DRAFT BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS AND DYNAMIC COMPETITION Maurice E. Stucke* INTRODUCTION Antitrust’s concept of competition assumes rational market participants with willpower who pursue their self-interest. This Article first examines how our conception of competition alters when this assumption is relaxed to reflect bounded rational market participants with imperfect willpower and bounded self-interest. Part II examines two implications of this dynamic theory of competition on antitrust’s monopolization law, namely herding and behavioral learning as entry barriers and second a monopolist’s exploitation of biases to illegally maintain its monopoly. I. THEORY OF COMPETITION WITH BOUNDED RATIONAL FIRMS AND CONSUMERS Before addressing the implications of behavioral economics on antitrust’s monopolization standard, it is helpful to quickly sketch how behavioral economics can inform our conception of competition. The prevailing assumption underlying today’s antitrust policy is that firms, consumers, and the government are rational. As I discuss elsewhere,1 our theory of competition changes when one relaxes the assumption of rational firms, consumers, and government. My aim here is summarize Scenario IV competition, whereby both firms and consumers are bounded rational.2 * Associate Professor, University of Tennessee College of Law; Senior Fellow, American Antitrust Institute. I wish to thank for their helpful comments <insert>. I also thank the University of Tennessee College of Law for the summer research grant. 1 Maurice E. Stucke, Reconsidering Competition, Mississippi L.J. (forthcoming 2012), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1646151. 2 Id. (discussing competition under scenarios I (firms, consumers, government 2 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 Under Scenario IV competition, biases and heuristics are systemic. At closer inspection, competition under Scenario IV is better viewed as a discovery process than a stable equilibrium. Bounded rational firms have imperfect knowledge about current and future consumer preferences, a blurred and changing understanding of their goals and preferences, and a limited repertoire of actions to cope with whatever problems they face.3 Bounded rational consumers have changing and, at times, inconsistent preferences.4 Thus, under a behavioral lens, competition is more fully understood as an “evolutionary trial and error process, in which the firms try out different problem solutions and can learn from the feedback of the market, which of their specific products and technological solutions are the superior ones.”5 Rather than an end-state capable of being perfected, competition is a continuous process “in which previously unknown knowledge is generated,” and “the multiplicity and diversity of the (parallel trials of the) firms might be crucial for the effectiveness of competition as a discovery procedure.”6 Firms and consumers make mistakes, readjust, and undertake new strategies. The competitive process “is inherently a process of trial and error with no stable end-state considered by the participants in the rational); II (firms relatively more rational than consumers); III (consumers relatively more rational than firms; and IV (firms, consumers, and government bounded rational). 3 Giovanni Dosi & Luigi Marengo, On the Evolutionary and Behavioral Theories of Organizations: A Tentative Roadmap, 18 ORG. SCI. 491, 492, 494 (2007). 4 See, e.g., Steven C. Michael & Tracy Pun Palandjian, Organizational Learning and New Product Introductions, 21 J. PRODUCT INNOVATION MGMT. 268, 270 (2004) (discussing shampoo industry dynamism where consumers with changing tastes buyers seek variety); Richard Layard, Happiness & Public Policy: A Challenge to the Profession, 116 THE ECON. J. C24, C24 (2006) (noting from happiness economic literature how “tastes are not given – the happiness we get from what we have is largely culturally determined”). 5 Kerber, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 2; see also Moreau, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 851 (discussing how “evolutionary theory refutes the neoclassical economic theory’s focus on a steady state of the economic system”). 6 Kerber, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 2. 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 3 process.”7 Scenario IV involves several important competitive dimensions beyond price. One facet of competition is the extent to which bounded rational firms debias themselves to provide a competitive advantage.8 The corporate literature describes firms being overconfident about a merger’s likely efficiencies,9 overvaluing the purchased assets,10 being overly confident or pessimistic about their chances of entering particular markets, 11 and consistent with the sunk cost fallacy throwing good money after bad in corporate projects.12 Even though firms are bounded rational, it does not follow that their heuristics and biases are of the same nature and to the same 7 Moreau, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 851. See, e.g., Andrew Healy, Do Firms Have Short Memories?: Evidence from Major League Baseball, 9 J. SPORTS ECON. 407, 415-18 (2009) (discussing how some professional baseball teams overweigh, relative to more successful teams, athletes’ recent performance in determining salary). 9 See, e.g., Matthew T. Billett & Yiming Qian, Are Overconfident CEOs Born or Made? Evidence of Self Attribution Bias from Frequent Acquirers, 54 MGMT. SCI. 1037 (2008) (finding from sample of public acquisitions between 1985 and 2002 that CEOs who previously engaged in a successful acquisition appear to overly attribute their role in successful deals, leading to more deals even though these subsequent deals are value destructive); ROBERT F. BRUNER, DEALS FROM HELL: M&A LESSONS THAT RISE ABOVE THE ASHES (2005) (summarizing major failed mergers). 10 Mathew L.A. Hayward & Donald C. Hambrick, Explaining the Premiums Paid for Large Acquisitions: Evidence of CEO Hubris, 42 ADMIN. SCI. Q. 103 (1997) (finding from empirical study of mergers over $100 million involving publicly traded firms over four year period that CEO hubris plays a substantial role in acquisition process and acquisitions tend to reduce shareholder wealth); see also Mauricio R. Delgado et al., Understanding Overbidding Using the Neural Circuitry of Reward to Design Economic Auctions, SCIENCE, Sept. 26, 2008, at 1849; RICHARD H. THALER, WINNER’S CURSE: PARADOXES AND ANOMALIES OF ECONOMIC LIFE 50–62 (1992) (discussing experimental and field evidence); Mackintosh, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 15 (discussing a 2010 auction of a $20 bill for $61). 11 Amanda P. Reeves & Maurice E. Stucke, Behavioral Antitrust, 86 INDIANA L.J. (forthcoming 2011) (discussing increasing interest in behavioral economics and its applications to competition law), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1582720; Maurice E. Stucke, Behavioral Economists at the Gate: Antitrust in the Twenty-First Century, 38 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 513 (2007). 12 Malcolm Baker et al., Behavioral Corporate Finance: A Survey 49 (Sept. 29, 2005), http://ssrn.com/abstract=602902; Hal R. Arkes & Catherine Blumer, The Psychology of Sunk Cost, 35 ORGANIZATIONAL BEHAVIOR & HUMAN DECISION PROCESSES 124-140 (1985). 8 4 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 degree.13 Accordingly, firms can implement mechanisms to debias their outlooks and decision-making. Firms with significant free cash flow can seek advice from outside advisors to evaluate prospective mergers to ensure the senior managers are not overconfident or optimistic on the potential efficiencies.14 As the management consulting firm McKinsey & Company summarized, First, managers can become more aware of how biases can affect their own decision making and then endeavor to counter those biases. Second, companies can better avoid distortions and deceptions by reviewing the way they make decisions and embedding safeguards into their formal decision-making processes and corporate culture.15 One effective mechanism for firms to identify biases and take preventive measures is through “frequent, rapid, and unambiguous feedback.”16 Accordingly, an important competitive dimension is providing firms (like consumers) the incentive to improve feedback mechanisms and ultimately their decision-making and willpower.17 With bounded rational firms with imperfect information, a second 13 John A. List, Neoclassical Theory Versus Prospect Theory: Evidence from the Marketplace, 72 ECONOMETRICA 615, 615 (2004); John A. List, Does Market Experience Eliminate Market Anomalies?, 118 Q. J. ECON. 41 (2003). For example, frequent and more experienced sports cards traders display less of an endowment effect for sports cards (such as baseball trading cards) than for other items such as chocolates and mugs. 14 Ulrike Malmendier, A “New” Paradigm in Corporate Finance: The Role of Managers and Managerial Biases, 4 NBER REPORTER 13, 15-16 (2010) (discussing correlation between overconfidence and acquisitions by cash-rich firms not dependent on external financing). 15 Dan P. Lovallo & Olivier Sibony, Distortions and Deceptions in Strategic Decisions, McKinsey Quarterly, Feb. 2006, available at http://www.mckinseyquarterly.com/Distortions_and_deceptions_in_strategic_decisions_17 16. 16 Lovallo & Sibony, supra note **; Camerer & Malmendier, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 269 (noting some of the literature, such as investment firms combating loss aversion by having traders switch positions with one another). 17 See Linda Argote & Henrich R. Greve, A Behavioral Theory of the Firm – 40 Years and Counting: Introduction and Impact, 18 ORG. SCI. 337 (2007) (surveying impact of Behavioral Theory of the Firm’s impact on organizational science research, including institutional theory and population ecology); Dosi & Marengo, supra note **, at 491. 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 5 important dimension of competition is the ways in which companies learn, accomplish tasks, and deal with the uncertainty, which again can vary across firms.18 Rather than incur costs to continually process information anew, bounded rational firms (like consumers) can use rules-of-thumb (heuristics). Firms with better routines/rules-of-thumb can lower their information processing and decision-making costs to gain a competitive advantage. While providing at times a competitive advantage, corporate routines can also disadvantage firms competitively. Bounded rational firms face the risk of competency traps, whereby they become wedded to existing routines, which as industry conditions change, place the firms at a competitive disadvantage.19 One CEO recently observed the paradox: “in a creative company, you want to give as much variability as possible, and yet in a manufacturing process you want as little variability as possible.”20 Under Scenario IV, “[i]n some sense knowledge depreciates in value over time.”21 So another important dimension of competition is adaptive efficiency,22 whereby bounded rational firms update routines to reflect consumers’ changing preferences.23 Rational choice theory often views 18 Dan Lovallo & Olivier Sibony, The Case for Behavioral Strategy, MCKINSEY Q. 3 (March 2010) (noting recent survey of 2,207 executives where only 28 percent said the quality of their companies’ strategic decisions was generally good, 60 percent thought that bad decisions were about as frequent as good ones, and 12 percent thought good decisions were altogether infrequent). 