Issue 52 September 2014 Measuring and Assessing the Performance of Regulators Mark Pearson and Simon Haslock* Recently, the question of how best to measure and assess the performance of regulators has been gaining significant traction in Australia, and also internationally. A range of reports released in Australia over the last 12 months focus on bestpractice principles for conducting performance assessments of regulators, such as the Productivity Commission’s (2014) Regulatory Audit Framework and the Australian National Audit Office (2014) revised guide to administering regulation. These reports feed into the broader objectives of the Australian Government, which is committed to regulatory reform, with the stated aims of boosting productivity, increasing competitiveness, reducing unnecessary regulation and lifting regulatory performance. Internationally, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2014b) has made a contribution to the field through the release in July 2014 of its own best-practice principles for regulatory policy and governance. These principles have been the subject of significant consultation with national regulators over the past two years, including the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC). This article provides some insight on the key elements of the OECD principles, while also noting the ongoing work that is being conducted by the OECD’s Network of Economic Regulators to devise a fit-for-purpose performance assessment framework for economic regulators. Background In 2012, the OECD’s Council on Regulatory Policy and Governance made a number of recommendations focused on developing a systematic governance framework that could deliver ongoing improvements to the quality of regulation in member countries. One of these recommendations (OECD 2014a) was that countries develop ‘a consistent policy covering the role and functions of regulatory agencies in order to provide greater confidence that regulatory decisions are made on an objective, impartial and consistent basis, without conflict of interest, bias or improper influence’. This recommendation has acted as the impetus for the OECD’s work on best-practice principles for regulatory policy and governance in the intervening period. The Council’s recommendations were the result of assessments made by the OECD’s Regulatory Policy Committee, established in 2009 to provide intellectual and practical support to countries in their regulatory reform efforts. OECD policy analysts had identified a gap in support mechanisms for countries facing reform pressures, and established the Regulatory Policy Committee in response. The Regulatory Policy Committee aims to provide a platform to help countries adapt regulatory policies, tools and institutions and through that, support member countries to undertake effective regulatory reform. It has a broader remit than economic regulation per se, which led to the more recent decision to establish the Network of Economic Regulators. Contents Lead Article 1 From the Journals 7 Regulatory Decisions in Australia and New Zealand 10 Notes on Interesting Decisions 16 Regulatory News 19 *Mark Pearson is the Chief Risk Officer of the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC). He oversees the ACCC’s deregulation efforts and also has a coordination role in relation to its regulatory functions. Prior to this, Mark was responsible for managing the ACCC’s Regulatory Affairs Division, first as Executive General Manager and then as Deputy Chief Executive Officer. Mark has around 20 years’ experience in senior management roles in the public service. In addition to his primary responsibilities at the ACCC, Mark sits on the Bureau responsible for governing the OECD’s Network of Economic Regulators. Simon Haslock is an Assistant Director in the Regulatory Coordination Unit at the ACCC, providing support to the ACCC’s regulatory line areas and senior management. Prior to this, he was in the ACCC’s Communications Group for five years. ministry, the judiciary, the regulator’s governing body and regulated entities; and internal governance (looking into the regulator) – the regulator’s organisational structure, standards of behaviour and roles and responsibilities, compliance and accountability measures, oversight of business processes, financial reporting and performance management. The OECD Best Practice Principles for Regulatory Policy mainly focus on external governance arrangements and their effect on the performance of regulators. However, some important elements of internal governance are addressed, including performance evaluation for regulators. Internal governance is the main focus of this article. The establishment of the Network of Economic Regulators was first considered at an April 2012 meeting of the Regulatory Policy Committee, where two major themes emerged. Firstly, appropriate governance models for regulators, including the institutional setting; and, secondly, the criteria that relate to a world-class regulator. The Regulatory Policy Committee decided to sponsor the Network of Economic Regulators on the basis that effective economic regulation is a fundamental pillar of economic reform and development. The Network of Economic Regulators aims to be a forum in which regulators can develop best practices, identify key operational principles, provide advice on challenges and how to overcome them, and develop case studies for the benefit of member countries and their reform processes. The OECD has identified seven principles for good governance, being: The Network of Economic Regulators considers the ability to move away from a pure sectoral approach (that is, communications, energy, post, ports) allows a much broader perspective to be brought to bear on regulatory issues, thereby improving the performance of individual regulators and the policy processes underpinning them. The OECD’s Best Regulatory Policy Practice Principles role clarity; preventing undue influence and maintaining trust; decision making and governing body structure for independent regulators; accountability and transparency; engagement; funding; and performance evaluation. Below is a summary of some of the key guidance provided by the OECD in relation to measuring and assessing the performance of regulators. Where relevant, the ACCC’s approach to these issues has been drawn upon as a case study in the Australian context. for The OECD Best Practice Principles for Regulatory Policy seek to construct an overarching framework to support initiatives to drive further performance improvements across regulatory systems in relation to national regulatory bodies or agencies. The OECD considers that efficient and effective regulators, with good regulatory management and governance practices, are needed to administer and enforce regulations. Accountability and transparency The OECD suggests that a good mechanism for ministers and regulators to achieve clear expectations is for ministers to issue a statement of expectations to each of their regulators. These statements should outline relevant government policies, including the government’s current objectives relevant to the regulator, and any expectations on how the regulator should conduct its operations (OECD 2014b, pp. 81-82). The regulator should then formally respond by outlining how it proposes to meet the expectations of government in its corporate plan or a statement of intent. This document should include key performance indicators (KPIs) agreed with the relevant minister. Regulatory activity has become increasingly important in the modern state in both policy formation (regulatory design) and in policy execution (regulatory delivery) because regulators have special expertise in drawing on the relevant evidence from the natural and social sciences, including economics, finance and behavioural theory (OECD 2014b). While the OECD acknowledges that there are different institutional models for regulators, it considers improving the governance arrangements of regulators can benefit the community by enhancing the effectiveness of regulators, and, ultimately, the achievement of important public policy goals. This process is already in place in Australia. Earlier this year, the Australian Government issued its Statement of Expectations to the ACCC and other regulators (Australian Treasury 2014a). The ACCC responded in turn with a Statement of Intent (ACCC 2014a). The ACCC has published both documents on its website for review by the public. The OECD (2014b, p. 19) has identified two broad aspects of governance relevant to regulators, which are: external governance (looking out from the regulator) – the roles, relationships and distribution of powers and responsibilities between the legislature, the minister, the In addition to publishing objectives, the OECD recommends that regulators produce and publish 2 clear operational policies covering compliance and also enforcement and decision reviews. The regulator should also disclose what rules, data and informational inputs will be used to make decisions (OECD 2014b). The ACCC already implements these measures, updating the ACCC Compliance and Enforcement Policy on a regular basis to ensure its priorities and strategies remain relevant (ACCC 2014a). The ACCC also provides public versions of all draft and final regulatory determinations on its website. budget statements, which outlines a number of outcomes the ACCC is expected to achieve during a financial year (Australian Treasury 2014b). The Annual Report provides a detailed account of deliverables against each of these outcomes. The ACCC, along with all other Commonwealth entities, is currently working with the Australian Government in relation to the development of a Commonwealth Performance Framework. The Public Governance, Performance and Accountability Act 2013 (PGPA Act), which came into effect on 1 July 2014 and replaced the Financial Management and Accountability Act 1997, established the Performance Framework as one of its four core objectives. The Performance Framework is being developed to promote improvements in the quality, reliability, and availability of descriptive and instructive information about the non-financial performance of Commonwealth entities. Performance evaluation The OECD notes that it is important that regulators are aware of the impacts of their regulatory actions and decisions. This will help drive improvements and enhance systems and processes internally. It also helps to build confidence in the regulatory system. The OECD considers this is best achieved by the identification and implementation of performance measures (OECD 2014b, p. 107). The Public Governance, Performance and Accountability Act 2013 establishes a number of requirements that are related to the development of the Performance Framework (Parliament of the Commonwealth of Australia, 2013). These include: The OECD recommends that the regulator should report against a comprehensive set of meaningful performance indicators, set with reference to the goals it is expected to achieve. These indicators should incorporate quantifiable aspects of the regulator’s activities that provide metrics to assess its performance and the costs that it imposes (OECD 2014b, p. 107). Regulators should consider which operational indicators can be used