in gold. Such an occurrence may occasion all sorts of references to King Midas -- who was supposed to have been turned into a statue of sold gold, but behind this rather dramatic way of characterizing the value of human organs lies in a story of untold and tragic human suffering. The leaders of our medical establishment are ideologically opposed to the use of the market system. So implacable and fervent is their hatred of free enterprise that they will gladly countenance the deaths of hundreds of their patients -- thousands if need be -- as long as no spectre of prices and profits infringes into their little world. We make this rather hysterical-sounding charge because the medical establishment in this country is largely responsible for arranging matters in such a way that it is illegal to harness marketplace incentives in order to encourage kidney donors. Instead, our society must resort to all sort of inefficient stratagems toward this end. Famous personages have exhorted us, in the event that we suffer untimely death, to make a posthumous gift of these organs; medical schools coach their students on the best techniques for approaching next-of-kin -- and asking permission of them at the precise time when they are least likely to give it -- upon the sudden demise of a loved one. But all of this has been to little avail. While potential recipients languish on painful kidney dialysis machines waiting ghoulishly for a traffic fatality which may spell life for them, the public has refused to sign cards giving permission for automatic posthumous donor status. Things have even come to such a pass that there are grotesque and fascistic plans now being bruited about which would allow the government to seize the kidneys of accident victims unless they have signed cards denying such permission. The free enterprise system could be a God-send to the unfortunates who suffer from diseased kidneys. A legalized marketplace would encourage thousands of donors. Would you sign a card donating your kidney after death for 13,000 big ones, right now, in cold hard cash? There are very few people who would turn up their noses at such an offer. And if sufficient supplies were still not forthcoming at this level, prices would rise even further until all demand was satisfied. Given free enterprise incentives, pardon the pun, we would be up to our armpits in kidneys. This is the tried and true process we rely on to bring us all the other necessities of life: food, clothing and shelter. After all, we do not depend for the provision of these goods and services on voluntary donations. We know this to be an unreliable system -- however much it is flogged by opinion leaders in the case of organ transplants. No one is contending that those responsible for preventing a free market in kidneys are purposefully murdering thousands of kidney disease sufferers. But no matter how benevolent their intentions, it cannot be denied that this is the effect of their ill-conceived actions. It is time, it is long past time, for our society to put aside its archaic and prejudicial opposition to the marketplace, so that we can lift a death sentence we have inadvertently placed on as hopeless and hapless a group of citizens that ever existed. 30 585 words Marian Regional High School Closing by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Now that the closing of the Marian Regional High School in Vancouver has receded from the front pages, it might he appropriate to more carefully consider the implications of this occurence from a public policy perspective. The decision to suspend the operations of this Catholic school for girls has been widely condemned. The schoolgirls themselves have engaged in a highly publicized protest at this action. The Catholic Secondary School Teachers' Association has asked the Industrial Relations Council to call a halt to this plan. According to a high profile leader of organized labour, the man responsible for this determination, Archbishop James Carney, is guilty of "the basest form of union busting." A local Vancouver newspaper columnist has gone so far as to characterize Catholics who support their church in this regard as unthinking sheep who blindly follow orders. "The church has long taught good Catholics their place. Good Catholics belong on their knees," were the c\;irt words. It doesn't seem to have occurred to many people that such a description could easily be interpreted as purposefully spreading hatred against an identifiable group, behaviour condemned by the anti hate-mongering Section 281.2 of the Criminal Code under which several now well known bigots were charged. Criminal or not, such a characterization, were it uttered against a group such as Sikhs. Jews, natives, blacks or any other minority, would be instantly condemned by all people of good will. Judging from the absence of protest about these intemperate words, it would appear to be open season on Catholics. For shame. Why was this exceedingly unpopular decision made? According to an announcement made by Archbishop Carney, the school was closed because the church had lost confidence in the teachers' ability to provide a Catholic education. / But there would appear to be more to this than meets the eye. After all, when / one loses confidence in one's housekeeper, one does not commonly close down one's / domicile; one merely fires the unrelkihle housekeeper, and hires another. When a ( person loses confidence in his attorney, it would be ludicrous to think that his only - \ option consists of giving up the lawsuit. Obviously, the more rational alternative is v ^-to dismiss that lawyer, and retain a replacement. Why then did not the Archbishop, having lost confidence in the seventeen Marian High School faculty members, simply fire the lot of them, and hire a replacement crew? The reason is not hard to discern: the B.C. Labour Code hung like a sword of Damocles above his head. The law compels him to "bargain fairly" with a group of people he wished to have nothing further to do with. In a word, it would have been deemed an "unfair labour practice" for him to replace the seventeen teachers with people he could trust to set a good example for the students, on a 24 hour per day basis. The ordinary businessman who loses confidence in his work force rarely closes up shop. Instead, he grits his teeth and carries on. Perhaps this is what the Archbishop might have done had the work force in question consisted of painters, electricians, plumbers or custodians. But when it came to the molders of young minds (these children, remember, were ultimately his responsibility), he could not tailor his beliefs to conform to the niceties of the labour code. Archbishop Carney was unwilling to compromise or "bargain." He has, at least from his own perspective, no less than a sacred mission, which leaves no room for negotiation. So. instead, he chose the only honorable course open to him, which was to close down the school. There are many who are quite understandably unhappy with this situation. But they should seek the root cause of the Archbishop's decision in an unwise, rigid and inflexible legal code, not as an cii'hiti';iry whim of the rricin himself. By in effect closing down a Catholic school which otherwise would have remained open, union legislation contravenes religions freedom. By forcing employers to deal with workers who no longer have their trust, the British Columbia labour code also violates the law of free association. True. rarely in our society does this denial of basic human rights result in such an altercation. But then, rarely do we find in public life a man of strong principle such as Archbishop Carney. 30 Market Failure by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Many professional economists subscribe to what might be called the argument from market failure. In this perspective, the market is imperfect, and therefore the government is justified in intervening in commercial activities, in order to improve matters. But this view has not gone unchallenged. First of all, any attempt to "justify" government regulation of business on this ground violates a distinction which is axiomatic in economics, that between the normative and the positive. Justification is by its very nature a normative, i.e., value-laden procedure; but economics is a value free subject. The point is, there is nothing in the value free corpus of economic science that could possibly justify anyone doing anything. Economics as sncli is limited to describing, explaining, understanding and perhaps predicting: the justification of action is entirely outside its realm. Second, even if there were any such thing as "market failure," and even if economics could somehow justify acting so as to obviate such a phenomenon, it by no means follows that its mere existence would justify state activity. For there is such a thing as "government failure" (the inability of state bureaucrats to act efficiently, due to a lack of the proper profit and loss incentives) and in any given case the latter might outweigh the former. That is, in ordinary parlance, the cure might be worse than the disease. Third, there has been no definitive demonstration that there exists any real world example of market failure. The major candidates put forth by the proponents of this doctrine include monopoly and pollution. Let us briefly consider each. .Trusts, or combines, or monopolies are said to misallocate resources, when they attain too great a degree of control over a given industry. But economists cannot even unambiguously define an industry. There may be only one widget producer in a given city, but if the whole province, country or the entire world is defined as the relevant market the concentration ratio (the proportion of sales, employment or profits accounted for by the top few firms) can be made to appear very low. Similarly, the more all inclusive the definition of the good in question, the less "control" there can be. That is. one is far more likely to find "monopoly" in the industry limited to colas, then in the one which includes all beverages, and yet there is no unambiguous way to define the industry. As well, the misallocative or dead weight losses described by some economists are solely a product of their narrowly constricted "blackboard" economics. Firms depicted in these models are timeless and static, while those which earn a living in the real world are forced to act in a dynamic setting. Nor is there an independent criteria (the perfectly The market manipulator, Part I competitive result, beloved of the blackboard economist) against which to measure the actual operation of a business concern which might run afoul of combines legislation. Rather, the proponent of such legislation must claim the contrary to fact conditional that were such an industry to exist, it would have arrived at a different pricing and quantity decision than the defendant accused of restraining trade. But here the firm finds itself in a "Catch 22" no-win situation. For if it charges more than its competitors, it can be found guilty of monopolizing or profiteering; if its prices are lower, it can be fined for "cutthroat or predatory competition." It cannot escape even if it proves it did neither: for then it stands condemned of engaging in collusive behaviour. Pollution is claimed as another instance of "market failure." The charge, here, is that the business firm need only calculate the costs of its inputs -- land, labour and capital - and can safely ignore the costs of smoke, wastes and pollution, since these are imposed on others. It is for this reason, claim the critics, that the capitalist system is earmarked by excessively dirty air and water and by noise inundations. There is of course a failure of some sort that must be used to explain these unfortunate circumstances. But it is not "market failure." On the contrary it is "government failure," in this case the neglect of the courts to carefully define and assiduously protect the property rights of those victimized by polluters. Were the state to have awarded injunctions to the plaintiffs in the early 19th century pollution or nuisance cases (as they were called then), our entire experience with smoke prevention devices and technology would have taken a far different turn than it has, and our environment would have been far more adequately protected. (For a Fraser Institute perspective that challenges the view that market failure is responsible for our poor ecological conditions, see The Environmentalists versus the Economy.) There may well indeed be market failure in the sense that commerce is conducted by flesh and blood creatures who are of course imperfect, and hence given to error. But no one has shown the existence of any "market failure" in the real world, apart from the fallibility of human beings. 1. 30 - he public is frightened and highly suspicious of those who profit through stock market manipulations. And their fears are often reflected by legislation. For example. according to the securities commissions that govern the stock markets in Canada, the U.S. and virtually every other advanced industrial country, it is illegal to intentionally sell shares in order to lower their pri •. .e, and then to profit by buying them back at those cut-rate prices. The law regards the market manipulator as having engaged in a fraudulent act. It is a false assumption. Take the case of the merchant who sells a sack labelled potatoes but which actually turns out to contain a bunch of wonhless rocks. This is a theft of the sale price, and is therefore properly held to be illegal. No such thing occurs in the case of stock manipulation. The purchases and sales are in bona fide tokens of ownership. so the charge of fraud is fallacious. Nevertheless. even though it cannot be fraudulem, buying and selling shares of stock in such a pattern raises several important questions: Ought such sales be prohibited on the grounds of being inimical to the public interest? What are the economic ramifications? What role do such transactions play in the economy? In order to answer these questions, let us consider stock manipulation in some detail. Suppose that the price of a share in a given finn, call it XYZ Corp., was trading at S 100 before the arrival of the manipulator, Mr. M. and suppose that it would have continued at this level for the foreseeable future if not for his intervention. At the outset of this process, at least according to traditional theory, the manipulator engages in massive sales, which drive down the price to say $50. At this point he begins repurchasing shares at these rock-bottom levels. catapulting the stock back up to its former price of 5100. In doing this, he earns a fortune for himself, and imposes great losses on the other XYZ stockholders. But there are grave flaws in this analysis. First of all, how did our manipulator obtain the massive position in XYZ in the first place that allowed him to sell off enough stock to drive down the price? If we assume that his sole interest in the corporation was to manipulate its stock. and that he first had to buy his shares in order to sell them later. then the economic picrure looks very different. All was going along swimmingly at the 5100 level, until Mr. \1 purchased enough shares for his operation. which caused the share price to climb. Suppose that his purchases raise XYZ's shares to $150. Then, when our boy M sells them off, he succeeds in lowering the price back down to the $100 level. But he has not yet earned any profits. On the contrary, he has suffered losses. showing nothing to offset the costs of his time, interest forgone or brokerage fees. So far we have been assuming that M's doings have no effect on the expectations of the other market participants. It is now time to retire that assumption. For in the real world, expectations play an important role in decisions in the marketplace, and they are altered by the actions of others. As well, for argument's sake we ignore the point that M must first purchase the shares of any stock he wishes to manipulate. In this scenario, when Mr. M begins his selloff he does so on such a massive scale that the bottom drops out of the market for XYZ. Others panic. selling their shares for whatever pittance they will fetch. As a result, the price drops farther arid faster than one would expect, based upon the unloading of the M's holdings alone. Then, when the price hits rock bottom. the clever M starts buying surreptitiously in bits and pieces, through frontmen. In this way he makes money both going and coming: the price goes down faster than his own sales could account for, and slower than might be expected. This way he can buy up all or at nearly all of the artificially undervalued shares (we assume that XYZ Corp. is as sound as a bell) before other people realize what a great bargain they are and begin placing purchase orders on their own accounts. T To he continued. Dr. Block is an economist with the Fraser Institute. BRITISH COLUMBIA REPORT. MARCH 25, 1997 15 STOCK MARKET MANIPUlATOR: Part I I by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute i , I The public is greatly frightened and highly suspicious of the stock market manipulator. This fear is commonly reflected in legislation forbidding such practices. For example, according to the securities and exchange regulations which govern stock markets in Canada, the U.S., and virtually all other advanced industrial countries, it is a fraudulent act to intentionally sell shares in order to lower their prices, and then i to buy them back when they hit bottom, in order to make a profit. This, however, is ill-conceived law. It is predicated on the false assumption that the stock market manipulator engages in a fraudulent act, and nothing could be further from the truth. The paradigm case of fraud is the sale of a good such as potatoes, when, what actually turn out to be in the sack is a bunch of worthless I ; I rocks. This is i equivalent to a theft of the sale price, and is therefore properly held to be illegal.. No such thing is even alleged to occur in the case of stock manipulation -j the purchases and sales are in bone fide tokens of ownership -- so the charge of fraud is entirely fallacious. Nevertheless, even though it cannot be fraudulent, buying and selling shares of I I stock in such a pattern, and with such a motive, raises several important questions. Ought it to be prohibited on other grounds, such as being inimical to the public , interest? Is there any justification for this behaviour? What are its economic I functions? What role does it play in the economy? In order to answer such questions, let us consider stock manipulation in some detail. Suppose that the price of a share in a given firm, call it XYZ corporation, was trading at $100 before the advent of the manipulator, and that it would have continued at this level for the foreseeable future but for his activity. We now have a market bench mark against which these transactions can be contrasted. At the outset of this process, at least according to the traditional theory we are I i considering, the manipulator engages in massive sales, which drive down the price to, say, $50. Whereupon he begins his repurchasing operations at these rock bottom levels catapulting the