19 Eyal Biyalogorsky et al., Stuck in the Past: Why Managers Persist with New Product Failures, 70 J. MARKETING 108 (2006) (discussing the “extensive attention in the literature” to firms’ escalation of commitment, which is the tendency of managers to stay committed to a course of action despite strong negative feedback with respect to the advisability of this action); Michael & Palandjian, supra note 4, at 270 (discussing literature on competency traps). 20 Hal Weitzman, The Man who Turns Post-it Notes Into Bank Notes, Fin. Times, Feb. 28, 2011, at 12 (quoting 3M CEO George Buckley). 21 NORTH, UNDERSTANDING, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 23 (discussing uncertainty in a non-ergodic world (e.g., Scenario IV)). 22 Id. at 70. 23 Michael & Palandjian, supra note 4, at 275. 6 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 suspiciously a strong incumbent firm that seeks to acquire a maverick firm with a new technology or business model.24 But in the business literature, a firm may acquire a maverick with a disruptive business model or technology to better adapt and compete.25 A third important dimension of Scenario IV competition is the importance of scale, openness, randomness, and connectivity. Innovation, as Steven Johnson recently wrote, occurs mostly in the adjacent possible, namely iterative advances leading from one innovation to an improvement in the adjoining space: “Environments that block or limit those new combinations–by punishing experimentation, by obscuring certain branches of possibility, by making the current state so satisfying that no one bothers to explore the edges—will, on average, generate and circulate fewer innovations than environments that encourage exploration.”26 Networks, and as discussed below network effects, are playing a greater role across industries. Firms can learn and adapt more quickly through the Internet’s social network technologies. Firms are also developing internal networks to better interact with employees and disperse information and ideas. Some firms are fully networked, combining both external and internal networks. One recent survey of 3,249 executives found significant correlations between market share gains and companies that are fully networked.27 Indeed with the proliferation of data on consumer preferences and purchasing behavior, networks will increase in competitive significance. By increasing the collaboration among consumers, suppliers and firm employees, the firms can quickly gain insights of the adjacent possible 24 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 2.1.5. Clayton M. Christensen et al., The New M&A Playbook, Harv. Bus. Rev., March 2011, at 49, 50, 54-55. 26 STEVEN JOHNSON, WHERE GOOD IDEAS COME FROM: THE NATURAL HISTORY OF INNOVATION 36, 41 (2010). 27 Jacques Bughin & Michael Chui, How Web 2.0 Pays Off: The Growth Dividend Enjoyed by Networked Enterprises, 2 McKinsey Quarterly 17, (2011) 25 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 7 (modifications to an existing technology or collection of technologies) and better tailor products and services to accommodate changing consumer preferences. A fourth dimension of Scenario IV competition is the value of individuality, creativity, and ethics. Under antitrust’s rational choice theory, firms and consumers are undifferentiated in motivation. They seek, whenever the opportunity, to promote their economic self-interest. But profit-maximization, as a direct goal, is arguably self-defeating for firms and consumers. “The most profitable businesses” observed John Kay “are not the most profit oriented.”28 Companies with excellent reputations deliver more than profits for their shareholders; they deliver value to society.29 Moreover, firms, even monopolists, at times do not behave as their rational self-interested counterparts in exploiting consumers.30 One 28 JOHN KAY, OBLIQUITY: WHY OUR GOALS ARE BEST ACHIEVED INDIRECTLY 12, 2434 (2011). 29 2011 Harris Annual RQ Poll, supra note **, at 9 (companies with high reputation quotients can be characterized as “’support[ing] the infrastructure of the lives of the American public, both personally and professionally”); Michael Porter, Shared Value, Harvard Bus. Rev. ** 30 Concurring Statement of Comm’r J. Thomas Rosch, FTC v. Ovation Pharms., Inc. (Dec. 16, 2008), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0810156/081216ovationroschstmt.pdf (hereinafter “Rosch Concurrence”); Concurring Statement of Comm’r Jon Leibowitz, FTC v. Ovation Pharms., Inc. (Dec. 16, 2008), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0810156/081216ovationleibowitzstmt.pdf (“Leibowitz Concurrence”). Ovation Pharmaceuticals, Inc. acquired two drugs to treat patent ductus arteriosus (“PDA”), a serious congenital heart defect in newborns. First, Ovation acquired from Merck the drug Indocin. Several months later, Ovation acquired from Abbott Laboratories the U.S. rights to the drug NeoProfen. After acquiring NeoProfen, Ovation raised the price it charged hospitals for Indocin by nearly 1,300 percent. In December 2008, the FTC challenged under Section 7 of the Clayton Act Ovation’s acquisition of NeoProfen as a merger to monopoly in a market for drugs used to treat PDA. Although Commissioner Rosch voted in favor of the Section 7 challenge, he argued in his concurrence that Ovation’s earlier acquisition of Indocin was also subject to challenge under Section 7. Here the actual evidence is hard to reconcile with the Chicago School’s neoclassical economic theories. Specifically Indocin for many years was the only FDAapproved pharmaceutical treatment for PDA. Given Indocin’s market position, Merck (its original owner) could have charged a monopoly price for its drug. Indeed under the Court’s dicta in Trinko, Merck’s charging a monopoly price would serve “an important 8 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 key driver of corporate reputation is whether consumers perceive that company having high ethical standards.31 Labor, under rational choice theory, is a commodity, an instrument for providing goods and services, which can be downsized, outsourced, or automated.32 There is no inherent dignity in work or greater social calling to use one’s skills to society’s betterment. But as a matter of common experience, the greater value we see our work as having, the more meaning we can attribute to our labor, the more engaged and motivated we are in our work.33 Scenario IV’s theory of competition helps explain why firms devote significant resources in identifying and attracting talented workers. It re-introduces moral beliefs of why we work.34 Scenario IV competition enriches our definition of labor, namely the opportunity to use one’s unique gifts to improve the welfare of others, and thereby express and deepen individual dignity. In addition, by inculcating a unique identity, firms can element of the free market system,” in that monopoly pricing serves as an inducement to “attract[] ‘business acumen’ in the first place” and engage in “risk taking that produces innovation and economic growth.” Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407. In a world of rational profitmaximizers, consumers would applaud, not condemn, Merck. Charging parents whose babies were born with this potentially life-threatening congenital heart defect the monopoly price would signal others to invest in such innovative drugs. Instead, reality suggests that consumers and rational choice theorists differ at times in their perception of what is fair. 31 Harris Interactive, The 2011 Harris Interactive Annual RQ Summary Report 7 (Apr. 2011) (interviewing 30,104 people on the reputations of 60 highly visible companies). Not surprisingly among the 60 companies with the poorer reputations was cable company Comcast, two domestic airlines (American and Delta), five financial institutions (JP Morgan Chase, Bank of America, Citigroup, Goldman Sachs, and AIG), two domestic automobile and two oil companies responsible for monumental oil spills (BP, ExxonMobil) 32 In contrast the Clayton Act provides that the “labor of a human being is not a commodity or article of commerce.” 15 U.S.C. § 17 (2006). 33 DAN ARIELY, THE UPSIDE OF RATIONALITY: THE UNEXPECTED BENEFITS OF DEFYING LOGIC AT WORK AND HOME 66-82 (2010); Jason Krieger, Creating a Culture of Innovation, GALLUP MGMT. J., Oct. 5, 2010, http://gmj.gallup.com/content/143282/creating-culture-innovation.aspx (finding that higher levels of employee engagement “correlate to more idea sharing, better idea generation, more creativity in role, and improved business outcomes (on key items, including customer metrics, productivity, and profitability)”). 34 R.H. TAWNEY, THE ACQUISITIVE SOCIETY 33 (2004) (“For what gives meaning to economic activity, as to any other activity is [] the purpose to which it is directed.”) 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 9 promote (or hinder) social, ethical and moral values that affect employee behavior;35 these values in turn can lower the firm’s monitoring costs and increase its competitiveness.36 Scenario IV competition, while offering several additional competitive dimensions, also presents two additional risks. One risk is that with bounded rational firms and consumers, some forms of market failure (such as cartels and monopolies) are likelier than rational choice theory predicts.37 The stronger the presumption of rationality, the more likely the market will be efficient, the less the governmental concern over the sustained exercise of market power in markets characterized with low to moderate entry barriers. Rational consumers often can defeat the exercise of market power by switching to lower-cost substitutes offered by rational fringe firms or entrants. But as discussed below, bounded rational consumers do not switch as predictably as rational choice theory predicts.38 Bounded rational firms will not always enter.39 Cartels can be more durable when pricefixers, like the subjects in other behavioral experiments, are more trustful 35 Paul C. Nystrom, Differences in Moral Values between Corporations, 9 J. BUS. ETHICS 971, 974 (1990) (survey of how closely-matched corporations within industrial sectors differed significantly in perceived importance of management’s moral values). 36 GEORGE A. AKERLOF & RACHEL E. KRANTON, IDENTITY ECONOMICS: HOW OUR IDENTITIES SHAPE OUR WORK, WAGES, AND WELLBEING 39–59 (2010) (exploring how workers can abide to shared corporate norms, and lose utility when they put in low effort, and how job-holders, if they have only monetary rewards and only economic goals, “will game the system insofar as they can get away with it”). 