to demonstrate the systems, processes and procedures that are applied within the organisation to complete tasks. In addition, regulators should consider which outcome indicators can be linked to their actions to demonstrate the overall strategic results of regulatory intervention (for example, investment in infrastructure) (OECD 2014b, p. 106). at: a new requirement that all Commonwealth entities prepare an Annual Performance Statement; and a restatement of the current requirement for all Commonwealth entities to prepare Annual Reports. Development of a Performance Assessment Framework for Economic Regulators Building on the OECD Best Practice Principles for Regulatory Policy, the OECD’s Network of Economic Regulators is committed to developing a Performance Assessment Framework for Economic Regulators. It is widely accepted that there are many challenges in performance measurement and assessment and developing appropriate KPIs for economic regulators. For example, gaming by businesses can impact significantly on the ability of regulators to achieve desired outcomes in regulatory processes. However, these challenges must be overcome as governments, parliaments and other stakeholders are increasingly demanding assurances around effectiveness, efficiency and impact of economic regulators. Traditionally, the ACCC’s primary reporting mechanism on its performance has been its Annual Report, which has been produced in conjunction with the Australian Energy Regulator.1 This report has responded to the framework in the Treasury portfolio Available annual-report a new requirement that all Commonwealth entities prepare a Corporate Plan; Performance statements will be part of an integrated Annual Report that brings together information about an entity’s strategy, governance and financial and non-financial performance. A copy of the statement will need to be included in an entity’s Annual Report when it is tabled in Parliament. The OECD suggests that regulators should conduct internal performance evaluations as part of good internal governance practices. These should be complemented by external evaluations. The OECD notes that, while regulators have a number of audiences for their performance evaluation, including government, regulated entities and citizens, the main purpose of the evaluation should be towards achieving self-improvement and accountability (OECD 2014b, p. 108). 1 http://www.accc.gov.au/publications/accc-aer- 3 Regulators play key roles in various industry sectors, thereby influencing growth, development and investment. Having an effective measurement framework is likely to lead to better outcomes for society, by providing for robust benchmarking of regulatory performance to ensure regulators are meeting the objectives they were established for and achieving value for money. telecommunications regulator, the Comision de Regulacion de Comunicaciones. A set of recommendations will flow from this assessment and include: Discussions amongst regulators at the OECD have been aimed at identifying ways of measuring their performance and impact on the sectors they regulate, and economic welfare more broadly. These discussions have included case studies on the development of KPIs, regulatory audits (especially of economic regulators undertaken by the UK’s National Audit Office)2 and papers prepared by the Secretariats of the Regulatory Policy Committee and the Network of Economic Regulators. methodologies for developing specific indicators; measurement techniques; and the institutional processes and arrangements for using performance measurement. The Productivity Commission (2014, p. 5) asserts that the need for a process to audit regulator performance reflects ongoing concerns that the way some regulators interact and engage with businesses and other regulated entities is responsible for much of the unnecessary cost imposed by regulation. The Productivity Commission (2014, p. 5) considers there is currently ‘no systematic process by which the costs that regulators impose on business are assessed ex post.’ The Productivity Commission’s (2014, pp. 9-10) audit framework sets out a number of steps that it considers should be taken by a regulator to measure and assess its performance, with particular regard to the compliance costs they impose. These steps are: 1. Establishment of an agreed set of indicators of good performance appropriate to each regulator. This should be documented in an audit plan. It should form part of the regulator’s stated intent for administering their regulations in a way that imposes the least cost on business. The Network of Economic Regulators is currently testing the Performance Assessment Framework for Economic Regulators, including utilising a questionnaire to assess Columbia’s are available As noted earlier, a number of reports have been released in Australia focusing on the performance of regulators. Two in particular provide frameworks for measuring and assessing this performance. The Productivity Commission’s Regulatory Audit Framework (2014) offers guidance for auditing the performance of regulators in regard to the compliance costs they impose on business and other regulated entities. The Australian National Audit Office’s Better Practice Guide – Administering Regulation (2014) has a broader focus, providing a framework to assist regulators in assessing the quality of their administrative practices and identifying improvements that can be made. While there are particular issues relevant to specific sectors, there is a growing understanding of the broad similarities and issues that all economic regulators face in measuring and assessing performance. The