price back up to its former level of $100. By doing this he earns a fortune for himself, and imposes great losses on his hapless fellow investors inXYZ. i But there, are grave flaws in this analysis. First of all, how did our manipulator obtain the massive position in XYZ in the first place, which allowed him to sell off enough stock ~o so appreciably lower the price? If we assume that his sole interest ! in the corporation is to manipulate its stock, and that he first had to buy shares (in order sell them at high prices so that he could later repurchase them) then the economic pictu looks very different. Here, all was going along swimmingly at the $100 level, until Mr. (the manipulator) purchased enough shares for his operation. But this, as can been see sharply increases prices compared to what they would have been, other things equal, ha he not so acted. Suppose that these purchases raise the shares to $150. Then, when our bo M sells them off, he only succeeds in lowering the price back down to the $100 level, b which time no profits have yet been earned for him. Indeed, on the contrary, he h suffered losses, having no gains to offset the costs of the time involved in the operatio the interest foregone, and the brokerage fees. So far we have been implicitly assuming that M's doings have no effect on th expectations of the other market participants. It is now time to relax this assumption. W do this in order to make our analysis more realistic. For in the real world, expectation play an important role in market decision making, and they are altered by the commerci actions of others. As well, for argument's sake, we now ignore the point that th manipulator must first purchase the shares of any stock he wishes to manipulate. In this scenario, when Mr. M begins his sell off, he does so on such a massive sca that, seemingly, the bottom drops out of the market for XYZ. Other market participan panic, throwing away their shares for whatever pittance they will fetch. As a result, th price drops farther and faster than one would expect based upon the unloading of th manipulator's holdings alone. Then, when the price hits the rock bottom, our clever Mr. starts buying surreptitiously in bits and pieces, through numerous fronts. In this way h makes money both going and coming: the price goes down faster than his own sales cou account for, and slower than that which might be expected to result from his purchases. this way he can buy up all or at least most of the artificially undervalued shares (we a still assuming that XYZ Inc is as sound as a bell, apart from all the finagling) before oth people realize what a great bargain they are, and begin placing purchase orders on the own accounts. (This is part I of a two part series on the stock market manipulator, which will be concluded in my next column.) MEDICAL LICENSING IN CANADA by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute an article for Financial Post According to U. S. Representative Claude Pepper (Democrat, Florida) over 10,000 "doctors" are now practicing in that country without benefit of proper medical licensing. These are not people with questionable credentials, or graduates from diploma mills, or physician's assistants or nurses practicing beyond their qualifications. We're talking about outright impostors here, individuals who have no official qualifications at all. Apart from this, fully 10% of the 450,000 duly licensed physicians practicing south of our border are incompetent. This, at least, is the opinion of Dr. Robert Derbyshire, past president of the Federation of State Medical Boards, and is seconded by Dr. David Axelrod, New York's Health Commissioner. What is the situation in Canada? There are no official estimates of fake doctors in this country, but according to the College of Physicians and Surgeons of Ontario, a random sample of doctors from that province showed that 13% either practiced medicine in a way that caused "serious concern" or kept poor records. This crisis applied mainly to family doctors, not specialists, and to ciderly doctors. An astounding 49% of physicians aged 70 and above caused "concern". Thus the situation here might even be worse than in the U. S. However, even if the usual ten-to-one rule of thumb applies, this would mean that about 1,000 practicing doctors in this country are outright frauds, and another 4,500 are unskilled — despite their legitimate credentials. How could this possibly be true? Are not this nation's doctors subjected to a complete and up-to-date medical school education, an exhaustive system of initial pre-diploma testing, and airtight procedures which ensure competence throughout their careers? This, at least, is the theory. But the practice, according to University of Alberta History Professor Ronald Hamowy, is far different. According to Hamowy, the author of Canadian Medicine: A Study in Restricted Entry, a book recently published by The Fraser Institute, the function of medical licensing in this country is not so much to insure physician quality, as it is to limit entry into the field, so as to increase the income, power and prestige of those doctors already in practice. According to the evidence amassed in this book, the Canadian medical establishment at one point or another in its history has: banned price and other advertising for licensed doctors; set minimum price schedules; acted to prevent "overcrowding," or an oversupply of physicians by setting up a whole host of irrelevant criteria for licensing - examples include a knowledge of grammar, mathematics, Latin, history, philosophy, and other academic studies, language requirements, citizenship, etc.; outlawed the uncontrolled study of medicine, even for those who do not intend to practice; placed roadblocks against foreign doctors practicing in Canada, where they would compete with domestic physicians; been content with imposing entry examinations only. If the certification of quality were the true goal of these exams, they would more likely be required of practicing physicians at least every decade or so. For, says Hamowy, there is little guarantee - certainly not on the basis of testing -that a doctor of seventy years of age is still qualified, merely for having successfully sat an examination forty years earlier; fought against pre-payment contract practice, opposed doctors testifying for plaintiffs in malpractice suits, and discouraged charity work as undermining minimum fee schedules and professional prestige; raised medical student lees in order to increase the costs of entry into the profession; succeeded, from time to time, in raising physicians' income levels beyond that of other, equally skilled, professions in Canada. If the present licensing system has failed, what, then, can be done about the epidemic of doctors who are either incompetent and/or sheer frauds? The public policy recommendation which follows from Hamowy's analysis would be to install a system of competitive certification, in place of the present system of monopoly licensing. Under licensing, if the applicant fails the test, he cannot practice (as in the motor vehicle licence); under certification, a rejected applicant can still practice (a non chartered accountant may legally help people fill out tax forms), but he cannot pass himself off as certified. The problem with monopoly licencing (as with all other coercive monopolies) is that if the institution in charge does a poor job, consumers have no alternative. Under competition, there is an incentive system for all competitors to try to outdistance each other in terms of quality control, innovativeness, cost-cutting, etc. The weakest producers are forced to the sidelines, the strongest can expand the scope of their operations, to the ultimate and on-going improvement of the industry. Although provision of knowledge to health care consumers about the skill, qualifications, experience, and general trustworthiness of doctors may not appear at first blush to be an "industry," the effects of competition would operate here as well. How might competition work in the medical profession? Were government so minded, it could announce that at some time hence (say, ten years) it would call a halt to the present monopoly system of licensing doctors. This would usher in a competitive certification system to begin at present, to co-exist with licensing for the next decade, and to be launched out on its own at that point. What kind of firms might undertake such an endeavor? One likely scenario would have various certification agencies - the Canadian Medical Association itself, the Royal College of Physicians and Surgeons of the provinces, the McGill University Medical Faculty, major insurance companies, for example - all competing with each other as to which might best be able to ensure the quality of physicians to the general public. Under such a system, the quality of medicine and the extent of monitoring medical practice would improve, to the great benefit of the health care of the Canadian populace. MEDICAL LICENSING IN CANADA by Walter Block, Senior Economist, Fraser Institute, an article for Financial Post According to U.S. Representative Claud? Pepper {Democrat, Florida) over 10,000 "doctors" are now practicing in that country without benefit of proper medical licensing. These are not people with questionable credentials or graduates from diploma mills, or physicians assistants or nurses practicing beyond their qualifications. We're talking about outright impostors here, individuals who have no official qualifications at all. Apart from this, fully 10% of the 10000 duly licensed physicians practicing south of our border are incompetent. This, at least, is the opinion of Dr. Robert Derbyshire, past president of the Federation of State Medical Boards, and is seconded by Dr. David Axelrod, New York's Health Commissioner. What Is the situation in Canada? There are no official estimates of fake doctors in this country, but according to the College of Physicians and Surgeons of Ontario, a random sample of doctors from that province showed that 13% either practiced medicine In a way that caused "serious concern" or kept poor records. This crisis applied mainly to [family doctors, not specialists, and to elderly doctors. An astounding 49% of physicians aged 70 and above caused "concern." Thus the situation here might even be worse than in the U.S. However, even if the usual ten-to-one rule of thumb applies, this would mean that about 1,000 practicing doctors In this country are outright frauds, and another 4,500 are unskilled —despite their legitimate credentials. How could this possibly be true? Are not this nation's doctors subjected to a complete and up-ro-date medical school education, an exhaustive system of initial pre-diploma testing, and airtight procedures which ensure competence throughout their careers? This, at least, is the theory. But the practice, according to University of Alberta History Professor Ronald Hamowy, is far different. According to Hamowy, the author of Canadian Medicine: A Study in Restricted Entry, a book recently published by The Fraser Institute, the function of medical licensing in this country is not so much to insure physician quality, as it is to limit entry into every field, so as to increase the income, power, and prestige of those doctors already in practice. According to the evidence amassed in this book, the Canadian medical establishment at one point or another n its history has: banned price and other advertising for licensed doctors: set minimum price schedules; acted to prevent "overcrowding," or an oversupply of physicians by setting up a whole host of irrelevant criteria for licensing- examples include a knowledge of grammar, mathematics, Latin, history, philosophy, and other academic studies, language requirements, citizenship, etc; Outlawed the uncontrolled study of medicine, even for those who do not intend to practice; placed roadblocks against foreign doctors practicing in Canada, where they would compete with domestic physicians; been content with imposing entry examinations only. If The certification of quality were the true goal of these exams, they would more likely be required of practicing physicians at least every decade or so. For, says Hamowy, there is little guarantee - certainly not on the basis of testing -that a doctor of seventy years of age is still qualified, merely for having successfully sat an examination forty years earlier; fought against pre-payment contract practice, opposed doctors testifying for plaintiffs in malpractice suits, and discouraged charity work as undermining minimum fee schedules and professional prestige; raised medical student fees in order to increase the cost of entry Into the profession; Succeeded, from time to time, in raising physicians' income levels beyond that of other, equally skilled, professions in Canada. These claims, and much of the data Professor Hamowy has unearthed, are a part of the Canadian historical record with which most people, even doctors, may not be familiar. The evidence he cites will thus come as a distinct and uncomfortable surprise to most Canadians. And for good reason. This is because the typical doctor in this country is not at all involved in limiting entry into the field as a means of feathering his own nest. On the contrary the average physician works long hard hours (Winston Churchill's oft-quoted remark about "blood, sweat, and tears" is a particularly apt description of medical practice), and has as his main concern the practice of his profession, not the financial exploitation of his patients. Thus the truth or falsity of Hamowy's claims cannot be based on the experience of individual physicians who do not perceive themselves to be engaged in restricting their competitors. On the other hand, as Hamowy's research shows, the leadership of the medical profession in conjuncture with well-meaning, though paternalist, bureaucrats have been doing just that for a century. If the present licensing system has failed, what, then, can be done about the epidemic of doctors who are either incompetent and/or sheer frauds? The public policy recommendation which follows from Hamowy's analysis would be to install a system of competitive certification, in place of the present system of monopoly licensing, Under licensing, if the applicant fails the test, he cannot practice (as in the motor vehicle license); under certification, a rejected applicant can still practice (a non chartered accountant ma» legally help people fill out tax forms), but he cannot pass himself off as certified. The problem with monopoly licensing (as with all other coercive monopolies) is that If the institution in charge does a poor job, consumers have no alternative. Under competition, there is an incentive system for all competitors to try to outdistance each other in terms of quality control, innovativeness, cost-cutting, etc. The weakest producers are forced to the sidelines, the strongest can expand the scope of their operations, to the ultimate and on-going improvement of the industry. Although provision of knowledge to health care consumers about the skill, qualifications, experience, and general trustworthiness of doctors may not appear at first blush to be an "industry," the effects of competition would operate here as well. How might competition work in the medical profession? Were government so minded, it could announce that at some time hence (say, ten years) it would call a halt to the present monopoly system of licensing doctors. This would usher In a competitive certification system to begin at present, to co-exist with licensing for the next decade, and to be launched out on its own at that point. What kind of firms might undertake such an endeavor? One likely scenario would have various certification agencies- the Canadian Medical Association itself, the Royal College of Physicians and Surgeons of the provinces, the McGill University Medical Faculty, major insurance companies, for example - all competing with each other as to which might best be able to ensure the quality of physicians to the general public. Under such a system, the quality of medicine and the extent of monitoring medical practice would improve to the great benefit of the health care of the Canadian populace. MOVIE REVIEW LIBEL by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute Attention all novelists, poets, artists, playwrights, actors, musicians, dancers, athletes, composers, and writ-era. You say you don't like the reviews you've been receiving lately? Who the hell do those critics think they are, right? Have you ever felt, "Let them get out on stage and perform, we'll see how they do," eh? Well, as the old aphorism goes, "Don't get mad, get even." Have I got an idea for you: sue theml This, at least, was the response taken by Cineplex Odeon Corp. to a negative review which appeared in the Toronto Star. Not that the nation's largest movie distributor didn't try to block publication of the offending column in the first place. They indeed made this attempt, and succeeded in obtaining an injunction, but when this was later set aside, Cineplex launched a libel suit against Toronto's afternoon newspaper. The newspaper column in question is entitled "On Your Behalf," and appeared on the front page of the entertainment section. Written by Toronto Star editor Douglas Marshall, the piece objected not to the movie exhibited by Cineplex, but to its practice of showing a 30second advertisement for an athletic shoe company right before the feature film. In the humble opinion of the present writer, Marshall's attack on the ancient and honorable practice was as snarly, low-down and worthless a piece of journalism as has ever graced the pages of a major newspaper. Further, it was hypocritical in the extreme, in that Marshall's employer, the Toronto Star, depends for a large part of its revenues upon this self-same practice of advertising. Cineplex Odeon could have contented itself with a back of the hand slap at Marshall along the lines of pots calling kettles black. Better yet, it might have launched an ad campaign of its own, publicly defending its decision to help make consumers :iware of products being made available to them under our marvelous system of free enterprise (commercial advertising of this sort is virtually unknown behind the Iron,Curtain.) Had they done any of these things, they would have been completely in the right. In the event, however, the movie distributor chose to deny Douglas Marshall his right to express his ludicrous opinions and the Star to print them. (I realize I am opening myself up to a possible libel suit, this time from Mr. Marshall or the Toronto Star; all I can say is, someone has to defend free speech, somewhere along the line, otherwise there will be no advertising and ultimately, no newspapers either). Odeon did so on the ground that "On Your Behalf" was "false, scurrilous and malicious," and would damage its reputation in the eyes of the cinema-going public. Unfortunately, our libel laws are based on the premise that reputations are the legitimate possessions of those to whom they refer. That is to say, I own my reputation, you own yours, Marshall, the Star and Cineplex Odeon own theirs. But nothing could be further from the truth. As a matter of fact, the reputation of each of us consists of the thoughts of everyone else except its purported owner. In other words, my reputation consists of the thoughts that everyone else may have about me. My own thoughts about myself do not form part of my reputation. Similarly, the reputation claimed by Cineplex consists of the thoughts of all other persons, except for this movie distributor. Since no one can properly claim to own the thoughts of other people, they cannot legitimately own their "own" reputations. As if this were not paradox enough, our reputations would undoubtedly be safer (even though they cannot be owned by ourselves) in the complete absence of all libel prohibitions. Right now, if we are "victimized" by a scurrilous attack, it may easily succeed in loss of good will and other economic setbacks. People reason that were the story not true, the victim would sue for libel. The problem with this is that libel suits are expensive, and only rich individuals or corporations can undertake them. (When was the last bisr.e you heard of Joe lunch-bucket suing for libel). As well, were libel legislation completely rescinded, attacks on reputation would come so thick and fast that they would lose all power to injure. Under a regime of full free speech, mere allegation would no longer be able to damage a reputation; the facts would have to be ascertained. - 30 742 words .