37 Stucke, Behavioral Economists, supra note 11, at 546-75. At times, market failure is less likely than rational actors faced with the prisoner dilemma. Some people are more trusting than others, and willing to incur a cost to punish unfair behavior. With a sufficient number of these conditional cooperators in the group, one study of 49 forest group users, the tragedy of the commons can be averted. Devesh Rustagi et al., Conditional Cooperation and Costly Monitoring Explain Success in Forest Commons Management, Science, Nov. 12, 2010, at 961. 38 See infra ; see also U.K. Independent Commission on Banking, Interim Report Consultation on Reform Options 33-38 (Apr. 2011) (noting how consumers do not switch banks as often as economic theory predicts). 39 Reeves & Stucke, Behavioral Antitrust, supra note 11. 10 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 and cooperative than rational choice theory predicts.40 A second risk of Scenario IV competition is new forms of market failure. In competitive markets, firms identify and discover ways to solve consumers’ problems.41 But the financial crisis, Professor Stiglitz wrote, showed how the financial innovations involving the subprime mortgage industry worsened, rather than solved, borrowers’ problems.42 Their mortgages increased costs and risks for consumers while providing the mortgage brokers and lenders greater fees. These products increased risk to the institutions that acquired the ensuing credit default swaps and collateralized debt obligations.43 Among the losers in the financial crisis were other supposedly sophisticated investors who failed to appreciate these assets’ risks.44 Moreover, these financial innovations made speculation easer.45 Thus market forces under Scenario IV do not necessarily yield the desired outcome. II. IMPLICATIONS OF DYNAMIC THEORY OF COMPETITION ON MONOPOLIZATION LAW Once the assumption of rationality is relaxed, a more dynamic conception of competition emerges. This conception of competition has many potential implications for monopolization claims. This Article focuses on two implications: entry barriers and behavioral exploitation. A. Herding and Behavioral Learning as Entry Barriers For Robert Bork and others, monopolies (other than those protected by 40 Stucke, Behavioral Economists, supra note 11; Stucke, Am I a Price-Fixer, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined.. 41 Kerber, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 4. 42 STIGLITZ, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 5, 80. 43 MICHAEL LEWIS, THE BIG SHORT: INSIDE THE DOOMSDAY MACHINE (2010). 44 JOHNSON & KWAK, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 199; CASSIDY, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 272. 45 CASSIDY, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 239, 243-50; GILLIAN TETT, FOOL’S GOLD: HOW THE BOLD DREAM OF A SMALL TRIBE AT J.P. MORGAN WAS CORRUPTED BY WALL STREET GREED AND UNLEASHED A CATASTROPHE (2009). 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 11 the government) are short-term phenomena46: the innovator’s supracompetitive profits serve as bait for imitators, who “first reduce and then annihilate [the monopolist’s] profit,” which reverts to the competitive mean.47 Innovation attracts imitation, which leads to commoditization. While not necessarily adopting Bork’s view of entry barriers, U.S. courts in considering whether a firm can attempt to monopolize, or monopolize, a market examine the likelihood of entry.48 Entry analysis plays a key role in any section 2 case. Courts will dismiss a monopolization or attempted monopolization claim if the plaintiff cannot prove that entry barriers in the relevant market are “significant” and “substantial” enough to confer monopoly power.49 Notwithstanding the firm’s intent to monopolize a market and its anticompetitive conduct, the court could find that rational profit-maximizing entrants will materialize and rescue the consumer. Given the importance of entry analysis in monopolization cases, it follows that the types of entry barriers that the courts recognize are of great importance. Traditional entry analysis focused on manufacturing, distribution and regulatory barriers, such as “planning, design, and management; permitting, licensing, or other approvals; construction, debugging, and operation of production facilities; and promotion (including 46 ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 19596 (1978). 47 JOSEPH A. SCHUMPETER, THE THEORY OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 89 (1934). 48 See, e.g., AD/SAT v. AP, 181 F.3d 216, 229 (2d Cir. 1999) (affirming summary judgment for defendant on attempted monopolization claim and noting that the presence of “low barriers to market entry” suggested that the defendant would “face significant competition from new entrants”); Bailey v. Allgas, Inc., 284 F.3d 1237 (11th Cir. 2002) (affirming summary judgment for defendant in Robinson Patman Act case where plaintiff failed to show the presence of entry barriers and noting that “the ease or difficulty of entry” is “[t]he most significant structural factor bearing on the ability to recoup predatory losses through inflated prices” because “[w]here a market has low barriers to entry, sellers charging supracompetitive prices will soon attract new competitors, sellers charging supracompetitive prices will soon attract new competitors”). 49 United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 81, 82 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (“firm cannot possess monopoly power in a market unless that market is also protected by significant barriers to entry”). 12 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 necessary introductory discounts), marketing, distribution, and satisfaction of customer testing and qualification requirements.”50 The agencies’ and courts’ analyses of entry barriers have evolved. One important entry consideration for branded differentiated consumer goods is the time, expense, and likelihood of an entrant in gaining consumers’ confidence and trust (especially for products with powerful chemicals that may pose significant health risks, like hair relaxers).51 Another important development in entry analysis is network effects.52 In Microsoft, the antitrust plaintiff had to prove that (1) “network effects were a necessary or even probable, rather than merely possible, consequence of high market share in the browser market and (2) that a barrier to entry resulting from network effects would be ‘significant’ enough to confer monopoly power.”53 Network effects can be direct or indirect.54 Direct network effects arise when a consumer’s utility from a product (e.g., telephone) increases when others use the product.55 Indirect network effects arise when “the greater the number of users of a given software platform, the more there will be invested in developing products compatible with that platform, which, in turn reinforces the popularity of that platform with users.”56 50 Firms compete to dominate markets 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 9. U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm’n, Commentary on the Horizontal Merger Guidelines 39 (Mar. 2006). 52 See, e.g., Skydive Arizona, Inc. v. Quattrocchi, 2009 WL 2515616, at *2 (D. Ariz. Aug. 13, 2009) (finding under Daubert that general economic principles on networks and network effects was reliable foundation); Bristol Technology, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 42 F. Supp. 2d 153, 169 (D. Conn. 1998); U.S. v. Microsoft Corp., 1998 WL 614485, at *4 (D.D.C. Sept. 14, 1998). 53 United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 83 (D.C. Cir. 2001). 54 Marina Lao, Networks, Access, and “Essential Facilities”: From Terminal Railroad to Microsoft, 62 SMU L. REV. 557, 560-61 (2009). 55 Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 49; In re Ebay Seller Antitrust Litig., 2010 WL 760433, at *10 (N.D. Cal. Mar. 4, 2010) (eBay not contesting significant entry barriers to the online auctions market because of network effects). 56 CFI Microsoft ¶ 1061. 51 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 13 characterized with network effects, and “once dominance is achieved, threats come largely from outside the dominated market, because the degree of dominance of such a market tends to become so extreme.”57 A behavioral economics perspective raises two additional entry barriers: herding and behavioral learning. Consumers, at times, are confronted with competing, incompatible technologies. In choosing, the consumer wants the technology platform that others will likely choose, as the more popular platform (e.g., Blu-ray v. HD DVD, Google’s Android versus Apple58) will attract more supporting complements developed for that platform.59 Each consumer may prefer the superior technology, but forego it for the perceived popular one.60 In believing that others will opt for the subpar technology, the consumer will choose the subpar technology and contribute to the suboptimal outcome. Herding leads to irrational exuberance (or pessimism) over stocks, real estate, and tulips.61 Fads emerge where a consumer’s utility from an item (such as a designer bag) depends on who else owns the item (either the perceived trend-setters62 or masses63). Thus, a firm may seek to secure (or maintain) its monopoly through herding, by using deceptive statements64 and vaporware.65 57 Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 505 F.3d 302, 308 (4 th Cir. 2007). Dylan Byers, Google and Apple Battle for Developers' Hearts and Minds, at Google I/O Conference, Fight between Android, iPhone Rages On, Adweek, May 12, 2011, http://www.adweek.com/news/technology/google-and-apple-battle-developers-hearts-andminds-131550. 59 See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 84 F. Supp. 2d 9, 20 (D.D.C. 1999); Case T201/04, Microsoft Corp. v. Comm’n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601 (Ct. First Instance). 60 CASSIDY, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 130-31. 61 JOHN KENNETH GALBRAITH, A SHORT HISTORY OF FINANCIAL EUPHORIA (1993). 62 See, e.g., THORSTEIN VEBLEN, THE THEORY OF THE LEISURE CLASS 25, 33 (Penguin 1994) (discussing primary motive to accumulate wealth is pecuniary emulation). 63 Peter Sheridan Dodds & Duncan J. Watts, Influentials, Networks, and Public Opinion Formation, 34 J. CONSUMER RES. 441-458 (2007). 