Performance Assessment Framework for Economic Regulators recognises and will build on the efforts of a number of economic regulators to develop assessment processes for their own performance. It aims to help fill any gaps in particular regulators’ work programs and to provide solutions across sectors through a common framework for regulatory learning. Examples of these regulatory audits http://www.nao.org.uk/search/type/report/. information on approaches and methodologies for setting measureable objectives and targets; The Australian Context The Performance Assessment Framework for Economic Regulators that is being developed under the auspices of the Network of Economic Regulators aims to operationalise in an economic regulatory context the principles of the Regulatory Policy Committee’s Framework for Regulatory Policy Evaluation (OECD 2014a). This framework was developed by the OECD Secretariat, working with member countries, to address the lack of guidance on exactly how to undertake assessments of regulatory policy within individual jurisdictions. There was also a recognised need to develop appropriate methodological tools to assist jurisdictions and those undertaking the assessments. The aim of the framework is to provide countries with a methodology that assists the capture of information sufficient to allow them to make decisions about where to invest scarce resources. 2 2. Collection of information and data on the chosen indicators. The audit plan should set out what data should be collected for annual reporting, and the form in which they should be collected and collated. 3. Conduct of an external audit. A written assessment of the regulator’s performance at: 4 against the indicators should be published in a central location. The Productivity Commission notes (2014, p. 15) that a key step in developing an audit plan is identifying the particular metrics or measures that will reflect achievement of the chosen indicators (step one, above). The Productivity Commission suggests that the metrics chosen should ideally reflect outcomes rather than processes or outputs. The Australian National Audit Office considers that well-documented and carefully-structured management systems and procedures provide a regulator with the tools to define regulatory outcomes and administrative priorities, and measure and report on performance (Australian National Audit Office 2014, p. 27). The Australian National Audit Office suggests that performance information systems should be designed to inform internal and external stakeholders about the performance of the agencies’ activities including (p. 27): whether the regulation is achieving the Australian Government’s stated policy objectives; the costs associated with administering the regulation; and the cost of compliance for regulated entities. identify appropriate data and information that can be used to measure performance against the indicators; conduct regular audits/assessments of performance against the indicators – this should include structured feedback from stakeholders subject to the regulation; and publish findings in a public forum, such as on the regulator’s website. Conclusion This article has demonstrated there is significant interest in governmental and regulatory policy circles regarding how best to measure and assess the performance of regulators. Regulators themselves are increasingly interested in implementing systems that allow them to closely analyse their own performance and focus on areas for improvement. As an example, the ACCC has implemented a number of self-reporting measures relevant to the conduct of its responsibilities, including producing a detailed Annual Report and publishing its priorities in relation to its enforcement and compliance functions on a regular basis. The ACCC will also continue to work closely with the Australian Government to implement the new Performance Framework for Commonwealth entities. The Australian National Audit Office outlines a set of key considerations in measuring, reporting and reviewing regulatory performance. These considerations are similar in nature to the steps proposed by the Productivity Commission. Initially, the Australian National Audit Office suggests that a regulator should define relevant effectiveness and efficiency indicators to support reporting for internal management and external accountability purposes. The regulator should then undertake periodic reviews to consider the effectiveness of the regulation being administered, and the efficiency and effectiveness of the agency’s regulatory administration. Throughout this process the regulator should draw on stakeholder views to understand their expectations about the effectiveness of the regulatory regime, whether an appropriate balance is being achieved in relation to risk, the underlying regulatory burden, and the efficiency and effectiveness of the regulatory regime (Australian National Audit Office 2014, p. 28). In addition to domestic developments, the OECD’s Regulatory Policy Committee, and Network of Economic Regulators, are building a significant body of theory and practical advice relating to the performance of regulators that can be implemented across international jurisdictions. International forums such as these are particularly useful in stimulating the exchange of ideas and experiences across a wide range of regulators. These exchanges help to illuminate what is ‘best practice’ in the international context. The ACCC will continue its active engagement in these forums to ensure that it remains abreast of new thinking and approaches that can be applied to the measurement and assessment of its