-^ -\^!S JC-'C"' Newfoundland Labour Strike jV^U by Walter Block, Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. The labour scene in Newfoundland is heating up once again. This time it is the Newfoundland Association of Public Employees (N.A.P.E.) which finds itself on the barricades. This 1,700 member union is engaged in a struggle with the Newfoundland Transportation and Public Works Department over a demand that their $6 to $8 an hour wages be lifted to match those which prevail in other provincial ministries. The organized workers are also campaigning against Bill 59, a law which declares essential (and therefore prohibits from striking) a proportion of all public sector bargaining units. The altercation over these issues has turned bitter. The strike has been declared illegal, and several N.A.P.E. officials have already been jailed for persisting in it. The likelihood is that more imprisonments will follow. John Fryer, president of the 250,000-strong National Union of Provincial Government Employees, vows that his group will fully support the local union. A member of the Canadian delegation to the International Labour Organization, Mr. Fryer has characterized Bill 59's strike limitation provisions as a "threat to the rights of free people in a free society," and intends to raise this issue with the I.L.O. Tempers are short, and all that is needed for a "made-in-Canada" version of the Arthur Scargill led British miners strike, is a spark hitting the dry tinder. This Newfoundland labour fracas raises an important question which has application far beyond its provincial borders. If we sit back and look at the issue with a some historical perspective, we can see that this episode does not really fit the classical economic model wherein business and labour meet in head-on confrontation. In that scenario, the capitalist was presumed to be a profit maximizer, and therefore unwilling and even unable to deal fairly with his employees. The government was thus brought into the picture, in order to play an unbiased and intermediary role. But in the present Newfoundland controversy, business has no part at all. We rather find the forces of unionism in confrontation with government, the institution presumed by the classical theory to be above the labour-management struggle. It is almost as if one hockey team were now trying to overcome not its opponent, but rather the referee, and the latter, instead of insisting that its role be respected, has entered the fray with alacrity. In such a case, who can act as the nonpartisan umpire? The answer is. No one! (The courts and judges in this country are correctly seen as part and parcel of the government which pays their salary, and through whose good offices they are appointed.) This is why labour strikes against government are so threatening to the very social fabric upon which civilization rests, in a way that business-union quarrels are not, and can never be. What can be done about this? We must first recognize that the classical theory was predicated upon the state truly being above the fray, apart from the hurley burley world of commerce. But once the modern government entered the realm of business, with its panoply of crown corporations and product-oriented ministries, a fatal contradiction arose. It was as if the hockey referee picked up the stick, and tried to knock the puck into one (or both) of the goals, all the while insisting that he be allowed to keep the whistle between his lips, and that the two teams respect his position as umpire. The point is, the two roles are simply incompatible. Government can be the referee (the classical-liberal definition of this institution), or government can be a player, but it cannot (successfully) be both. One or the other must go. When put into these terms, it is painfully obvious which way our society must move. There is only one choice if we are to avoid the chaos involved in having either no referee at all, or what is almost worse, a referee who is not respected because correctly perceived as party to the altercation. And that of course is a move toward privitization: government must be encouraged to sell off crown corporations in a wholesale manner not yet even contemplated by the present administration; the public sector must divest itself on a massive scale of its lands, businesses, commercial undertakings, and those ministries involved in competing with the private sector; the apparatus of the state must cease and desist from attempting to provide goods and services whose manufacture could be organized through the marketplace. Then, secure in the knowledge that it can at last play a truly judiciary role in labour management relations, government can in good conscience ban public sector unions. (This i^ould not mean that individual civil servants could not quit, nor even that they could not quit, or threaten to do so, en masse; it would only mean that society would no longer grant to these institutions special privileges to picket -- privileges denied all other citizens.) First of all, there would no longer be much of a public sector left for unions to organize. And what of those functions which would still remain even after a wholesale privitization (police, fire, army, courts, welfare, etc.)? Here, we could at last approach the classical model where government could be sharply distinguished from business enterprise: the latter might be seen by some as having interests diametrically opposed to organized labour, but this would no longer apply to the former. In this way respect for the refereeing process in Canada could be resurrected. In this way, and only in this way, can our nation be spared some of the agonized labour strife suffered by many of our neighbors. - 30 - Pay Equity-by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Canada is now in the process of implementing a spate of legislation in order to promote "equality in employment", as called for most notably by Judge Rosalie Abella. The main finding of the Abella Royal Commission is that the female-male wage ratio of 63.9 percent in 1982 is largely due to sexual discrimination on the part of the nation's employers, both public and private. Its chief recommendation is that a new affirmative action policy of "employment equity" be implemented, which would require business and Crown corporations to change their hiring and promotion practices, until balanced job representation and equal pay have been much more nearly attained. However, this is the wrong solution to a non-existent problem. The major finding of the Fraser Institute study is that the income gap between genders is not due to employer discrimination, but rather to differences in productivity. There is no determination that these differences are inherent, or based on genetics. Rather, one major factor is the asymmetrical effect of marriage on earnings. It raises the earnings of the husband, and reduces those of the wife. This, in turn, is because of unequal child care and house management responsibilities, different psychic, attachments to the labour force vs. home and hearth. The proof? Women who have never been touched by the institution of marriage, and who thus can be presumed to have productivity levels similar to those of men, do not suffer from lower incomes. The statistics are revealing. In 1981, the last year for which such data is available, the female-male ratio for Canadians who have never been married was 83.1 percent. But even this is an underestimate of the true relationship, because the statistics have not been corrected for labour force experience, age, education, unionization, etc. When just one of these corrections is made, for example, and we compare female to male incomes ratios for never-marrieds with a university degree, the figure rises to 91.3 percent. (For 1971. such university educated nevermarried females actually earned 9.8 percent more than their equally accomplished male counterparts!). In other words, when we consider only males and females who have never been touched by the productivity-differentiating institution of marriage, that is, compare men and women who are likely to have similar market productivities, we find no statistically significant differences in their earnings. The Perils of Nuclear Energy? by Dr. Waiter Block The recent death of 84 men with the sinking of the oil drilling rig Ocean Ranger off Newfoundland was a great tragedy. All the more reason, then to re-examine the widely publicized misgivings about nuclear energy foisted upon us by the "ecology" movement. The Ocean Ranger tragedy was not, unfortunately, the first energyrelated accident to claim numerous lives. Ralher, the non-nuclear energy field has been plagued with a series of similar mishaps. Other recent offshore oil drilling rig mass fatalities include: the capsizing of the 10,000 ton Alexander Kielland accommodation rig off Norway in the North Sea in March 1980, with the catastrophic loss of 123 lives. A November 1979 oil rig collapse during a storm in the Bohai Gulf of northeast China, which killed 72 workmen. A blow out in October 1980 of the U.S.-owned rig Tappmeyer off Saudi Arabia in which 18 people perished. Coal mining, too, has been marred by numerous large-scale accidents, the world over: In Canada, the Nova Scotia coal mine "Springhill" was the site of a disaster which claimed 39 lives in 1956, and another 74 in 1958. In the US roughly 300 coal miners die In the line of duty every year. In addition to cave-ins, coal miners have long been subject to the dreaded "black-lung" disease which has crippled many, and directly or indirectly killed many others. If this past record looks bleak, the future bodes ill as well. Despite ever-improving technologies, as the quest for offshore oil continues apace, into evermore inhospitable environments, the only rational expectation is for more of the same, only more so. The same holds true for coal mining. If energy prices continue their recently interrupted upward path, one source of additional coal supplies may be to dig deeper — into increasingly more dangerous terrain. Strip-mining of coal nearer to the surface brings in its wake the risk of water run offs, and slides, and other hazards — vociferously pointed out to us by the self-styled "ecologists". And other alternative energy supplies come with dangers of their own. The recent hydro-electric dam eruption which drowned thousands of people in India is a chilling case in point. What of nuclear power? Despite the widespread media-led wailing and gnashing of teeth which accompanied the meltdown at Three Mile Island in Pennsylvania, the plain fact is that not a single solitary radiation-related death has occurred in the quarter century of commercial nuclear power generation. And yet the litany goes on. Protestors at nuclear power station continually attempt to halt operations — and are accorded a respectful-to-fawning hearing by the nation's press. Although trespassers on private property, the protesters are given credit for "morality" and "concern". Based on the well-attended movie "China Syndrome" starring trendy lefties Jane Fonda and Jack Lemmon, the impartial observer would be led to think that oil, gas, coal, and hydroelectric power were cheap and safe energy sources, while nuclear was a mass killer. Can anyone imagine how the media would have reacted had the victims of the Ocean Ranger instead perished In a nuclear accident? There is little doubt that the nuclear industry would have been brought to its knees. A sea of front page news coverage would have made the publicity accompanying the repatriation of the Canadian Constitution seem pale by comparison. It is time, it is long past time to redress this imbalanced analysis which has been perpetrated upon society. This does not mean, of course, that we must bring the same unreasoning passion to bear on the traditional energy industries, as the left wing "ecologists" have long aimed at nuclear power. This would mean a serious curtailment of all energy supplies — and the death of millions of consumers who are dependent upon energy for their very lives. On the contrary, a more sober and measured evaluation would appear to be in order. One which looks carefully at the evidence before launching into public policy recommendations. And when this is done, the conclusion is inescapable that nuclear must be allowed to compete fairly with all other energy industries without fear or favor on either side. May, 1982 Sterling Newspapers. A policy that needs some improvements 3. ew Democratic Party housing critic Robin Blencoe (MLA, Victoria) released a position paper which proposes to provide adequate shelter at affordable prices for all British Columbians. Unfortunately, this missive is part ofthe problem, not part of the solution. It advocates precisely the policies which have brought us to our present sorry housing mess. If acted upon, the document will worsen our situation, not improve it. It is tempting to dismiss this initiative as the blatherings of an unreconstructed socialist, and to let it go at that. Unfortunately, however, we cannot do this. Mr. Blencoe is more than likely to become the minister of housing in any future NDP government, and that scenario is fully within the realm of possibility. So his proposal, if for no other reason, deserves our serious consideration. Let us consider the elements of the program: • A tax on speculative housing flippers. Although the continual move of housing prices toward the stratosphere has been somewhat curtailed of late, prices are still far too high for many first-time homebuyers and young families. But prices can rise whether or not speculators enter the market. Successful speculators sell when prices are high and buy when they are low. By doing so, they iron out price fluctuations, lowering the pinnacles, and raising the troughs. Taxing such public beneficiaries will only increase the violability of this sector of the economy, something no one wants, even NDP housing ministers. • Re-institute the Rentalsman. Rent control or rent review reduces the supply of rental accommodation. Other things equal, investors will be less likely to place their hard-earned money in this sector with these programs in effect. With fewer units available, vacancy rates cannot rise. Office towers have ~ever been subject to controls of this sort; their supply is continually increasing, and vacancy rates are relatively high. • Allow municipalities to charge developers for added burdens on roads, sewers, schools, etc. This excrescence from the slow-growth philosophy will have precisely the opposite results from those intended. Its purpose is presumably to promote house-building, so as to combat the shortage now afflicting the citizenry. How will placing rates and greater burdens on builders encourage them to create more housing? • Develop a comprehensive government program for affordable rental to home ownership. If we have learned anything from the disarray of the Soviet and Eastern European economies, it is that central planning doesn't work. That decades-long experiment should have convinced all of us that what is needed for a sound economy, and a healthy vibrant housing sector, is greater reliance on decentralized markets, not on provincial economic czars. . • Land banking, a ban on public land sales, and a retention of the Agricultural Land Reserve. These programs, too, are part of the problem, not part of the solution. The last thing we need to solve the housing crisis is for land to be artificially kept off the market. Building lots are a major part of the costs of new housing. The greater their supply, the lower their price, and the lower their price, the more housing that can be inexpensively created. In B.c., great gobs of land, perfectly suited for development, are being held off the market, courtesy of the Agricultural Land Reserve, a policy created by the 1972-75 NDP government. If Mr. Blencoe really wants to lower housing prices, he would urge wiping this element of Soviet-style central planning off the books, something the supposedly freeenterprise Social Credit government has so far-in its 15 years in power-been unable or unwilling to do. This housing agenda shows that the NDP has not yet changed its socialist spots. At a time when the momentum is toward economic freedom, their stance takes on all the attributes of an ostrich with its head in the sand. And that is really too bad, especially given the New Zealand experience. There, under the inspired leadership of Roger Douglas, a social democratic labour -based party was able to modernize and rationalize the economy, in a decentralized direction. When will our home-grown socialists learn to borrow a leaf from their New Zealand counterparts? N Dr. Block is an economist with the Fraser Institute. BRITISH COLUMBIA REPORT, JUL Y 16, 1990 19 NDP Housing Policy by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.c. New Democratic Party Housing Critic Robin Blencoe (MIA, Victoria) released a position paper which attempts to help provide adequate shelter at affordable prices for all British Columbians. Unfortunately, this missive is part of the problem, not part of the solution. It advocates precisely the policies which have brought us to our present sorry housing mess. If acted upon, the document will worsen our situation, not improve it. It is tempting to dismiss this initiative as the blatherings of an unreconstructed socialist, and to let it go at that. Unfortunately, however, we cannot do this. Blencoe is more than likely to become the Minister of Housing in any future NDP government, and that scenario is fully within the realm of possibility. So his proposal, if for no other reason, deserves our serious consideration. Let us consider the elements of the program: · A tax on speculative housing flippers. Although the continual move of housing prices toward the stratosphere has been somewhat