64 FTC Intel Compl. ¶ 10 (alleging how Intel engaged in deceptive acts and practices to mislead consumers and the public, including pressuring independent software vendors to label their products as compatible with Intel and not to similarly label with competitor’s products’ names or logos, even though these competitor microprocessor products were 58 14 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 A second entry barrier is behavioral learning, whereby a firm to effectively compete must attain a sufficient scale of trial-and-error feedback. As Part I discusses, bounded rational firms compete by improving their products and services through a trial-and-error process. Through trial-and-error firms can increase internal productive efficiencies. Semiconductor firms, as F.M. Scherer discusses, make mistakes in the early stages of production, adjust their processes, and thereby lower their manufacturing costs for their next batch.66 Consequently, aside from the direct and indirect network effects,67 Intel benefited from another network effect, namely continually learning from its mistakes during its early production period, which enabled it to lower costs as it increased output. Aside from internal behavioral learning, firms can also learn through their networks with suppliers and customers. Here scale is also critical when consumer preferences are not stable and predictable. To keep abreast with changing customer preferences, bounded rational firms rely on trialand-error feedback loops. Firms experiment with an option, monitor customer reaction to their (and their competitors’) offerings, readjust, and monitor. The more feedback firms receive from a larger percentage of targeted consumers, the more the firms can refine their technologies, the better able they can match their technology to customers’ preferences, the greater their competitive advantage. Thus, competitors in some industries compatible). 65 Maurice E. Stucke, How Do (and Should) Competition Authorities Treat a Dominant Firm’s Deception?, 63 SMU L. REV. 1069 (2010). 66 Scherer, High Tech, supra note **, at 49-50. 67 Complaint, In re: Intel Corporation, FTC Docket No. 9288, ¶ 10 (discussing the need simultaneously to secure a large number of users in order to make the product attractive to software developers and to secure the efforts of software developers in order to make the product attractive to users, and Intel’s success “in obtaining commitments from many computer manufacturers and software vendors to build computers and write software for Intel's new 64-bit Merced microprocessor, even though the product will not be available for nearly two years”). 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 15 may require a minimum scale of feedback from bounded rational customers, without which they cannot effectively compete. One example is search engines. To navigate the Internet, Google, Yahoo and other search engines rely on algorithms to identify web pages that match the consumers’ search terms. In this two-sided market, the better the search engine is in identifying the right matches, the more popular the search engine is for consumers, the more attractive the search engine is to advertisers seeking to target those consumers, the greater the advertising revenue the search engine garners compared to competitors, and the likelier the search engine company can monopolize this two-sided market.68 Under rational choice theory, an antitrust plaintiff would have a difficult time proving that (1) network effects were probable and (2) if even if probable, they would create entry barriers significant enough to confer monopoly power. With Mozilla’s Firefox Internet browser for example, one can easily run a search among the different search engines and compare results. To the extent one search engine is lagging, it can hire a competitor’s search engine engineers to develop better algorithms. Accordingly, one would expect a competitive equilibrium among search engines, whereby a consumer could obtain roughly similar results for the same search terms. Absent another point of differentiation (such as better graphics or quicker results) or a tipping point (similar to daily newspapers whereby advertisers would support only one competitor), one search engine should not dominate the market. But with bounded rational consumers, a new form of network effects emerges. When a consumer types “orange” and “apple” in Google, for 68 See Competitive Impact Statement, United States v. Google, (D.D.C. Apr. 8, 2011); Author’s Guild v. Google, No. 05 Civ. 8136 (DC), 2011 WL 986049, at *12 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 22, 2011) (recognizing “Google’s market power in the online search market”). 16 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 example, the search engine quickly generates results that seek to best match the consumer’s interest. Google has the benefit of observing which, if any, links the consumer actually chooses. If many consumers choose a link that was originally offered down the list (say on the fourth page of results), Google can move that result up the list, and demote suggested links that are infrequently tapped down the list. Thus the greater the number of consumers who use the search engine and the greater the number of searches, the more trials the search engine company has in predicting consumer preferences, the more feedback the search engine receives of any errors, and the quicker the search engine can respond with recalibrating its offerings. Increased traffic volumes make more experiments possible, thereby improving search results.69 With a greater churn of trial and error, the search engine can quickly adapt to changing preferences, improve its product, and thereby attract additional consumers to that search engine compared to competitor sites. If consumers lack time or inclination to run their search on multiple sites, then entry becomes more difficult. The new entrant can hire Google’s tech talent, but it still lacks the scale of this trialand-error experimentation. With fewer trials, search results will likely be inferior going forward in identifying sites that consumers prefer, decreasing the popularity of that search engine for consumers and advertisers. Indeed, with more trial-and-error experimentation, the search engine can innovate with predictive search technology (such as suggesting search phrases that refine the consumer’s search or her need to complete typing the search term). To the extent that preferences diverge across demographics, a search engine that loses important segment of the population can become a niche player. As Microsoft observed, 69 Teresa Vecchi et al., The Microsoft/Yahoo! Search Business Case, European Commission Competition Policy Newsletter Issue 2, at 46 (2010). 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 17 there's this kind of inverse power loss, where 39 percent of the users account for 66 percent of all the searches. I think of them as the heavy searchers. Ourselves and Yahoo! and others have been losing heavy searchers for the last number of years. Since the Bing launch, we've actually inverted that, we're actually growing heavy searchers. And when you look at the demographics, we are over-indexed on 18 to 24 year olds now as a result of those heavy users. Before that, we were over-indexed on 65-year plus in terms of demographics, which is our MSN base.70 A justification of the Microsoft-Yahoo partnership was to achieve this scale of behavioral learning through trial-and-error. In December 2009, Microsoft partnered with Yahoo! to provide the exclusive algorithmic and paid search platform for Yahoo! Web sites. Microsoft believed this agreement would allow it over time to improve the effectiveness and increase the value of its “search offering through greater scale in search queries and an expanded and more competitive search and advertising marketplace.”71 Before the partnership, fewer people used Microsoft’s and Yahoo’s search engines.72 The European Commission found that Yahoo and Microsoft were below 10 percent in both search and search advertising in the European Economic Area.73 Google’s share of the search and advertising markets was over 90 percent.74 The search business, the European Commission found, required “substantial and continuous investment in the quality of the search and related R&D.”75 The 70 Credit Suisse Annual Technology Conference, December 1, 2009, Yusuf Mehdi, senior vice president, Online Audience Business. 71 Microsoft 2010 Annual Report. 72 Teresa Vecchi et al., The Microsoft/Yahoo! Search Business Case, European Commission Competition Policy Newsletter Issue 2, at 46 (2010). 73 Vecchi et al., supra note **, at 46. 74 Vecchi et al., supra note **, at 46. 75 Vecchi et al., supra note **, at 46. 18 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 Commission’s market investigation found that the “quality and relevance of the algorithmic search engine” as “the most important factor in attracting users to a particular search engine.”76 As Microsoft’s CEO Steve Ballmer said, it turns out there's a feedback loop in the search business, where the most searches you serve, or paid ad searches you serve, the more you learn about what people click on, what's relevant, and it turns out that scale drives knowledge which then can turn around and redrive innovation and relevance. So, actually even our ability to understand our customers and innovate around that is enhanced by putting the two assets together. It's not just putting them together, but putting them together in this business, which is unlike other businesses, there is a return to scale from seeing that much more Internet activity than either Yahoo! or Microsoft sees independently.77 One year later, Microsoft’s Bing has seen an increase in consumer usage; whether the search engine will attain the necessary scale to threaten Google’s monopoly is less clear.78 Consequently, aside from conventional network effects, courts going forward must consider other entry barriers when consumer preferences are unstable and hard to predict. To effectively compete, an entrant in some industries must attract enough consumers (or those heavy consumers whose preferences most closely resemble the target audience) to engage in this trial-and-error feedback loop. This behavioral entry barrier will be of greater significance going forward as companies seek to match offerings with consumer tastes. To the extent pairing specific products with consumer preference is an important facet of competition, companies with more 76 Vecchi et al., supra note **, at 46. http://www.microsoft.com/presspass/exec/steve/2009/07-29search.mspx. 78 Matt Rosoff, Microsoft Should Have Let Google Have Search To Itself, Business Insider, Apr. 20, 2011, http://www.businessinsider.com/microsoft-should-have-let-googlehave-search-to-itself-2011-4#ixzz1Lyx0ikow. 77 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 19 subscribers (like Netflix, Amazon, or Apple’s iTunes) have more opportunities to predict what movies, books, or music the subscribers would enjoy, monitor actual selections, and revise their predictions, thereby adapting to evolving consumer preferences and products. With this scale from behavioral learning, the company will secure a significant competitive advantage over smaller rivals and decrease the likelihood that an entrant can threaten its monopoly. B. Behavioral Exploitation Although firms and consumer, while bounded rational, are not necessarily bounded rational in the same way and to the same degree. Firms, for example, may be more susceptible than consumers to one bias in one factual context (e.g., overconfidence over a merger’s efficiencies). Moreover being bounded rational with bounded willpower does not necessarily mean ignorance. One may recognize one’s shortcomings (eating snacks before the television rather than exercising), but lack the necessary commitment device. Thus firms can compete in ways to help consumers address or mitigate their biases and bounded willpower and provide consumers a better mix of solutions.79 As subpart A discusses, bounded rational firms through their (or monitoring their competitors’) trial-and-error experiments can update product offerings to accommodate consumers’ changing preferences. Their ability depends in part on the feedback loop’s efficacy and the competitive behavior’s transparency.80 Alternatively firms can compete in devising better ways to exploit consumers’ bounded rationality to the consumers’ detriment. Firms also 79 Kerber, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 4; MISES, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 24 (“competition among the various entrepreneurs is essentially a competition among the various possibilities open to individuals to remove as far as possible their state of uneasiness by the acquisition of consumers’ goods”). 