performance. References ACCC (2014a), ACCC Compliance and Enforcement Policy, February. Available at: http://www.accc.gov.au/publications/compliance-andenforcement-policy. To summarise, there are some recurring themes across the Australian and OECD reports in relation to how regulators (or third parties) should go about measuring and reporting on their performance, including: ACCC (2014b), Accountability – Government Expectations. Available at: http://www.accc.gov.au/about-us/australiancompetition-consumer-commission/accountability. clearly define a set of indicators of good performance that are relevant to the regulator’s specific responsibilities and activities – this process should involve stakeholder input; Australian National Audit Office (2014), Better Practice Guide – Administering Regulation: Achieving the Right Balance, June. Available at: 5 http://www.anao.gov.au/Publications/Better-PracticeGuides/2013-2014/Administering-Regulation. Australian Treasury (2014a), Statements Expectations, available http://www.treasury.gov.au/PolicyTopics/PublicPolicyAndGovt/Statements-ofExpectations. of at: Australian Treasury (2014b), Treasury Portfolio Budget Statements 2014-15 – ACCC. Available at: http://www.treasury.gov.au/PublicationsAndMedia/Pu blications/2014/PBS-201415/Report/ACCC. OECD (2012), Recommendation of the Council on Regulatory Policy and Governance, March 2012 available at: http://www.oecd.org/gov/regulatorypolicy/2012recommendation.htm. OECD (2014a), OECD Framework for Regulatory Policy Evaluation, June. Available at: http://www.oecd.org/regreform/framework-forregulatory-policy-evaluation.htm. OECD (2014b), OECD Best Practice Principles for Regulatory Policy: The Governance of Regulators, July. Available at: http://www.oecdilibrary.org/governance/the-governance-ofregulators_9789264209015-en Parliament of the Commonwealth of Australia (2013), Public Governance, Performance and Accountability Act 2013, Replacement Explanatory Memorandum, pp. 32-33. Available at: http://parlinfo.aph.gov.au/parlInfo/download/legislatio n/ems/r5058_ems_7f7ccf98-dd9f-40a6-949cfdd9a2830ddf/upload_pdf/381803.pdf;fileType=applic ation%2Fpdf Productivity Commission (2014), Regulatory Audit Framework, March. Available at: http://www.pc.gov.au/research/submission/regulatoraudit-framework 6 Critical Issues in Regulation – From the Journals size rather than profits – plays an important role in many areas. The Causes and Effects of Deregulation, Paul MacAvoy and Richard Schmalensee (eds), Edward Elgar Publishing, 2014. How large are efficiency losses due to imperfect competition when firms employ such strategic incentives? Ritz observes that, while it is well-known that such departures from profit-maximisation lead to lower prices, only very little attention has been paid actually to quantifying their welfare impact. Welfare losses are defined in terms of the loss of economic surplus as a proportion of maximum possible economic surplus. Ritz’s theoretical model with n symmetric businesses suggests equilibrium welfare losses are of order 1/n4, and thus ‘vanish extremely quickly’ as the number of businesses increases. Efficiency losses are less than five per cent for many empirically relevant market structures. This is despite significant business asymmetry and industry concentration. These efficiency losses can be estimated using only basic information on market shares. These results apply to strategic forward trading; for example, in restructured electricity markets. This is a collection of previously published articles on the causes and effects of deregulation in the areas of energy, telecommunications and transport. Edited by Paul MacAvoy and Richard Schmalensee (who provide an original introduction), it brings together in two volumes 41 articles published between 1968 and 2012. The articles are collected under these headings: overview; railroads; trucking; airlines; natural gas; telecommunications; electricity and cable television. Contributors include: Severin Borenstein, Jerry Hausman, Paul Joskow, Alfred Kahn, Roger Noll, Sam Peltzman, Nancy Rose, George Stigler, Peter Temin, and Michael Whinston. There are many seminal articles reproduced, including: Stigler’s theory of regulation; Noll’s article on the politics of regulation; two articles by Wesley Wilson on railroad deregulation; Kahn’s article on vested interests and deregulation in airlines; Macavoy’s article on the natural gas market; Hausman on regulated costs and prices in telecommunications; and Joskow and Schmalensee on incentive regulation of electricity utilities. This paper is available by subscription to the Journal of Industrial Economics. Running Out of Power? Commission Moderates State Aid for Electricity, Michael This note is based on information about this collection available at: http://www.eelgar.com/bookentry_main.lasso?id=14986 [accessed on 16 September 2014]. Kraus, Oxera Agenda, April 2014. This brief article is about the European Commission’s revised Environmental and Energy Aid Guidelines. The article has many detailed references relating to these guidelines. Many of these references relate to the German reaction to the guidelines and are in the German language. On Welfare Losses due to Imperfect Competition, Robert Ritz, Journal of Industrial Economics, March 2014, 62, 1, pp. 167-190. This paper is about welfare (efficiency) losses due to imperfect competition; particularly where businesses pursue objectives other than profit maximisation. While it is primarily a theoretical paper, the author, Robert Ritz, makes reference to a number of empirical studies; particularly in wholesale electricity; and in banking and finance. The