curtailed of late, they are still far too expensive for many first time home buyers and young families. But prices can rise whether or not speculators enter the market. Successful speculators sell when prices are high and buy when they are low. By doing so, they iron out price fluctuations, lowering the pinnacles, and raising the troughs. Taxing such public beneficiaries will only increase the violability of this sector of the economy, something that no one wants, even potential NDP housing ministers. · Re-institute the Rentalsman. Rent control or rent review reduces the supply of rental accommodation. Other things equal, investors will be less likely to place their hard earned money in this sector with these programs in effect. With fewer units available, vacancy rates cannot rise. Office towers have never been subject to controls of this sort; their supply is continually increasing, and vacancy rates are relatively high. Instead of the rentalsman, we should move in the opposite direction and constitutionally guarantee that government rent monitoring will never again occur. Then residential renters will be placed in the enviable position how enjoyed by their commercial counterparts. · Allow municipalities to charge developers for added burdens on roads, sewers, schools, etc. This excrescence from the slow growth philosophy will have precisely the opposite results from those intended. Its purpose is presumably to promote house building, so as to combat the shortage now afflicting the citizenry. How will placing rates and greater burdens on builders encourage them to create more housing? Why, in any case, impose the costs of infrastructure on developers? Is that not the very purpose for which taxes are collected in the first place? Nor is it any accident that economic development is seen as a ''burden'' on such facilities. They are now, unfortunately, provided to us by government. Were they to be privatized, as they should be, development would no more be seen as a burden on infrastructure than infrastructure is now seen as a burden on housing. . Develop a comprehensive government program for affordable rental to home ownership. If there is anything that we have learned from the disarray of the Soviet and Eastern European economies, it is that central planning doesn't work. That decades long experiment should have convinced all of us that what is needed for a sound economy, and a healthy vibrant housing sector, is greater reliance on decentralized markets, not on provincial economic czars. . Land banking, a ban on public land sales, and a retention of the Agricultural Land Reserve. These programs, too, are part of the problem, not part of the solution. The last thing we need to solve the housing crisis is for land to be artificially kept off the market. Building lots are a major part of the costs of new housing. The greater their supply, the lower their price; and the lower their price, the more housing that can be inexpensively created. In B.C., great gobs of land, perfectly suited for development, are being held off the market, courtesy of the Agricultural Land Reserve, a policy created by the 197275 NDP government. If Blencoe really wants to lower housing prices, he would urge wiping this element of Soviet-style central planning off the books, something the supposedly free enterprise Social Credit government has so far -- in its 15 years in power -- been unable or unwilling to do. This housing agenda shows that the NDP has not yet changed its socialist spots. At a time when the momentum is toward economic freedom, their stance takes on all the attributes of an ostrich with its head in the sand. And that is really too bad, especially given the New Zealand experience. There, under the inspired leadership of Roger Douglas, a social democratic labour-based party was able to modernize and rationalize the economy, in a decentralized direction. When will our home-grown socialists learn to borrow a leaf from their New Zealand counterparts? - 30- NDP Housing Policy by Walter Block, Senior Research Fellow, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. NDP Housing Critic Robin Blencoe (MLA, Victoria) has just released a position paper which attempts to solve problems in that field. Unfortunately, it is part of the problem, not part of the solution. It advocates precisely the policies which have brought us to our present sorry housing mess. If acted upon, it will worsen our situation, not improve it. Let us consider the elements of the program: · A tax on speculative housing flippers. House prices are escalating toward the stratosphere because demand is vastly outstripping supply. Prices rise whether or not speculators enter the market. Successful speculators sell when prices are high and buy when they are low. By doing so, they iron out prices, lowering the pinnacles, and raising the troughs. Taxing such public beneficiaries will only increase the violability of this sector of the economy, something that no one wants, even potential NDP housing ministers. · Re-institute the Rentalsman. Rent control or rent review reduces the supply of rental accommodation. Other things equal, investors will be less likely to place their hard earned money in this sector with these programs in effect. With fewer units available, vacancy rates cannot rise. Office towers have never been subject to controls of this sort; their supply is continually increasing, and vacancy rates are relatively high. Instead of the rentalsman, we should move in the opposite direction and constitutionally guarantee that government rent monitoring will never again occur. Then residential renters will be placed in the enviable position how enjoyed by their commercial counterparts. · Allow municipalities to charge developers for added burdens on roads, sewers, schools, etc. This excrescence from the slow growth philosophy will have precisely the opposite results from those intended. The purpose of this proposal is presumably to promote house building, so as to combat the shortage now afflicting the citizenry. How will placing rates and greater burdens on builders encourage them to create more housing? Why, in any case, impose the costs of infrastructure on developers? Is that not the very purpose for which taxes are collected in the first place? Nor is it any accident that economic development is seen as a "burden" on such facilities. They are now, unfortunately, provided to us by government. Were they to be privatized, as 1 they should be, development would no more be a burden on infrastructure than infrastructure is now a burden on housing. . Develop a comprehensive government program for affordable rental to home ownership. If there is anything that we have learned from the disarray of the Soviet and Eastern European economies, it is that central planning doesn't work. That decades long experiment should have convinced all of us that what is needed for a sound economy, and a healthy vibrant housing sector, is greater reliance on decentralized markets, not on provincial economic czars. . Land banking, a ban on public land sales, a retention of the Agricultural Land Reserve. These programs, too, are part of the problem, not part of the solution. The last thing we need to solve the housing crisis is for land to be artificially kept off the market. Building lots are a major part of the costs of new housing. The greater their supply, the lower their price; and the lower their price, the more housing that can be inexpensively created. This housing agenda shows that the NDP has not yet changed its socialist spots. At a time when the momentum is toward economic freedom, their stance takes on all the attributes of an ostrich with its head in the sand. And that is really too bad, especially given the New Zealand experience. There, under the inspired leadership of Roger Douglas, a social democratic labour-based party was able to modernize and rationalize the economy, in a decentralized direction. When will our home-grown socialists learn to borrow a leaf from their New Zealand counterparts? - 30- 2 IN PRAISE OF UNIONISM by Walter Block There are two possible types of unions: compulsory and voluntary. The sole difference between a legitimate and an illegitimate union is that in case of a strike, the latter will threaten to interfere with the bosses' and "scabs'" persons or property, or ask that the government do so on its behalf, while the former will refrain from these coercive activities. (A "scab" is the term of denigration applied by some, to people who are willing to accept employment conditions rejected by strikers. In a truly free society, such employment contracts would be considered as valid as any other; in a truly just society, no tinge of impropriety or immorality would attach to such workers.) A union which forcibly prevents the factory owner from hiring a strikebreaker is like a husband who divorces his wife — and then threatens to beat her up, and any prospective suitor as well — if she tries to remarry. But a union that will not threaten or initiate the use of force (except, of course, in self defense against physical abuse) is entirely legitimate. It has as much right as any other respected institution in society. It can provide great benefits to its members, and to the general public as well. As the great economist Henry Hazlitt said: "The central function unions can serve is to improve local working conditions and to assure that all of their members get the true market value of their services." For the competition of workers for jobs, and of employers for workers, does not work perfectly. Neither individual workers nor individual employers are likely to be fully informed concerning the conditions of the labor market. An individual worker may not know the true market value of his services to an employer. And he may be in a weak bargaining position. Mistakes of judgement are far more costly to him that to an employer. If an employer mistakenly refuses to hire a man from whose services he might have profited, he merely loses the net profit he might have made from employing that one man; and he may employ a hundred or a thousand men. But if a worker mistakenly refuses a job in the belief that he can easily get another that will pay him more, the error may cost him dear. His whole means of livelihood is involved. Not only may he fail promptly to find another job offering more; he may fail for a time to find another job offering remotely as much. And time may be the essence of his problem, because he and his family must eat. So he may be tempted to take a wage that he believes to be below his "real worth" rather than face these risks. When an employer's workers deal with him as a body, however, and set a known "standard wage" for a given class of work, they may help to equalize bargaining power and the risks involved in mistakes." With regard to such legitimate unions, I have nothing but praise. They are an integral part of society, and should be protected to the fullest extent of the law. To this end, prohibitions against the closed shops (based on the fallacious "right to work" doctrine) should be repealed. A union and an employer can come to a voluntary agreement whereby all workers must be . members of the labor organization as a precondition of employment. This is a contract between consenting adults, and must be upheld in the same manner as all other commercial agreements. Outside workers have no more "right to work" for an employer who has signed such a contract than does the "other woman" have a "right to marry" an already married man. Nor should such legitimate unions be precluded from engaging in boycotts, whether primary, secondary or even tertiary. Part of the system of consumer sovereignty, of which we are so justly proud in the Western democracies, is the right not to buy. If a person may properly refuse to purchase an item for whatever reason, so may others, even if they act in concert. We must never forget that union members are citizens too, and do not give up their rights as consumers when they join a labor organization. Jews and Hindus boycott pork; vegetarians refuse all meat; Greenpeace members do not buy fur coats; athiests reject religious implements; reformed alcoholics do not purchase booze. Where is the justice in singling out unions, and requiring that they alone not be allowed to boycott? And in like manner, compulsory labor arbitration is an affront to organized working men and women. To force people to work for wages and under conditions they find unacceptable is a step down the road toward slavery. Compulsory labor arbitration and the involuntary servitude it breeds must be opposed by all men of good will. However, and this is a giant caveat, this analysis does not apply to unions which either use physical violence against "scabs," or urge that the government do so in its behalf. (The Wagner and NLRB Acts make it an "unfair labor practice" and hence illegal, to hire (permanent) replacements for striking employees.) Such unions, unfortunately the overwhelming majority nowadays, are coercive, involuntary and hence illegitimate. Any good effects they might conceivably have on society such as outlined above are as nothing, compared to . the monumental evil of initiating physical aggression against those who have not first engaged in physical aggression: the employer who is trying to "divorce" his union, and the "other woman," or workers who are willing to accept the terms rejected by the striking workers. But what of the claim that "unions raise wages?" Is this not a great benefit brought about by unionism, whether legitimately or not? Price Gouging It is easy to see why prices of many goods and services would rise in cities holding sports or civic spectaculars, such as the Olympics or Expo. With tens and even hundreds of thousands of tourists suddenly descending upon a city, the demand for goods and services severely outpaces the supply. Especially affected are items normally utilized by out-of-towners: hotel rooms, taxi cabs, rental automobiles, parking, bed and breakfast emporiums, and restaurants. Such increases in prices usually offend local politicians, who object on two grounds. First, they feel that price rises are somehow unfair and improper. This sentiment is quite understandable. No one likes to be taken advantage of, and price gouging during a time of great demand would appear to be quite underhanded. Nevertheless, price rises have a role to play in a market economy. They signal an abrupt increase in the importance placed upon a good or service. If prices spurt upwards in Vancouver during a world exposition, this is a signal to all entrepreneurs. It is akin to a cry for help. It provides the knowledge that there is a sudden need for more goods and services there, at the same time it also provides, through the prospect of greater profits, the incentive to satisfy that need. To the extent that increased supply is thus called for, the original price increase will be tamped down. If local politicians forbid price gouging, they cut off this vital information and sever the incentive to "rescue" the beleaguered visitors. If politicians are really concerned with the plight of consumers, instead of worrying about price gouging they would do better by eliminating some of the laws they themselves have enacted which have the effect of reducing the supply of goods and services that can be offered to the market. For example, they could relax the laws which retard the operation of the bed and breakfast industry, which interfere with street peddlers of food, which prohibit alternative taxi services, and which prohibit the location of recreational vehicles and campers in certain areas of the city. But there is a second objection to price gouging. It is felt that such behavior reflects badly upon a city, and that although tourists may put up with it while they visit for the special event, a bad taste will be left in their mouths which will make a return visit unlikely. However, as we have seen, if markets are free and if the gouging calls forth additional supplies, price rises will be moderated. As well, if prices cannot ration limited supplies to an excessive number of would-be buyers, other institutions favouritism, graft, first come first served^— will have to do so, and these have drawbacks of their own. Even worse, these alternative arrangements do not encourage a solution of the problem through increased supply. W.B. ^ii ^(e-3! Rent Control: A tale of two Canadian cities by Walter Block The rental housing experiences of Vancouver and Toronto serve almost as a laboratory test of the effects of rent control legislation. Consider their histories. British Columbia enacted province-wide rent controls in 1972, under the N.D.P. government of then Premier Dave Barrett; the phasing out process began on July 1, 1983, and ended on July 1, 1984 at the behest of then Premier Bill Bennett and the Social Credit Party. Ontario began its experiment with government central housing planning in 1975 under the supposedly Progressive Conservatives of Bill Davis, and still retains them to this day with David Peterson and the Liberals at the helm. What occurred in the two rental housing markets as a result? There are many possible ways to trace the effects: rent levels, units of new construction, housing maintenance or deterioration, homelessness, etc. But the easiest and best variable is that of vacancy rates. These are objective, easily calculated, and interact with all the others. E.g., the lower the vacancy rate, other things equal, the higher die rents, the greater the homelessness, etc. They are published twice annually, in April and October (in June and December up until 1974), so reasonable coverage for each year is provided. Let us first consider the vacancy experience of the two cities from October 1984 to October 1988, the time during which Vancouver no longer had rent controls, but Toronto did. As the accompanying chart makes clear, for each and every one of the nine observations during this epoch, Toronto had a lower vacancy rate than Vancouver. This indicates a tighter market in Ontario, with higher rent levels, more difficulty in finding an apartment suite to rent, less new rental construction, etc. Nor are the differences only marginal. Over this short '84 to '88 time period as a whole, the average Toronto vacancy rate was a minuscule 0.34%. The comparable figure for Vancouver was a relatively healthy 1.53%, fully 350% higher. Nor can it be objected that Vancouver "traditionally" has a higher vacancy rate than Toronto, or has always had one. A perusal of the earlier years shows ;i mixed record, with the vacancy rate sometimes higher in one city, and sometimes in the other. Over all, for the period June 1972 to April 1984, Toronto actually had a slightly higher vacancy rate at 1.18%, than Vancouver at 0.90%. A wealth of evidence showing the dismal effect of controls on rental housing was presented in the Fraser Institute's best selling 1983 book, Rent Control: Myths and Realities. But as this study makes abundantly clear, rent controls are a subtle andinvidious piece of legislation. For not only will the law itself lead to rental housing disarray, even the threat of it will tend to do the same, as would-be landlords seek greener, freer, less