80 Kerber, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 5. 20 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 can seek to lessen competition by reducing price transparency and differentiating their products or services through branding and technological innovation.81 So too monopolists can use the biases and heuristics discussed in the behavioral economics literature (such as status quo bias, framing effects) to attain or maintain their monopoly. Through the lens of neoclassical economic theory, such behavior, rather than exploitive, would appear benign. One example is the European Commission’s prosecution of Microsoft for abusive tying. Although similar behavior was at issue in the U.S. prosecution, the Commission’s case provides a richer narrative: how Microsoft premised its defense on rational choice theory; the Commission and Court of First Instance’s response, which was in accord with behavioral economics findings of actual consumer behavior; the shortcomings of the Commission’s remedy (which indeed was predictable under behavioral economics); the Commission’s reappraisal of its behavioral remedy in the Internet browser settlement, and the remedy’s advantages and shortcomings. The Commission accused Microsoft inter alia of tying its media player to its operating system, where it enjoyed a dominant position. Media players, which are now ubiquitous, enable consumers to store and play music and videos on their computers (and now on handheld devices). Originally RealNetworks licensed Microsoft its media player, RealPlayer.82 In 1997, senior Microsoft executives “noted the dangers of Apple’s and RealNetworks’ multimedia playback technologies, which ran on several 81 State of Ill., ex rel. Burris v. Panhandle Eastern Pipe Line Co., 935 F.2d 1469, 1481 (7th Cir. 1991) (“Virtually all business behavior is designed to enable firms to raise their prices above the level that would exist in a perfectly competitive market.”); see also Desai & Waller, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined.; Steiner, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 84-85 (discussing price premium for strong reputation brands). 82 CFI Microsoft ¶ 837 (noting how Microsoft included RealPlayer in its Internet Explorer 4.0). 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 21 platforms (including the Mac OS and Windows) and similarly exposed APIs to content developers. Microsoft feared all of these technologies because they facilitated the development of user-oriented software that would be indifferent to the identity of the underlying operating system.”83 In 1998, Microsoft released its Windows Media Player, which at that time supported different formats, including Apple’s QuickTime and RealNetworks’s RealAudio and RealVideo. But that changed by 1999, when Microsoft released its Windows 98 Second Edition. The European Commission found Microsoft liable for abusive tying of its personal computer operating system and its streaming media player. Of the offense’s four elements, the focus was on the second element (the tied and tying products are two separate goods).84 The first and third elements of abusive tying were not at issue. Microsoft’s dominant position in the operating system market (the tying product) was not seriously disputed. Nor was the third element, namely that Microsoft did not give customers a choice to obtain the tying product without the tied product, seriously contested. In both the U.S. and EU, one evil of tying is the monopolist “affords consumers no choice but to purchase” (not so much to use85) the 83 U.S. v. Microsoft Corp., 84 F. Supp. 2d 9, 30 (D.D.C. 1999), affirmed in part, reversed in part, 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001). 84 Microsoft argued that liability would punish dominant undertakings from improving their products by integrating new features in them. A dominant firm, argued Microsoft, would be obligated to remove its innovations whenever a third party marketed a standalone product that provided the same or similar functionalities. CFI Microsoft ¶ 888. The United States Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit was sympathetic to Microsoft’s claims. The Court held that the per se illegality standard should not apply to Microsoft’s tying its Internet web browser, Explorer, to its operating system. The Court remanded for a more lenient rule of reason standard, and the United States and Microsoft settled. 85 CFI Microsoft Decision ¶ 970 (“neither Article 82(d) EC nor the case-law on bundling requires that consumers must be forced to use the tied product or prevented from using the same product supplied by a competitor of the dominant undertaking in order for the condition that the conclusion of contracts is made subject to acceptance of supplementary obligations to be capable of being regarded as satisfied”). 22 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 tied product.86 Microsoft’s Windows Media Player came with the operating system. Neither computer manufacturers (OEMs) nor consumers could remove the Windows Media Player.87 What is interesting for our purposes is the offense’s fourth element, namely that Microsoft’s tying practice foreclosed competition. The European Commission, like the district court in the U.S. case, observed how the industry was characterized with network effects. One complaint was that with its operating systems monopoly (enforced by network effects), Microsoft could ward off potential threats by tying its imitation product. Once Microsoft added its version, the Commission found, programmers will develop solutions for the Microsoft platform because it will reach automatically 90% of client PC users, and thus save the content providers the costs of supporting different technology platforms. Under this positive feed-back loop, more users of a given software platform lead to a greater incentive to develop products compatible with that platform, which reinforces that platform’s popularity with end-users (and the software company’s market power). Thus Microsoft chilled the incentives for potential innovators to challenge the entrenched monopolist. As the Commission argued and Court of First Instance found, such bundling “discourages investment in all the technologies in which Microsoft could conceivably take an interest in the future.”88 But from a rational choice perspective, it is difficult to see the coercion or foreclosure one typically finds in tying claims. It was uncontested that consumers, after unpacking the computer and starting it up, could search the Internet for the media player they want, download the software to their 86 Cite Microsoft, Kodak, Jefferson Parish. The evil is in coercing the consumer to purchase the tied good. CFI Microsoft ¶ 865 (noting how coercion was mainly applied first of all to OEMs, who then pass it on to the end user). 87 CFI Microsoft ¶¶ 832, 837. 88 Microsoft, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601. 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 23 computer, and use that media player for listening to music or watching videos.89 Consequently, the issue was to what extent did the monopolist foreclose competition when consumers could download (often for free) alternative media players on the Internet.90 Nor were consumers or the OEMs disadvantaged if they opted for an alternative media player.91 After the U.S. antitrust consent decree, Microsoft could not design its operating system to hamper rival media players, as it earlier did with its Internet browser. Nor could Microsoft contractually require software developers, content providers or anyone else to distribute or promote exclusively or mainly its Windows Media Player.92 It was undisputed that Microsoft’s operating system could run one or more media players without affecting the media players’ performance.93 Nor were consumers forced to use Microsoft’s Windows Media Player. Consumers could set another media player as the default option.94 As the Commission and Court of First Instance observed, a “not insignificant number of customers continue to acquire media players from Microsoft’s competitors, separately from their client PC operating system, which shows 89 CFI Microsoft ¶ 829. Moreover media players may be sold in retail outlets or distributed with other software products. CFI Microsoft ¶ 830. 90 The Commission questioned the extent the media players were free: “Third-party media players offering all the functionality of WMP are often not given away for free. Microsoft’s argument that ‘media player vendors have business models in which they give away most copies of their products’ therefore has to be taken with a degree of caution. It would indeed appear that users feel still less inclined to buy a second media player - even though it offers more functionality than a basic free version of the same brand - where they have already obtained a comparable full-fledged media player pre-installed on their PC.” EC Decision ¶ 847 (footnotes omitted). Consumers today can download a free copy of RealPlayer (http://www.real.com/realplayer), QuickTime (http://www.apple.com/quicktime/download/), and other media players (http://download.cnet.com/windows/media-players/). 91 CFI Microsoft ¶ 995. 92 CFI Microsoft ¶ 995 (no exclusivity provisions). 93 CFI Microsoft ¶ 993. 94 CFI Microsoft ¶ 952. 24 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 that they regard the two products as separate.”95 At the time of litigation, consumers used on average 1.7 media players each month, and that number was increasing.96 One could strain under rational choice theory to find some coercion. First, rational consumers must devote some time and effort to download a media player,97 which could take longer for users without broadband Internet service. Second, OEMs and consumers could not delete Windows Media Player from Microsoft’s Windows operating system. Any media player would be in addition to Microsoft’s product.98 Thus, consumers were unable to devote this computer memory, used by Microsoft’s media player, for other purposes. Third, Microsoft devised its software so that its Windows Media Player could override the consumer’s default setting and reappear when the consumer used Microsoft’s Internet Explorer to access media files streamed over the Internet.99 While annoying, these factors hardly justify a finding of coercion or foreclosure. If other media players offered superior performance for free (or at an attractive price), then rational consumers would incur these minor costs to install and use a competing media player. Put simply, the benefits of using a competing media player outweigh the costs to download it (and use up some additional computer memory). Accordingly, rational consumers would switch if alternative media players indeed were objectively of “better quality.”100 Since rational consumers would switch to superior media players, then logically software programmers and music companies would continue to support the superior players’ formats; 95 CFI Microsoft ¶ 932. CFI Microsoft ¶ 953. 