paper features a comprehensive reference list containing 44 items. According to the author, the guidelines ‘have had a rocky start, fostered by an intense consultation process with member states’. As the guidelines eventuated, the proposed technological neutrality became subject to concessions and existing state aid to renewable generation was allowed to continue. According to Michael Kraus, ‘the new Guidelines are less revolutionary than might have been expected when the draft emerged towards the end of 2013’. The author contends that existing contributions to the literature on the efficiency effects of imperfect competition assume, either explicitly or implicitly, that firms are profit-maximisers. In contrast, Robert Ritz focuses on situations where corporate managers and executive compensation (strategic incentives) place significant emphasis on measures of business size, such as sales revenue or market share. Ritz presents evidence suggesting that, in practice, competition for rankings in ‘league tables’ – based on In the shorter term, member states will retain substantial discretion as to their energy policy. This discretion is particularly valued in the context of Germany’s Energiewende. For example, the German Government had opposed technological neutrality. The Guidelines allow a transition en douceur, where the new rules suggest that renewable energy sources should become ‘grid-competitive’ between 2020 and 7 2030, with current subsidies eventually being phased out. The analysis in the fourth section estimates the additional network infrastructure cost to existing carriers that arises from the emergence or entry of an additional nationwide carrier. The market simulation model does not explicitly consider whether entry could significantly affect the fixed costs of network build-out facing the emergent or incumbent wireless carriers. Providing mobile wireless services requires building capital-intensive networks that use a specific scarce resource; radio spectrum. The engineering of wireless networks and scarcity of wireless spectrum imply a trade-off between the benefits of increased competition and the higher costs resulting from individual carriers having less spectrum with which to build their networks. The authors attempt to quantify some of these added costs. This article is available by subscription to Oxera Agenda. Canadian Wireless Market Performance and the Potential Effect of an Additional Nationwide Carrier, Brattle Group for the Canadian Commerce Commission, 12 May 2014. Canada’s Competition Bureau engaged The Brattle Group to evaluate the competitiveness of the Canadian wireless market to provide evidence in relation to the Canadian Radio-television and Telecommunications Commission’s (CRTC’s) review of wholesale mobile wireless services. The resulting study was prepared by Kevin Hearle, Giulia McHenry, James Reitzes, Jeremy Verlinda and Coleman Bazelon. The study is 144 pages in length including the authors’ biographies and three appendices. This report is available by following this link: http://t.e2ma.net/message/as6jg/ya16kg [accessed on 16 September 2014]. Analysis of Postal Price Elasticities, Office of The authors first assess existing market power in the Canadian wireless market based on wireless performance metrics and the potential profitability of the wireless carriers. To expand the analysis, the competitive impact on prices and consumer surplus from the introduction of an additional nationwide carrier is estimated. The analyses build on previous research and offer new approaches to evaluating the effect of additional competition on wireless customers and incumbent producers. Inspector General United States Postal Service, White Paper, 1 May 2013. This paper analyses the effect of increases in postal prices on revenue and volume. Analysis of the demand for postal products in the United States shows that price increases will increase revenues, suggesting that demand for postal services is price inelastic. Recent events such as the global financial crisis and the growth of use of the Internet do not change this broad conclusion. The Office of Inspector General United States Postal Service (USPS) retained Lauritis R. Christensen Associates, an economic consulting firm, to conduct the analysis. Christensen Associates reviewed the demand models that the USPS filed with the Postal Regulatory Commission in 2011 and 2012. The USPS uses these models in financial forecasting, pricing, marketing, and planning processes. Christensen Associates also reviewed other econometric formulations of the demand for postal services. This econometric evaluation of Postal Service price elasticities uses both the USPS’s models and an alternative set of models. The paper is in the form of a detailed technical report, including several references to relevant literature. The engineering of wireless networks and scarcity of wireless spectrum imply a trade-off between the benefits of increased competition and the higher costs resulting from individual carriers having less spectrum with which to build their networks. The analysis attempts to quantify some of these added benefits and costs. Canadian wireless industry metrics suggest that additional competition would benefit consumers. Canadian wireless carriers are highly concentrated, especially at the province-level. At a nationwide level, international comparisons, particularly with the United States, suggest to the authors that Canadian wireless is underperforming in several respects. TELUS and Rogers Communications’ wireless businesses are generally making above-normal returns on their capital employed, consistent with the