controlled options for their investment dollar. It is no accident, for example, that Vancouver's vacancy rate for October 1988, at 0.4%, was the lowest it had ever reached since controls were repealed. Given the inevitable time lags in such matters, this coincided with the fall from grace in the public opinion polls of Premier Bill Vander Zaim and his Social Credit government. Why should this matter? Because those with money to invest in rental housing reasoned that if the Socred government falls in the next election, the overwhelming probability is that Mike Harcourt and the N.D.P. will sweep in, bringing rent controls in their wake as they did in 1972. And who wants to put his hard-earned money up for ransom under such conditions? This somewhat convoluted scenario may appear to some people as unlikely in the extreme. But consider the fact that we have just witnessed an ominous parallel on the federal scene. Every time John Turner and the Liberals rose in popularity, the Canadian dollar plunged. And when the Mulroney forces improved in the public opinion polls, the value of our dollar increased. This was attributable not to some sort of disembodied Capitalist System speaking out in favour of free trade, but rather to the trust, or lack of it, placed in the Canadian economy on the part of millions ol investors from all around the world. Investors in Canadian rental housing can also read the lips of the various political leaders. SPARE BODY PARTS Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for The Financial Post In the days of yore, there was no &quotcrisis" in spare body parts. Organ transplants were an utter impossibility, the stuff of science fiction. Only Dr. Frankenstein and his literary ilk had any need for live organs. But nowadays, thanks to the magnificent discoveries and new techniques of modern medicine, these possibilities are upon us. At present, it is now possible to transplant hearts, kidneys, blood and corneas. People who would have been consigned to death, or lingering, tenuous and painful lives only a few short years ago, can now avail themselves of these medical miracles and lead healthy, happy, productive lives. All is not well, however, on the organ transplant front. Instead of being the occasion for unrelieved rejoicing, these new breakthroughs have brought in their train a whole host of problems. First of all, there is a shortage of body organs suitable for transplant. It is claimed that some are diseased, and that others would be rejected by the recipient because of incompatible blood types. This had led to a set of problems which have strained what passes for medical ethics in this country to the breaking point. For, given the limited supply of donororgans, our doctors have had to pick and choose — on no criteria whatever other than their own arbitrary whim — which of the many needy recipients shall have this life-giving aid, and which of them shall be denied. The difficulty here, is that our legal-economic system has not kept up with advancing medical technology. The law has prohibited people from using the property rights we each have in our own persons and bodily parts. Specifically, it has banned trade, or a marketplace in live spare body parts. We shall claim that deregulation of this market is the solution to the transplant problem. But before we explain how free enterprise would work in this connection, let us lay a few fears to rest. ' Yes, it is gory, disgusting and very uncomfortable to discuss allowing profit incentives to work in this field. The very idea involves images of grave robbers, Frankenstein monsters, and gangs of &quotorgan thieves" stealing people's hearts, livers and kidneys in the manner described by several novels of Robin Cook. It seems cruel and unfeeling to discuss the market for used body parts in much the same manner as we might describe the used car market. But this is only because in our present society, while we can appreciate the miracles of modern medicine without necessarily comprehending them, we have such a poor understanding of the miracles of the marketplace, and cannot even begin to appreciate them without this knowledge. So let us sit back, and relax, and calmly and dispassionately consider this idea on its own merits, all pre-conceptions and biases to one side. Let our only criteria be not our prejudice, but our assessment of whether this idea will really increase the number of donors, save lives, and free doctors from the onerous decision of picking which needy people shall be saved, and which consigned to a lingering and painful death. Having said this, let us now consider the economics of the situation. As any first year student in economics can tell you, whenever a good is in. short supply, its price is too low. And the case of spare body parts is no exception. On the contrary, it is a paradigm case of this phenomenon. For our laws on this question, in prohibiting a marketplace in human organs, have effectively imposed a zero price on these items. But at a zero price, it should not occasion any surprise that the demand for human organs would vastly outstrip the supply. This, after all, is one of the most basic laws in all of economics. If the price were allowed to rise to its market clearing level, there might not be too great a change in the number of used body parts demanded. This is called by economists "inelastic demand". All it means is that if you need an organ transplant at all, price, no matter how high, within limits of course, is not likely to deter you. No. The main effect of a free market in used bodily parts will be on the amount supplied. How would a marketplace in human organs actually work? While it is never possible to fully anticipate -the functioning of an industry now prohibited by government edict, the following scenario will do as well as any other in describing one possible option. We know that the major source of preferred organ donations will come from young healthy people who are cut down in the prime of life. This can occur in the case of traffic fatalities, murder victims, perhaps, soldiers who die in war, people who die quickly of a disease such as a heart attack, which leaves their other organs intact. Were the industry to be legalized, new firms would spring up. Or perhaps insurance companies, or hospitals would expand their bases of operation. These companies would offer thousands of dollars to people (who met the appropriate medical criteria) who would agree that, upon their demise, their bodily organs would be owned by the firm in question. Then this company would turn around and sell these organs, for a profit, to people in need of an organ transplant. In addition these new firms would operate, as at present, to try to obtain consent from the -4- relatives of newly diseased persons, for use of their organs. Only now, under economic freedom, these firms would be in a position to offer cash incentives — as well as the chance to save another human life. The main effect of such a program would be to vastly increase the supply of donor organs. Certainly, many people in Canada and in the third world as well would be happy to take advantage of this opportunity. No one who objected on religious grounds, for example, would have to cooperate with the venture. As a result, no longer would potential recipients have to make do without transplants. We need not even fear that those who engaged in this practice would earn &quotexhorbitant" profits. For any such tendency would call forth new entrants who would act so as to increase supply even further and reduce profits to levels which could be earned elsewhere. Let us allow free enterprise to work in this field, and save us a lot of pain, sorrow, suffering and tragedy. -303anuary 20, 1984 Replacing Ray Spaxman as Vancouver City's Planning Director/ by Walter Block Ray Spaxman handed in his resignation as Vancouver City's Director of Planning after a 15 year stint on the job, citing his inability to get along with the city council as chief among his reasons for departure. The commentary on this event emanating from the local pundits, politicians and public policy analysts has so far centered on the qualifications needed by his replacement. For example, Alderman Libby Davies has called for a tough minded planner who can see the big picture. In her own words, "the city ... need(s) an ironfisted planner who can visualize Vancouver's skyline in 20 years rather than swaying with the comings and goings of elected councils." In contrast, Mayor Gordon Campbell said he was searching for a person who would serve as a resource to city council. "I think we want someone who is independent and aggressive and yet knows how to provide council with the information it needs to make the right decisions." Should the vision of the new planner be elevated beyond that of the elected city council? Surely this is an anti democratic perspective; why go through the expensive process of voting in the ballot box if the decisions of our political representatives are to be subordinated to civil servants and bureaucrats. On the other hand, the presumption is that the planner, whoever he or she turns out to be, will bring some measure of professional expertise to bear on the questions of zoning and other land use problems. Why accord the primary role in such decision making to a committee of ex-used car salesmen, merchants, teachers, lawyers, unionists, etc? The problem with this entire debate is that it could easily be taking place in the pre-Gorbachev Soviet Union. For that is pre-eminently the country which engages in long and bitter controversies (sometimes fatal ones) over how best to centrally plan the economy. But even the Russians have learned, through bitter experience, that central planning leads to economic chaos. It is the signal contribution of Mikhail Gorbachev that the decentralized marketplace may actually be a better method of organizing economic activity than bureaucratic control. His proposal of perestroika is nothing if not a plan to free up the economy from the controls that have long been exercised by a Ray Spaxman, and would be undertaken by any replacement. Adam Smith, of course, said much the same thing. It is a sad reflection of the intellectual tradition now reigning in Canada that a Soviet dictator is now a more credible authority than a Scottish philosopher in some circles. But given this reality, and given the importance of placing greater reliance on markets, not public managers, we could do worse than apply perestroika to Vancouver city planning; that is, allow this job to go unfilled. But there are those who take the view that city planning is different. They claim that while central planning cannot rationally be applied to agriculture, or mining, or steel making or forestry, it is necessary in order to determine where housing, commerce and industry shall be located. After all, we don't want high rises all over the place; we don't want cement works in the business district; we don't want pickle factories in residential areas; we don't want filling stations located in cul-de-sacs. But there is a fundamental mistake made by these people. They think that if society is to be rationally planned in this manner, there must be an actual person— a Ray Spaxman clone - to do the planning. They fail to reckon with the "invisible hand" of Adam Smith. They do not understand that downtown real estate values are simply too expensive to allow for cement works; that a pickle factory would bankrupt itself trying to buy into Shaughnessy; that placing a gas station in a cul-de-sac is an invitation to economic ruin. Yes, it is hard to visualize how a city the size of Vancouver could grow and develop without anyone at the helm. Fortunately for those lacking in this type of imagination, there is a real world example of a similarly sized city which functions quite nicely thank you without any zoning or central planning: Houston, Texas. Its. story, and the general case against zoning and land use controls, may be found in the; Fraser Institute publication Zoning: Its Costs and Relevance. Stop the Drug Profiteers??? by: Walter Block, The Eraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Once upon a time, in a land far, far away, there was a golden goose. It would lay golden eggs - one per day. But this was the source of the problem: the owner wanted to get rich quick, so he killed the golden goose and we all know what happened after that. Or do we? This is highly questionable that we have learned our lesson, at least in view of some of the problems recently encountered by Burroughs-Wellcome Co., the producers of the AIDS drug AZT, and the modern day equivalent of the golden goose. Last month several AIDS activists chained themselves to the visitors gallery at the New York Stock Exchange, in protest against a pricing policy for AZT, which translates into an annual cost of $8,000 per year per patient. But this is only the tip of the ice-berg. For years self-styled moralists, clergymen, pundits and editorialists have charged that it is unethical to profit from the plight of sick people. Since AIDS sufferers are as desperate as can be imagined, the incessant complaints of these and other know-nothing busybodies have began to be applied to AZT. In this vein, U.S. Senator David Pryor has held hearings, examining the pricing policies of BurroughsWellcome. Congressman Henry Waxman, a long-standing critic of drug industry pricing, maintains that "Congress has the responsibility to ensure that this life saving drug is available to everyone ... and through a reasonable price to all." Possibly as a result of all this brou-ha-ha, AZT prices have been reduced from the $8,000 per year level to $6,000. But this makes as much sense - from the point of view of finding a cure for AIDS - as killing the proverbial golden goose. What kind of signal is this sending out to all potential discoverers of an antidote for this dreadful disease? Will it encourage them to keep the laboratory lights burning all night? Will it lead them to invest more money to this end? Will it push the next generation of scientists and medical researchers into this field, or dissuade them from it? Far from trying to reduce profits in this industry. AIDS victims and their supporters should urge the very opposite course (if action. They should hold ticker-tape parades for Burroughs-Wellcome executives and employees. They should carry them on their shoulders around town. as we do for winning spirts figures. Instead of attacking its bottom line, they should be donating money to this heroic company. Profit controls are like regulations limiting the decibels with which campers lost in the woods can cry out for rescue. If we are to wrestle the deadly AIDS virus to its knees, and are for socialist ideological reasons intent upon using price and profit controls, it would be much better to interfere in this way with every other industry under the sun except for pharmaceuticals. In that way, funds would flow from other sectors into drug research. Pryor, Waxman and the gay community have their priorities exactly backwards. There is one way, however, that AZT prices can be sharply reduced - without endangering the quest for an AIDS solution. The average cost of developing a new drug and getting it past Food and Drug Administration hurdles is about $70 million. Eliminating Phase-3 tests alone would reduce this by some 30%. Better yet, disbanding the PDA entirely would reduce drug prices even more. If the crucially important task of certifying the safety of drugs were privatized, sick and dying people would be able at long last to exercise their rights of free choice. Information about drug reliability would be supplied more cheaply and accurately by private enterprise, organized into a competitive industry in order to accomplish that task. Remember, the FDA is the institution responsible for keeping AZT off the market while many AIDS sufferers had to go without, and for giving its imprimatur to thalidomide. Surely a competitive private drug testing industry could do far better than that. - 30Teen Suicide by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute According to two recent studies reported on in the prestigious New England Journal of Medicine, television news stories and dramas about suicide have been responsible for an increase in the suicide rate amongst teenagers. Paradoxically, this unfortunate effect has resulted even from programs which were ostensibly designed to increase public awareness of the problem -- in the hopes of reducing it. According to the psychiatrists who undertook the research, the young people in question ignored the message being broadcast to them, and instead engaged in "imitative suicidal behaviour". The television networks which were involved in these episodes issued immediate challenges to the findings. One spokesperson sharply denied that any causal relationship had been established between the T.V. shows and an upsurge in teen suicides. However, the scientists had studied 38 such shows which were broadcast between 1973 and 1979, and found an average increase of 2.91 suicides in the following eight day period -- a result which could not be explained through normal statistical variance. Let us not argue over the facts of the case. Instead, let us assume for the sake of argument that the finding of a causal relationship between these programs and subsequent suicides is correct. What follows, if anything, from such a stipulation? In the view of some public policy analysts, there would then be a clear case for banning all television treatments of suicide. (This, at least, would be the reasoning of those who urge that pornography be prohibited on the ground that it leads to rape). The difficulty with this stance is that it can interfere with not only the free speech rights of the media, but also with scientific research. Take the studies reported in the New England Journal of Medicine themselves as an example. It is more than likely, given the intellectual precociousness of the younger generation, that many teenagers read this material. Given the assuming, the probability is that at least some of these young scholars have committed suicide as a result. But the situation is even worse than that. If the mere mention of suicide can bad impressionable youngsters to indulge in this behaviour, and if pornography can induce rape, then we may easily suppose that the depiction of detective stories will cause crime, that the study of history will encourage war, and that courses in chemistry and physics will result in the widespread creation of thermonuclear devices. More to the point there is an element of truth in each of these allegations. There is an element of risk involved in all of knowledge, including threats. However, if all such activities were therefore prohibited, it would man a virtual end to culture as it has developed over the course of the last few dozen centuries. Paradoxically, if art, culture and science have had a civilizing effects on the human animal, then banning it in the name of saving lives may actually result in more death, not less. The moral of the story should be clear. People have a right to do whatever they wish, as long as it does not involve the invitation of force against others. We cannot stop the