97 EC decision ¶ 866-67. The scarcity of broadband Internet, slower download times, and failed downloads also may have contributed to consumers’ sticking with the default. 98 CFI Microsoft ¶ 946. 99 CFI Microsoft ¶ 974. 100 CFI Microsoft ¶ 971. 96 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 25 Microsoft’s attempt to thwart the competitive threat of middleware (or leverage its monopoly to the media player market) would fail. Many consumers, however, did not (i) purchase Windows N (the version of Microsoft’s operating system without its Windows Media Player), and (ii) download RealNetworks’s and Apple’s competing media players when they readily could have. But this too is explainable under rational choice theory: these facts are consistent with competition on the merits. Rational consumers could and would easily switch to superior media players. If actual consumers are rational and if many did not download other media players, one can deduce that Microsoft’s Windows Media Player was as good as, if not superior to, competing media players. Herein lies the problem. Windows Media Player’s growth, as Microsoft itself recognized, was not attributable to its superior quality to rival products or that the rival products, in particular RealPlayer, had defects.101 “In fact, Microsoft’s own October 2003 submission illustrates that the reviews presented (1999-2003) rate the best product to be RealNetworks’ player more often than WMP.”102 Consequently, rational choice theory cannot explain actual consumer behavior. For a rational choice theorist, the default option (assuming low transactions costs) should not matter. Whatever the default option, consumers would readily opt for their preferred option, which here would be the superior media player. If many consumers preferred Windows Media Player, but OEMs installed RealNetworks’s player, then consumers would switch to Windows Media Player. But as the behavioral economics literature shows, the setting of the default can often determine the outcome (even when transaction costs are 101 102 CFI Microsoft ¶ 1057. EC Microsoft ¶ 948. 26 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 nominal).103 Default options have played an important role in participation and investments in retirement savings, contractual choices in health-clubs, organ donations, and car insurance plans.104 With different views (until perhaps recently) of the benefits of class actions, the EU and the U.S. have different preferences of class members opting out versus opting into the class.105 The district court in the Google book search action recently observed that many concerns over the proposed settlement would be “ameliorated” if the settlement were converted from an “opt-out” to an “opt-in” settlement.106 Not surprisingly, firms and consumers can have different preferences over the default option. In the Federal Reserve’s testing, for example, the majority of surveyed participants preferred setting the default as consumers having to opt into the bank’s overdraft program rather than having to opt out (which many banks preferred).107 In Microsoft, the monopolist preferred having its inferior media player as the default option requiring consumers to opt into an alternative media player. As Microsoft recognized, some consumers would reject the default 103 RICHARD H. THALER & CASS R. SUNSTEIN, NUDGE: IMPROVING DECISIONS ABOUT HEALTH, WEALTH, AND HAPPINESS 78 (2008); Camerer et al., supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 1211. 104 SUNSTEIN & THALER, NUDGE, supra note 103, at 129-30; Stefano DellaVigna, Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field, 47 J. ECON. LIT. 315, 322 n.11 (2009); Eric J. Johnson et al., Defaults, Framing and Privacy: Why Opting In-Opting Out, 13 MARKETING LETTERS 5-15 (2003) (consent to receive e-mail marketing); C. Whan Park et al., Choosing What I Want Versus Rejecting What I Do Not Want: An Application of Decision Framing to Product Option Choice Decisions, 37 J. MARKETING RES. 187-202 (2000) (car option purchases). 105 European Consumer Consultative Group, Opinion on Private Damages Actions 4 (2010) (noting Europe’s recent experience that the rate of participation in opt-in procedure for consumer claims was less than one percent, whereas under opt-out regimes, rates are typically very high (97% in the Netherlands and almost 100% in Portugal)), http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/empowerment/docs/ECCG_opinion_on_actions_for_damage s_18112010.pdf. 106 Authors Guild v. Google Inc., Civ. Act. No. 05 Civ. 8136, slip op. at 46 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 22, 2011). 107 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Final rule; official staff commentary, 12 C.F.R. Part 205, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/bcreg/bcreg20091112a1.pdf. 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 27 option and download a rival media player. But many simply would stick with the default option. Consequently, the Court of First Instance recognized that consumers “who find Windows Media Player pre-installed on their client PCs are generally less inclined to use another media player.”108 The EC was blunt: “A supply-side aspect to consider is that, while downloading is in itself a technically inexpensive way of distributing media players, vendors must expend resources to overcome end-users’ inertia and persuade them to ignore the pre-installation of WMP.”109 Not only is inertia (status quo bias) at work. Some non-computer savvy consumers may believe that default option represents the deliberate choice by the OEM to include the superior media player.110 Status quo bias explains why many consumers remain with the default option, even though rational choice theory predicts that they would download the superior rival media browser. Although the facts did not support its rational choice theory, Microsoft argued that the facts contradicted the Commission’s behavioral explanation. Downloading was a viable mechanism to distribute a media player, Microsoft argued, as “more than 100 million copies of WMP 9 were downloaded in the ten months the software was available to the general public.”111 The EC noted that these “copies were downloaded by people who already had a version of Windows Media Player installed on their PCs.”112 If bounded rational consumers remain with the default option, then logically consumers would stick not only with the default media player, but also with that version of the media player. If Microsoft users overcame 108 CFI Microsoft ¶ 980. EC Microsoft ¶ 870, quoted in CFI Microsoft ¶ 1052. 110 CFI Microsoft ¶ 1050. 111 EC decision ¶ http://ec.europa.eu/competition/elojade/isef/case_details.cfm?proc_code=1_37792 112 EC decision ¶ http://ec.europa.eu/competition/elojade/isef/case_details.cfm?proc_code=1_37792 109 864, 864, 28 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 status quo bias to upgrade their default media player, arguably they could upgrade to any media player. But here Microsoft did not rely on consumers to search for and download software updates. Instead Microsoft nudged its consumers. Microsoft implemented a mechanism in its Windows Media Player by which the player independently and regularly looked for upgrades on Microsoft’s Web site, and prompted the user to download it.113 Moreover, since consumers procrastinate, Microsoft “repeatedly” prompted the consumer to download the upgraded WMP 9 if consumers chose not to do so at the first prompt.114 Thus as the European Commission recognized, the default option matters. Regulators and the industry will continue to battle over whether consumers need to opt-out or opt-in. For if Microsoft seriously considered downloading as “an equivalent alternative to pre-installation,” observed the European Commission, then Microsoft’s “insistence on maintaining its current privilege of automatic pre-installation appears inconsistent.”115 Besides status quo bias, there is also the sunk cost fallacy. Consumers, under rational choice theory, “ignore sunk costs (costs that cannot be recovered, such as the cost of nonrefundable tickets).”116 Consumers should instead consider the costs and benefits going forward. To illustrate: Assume that you have spent $100 on a ticket for a weekend ski trip to Michigan. Several weeks later you buy a $50 ticket for a weekend ski trip to Wisconsin. You think you will enjoy the Wisconsin ski trip more than the Michigan ski trip. As you are putting your just-purchased Wisconsin ski trip ticket in your wallet, you notice that the Michigan ski trip and the Wisconsin ski trip are for the same weekend! It’s too late to sell either ticket, and you cannot return either one. You must use one ticket and not the other. Which ski trip will you go on?117 113 EC decision ¶ 864. EC decision ¶ 864. 115 EC Decision ¶ 871. 116 Jolls et al. supra note, at 1482. 117 Hal R. Arkes & Catherine Blumer, The Psychology of Sunk Cost, 35 ORG. BEHAV. 114 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 29 Under rational choice theory, the $50 and $100 costs are effectively sunk. Consumers instead would consider the costs/benefits going forward and opt for the more enjoyable Wisconsin ski trip. But more people, in response to this question, chose the Michigan trip.118 Bounded rational firms, governments, and consumers “throw good time and money after bad even when the logical decision is to cut bait.”119 Monopolists also can use the sunk cost fallacy to maintain their monopoly. Consumers, for example, can invest significant costs in downloading songs and movies, creating play lists, and organizing their music and videos in their media players. These costs are effectively sunk if consumers cannot transfer their media library to a rival player. Originally Microsoft’s media player was compatible with rivals. But Windows Media Player no longer supported the formats of its rivals’ media players. For rational consumers, the sunk costs invested in Windows Media Player are irrelevant. Knowing they will continue to download music and movies, consumers would consider the benefits and costs going forward with the different media players. But bounded rational consumers, under sunk cost fallacy, would not want to waste their prior time, expense and effort; so they continue using Windows Media Player until a new disruptive innovation (like the iPod, iPhone, and iPad) comes along.120 & HUM. DECISION PROCESSES 124, 126 (1985). 