onward and upward march of knowledge and culture just because some impressionable young people may be adversely affected. - 30 550 words The Travails of Mervyn Levigne by Walter Block Mervyn Levigne, with the support of the National Citizen's Coalition, has just won a signal victory in the Ontario Supreme Court. Mr. Levigne teaches at a college which is covered by an agreement negotiated through the Ontario Public Service Employees Union. He isn't a member, but pays dues under the Rand formula, on the ground that since he benefits from the labour organization, he should pay for its collective bargaining activities. But the court drew the line at forcing Levigne to underwrite the union's political program: support for such things as the N.D.P. and abortion. It held that this violated the college teacher's rights of association under the Charter of Rights. At a superficial level, this finding would appear to be a blow for freedom and human rights. But by looking beneath surface appearances, we can see several disquieting aspects of this court opinion. . The chief stock in trade of unions is their ability to restrict the entry into the labour market of would be competitors. They do so by initiating not only threats, but actual force against strikebreakers, and others who oppose them. They are virtually the only ones in society who can with legal impunity initiate violence against other citizens. It is thus problematic that the court in the Levigne ease failed to make this more basic criticism of organized labour. . It is by no means clear that unions really benefit the work force. The best available evidence indicates that organized workers earn some 15% more than they would have otherwise in the absence of their union, but this is accomplished by exacerbating unemployment on the part of non union members. (Nor would it help if al^ employees were unionized. For the way these organizations raise wages is by restricting entry. In order for the process to work, someone has to be frozen out.) As well, in many cases, unions become so greedy that they choke off the lives of the firms they live off, in the manner of parasites unaware of their ^' best interests. If on net balance unions are not of benefit to employees, then the Rand formula, approved by the court, can hardly be justified. . But even if it were true that unions benefit workers in general, it still does not follow that they should be allowed to charge those employees who are unwilling to join up for this privilege. For many groups in our society benefit non-contracting third parties, without being able to bill them for their gains. For example, my lot in life is vastly improved if you wash your car, or mow your lawn, or bathe regularly, or smile at me as we pass by each other on the sidewalk. Yet what would we think of a government that allowed you to charge me for these undoubted advantages, against my will. But this is precisely what the Rand formula allows to unions. It should be struck down if for no other reason than this. - 30 THE TUBE MADE ME DO IT by Walter Block, Senior Economist, The Fraser Institute This fall NBC presented a made-for-T.V. movie &quotThe Burning Bed". Starring Farrah Fawcett, it told the story of Francine Hughes, a woman who had been beaten by her husband for 13 years. Finally, the battered wife soaked her husband's bed with gasoline, and while he was asleep, burned him to death. Right after the broadcast of this movie, violence occurred in three separate cities in the U.S. In Milwaukee, 39 year old Joseph Brandt waited for his estranged 37 year old wife Sharon in her driveway. When she pulled up, he doused her with gasoline and threw a lighted match at her. In Quincy, Massachusetts, a husband became enraged by the show and beat his wife to a bloody pulp. According to the director of the shelter that took her in, the husband told her he wanted to get her before she got him. And in Chicago, as if to feed the fears of this Quincy husband, a battered wife watched &quotThe Burning Bed", and shot her husband with a pistol. Nor was this the only case of life imitating art. In Portsmouth, Virginia, a man watched the movie &quotRevenge of the Ninja", a story about a Japanese assassin. Depressed over his families' eviction from their home, Gregory Eley, 2^, donned oriental garb and battle stars, armed himself with a submachine gun, two crossbows and a hand gun, and murdered a woman who had sued him over a business deal. A question not unnaturally arises. Should society ban movies which feature themes of death and destruction, which may lead people to emulate them? It is easy to advocate censorship, for had these two movies not been shown, several people who were killed might today still be alive. But a moment's reflection casts doubt on such a public policy decision. If we banned movies, we would have to ban books, stories, paintings, plays, operas, etc. Even children's fairy tales -- 3ack and the Bean Stalk, Little Red Riding Hood, Chicken Little, Hansel and Gretel -- are replete with mayhem and murder. Down this path lies the end of culture and art as we know it. But there is ^an even more basic objection to censorship and prior restraint. The human being is a creature of free will. People, whether they like it or not, are responsible for their own acts. &quotThe Burning Bed", and all other artistic endeavours which depict violence, are not to blame for the acts of those who chose to emulate them. Only the criminals themselves are to blame. UNIONISM by Walter Block, The Eraser Institute, Vancouver B.C. A strange adventure recently befell Patrick McDermott, the 27 year old son of Canadian Labor Congress president Dennis McDermott. Young Patrick was innocently riding a bus in suburban North York when he witnessed a beating in the street. A woman, Dianne Mclntyre, aged 42, was being assaulted by a man -whereupon our hero jumped off the bus, came to the rescue of the damsel in distress, and for his pains was wrestled to the ground by four other men, colleagues of the hoodlum battering Mrs. Mclntyre, and was kicked and punched while he was down. "No big deal" you say? "Happens every day?" Well, yes, unfortunately; street violence seems to be part and parcel of modern day life, not only in the U.S., but increasingly in this country as well. But this case was exceptional. For the victimized woman was crossing a picket line at the main Visa credit card centre for the Imperial Bank of Commerce, and the five bully boys were bank workers, engaged in a labor strike against this financial institution. What a position to be in for Patrick McDemott, a staunch union supporter in his own right, and son of the outgoing president of the CLC1 But Mr. McDermott the younger tried to remain loyal to his principles. That is, to both of them: chivalry and unionism. Although suffering from an arm injury, bruised ribs and a split lip in his confrontation with the minions of organized labour, he stated that he still believes "in the strike and the cause, but when it comes to goons hitting defenceless women, it's got to stop. That guy should be thrown out of the union." This, however, is too facile, by half. Unionism as practiced in Canada is intrinsically a violent, confrontative and physically aggressive institution, and young Mr. McDermott cannot have it both ways. He must either renounce the "cause," or give up on his principle that goons should not be able to beat innocent persons• Why is this? How can it be that a widely respected institution, organized labour, necessarily initiates violence against non-agressing people? The reason is straightforward. Actual union practice/ and the labour codes of the land which underly it, are predicated on the assumption that competition, no matter how well it works elsewhere in the economy, is simply inappropriate for the labour market. But not only inappropriate. Deserving of legal penalties as well! Labour enactments in Canada mandate that the employer "bargain fairly" with a union, when what he may want to do most of all is ignore his striking employees entirely, and hire competing workers (i.e., "scabs") in their place. Some provinces (i.e., Quebec) prevent management from hiring temporary replacements for the duration of the labour dispute; others allow this, but insist that the firm not deal more favourably with these labourers than with its unionized work force. If the employer declines to be bound by these restrictions, he is liable to fines or even jail sentences -- which is certainly equivalent to visiting violence against a person, the employer, for doing no more than encouraging competition in the labour market. It is perhaps for this reason that the police and courts turn a blind eye -- or even a sympathetic one -- to situations where union violence is directed against the employer, or, in the case of Mrs. Mclntyre, against those who support scab workers by crossing picket lines. "If the government will physically prohibit labour market competition anyway, why penalize organized labour for doing the same thing?" seems to be the prevailing opinion. A moment's reflection will convince us that this practice -union violence or government violence practiced against employers and/or scabs -- is completely unjustified. The non-employed competing workers (scabs) have every bit as much right as the striking unionists to compete for jobs offered by the employer. Any other conclusion would set up two classes of people -- unionists, scabs — with different types of rights. But all Canadians have the same human rights to compete for employment, without being victimized by physical violence, whether from unionists or policemen. As for the assault and battery perpetrated on Patrick McDermott and Dianne Mclntyre, a union spokesman termed the incident "minor," and said there were no plans for disciplinary action against the pickets who injured them. And of course the police did nothing to quell this violence in our streets, even though they, and all Canadians would have been outraged had this situation occurred in any context other than that of a labour strike. 30 - UNIONS - I An Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for C30R Radio There have been labour difficulties between union and non-union firms at the Pennyfarthing construction site in False Creek. And there may be more in the offing regarding Expo 86, where unions are refusing to work alongside contractors employing non-union labour. The construction unions are determined to maintain the $26 per hour union pay scales, as against the $17 paid by Kerkhoff Construction Co., the non-union firm now working in False Creek. The argument used by unionists is that all attempts to undermine their organization with non-union labour should be resisted. Otherwise, according to this view, the working people will soon find themselves back in a non-unionized sweat shop type of economy, where wages would fall to barely supportable levels. How would this work? Well, if non-union firms paying $17 per hour are allowed into Expo 86, and other large scale operations, they will be able to outcompete the union shops. With the alternative of unemployment staring them in the face, the unions would have to take wage cuts down to the $17 level, thus allowing their firms to contend with the non-union builders. But the process wouldn't stop here. With a defanged labour movement, according to this argument, there is simply no reason why Kerkhoff and his colleagues should continue to pay $17. No, with unionism on the retreat, nonunion construction firms might now offer as little as $10 per hour. K they did so, they would again be able to underbid union firms for construction jobs. And this would push union scales down once more, in an attempt to compete. Where the process would end, no one knows — somewhere in the dark ages of sweat shop employment, according to this view. What a horrifying scenario! But it is entirely false, and based on mistaken assumptions. Wages dont rise because unions pull them up. Real wages were rising for centuries before unions first came into being in the late 1800s; they continue to rise nowadays in countries with little or no organized labour, and in the nonunion sectors of nations with a labour movement. Why, then, do wages in the marketplace rise? It is not because of the benevolence of non-union firms like Kerkhoff that his employees receive $17 per hour. It is because of their productivity. If Kerkhoff didn't pay them what they were worth, say, if he paid them only $10 per hour, some other firm would snap them up at $12, earning a cool $5 profit per man-hour. But Kerkhoff, facing a loss of his workforce, would have to up the ante. That's why he pays $17. Productivity. And competition in the labour market. And this would remain the same in the absence of featherbedding unions, which have priced themselves out of the market at $26 per hour. The sooner the unions come to their senses, the better off they, and all the rest of us, will be. This is Walter Block for Vancouver AM. Time: 3:25 Script #5 April 12/84 UNIONS - m An Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for C30R Radio In the past two days, we were discussing the increasingly bitter animosity of the construction unions toward firms which employ non-union labour. We stated that this animosity — which has taken the form of violence, egg and rock throwing, tire slashing — has no moral justification, and no economic justification either. The unions feared that if non-union firms such as Kerkhoff Construction Co. were able to under bid for contracts, that not only would their own puffed up inflated wage scales of $26 per hour be put at risk, but even the more realistic $17 paid in the non-union sector would be threatened. We showed that Kerkhoff pays $17 because of the productivity of his non featherbedded workers, that the main danger to the unions was the $26 per hour with which they had prices themselves out of the market. We indicated that unrealistically high unionized construction pay scales were a source of unemployment, and that fears of a return to sweat shop conditions were only a red herring. Today we consider another topic on the labour front: the recent Vancouver city council 7-U- vote to hire a union contractor to build a sewage pumping station - instead of a non-union firm which was the lowest bidder. Interland Contractors Ltd., the unionized company, put in a bid for $1^9,963 to build the station, and this was accepted, even though Phased Construction Ltd., a non-union concern, put in a bid for $14^55 - $5,508 less. Now an extra $5,000 or so won't break the city budget. Although $5,000 here and $5,000 there can add up. As well, the next time city council takes a higher unionized bid, it might amount to more than $5,000 or so. But money isn't the only concern. There is also a little matter of principle. There is simply no moral justification for the duly elected government of the City of Vancouver to discriminate in favor of some of its citizens, and against others. It was elected by all voters, some of whom are in unions, others not. There is no difference in principle between such discrimination in favor of unions and discrimination in favour of white people, or men, or the non-handicapped. This decision is an affront to fair play, to equal treatment, and to the human rights of individuals who do not happen to belong to labour unions. It should not happen, never ever again. This is Walter Block for Vancouver AM. Time: 2:54 Script #7 April 12/84 UNIONS - II An Editorial Commentary Prepared by Walter Block for C30R Radio This is the second in a series of commentaries concerned with the labour difficulties now plaguing the B.C. construction industry. Last time out, we discussed the Pennyfarthing Development Corporation's Harbour Cove condominium project on False Creek in Vancouver. Over bitter union opposition, the non-union 3.C. Kerkhoff & Sons Ltd is now engaged in building on that site. Incidentally, at a top salary paid of $17 per hour, this non-union shop has been able to save the owners a cool $3.5 million, in contrast to union firms forced to pay wage scales of $26 per hour. We suggested that the construction unions come down to reality, and stop creating their own unemployment by pricing themselves out of the market. Organized labour in B.C. would do well to borrow a leaf from the construction unions in the U.S. In Washington, D.C. for example, the unionized share of the $3 billion per year construction business fell from 75% to 10% of the total in the last few years. As a result, a majority of the unions in the Washington Building and Construction Trades Council have agreed to wage cuts which will allow a 20% reduction in labour costs. In addition to less take home pay, they have agreed to wage freezes, use of lower-paid helpers, streamlined work rules, straight pay on Saturday make-up days to cover rainouts, and even shorter coffee breaks. This pattern, moreover, is based on one set by AFL-CIO affiliates in Little Rock, Milwauke, Knoxville and Cincinati. But British Columbia construction unions are instead digging in their heels, and demanding that the status quo on wages and benefits be maintained. They are opposed to working alongside non-union firms, like Kerkhoff, on the construction of Expo 86. They insist, as a precondition to any such coopeation, that instead of lowering their own pay scales of $26 per hour, the non-union workers be brought up to this unrealistic level from their present $17 per hour. But this would worsen matters, not improve them. Instead of creating more jobs for union workers — it would destroy them in the non-unionized sector. This idea, moreover, has been put forth on moral grounds. But what is so ethical about threatening the imposition of wage scales that would put at risk the entire project? How can it be considered moral for the unions to attempt to dictate non union pay scales — especially ones which would create havoc in the non union sector, as they have already done for organized labour. This is Walter Block for Vancouver AM. Time: 3:10 Script //6 April 12/84 MEDICAL CARE FINANCE AND THE LICENSING OF PHYSICIANS by Arnold Aberman, MD. and Walter Block, Ph.D. When individuals pay directly for medical care, an increase in the supply of physicians is always to the benefit of the public, since it maintains downward pressure on medical fees. However, although the individual fees will be lower when competition is permitted, the total amount of money spent on medical care may rise. This will happen if the increased number of services performed add more to costs than do the lower fees decrease costs. (In technical economic parlance, this applies if the elasticity of demand for medical services is greater than unity). But that is of no concern whatsoever to the individual as long as the price he pays for a given amount of medical services decreases. Price per unit of medical service may decrease because advertising, for instance, allows more efficient delivery of services. -More generally, economics teaches us that the greater the supply of good or service, the lower will be its price, other things equal. But this does not necessarily mean that doctors will earn less, since each one may perform more services. But the individual consumer of health care will save money at the lower price. He will also gain if the amount of services performed increases. This must be a benefit since consumers would not be forced to change their buying patterns. So, as usual, the market, if allowed to operate, benefits both consumers and producers. Of course, it is true that the physicians who cannot satisfy consumer preferences will lose out. This fear of failure may have led physicians organizations to try to limit entry into the health care field. They have done so in two ways: by trying to limit the scope of alternative practioners, such as acupuncturists, chiropracters, etc., and by attemping to reduce the numbers of medical students, and immigrant doctors to this country. (Canadian Medicine: A Study in Restricted Entry, a new book published by the Fraser Institute, and written by Professor Ronaid Hamowy of the University of Alberta, documents this sorry aspect of Canadian history). However, nowadays the government pays doctors, and this situation brings about several complexities. For one thing, when government pays the entire bill it has little interest in price per service. It is mainly concerned with the total cost of medical care. If the patient paid directly for medical care, one way to diminish total cost might be to increase the price per service and thus reduce the number of services performed. But since the government pays for the entire price of medical care and provides it to patients for "free", it cannot decrease the number of medical services by raising price. A second way to cut total cost would be to radically reduce the fees paid to doctors. Since patients are already receiving care for "free", this would not lead to increased utilization. But the government could not slash fees without greatly angering the doctors and possibly leading to serious repercussions. So the only way to decrease number of services and thus total costs is by restricting the number of licensed physicians. Thus regulations are enacted that retard free movement of physicians between provinces, immigration of doctors to Canada is discouraged, and licenses are granted to newly graduated doctors only with added difficulties. And, of course, since not increasing the number of physicians is in the economic interest of licensed physicians, the government have a natural ally in currently practicing doctors. This is where the Hamowy book comes in. Professor Hamowy has shown persuasively that the actions of the various medical regulatory bodies, made on the basis (pretext!) of protecting the public interest, has had the opposite effect. Whether purposely or otherwise, medical licensing has protected the financial interests of licensed physicians by restricting supply, limiting competition, and reducing the spread of market information by outlawing advertising. It is interesting to read the arguments of spokesmen for physicians made in the 19th and early 20th century amassed by Hamowy. They are very similar to the arguments used today -not only by physicians, but taxi drivers, trucking companies, lawyers as well. Such positions by various professional associations are common. After all, why should doctors not act to protect their financial interest (as they see it)? The real problem is that governments have the power to bow to the selfish demands of the doctors (and other such groups). Today government regulatory bodies, for example agricultural marketing boards, openly and without any evasion, act to restrict production and set prices. If a group of doctors wanted to decrease their fee schedule and advertised that fact, (in order to increase total income), the government (acting through the College of Physicians and Surgeons) would not allow them to do so. Of course, in a market situation, the physicians could lower fees, patients would pay less, more services would be consumed (a reflection of consumer preference), and the doctors would make more money, to the benefit of all concerned. The notion that the total amount of money spent on medical care must not be allowed to increase is nonsense. For example, let's consider computers. Everyone knows that the price of computers has decreased markedly over the past five years. But the amount of money spent on computers has gone up. Now suppose that government had to pay for the entire cost of computers. If so, it would want the price of computers to stay high if this would decrease the total cost of computers. But it is even more complicated than that. To make the analogy complete, we must assume that the government gives computers away for "free". In that case the only way the government can reduce the total cost of computers is to limit the number of computer manufacturers (like decreasing the number of doctors). Aren't we lucky that governments do not pay for computers? If they did, we would be reading in the newspapers how the cost of computers has gone up in the past few years, that this is a danger to the public weal, and that something must be done (a government restraint program?). In the interests of patients, our medical care financing ought to be re-oriented in the direction of individual responsibility. People ought to pay directly for health services (with the exception, perhaps, of catastrophic medical insurance) and not indirectly through taxes, "for free", which only encourages over-optimal utilization. As well, as shown by Canadian Medicine A Study in Restricted Entry, our laws ought to be revised so as to lower the barriers to entry into the medical profession. A break for Big Apple beggars-Part II he lower-court Judge Sand ruled it would indeed be an abuse of the free-speech rights of these sometimes violent beggars to prohibit them from "doing their thing." Happily for the longsuffering mass-transit riders, Judge Altimari of the appeals court reversed him; holding that the rights of passengers to be safe must be "balanced" against the right of people to beg. According -to this balancing doctrine, safety considerations must sometimes be curtailed in favour of free speech. But without any balancing, there is danger that this doctrine will be reduced to arbitrariness. In our analysis, there cannot be a real conflict between rights. It only appears as if there is because of a lack of private-property rights. We argue that if the New York subway system were privatized, the conflict would disappear. Consider the following: A cleanshaven man dressed in a three-piece suit with five $100 bills in his wallet (which the Transit Authority cashier refuses to change) but coins amounting to 10 cents less than the required exact subway fare asks passersby to give him a dime. Or, a well-dressed elderly woman whose purse has just been stolen begs people for subway fare. According to Altimari's Second Circuit ruling, both of these people should be penalized. No matter how welldressed and benign they appear, they are still begging. Nonsense. If this determination is not a violation of their free-speech rights, nothing is. But if we are to be consistent, the same principle should apply to dishevelled smelly people whose panhandling takes on a threatening manner. They too have free-speech rights. Forbidding people to speak in public thoroughfares such as subway stations is a denial of their free-speech rights, plain and simple. If, however, the subway system were private property-as private as a bedroom-then the solution would follow simply and directly. The owner 'would have the right to determine the behaviour of his customers, while they are on or about his property . Just as restaurateurs now have the'right to expel unruly or inebriated patrons or people who refuse to wear shoes or a shirt (or in the finer eating establishments, business attire), so would the private subway firm have a right to exclude unkempt beggars. Free-speech rights would not even enter the picture, as people can have such rights only on their own property, not on premises belonging to others. Imagine if you will, a competitive subway industry consisting of several firms. It may be difficult to do, since people are accustomed to state-owned mass-transit monopolies. As it happens, the New York subway was built by private enterprise; the Brooklyn-Manhattan Transit Co. (BMT) and the Interborough Rapid Transit Co. (IRT) were taken over by the city only after severe governmental price controls made it impossible for them to operate. Under privatization, these firms would compete not only on price, service, cleanliness, safety, reliability and speed, but also on the basis of their antisolicitation rules. Some might welcome beggars with open arms. Others might forbid panhandling entirely. Still others might set up special facilities to deal with the problem of the well-dressed man or the victimized woman. There might even be "begging zones" on some premises similar to smoking areas in restaurants. Then, the people would speak, their voices clearly articulated through the intermediation of the profitand-loss market system. The presumption is that firms that strictly proscribe begging would prevail. If so, the commonsensical results desired by Altimari, and haughtily deprecated by Sand, will have been achieved. But this will be accomplished without the irrational fiction that basic rights conflict with each other. Why is it of practical importance that the subway be privatized, whether in New York or anywhere else? Apart from improved safety and operation,there are important legal precedents at stake. A similar analysis may be applied to leafletting in private malls, begging in restaurants, and the imposition of dress codes. In all cases, it is possible that authorities will try to "balance" rights, one against the other. If they do, we will substitute socialism for private-property rights. Judges will become central planners. The way to resolve the conflicts between free-speech and other rights is to determine where the confrontation takes place. If it is public property. privatize it. This is the second of a two-part series devoted to analyzing a lawsuit that has arisen concerning the freespeecb rights of panhandlers in the New York City subway system. Dr. Block is an economist with the Fraser Institute. BRITISH COLUMBtA REPORT, FEBRUARY 11, 1991 21 T Begging in the Big Apple: Part II by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute This is the second in a two part series devoted to analysing a law suit which has arisen in New York concerning the free speech rights of panhandlers in that city's subway system. The lower court Judge Sand had ruled that it would indeed be an abuse of these of times violent beggar's free speech rights to prohibit them from doing their thing. Happily for the long suffering mass transit riders, Judge Altimari of the Appeals Courts reversed him, holding that the rights of passengers to be safe must be "balanced" against the right of people to beg. According to this balancing doctrine, sometimes safety considerations should be curtailed in favour of free speech, and sometimes the reverse should obtain. But without any balancing criterion, there is danger that this doctrine will reduce to arbitrariness. In our analysis, there cannot be a real conflict between rights. It only appears as if there is, because of a lack of private property rights. We are arguing that if the New York City subway system were privatized, the seeming conflict would disappear. Consider the following case. A clean shaven man dressed in a three piece suit with five one hundred dollar bills in his wallet (which the Transit Authority cashier refuses to change) and coins amounting to ten cents less than the required subway fare, asks passersby to give him a dime. Or better yet, a well dressed elderly woman whose purse has just been stolen begs people to give her the fare needed for entry into the subway. According to Altimari's Second Circuit ruling, both of these people should be penalized by law. No matter how well dressed and non threatening, they are still engaged in begging. What arrant nonsense. If this determination is not a violation of their free speech rights, then nothing is. Still others might set up special facilities to deal with the problem of the well dressed man, or the victimized woman. There might even be ''begging zones" set up on some premises, similar to "smoking zones" now established in many restaurants. Then, the people would speak, their voices clearly articulated through the intermediation of the profit and loss market system. The presumption is that firms which strictly proscribe begging would prevail in the competitive struggle. If so, the common sensical results desired by Altimari, and haughtily deprecated by Sand, will have been achieved. But this will be accomplished without the irrational fiction that basic rights can conflict with one another. Why is it of practical importance that the subway be privatized, whether in New York City or anywhere else? Apart from the increased safety and well functioning of the system, there are important legal precedents at issue. For a similar analyis may be applied to leafletting in private malls, begging in restaurants, and the private imposition of dress codes. In all of these cases, it is possible that the authorities will try to "balance" rights, one against the other. If they do, we will substitute the socialist system that brought down the Soviet Union for the private property rights one responsible for the success of our own. Judges will become the central planners. The way to resolve all seeming conflicts between free speech and other rights is to determine on whose property is the confrontation taking place. If it is public property, privatize it. - 30THE BURNING BED by: Walter Block, The Fraser Institute The T.V. movie "The Burning Bed" had everything going for it. It featured a first rate actress, Farah Fawcett-Majors in perhaps her most theatrical role. It boasted a dramatic plot-an abused wife doused her husband with gasoline while he slept, tossed a match on him and burned him to death. With this combination, the performance attracted wide interest from the television audience, and much attention from pundits and critics. In fact, there was only one thing wrong with this presentation: it led to a copy-cat murder in real life, only this time the genders were reversed. In a tragedy of life mimicking art, a Milwaukee man doused his estranged wife with gasoline, and set her afire right after watching "The Burning Bed" on T.V. She died a horrible death after lingering in hospital for a week, and he was sentenced to a 19 year prison term for perpetrating this truly evil act. This episode presents us with a bit of a dilemma. The movie "The Burning Bed" was produced by feminists, to illustrate the problem of wife-beating. Yet these very people have vociferously protested against pornography, on the ground that it leads to violence perpetrated on women. Were these feminists to be consistent with their anti-pornographic stand, they would have to eschew their own exhibition of "The Burning Bed", since it, like pornography, presumably promotes violence against women. If they refuse to do any such thing, then logic would compel them to drop their opposition to pornography, at least on this one ground-which forms the major element in their case against this practice. No matter how they twist and turn, the feminists cannot have it both ways. Talk of painting yourself into a corner. - 30 300 words Canadian Conference of Catholic Bishops Attacks Free Trade by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. According to Bishop Remi de Roo of Victoria, the free trade deal now in the process of being hammered out between Canada and the U.S. will harm this nation. In his view, the negotiations are likely to severely limit Canada's economic and political autonomy. These perspectives are presented in a discussion booklet entitled "Free Trade: At What Cost?" released last week at a highly touted press conference. In it, the bishops question not only the economics of free trade, but the ethics of it as well. They maintain that an end to trade barriers could hurt the poor, and create unemployment. While this viewpoint bespeaks a profound concern for Canada and its people, the bishops, unfortunately, may have been mislead by their economic advisors. It has been a basic premise of economic analysis, since the days of Adam Smith and even before, that voluntary trade across international boundaries helps both participants. Consider the trite but illuminating case of trade of a tropical for a temperate product, e.g., bananas for maple syrup. It is of course possible for a country such as Canada to grow both items. While our climate is hardly receptive to it, we could nurture banana trees - but only in large and very expensive hot houses. Similarly, a country such as Costa Rica could, if it very much wished to, cultivate maple trees. It would have to build gigantic refrigerators, hundreds of feet high, at the cost of a good deal of that nation's entire G.D.P. Under such an unlikely scenario, each country could attain "self sufficiency" in both commodities. Of course the poor, and everyone else for that matter, would suffer greatly. Maple syrup would be frightfully expensive in Costa Rica, as would bananas in Canada. Suppose, now, that under such conditions there began a movement toward free trade between the two countries. Without tariff barriers, Canada would end up specializing in maple products, while the production of bananas would tend to be concentrated in Costa Rica, to the enrichment of consumers in both places. However, it would be vociferously objected that "Canadian jobs Promoting capitalism in Eastern Europe would be lost in the banana industry." Similarly, the Costa Ricans — at least those engaged in the production of maple syrup - would bitterly complain about the rising tide of unemployment in their country. From the perspective of the economist, we can see that both grievances would be true. But contrary to the contention of bishop de Roo and his colleagues, this would be a reason for rejoicing, not for the wailing and gnashing of teeth. For if we want to economize on God's blessings, we do well to encourage unemployment in the misbegotten Canadian banana, and Costa Rican maple syrup industries. Further, perhaps the greatest benediction an industrialized country like Canada can confer on an economically backward nation such as Costa Rica is to offer to integrate its economy with our own. In "Ethical Reflections on the Economic Crises" the Conference of Canadian Bishops urges the "Preferential Option for the Poor." According to this doctrine, public policy should focus on the plight of the impoverished, and seek to improve their lot in life. Since the world's poor are clustered in the underdeveloped nations, this is an argument for open borders with the entire family of nations, not just with the U.S. But the Catholic bishops of Canada may not welcome advice from the economics profession. (In recent surveys, only 3.8% of Canadian economists, and 2.8% of their counterparts in the U.S. failed to support the view that "Tariffs and import quotas reduce general economic welfare.") Perhaps, then, they can borrow a leaf from their co-religionists south of the border. While the U.S. bishops are hardly flaming advocates of an Adam Smithian policy of full free trade, their text, "Catholic Social Teaching and the U.S. Economy" is greatly at variance with the views expressed by Bishops de Roo, Proulx and O'Byrne. In it they refer to "the flaws in the traditional notion of national boundaries," and perceptively state, "...within a frame of reference characterized by the 'preferential option for the poor,' we lean toward an open trading system." 