118 Arkes & Blumer, supra note **, at 126 (33 opted for Michigan v. 28 for Wisconsin). 119 Malcolm Baker et al., Behavioral Corporate Finance: A Survey 49 (Sept. 29, 2005), http://ssrn.com/abstract=602902; Janky v. Batistatos, 2008 WL 4411504, at *1 (N.D. Ind. Sept. 25, 2008) (noting how “from the acorn of a relatively minor copyright dispute a mighty oak tree of litigation has resulted-two federal cases, three federal appeals, a state case, and several rounds of sanctions”). 120 Interestingly, Apple is currently being sued for encoding its digital music files with its proprietary digital rights management software that only allowed digital music files purchased from Apple’s iTunes Store to be played directly on iPods; the files could not be played directly on competitors’ digital music players. Apple allegedly prevented digital 30 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 To lock-in consumers, monopolists can proactively remind bounded rational consumers of the sunk costs (e.g., how many installments they already paid for their appliances, furniture, or home, to induce them to continue paying installments), even though the consumer going forward would be better off opting out (e.g., item’s value is less than the remainder of payments). Thus the sunk cost fallacy magnifies the switching costs, thereby increasing the “locked-in” effect and the level of price increases (or reduced quality or services) bounded rational consumers tolerate before switching brands.121 One issue with status quo bias is determining an appropriate remedy. In the Commission’s Microsoft case, the remedy was criticized as ineffectual.122 The Commission, as Microsoft argued, would not have found an abusive tie if Microsoft offered at the same price two versions of its operating system: one with Windows Media Player and one without.123 As its principal remedy, the Commission required Microsoft to allow consumers to obtain a version of its operating system without its media player, “a measure which does not mean any change in Microsoft’s current technical practice other than the development of that version of music files sold at other companies' online music stores from being played on iPods. Plaintiffs in the private antitrust claim allege that Apple sought to foreclose RealNetworks, which in 2004, announced that its digital music files could be played on iPods. When Apple's updates to the software were released in October 2004, plaintiffs allege that “users were forced to update their iTunes applications and iPods, the digital music files from RealNetworks's online store were no longer interoperable with Apple's iPods.” Apple iPod iTunes Antitrust Litigation, Slip Copy, 2011 WL 976942, at *1 (N.D. Cal. March 21, 2011). 121 Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992). 122 Kevin J. O'Brien, As EU Debated, Microsoft Took Market Share, N.Y. Times, Sept. 16, 2007, at http://www.nytimes.com/2007/09/16/business/worldbusiness/16ihtmsft17.1.7522119.html (noting that settlement perceived as a “commercial flop”); Frederic M. Scherer, Abuse of Dominance by High Technology Enterprises: A Comparison of U.S. and E.C. Approaches, 38 J. Indus. and Bus. Econ. 39, 45 (2011) (characterizing remedy as “an abject failure”). 123 CFI Microsoft ¶ 891. The EC denied making this admission in its decision. Id. at ¶ 908. 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 31 Windows.”124 As Microsoft accurately predicted, no one would demand the operating system without the media player.125 This lack of demand, argued Microsoft to the Court of First Instance, supported its contention that “’Windows with media functionality’ is a single product.”126 One need not be a behavioral economist to predict the shortcomings of the Commission’s remedy. But the remedy shows the importance of prospect theory’s framing effects and the reference point. Prospect theory predicts that consumers’ response will vary if the option is perceived as avoiding a loss (consumers are more risk seeking) or as a sure gain (consumers are more risk adverse). Losses closer to a reference point hurt more than twice the joy from comparable gains. So if one could measure joy and pain in standard units (say utils), prospect theory predicts that the pain one feels in losing $100 is more than twice the joy one would feel in finding $100.127 Whether the remedy is perceived as a loss or a gain depends on the reference point.128 124 Microsoft effectively set the reference point as the EC PRESS RELEASE No 63/07, Judgment of the Court of First Instance in Case T-201/04, Microsoft Corp. v Commission of the European Communities, 17 September 2007, http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=CJE/07/63&format=HTML&age d=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en. 125 CFI Microsoft ¶ 891. 126 CFI Microsoft ¶ 891. 127 Kahneman, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 1456. 128 Kahneman et al., supra note **, at 257. One sees the importance of the reference point for merchants accepting credit cards. The merchant bears different cost for accepting different credit card. The merchant has two ways to characterize the reference point: first as a lower cash price and impose a surcharge for customers using a credit card with a higher interchange fee. Alternatively, the merchant can set the credit price as the reference point, and offer consumers a discount if they paid with cash (or a credit or debit card with a lower interchange fee). Since the net price is the same, how the choice is framed should not affect the outcome. After the credit card companies' No-Discrimination Rule was abolished, Dutch merchants could impose surcharges or offer discounts, based on how the customer was going to pay. Over seventy percent of the merchants surveyed were unaware of the rule's abolition, and eighty-nine percent of the merchants did not surcharge customers. Nine percent of the merchants offered discounts to customers who paid by different means. Of the consumers surveyed, seventy-four percent thought it (very) bad if a 32 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 bundled product, namely an operating system with a media player. Thus the Commission’s remedy was a perceived loss in two aspects: getting a “degraded” product (the Windows product without a media player)129 and effectively paying more for it. Since losses (here the loss of one media player) hurt more than comparable gains (adding one media player of one’s choosing130), the European Commission’s remedy was likely to fail. The Commission put itself in an awkward position when it chose as the reference point the basic unbundled operating system. The Commission argued that consumers and OEMs could choose which competitor’s media player, if any, they wanted. Although the Commission properly insisted that the operating system and media player were two separate products, they were nonetheless complementary products. The Commission implicitly told consumers to settle for less (simply an operating system). Alternatively, the Commission could have required consumers to pay more for the Windows operating system with Windows Media Player, but this remedy increases the Commission’s regulatory role for a product that is freely available on the Internet.131 Neither option is desirable. Instead, using prospect theory, the European Commission should have moved the reference point in the opposite direction such that consumers would have perceived Microsoft’s reference point as a loss. The Commission never asserted that operating systems and media players were unrelated. Rather, the Commission asserted that it was not necessary for merchant asked for a surcharge for using a credit card. But when asked about a merchant offering a discount, only forty-nine percent thought it (very) bad, with twenty-two percent neutral and twenty-one percent saying it is a (very) good thing. ITM Research, The Abolition of the No-Discrimination Rule at 7-8 (March 2000), http:// ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/antitrust/cases/29373/studies/netherlands/report.pdf. 129 CFI Microsoft ¶ 1171 130 The EC believed that OEMs would respond to consumer expectations by preinstalling another media player on the version without Windows Media Player. CFI Microsoft ¶ 1204. 131 CFI Microsoft ¶ 968. 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 33 Microsoft’s media player to be bundled with its operating system. Thus, the Commission could have established as the reference point an operating system that came with several choices of media players, from which users could chose. With this reference point, a Windows operating system that comes only with Windows Media Player is a perceived loss (and the loss of two options hurts more than the pleasure gained from one option); moreover consumer prefer having some choices rather than having no choice. The Commission learned from its mistake, and experimented with this other reference point when it later challenged Microsoft for tying its web browser, Internet Explorer, to its personal computer operating system, Windows.132 Before the settlement, consumers who used Windows had Microsoft’s Internet Explorer as their default web browser. Although consumers could download other Internet browsers, many did not, a function not attributable necessarily to the superiority of Microsoft’s browser but status quo bias.133 Rather than using its earlier reference point (namely an operating system without a browser), the Commission effectively shifted to the superior reference point: “’The commission had suggested to Microsoft that consumers be provided with a choice of web browsers,’ the EC wrote regarding the standalone software proposal. ‘Rather than more choice, Microsoft seems to have chosen to provide less.’”134 As part of its settlement, Microsoft for five years must provide 132 Press Release, European Commission, Antitrust: Commission Welcomes Microsoft's Roll-Out of Web Browser Choice, IP/10/216 (Mar. 2, 2010), http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/10/216&format=HTML&aged =0&language=EN. 133 Shane Frederick, Automated Choice Heuristics, in HEURISTICS AND BIASES: THE PSYCHOLOGY OF INTUITIVE JUDGMENT 555 (Thomas Gilovich et al. eds. 2002) (summarizing experimental evidence of peopling preferring current options over other options to a degree that is difficult to justify). 134 Ryan Singel, EU Criticizes Microsoft’s IE Unbundling, but Does It Matter Anymore?, Wired, June 12, 2009, http://www.wired.com/epicenter/2009/06/eu-criticizesmicrosofts-ie-un-bundling-but-does-it-matter-anymore/ 34 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 consumers within the European Economic Area a Browser Choice Screen. Rather than having one Internet browser as the default, computer users must choose whether they want a browser, and if so, which browser they want to install from the competing web browsers listed on the screen.135 Identified are five Internet browsers, with a short description of each, along with links for further information.136 The European Commission’s browser remedy is superior under prospect theory to its earlier media player remedy. But it remains unclear how successful the settlement has been to date. On the one hand, Microsoft’s share of the European browser market declined after the settlement--from 44.9 percent in January 2010 to 39.8 percent in October 2010. 