1. Dr. Block is an economist with the Fraser Institute. rime Minister Brian Mulroney announced, with great fanfare, that Canada would grant $42 million in foreign aid to Poland and Hungary in order to promote capitalism. That he could do this indicates, as much as anything, that he does not have even the most basic and elementary understanding of the free enterprise philosophy. That the nation's journalists and editorial writers, ever ready to pounce upon the Progressive Conservatives for just about anything under the sun, could let him get away with such a travesty speaks volumes about the sorry state of their economic understanding as well. Let it be said then, that capitalism is a system based upon private property, free markets, and the lure of profits. It is a total contradiction to this system that government should subsidize anything, let alone another government. This foreign aid is actually an attack on capitalism in several senses. For one thing, it undermines our free enterprise institutions here at home. The more aggrandized is Ottawa, the less economic power remains with "the people," in the form of individual initiative. That grant of $42 million will not come out of thin air. On the contrary, it will be exhorted out of the pockets of the long-suffering Canadian taxpayer. Given the rakeoff that inevitably goes to the bureaucrats, moreover, for our government to actually disburse $42 million means that taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been by a multiple of that amount. For another, it has the exact opposite of its intended effect in the recipient countries of Eastern Europe. The ostensible purpose of this income transfer is to promote capitalism in Poland and Hungary. Ultimately, of course, the goal is to help the citizens of these beleaguered countries lead a better life, but the underlying theory is that since central planning is responsible for their present plight, what is needed now is a healthy dose of individual initiative. But if aggrandizement of the public sector at the expense of the private fosters socialism, not free enterprise, in Canada, it has the same effect in formerly communist countries as well. Giving money to the Polish and Hungarian bureaucrats---even though their ministerial bosses are now democratically elected-will do no more good for their respective economies than it did in the past when they were appointed by a Communist party. Democratic socialism is still socialism. As far as the potential Eastern European entrepre. neur is concerned, it matters little whether he pays exorbitant taxes to the central planner who emerges from the ballot box or from the the totalitarian system of the bayonet. Nor does it matter whether the regulation that drives him out of business arises from one system or the other. The only economic benefit derived from a free vote is that the excesses of socialism can only be pushed so far before they can peacefully exchanged for an alternative. This option does not exist under totalitarianism. Transferring money from one government to another sets up perverse incentives in the recipient country. Instead of concentrating on consumer needs-people in these countries are faced with shortages of toilet paper, soap, bread, meat and countless other items we take for granted in the West-the best and brightest of the Poles and Hungarians will be sorely tempted to focus their attention on the government in order to obtain that 542 million for themselves. This is why it is extremely pejorative to refer to this money as foreign "aid." With all of these boomerang effects, it would be more accurate to call it foreign "harm." If we really wanted to help the people of Eastern Europe, the encouragement of Canadian private investment in these countries would be a far better plan. Unfortunately, because of Mulroney's unfortunate decision, there is now $42 million less forthis purpose. Let us at least resolve that no more money should be wasted in this manner in the future. Further, let us extend the Free Trade Agreement recently concluded with the U.S. to Poland, Hungary, other former Iron Curtain countries, and even to the entire world. But even more than investment, knowledge and understanding of how free enterprise really works is crucially needed by the people behind the former Iron Curtain. Such research is often dismissed by Canadian socialists as "ideological" and "Neanderthal." but it is the very life blood of those struggling to throw off the shackles created by the seven-decade-long experiment with publicsector economic planning. P 32 BRITISH COLUMBIA REPORT, AUGUST 27, 1990 Promoting Capitalism in Eastern Europe by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Prime Minister Brian Mulroney announced, with great fanfare, that Canada would be granting $42 million in foreign aid to Poland and Hungary, in order to promote capitalism. That he could do this indicates, if anything can, that he does not have even the most basic and elementary understanding of the free enterprise philosophy. That the nation's journalists and editorial writers, ever ready to pounce upon the Progressive Conservatives for just about anything under the sun, could let him get away with such a travesty, bespeaks volumes about the sorry state of their economic understanding as well. Let it be said, then, that capitalism is a system based upon private property, free markets, and the lure of profits. It is a total contradiction to this system that government should subsidize anything, let alone another government. This foreign aid is actually an attack on capitalism in several senses. For one thing, it undermines our free enterprise institutions here at home. The more aggrandized is Ottawa, the less economic power remains with "the people," in the form of individual initiative. That grant of $42 million will not come out of the thin air. On the contrary, it will be exhorted out of the pockets of the long suffering Canadian taxpayer. Given the rakeoff that inevitably goes to the bureaucrats, moreover, for our government to actually disburse $42 million means that taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been by a multiple of that amount. For another, it has the exact opposite to its intended effect in the recipient countries of Eastern Europe. The ostensible purpose of this income transfer is to promote capitalism in Poland and Hungary. Ultimately, of course, the goal is to help the citizens of these beleaguered countries to lead a better life, but the underlying theory is that since central planning is responsible for their present plight, what is needed now is a healthy dose of individual initiative. But if aggrandizement of the public sector at the expense of the private fosters socialism not free enterprise in Canada, it has the same effect in formerly communist countries as well. Giving money to the Polish and Hungarian bureaucrats -- even though they are now democratically elected -- will do no more good for their respective economies than it did in the past when they were appointed by a Communist Party. Democratic socialism is still socialism. As far as the potential eastern European entrepreneur is concerned, it matters little whether he pays exorbitant taxes to the central planner who emerges from the ballot box or from the the totalitarian system of the bayonet. Nor does it matter whether the regulation which drives him out of business arises from one system or the other. The only economic benefit derived from a free vote of the polity is that the excesses of socialism can only be pushed so far before they can peacefully exchanged for an alternative. This option does not exist under totali tarianism. Transferring money from one government to another sets up perverse incentives in the recipient country. Instead of concentrating on consumer needs -- people in these countries are faced with shortages of toilet paper, soap, bread, meat and countless other items we take for granted in the west -- the best and brightest of the Poles and Hungarians will be sorely tempted to focus their attention on the government, in order to obtain that $42 million for themselves. But this is the initial problem which created the felt need on the part of the Canadian government to grant the funds in the first place: too much economic emphasis on the public sector, too little on the private. This is why it is extremely pejorative to refer to this $42 million as foreign "aid." With all of these boomerang effects, it would be more accurate to call it foreign "harm." This amount of funding may not be any great shakes in the capitalist west, but it is an inordinate amount of money in the capital-starved east -- especially since it will not go to help the people there, but rather to divert the more entrepreneurial inclined away from needed private commercial endeavors. If we really wanted to help the people of Eastern Europe, the encouragement of Canadian private investment in these countries would be a far better plan. Unfortunately, because of Mulroney's unfortunate decision, there is now $42 million less available for this purpose. Let us at least resolve that no more money should be wasted in this manner in the future. Further, let us extend the Free Trade Agreement recently concluded with the U.S. to Poland, Hungary, other former Iron Curtain countries, and even to the entire world. But even more than investment, knowledge and understanding of how free enterprise really works is crucially needed by the people behind the former Iron Curtain. Such research is often dismissed by Canadian socialists as "ideological," and "neanderthal," but it is the very life blood of those who are struggling to throw off the shakles created by the seven decades long experiment with public sector economic planning. - 30- Promoting Capitalism in Eastern Europe by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. Prime Minister Brian Mulroney announced, with great fanfare, that Canada would be granting $42 million in foreign aid to Poland and Hungary, in order to promote capitalism. That he could do this indicates, if anything can, that he does not have even the most basic and elementary understanding of the free enterprise philosophy. That the nation's journalists and editorial writers, ever ready to pounce upon the Progressive Conservatives for just about anything under the sun, could let him get away with such a travesty, bespeaks volumes about the sorry state of their economic understanding as well. Let it be said, then, that capitalism is a system based upon private property, free markets, and the lure of profits. It is a total contradiction to this system that government should subsidize anything, let alone another government. This foreign aid is actually an attack on capitalism in several senses. For one thing, it undermines our free enterprise institutions here at home. The more aggrandized is Ottawa, the less economic power remains with "the people," in the form of individual initiative. That grant of $42 million will not come out of the thin air. On the contrary, it will be exhorted out of the pockets of the long suffering Canadian taxpayer. Given the rake off that inevitably goes to the bureaucrats, moreover, for our government to actually disburse $42 million means that taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been by a multiple of that amount. For another, it has the exact opposite to its intended effect in the recipient countries of Eastern Europe. The ostensible purpose of this income transfer is to promote capitalism in Poland and Hungary. Ultimately, of course, the goal is to help the citizens of these beleaguered countries to lead a better life, but the underlying theory is that since central planning is responsible for their present plight, what is needed now is a healthy dose of individual initiative. But if aggrandizement of the public sector at the expense of the private fosters socialism not free enterprise in Canada, it has the same effect in formerly communist countries as well. Giving money to the Polish and Hungarian bureaucrats -- even though they are now democratically elected -- will do no more good for their respective economies than it did in the past when they were appointed by a Communist Party. Democratic socialism is still socialism. As far as the potential eastern European entrepreneur is concerned, it matters little whether he pays exorbitant taxes to the paper pusher who results from the ballot box or from the bayonet. Nor does it matter whether the regulation which drives him out of business arises from one system or the other. The only economic benefit derived from a free vote of the polity is that the excesses of socialism can only be pushed so far before they can peacefully exchanged for an alternative. This option does not exist under totalitarianism. Transferring money from one government to another sets up perverse incentives in the recipient country. Instead of concentrating on consumer needs -- people in these countries are faced with shortages of toilet paper, soap, bread, meat and countless other items we take for granted in the west -- the best and brightest of the Poles and Hungarians will be sorely tempted to focus their attention on the government, in order to obtain that $42 million for themselves. But this is the initial problem which created the felt need on the part of the Canadian government to grant the funds in the first place: too much economic emphasis on the public sector, too little on the private. This is why it is extremely pejorative to refer to this $42 million as foreign "aid." With all of these boomerang effects, it would be more accurate to call it foreign "harm." If we really wanted to help the people of Eastern Europe, the encouragement of Canadian private investment in these countries would be a far better plan. Unfortunately, because of Mulroney's unfortunate decision, there is now an excess of $42 million less available now for this purpose. Let us at least resolve that no more money should be wasted in this manner in the future. Further, let us extend the Free Trade Agreement recently concluded with the U.S. to Poland, Hungary, other former Iron Curtain countries, and even to the entire world. - 30- Promoting Capitalism in Eastern Europe by Walter Block, The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. ~\ ,k~ (~ct .. \ ~ -, / \." (I{ ( )C). / [: I'.' ' )f' ~. ( be ;~---' ,,!V. I\ \..- ,J '1 "/'/ \ (~ be granting $42 million in foreign aid to Poland and Hungary, in order to promote capitalism. '<'> Prime Minister Brian Mulroney announced, with great fanfare, that Canada would .:'--// f.~~ That he could do this indicates, if anything can, that he does not have ~ ~ even the most basic and elementary understanding of the free enterprise philosophy. That the nation's journalists and editorial writers, ever ready to pounce upon the Progressive Conservatives for just about anything under the sun, could let him get away with such a travesty, bespeaks volumes about the sorry state of their economic understanding as well. Let it be said, then, that capitalism is a system based upon pr,i~ate_ property, free o.. ,(\C~~lf markets, aIJ. d tp;{ lure of profits. It is totalJbi aIUl~~h' .~~ ;lY,,)( . government te subsidize anything, let alone another government. ~,,-v.~~ 1.'71r'- This foreign aid is actually attack on capitalism in several senses. For one thing, 1" it undermines our free enterprise institutions here at home. The more aggrandized is Ottawa, the less economic power remains with "the people," in the form of individual initiative. That grant of $42 million will not come out of the thin air. On the contrary, it will be exhorted out of the pockets of the long suffering Canadian taxpayer. Given the rakeoff that inevitably goes to the bureaucrats, moreover, for our government to actually disburse $42 million means that taxes will be higher than they otherwise would have been by a multiple of that amount. For another, it has the exact opposite to its intended effect in the recipient countries of 'Eastern Europe. The ostensible purpose of this income transfer is to promote capitalism in Poland and Hungary. Ultimately, of course, the goal is to help the citizens of these beleaguered countries to lead a better life, but the underlying theory is that since central planning is responsible for their present plight, what is needed now is a healthy dose of individual initiative. But if aggrandizement of the 2. 3. __ ," . 1,,,/ public sector at the expense of the private,,/osters socialism not free enterprise in Canada, it has the same effect in formerly communist countries as well. j Giving money to the Polish and Hungarian bureaucrats -- even though they are now democratically elected -- will do no more good for their respective economies than it did in the past when they were appointed by a Communist Party. Democratic socialism is still socialism. As far as the potential eastern European entrepreneur is concerned, it matters little whether he pays exorbitant taxes to the paper pusher who j results from the ballot box or from the(~~~ bayonet~it I, Nor does it matter '~,.,~.~-~ whether the regulation which drives him out of business arises from one system or the other. The only economic benefit derived from a free vote of the polity is that the excesses of socialism can only be pushed so far before they can peacefully exchanged for an alternative. This option does not exist under totalitarianism. Transferring money from one government to another sets up perverse incentives in the recipient country. Instead of concentrating on consumer needs -- people in these countries are faced with shortages of toilet paper, soap, bread, meat and countless other items we take for granted in the west -- the best and brightest of the Poles and Hungarians will be sorely tempted to focus their attention on the government, in order to obtain that $42 million for themselves. But this is the initial problem which created the felt need on the part of the Canadian government to grant the funds in the first place: too much economic emphasis on the public sector, too little on the private. This is why it is extremely pejorative to refer to this $42 million as foreign "aid." With all of these boomerang effects, it would be more accurate to call it foreign "harm." If we really wanted to help the people of Eastern Europe, the encouragement of Canadian private investment in these countries would be a far better plan. Unfortunately, because of MUlroney's unfortunate decision, there is now an excess of $42 million less available now for this purpose. Let us at least resolve that no more money should be wasted in this manner in the future. Further, let us extend the Free Trade Agreement recently concluded with the U.S. to Poland, Hungary, other former Iron Curtain countries, and even to the entire world. - 30- December 27, 1989