137 Thus Microsoft has a lower market share in the European Union, where consumers are given a choice, than elsewhere in the world where consumers with the Windows operating system must continue downloading an alternative browser.138 Moreover, according to one report, downloads of Opera Software’s desktop browser “increased in number significantly after Microsoft started offering Windows users in Europe a choice in browser with a so-called ballot screen” with “on average, more than half of the European downloads of Opera’s latest browser com[ing] directly from that Choice Screen.”139 The remedy, by enabling consumers to easily choose 135 Summary of Commission Decision of 16 December 2009 relating to a proceeding under Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union and Article 54 of the EEA Agreement (Case COMP/39.530 — Microsoft (Tying)) (2010/C 36/06). 136 http://www.browserchoice.eu/BrowserChoice/browserchoice_en.htm. 137 In 2009, Microsoft’s share declined by 5.5 percentage points; in 2008 by 8 points. Kevin J. O'Brien, European Antitrust Deal With Microsoft Barely Affects Browser Market, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 10, 2010, http://www.nytimes.com/2010/10/11/technology/11eubrowser.html?ref=business. 138 As of April 2011, Microsoft’s Internet Explorer accounted for 55.11 percent of the global usage of browsers, Mozilla's Firefox had 21.63 percent, Google's Chrome had 11.94 percent, and Apple's Safari held 7.15 percent. http://marketshare.hitslink.com/browsermarket-share.aspx?qprid=0&qptimeframe=M 139 http://techcrunch.com/2010/03/18/microsofts-european-browser-choice-screencauses-spike-in-opera-downloads/. 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 35 which browser they desire, increases the likelihood that the market share reflects more the consumers’ informed choice, rather than the monopolist’s.140 On the other hand, even before the settlement, Microsoft’s browser market share was declining.141 So Microsoft’s share could have declined absent the remedy. Moreover, while providing consumers some choice is better than no choice, the choice remedy has at least two limitations. First, offering too many choices can be self-defeating. For example, having consumers choose among 16 web browsers may lead to a worse outcome than choosing among five. Consumers may demand more choices than they actually prefer.142 Again under loss aversion, consumers hate giving up options and restricting their choice set. But when faced with many choices, some bounded rational consumers avoid choosing any option, even when the choice of opting out has negative consequences for future wellbeing.143 Other consumers choose an option, but have lower confidence in their choice and greater dissatisfaction in choosing. Thus too many choices 140 Emanuele Ciriolo, Behavioural Economics in the European Commission: Past, Present and Future, OXERA AGENDA, Jan. 2011, at 3 (noting how 25% of the consumers who viewed the Choice Screen chose an alternative browser), http://www.oxera.com/main.aspx?id=9324. 141 Id. 142 In one computer experiment, participants tried to keep options open even when counter-productive. ARIELY, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 142-48. In the Door Game, each MIT student could click on three doors on the computer screen to find the room with the biggest payoff (between 1 and 10 cents). Each student was given 100 clicks, and could click one door as many times possible without a penalty. Each time the student sampled another door, that switch cost the student one additional click. Experiment 2, the Disappearing Door Game, was the same as the Door Game except each time a door was left unvisited for 12 clicks, it disappeared forever. To keep options open, participants in Experiment 2 ended up making substantially less money (about fifteen percent less) than participants in Experiment 1. Participants would have made more money by sticking to one door. Id. at 147. A similar result occurred when participants were told the exact monetary outcome they could expect from each room. 143 Simona Botti & Sheena S. Iyengar, The Dark Side of Choice: When Choice Impairs Social Welfare, 25 J. PUBLIC POL’Y & MARKETING 24, 26 (2006) (discussing information overload, where an increase in options raises the cognitive costs in comparing and evaluating the options and leads to suboptimal decision strategies). 36 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 may lead to suboptimal results for consumers and firms.144 A second shortcoming with the Commission’s choice model is the lack of any feedback loop, whereby consumers can test the products and compare their performance. For search engines, the consumer can see the number and quality of results for a search term. But benchmarking web browsers and media players may be harder. To the extent the choice screen provides consumers a way to compare the products’ performance on popular metrics, the more likely the consumer’s choice will be informed. One may question the extent to which defaults matter going forward for technological innovation. Consumers arguably are more comfortable with computer technology. Indeed Apple’s Steve Jobs discusses the post- Personal Computer world of handheld devices,145 where Microsoft is lagging.146 Many consumers today search and download apps for their mobile telephones, iPods, and iPads; “the average number of apps downloaded to every iPhone/iPod touch and iPad is more than 60.”147 Downloading itself may become dated with cloud computing. It is fitting that the same week that the United States antitrust consent decree with 144 The bounded rational firms, as a result, lose sales opportunities of their products. Iyengar and Lepper, in their famous experiment, set up a tasting booth in an upscale grocery store. The booth displayed either six or twenty-four different flavors of jam. A greater percentage of the shoppers stopped to sample one of the displayed jams when the booth had twenty-four jam flavors (60 percent versus 40 percent when booth displayed six jam flavors). But a lower percentage actually purchased a jar of jam (3 percent versus 30 percent of customers when booth had only six flavors). Sheena S. Iyengar & Mark R. Lepper, When Choice Is Demotivating: Can One Desire Too Much of a Good Thing?, 79 J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 995–1006 (2000). 145 Brier Dudley, Feisty Steve Jobs Talks Up Apple's 'post-PC' iPad 2, Seattle Times, March 2, 2011, http://o.seattletimes.nwsource.com/html/businesstechnology/2014381153_brier03.html. 146 In a recent Nielsen survey of U.S. mobile consumers for January 2011 to March 2011, 31 percent of consumers who plan to get a new smartphone indicated that Android was now their preferred operating system, 30 percent preferred Apple’s iOS, 11 percent identified RIM/Blackberry, and 6 percent identified Windows Phone devices (nearly 20 percent were unsure what to choose next). http://techcrunch.com/2011/04/26/nielsenconsumer-desire-for-android-grows-unlike-ios-and-blackberry/ 147 BRYAN M. WOLFE, The Number Of Apps Downloaded Each Day Reaches 30 Million, Jan. 20, 2011, 8-Feb-16] Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition 37 Microsoft expired, two other things happened. First, Google announced its Chromebook, whereby the user accesses its data and applications through the Internet. The computer has no operating system (which would require downloads, updates, etc.). As advertised none of the consumer’s data is lost, if the computer falls in a lake. Second, Microsoft announced its purchase of Skype. Microsoft hopes Skype will provide greater inroads in social networks, which like Facebook, the most popular visited site, do not require downloads, but can be accessed anywhere.148 Nonetheless defaults will continue to be an issue. Competitors in South Korea, for example, have complained to the Korean FTC of Google offering its Android system for free with smartphones.149 Android smartphones use Google as the default search engine.150 Although it its technically possible to switch to competing search applications, the competitors argue, as did Microsoft’s competitors in the earlier antitrust cases, that it is not easy. 151 They complain that their applications cannot be preloaded on the smartphone.152 CONCLUSION Dynamic competition with bounded rational market participants is inherently complex and difficult to predict. We can only comprehend the competitive process imperfectly. But by updating competition policy with the developments of behavioral economics we can see the importance of feedback loops and adaptation to the competitive process as well as a potential entry barrier. Antitrust analysis accordingly must move beyond rational choice theory to assess the behavior observed in the marketplace. 148 Richard Waters et al., Micosoft Pays $8.5bn for Skype in Push for Consumer Internet Control, Fin. Times, May 11, 2011, at 1. 149 McDonald, supra note **, at B3. 150 McDonald, supra note **, at B3. 151 McDonald, supra note **, at B3. 152 McDonald, supra note **, at B3. 38 Behavioral Economics and Dynamic Competition [8-FEB-16 Besides the recognized arsenal of practices to illegally maintain their monopolies, monopolists can exploit consumer biases and heuristics, such as status quo bias and the sunk cost fallacy, to attain or maintain their monopoly. Ultimately the issue involves incentives. Bounded rational firms, as this Article discusses, have an incentive to improve their rationality and willpower when debiasing provides a competitive advantage. government often lacks this incentive. But the At times competition agencies compete for prestige, resources, and cases (such as the FTC and DOJ over mergers). But inter-agency competition does not necessarily increase political accountability and reduce the government’s biases and heuristics.153 Although the competition agencies may attract dynamic leaders with a desire to critically test the prevailing economic theory’s assumptions, there are no built-in institutional mechanisms that will regularly the incentives for government officials to recognize their bounded rationality, to continually test their theories’ assumptions, to retrospectively examine the efficacy of their actions, and to use these findings to update their policies.154 Consequently, while competition can supply firms the incentive to debias, competition agencies must now design institutional mechanisms to engage in the same trial-and-error feedback loop. While some may argue boring, antitrust enforcement requires patient gardeners, who experiment, monitor, and update the economic theories of competition, entry barriers, and monopolization. 153 When test subjects were expected to defend their judgments to their peers, subjects chose more complex and time-consuming decision-making strategies. Ziva Kunda, The Case for Motivated Reasoning, 108 PSYCHOLOGICAL BULL. 480, 481(1990). 154 NORTH, UNDERSTANDING, supra note Error! Bookmark not defined., at 68.