exercise of market power. Using stock price effects, the authors predict that the entry of an additional nationwide carrier would increase consumer surplus by approximately $1 billion annually, which represents five per cent of 2012 industry revenues. The authors estimate that an additional nationwide carrier would expand wireless penetration from 78 to 81 per cent, and drive down incumbents’ average prices by about two per cent. Price elasticity is estimated using econometric models of product demand. The USPS has produced its econometric demand models for more than 30 years with periodic refinements to reflect changes in both the economy and in the postal industry. Some argue that the models provide evidence of an upward trend in price elasticity and that the price elasticity of postal customers is ‘in flux’ due to the increase of electronic alternatives and the disruptive effects of the global financial crisis. In order to test these 8 and ‘open to improvements’. Some suggested improvements are outlined in the paper. propositions, the Christensen study examines the demand for three classes of market dominant postal services: First-Class Mail, Standard Mail, and Periodicals. These classes account for the majority of mail volume, mail revenue, and contribution to institutional costs. The study finds that the demands for all three categories is inelastic with respect to price, and – if anything – is getting more inelastic over time. The overall conclusion is that: This article is accessible by subscription to the Journal of Regulatory Economics. The Design of Light-handed Regulation of Airports: Lessons from Experience in Australia and New Zealand, Margaret Arblaster, Journal of Air Transport Management, 38, 2014, pp. 27-35. to the extent the analysis shows own price elasticities to be ‘in flux’, the changes are predominantly in the direction of lower own price elasticities. Additionally, the data do not suggest that the inclusion of older observations in the demand regressions result in smaller elasticity estimates. The overall picture is that while demands for market dominant postal products have shifted substantially due to a combination of factors other than postal prices, they remain own price inelastic. This paper is about the use of light-handed regulation as an alternative to traditional regulation that involves the direct determination of prices and quality of service. Margaret Arblaster observes that experience with light-handed regulation of airports is primarily confined to Australia and New Zealand. The paper contains an examination of the design features of light-handed regulation in these two countries in relation to their stated objectives. The analysis is qualitative in nature, and a comprehensive reference list of 44 items is presented. This report is available at: https://www.uspsoig.gov/sites/default/files/documentlibrary-files/2013/rarc-wp-13-008.pdf [accessed on 16 September 2014]. The author identifies important aspects associated with the design of light-handed regulation including the incorporation of a credible threat of stronger regulation, and the characteristics of this, and an apparent trade-off in objectives achieved with different approaches to light-handed regulation. Guaranteed Return Regulation: A Case Study of Regulation of Water in California, Michael Crew and Rami Kahlon, Journal of Regulatory Economics, 46, 1, August 2014, pp. 112121. This article is available by subscription to the Journal of Air Transport Management. This paper analyses some of the forces at work that are leading to the development of a new form of regulation in the energy and water sectors in California. This is known as guaranteed return regulation (GRR). The authors argue that a previous regulatory approach – rate-of-return regulation (ROR) also known as cost of service regulation – resulted in excessive use of both capital and other inputs. Price cap regulation (PCR) had then been proposed for its superior efficiency properties. In energy and water there has now been a move away from PCR into an extended form of ROR, referred to as GRR. The article is substantially non-technical in its exposition and has a reference list containing eight items. The Decoupling of Treasury Yields and the Cost of Equity for Public Utilities, Kurt G Strunk, NERA Energy Policy Briefing Note, 13 June 2014. In this NERA briefing note, Kurt Strunk examines how – in the context of utility regulation in the United States – capital market conditions affect the cost of capital for utilities. The note contains a table and four references. The note includes a table covering the years 2006 to 2013 showing the thirty-year Treasury yield (that decreased substantially from 4.91 per cent to 2.91 per cent before increasing slightly in 2013) and a measure of the average allowed return (ROE) for electric utilities (which ‘hovered’ in the range of 10.0 to 10.5 per cent). According to the author, if the market risk premium had been unchanged during this period, the allowed ROEs (‘which themselves are based on the capital market data put forth by public utilities and intervenors alike’) would have declined as much as the Treasury yields did. According to the authors, GRR is employed to implement a policy, namely taxation, that legislators are unwilling to apply by transparent methods, but are willing to apply opaquely through the regulatory process. The authors argue that GRR does not promote efficiency and, in their view, the California experience shows the guarantees it provides are limited. In summary, Michael Crew and Rami Kahlon argue that the success of GRR in California has been mixed and it should be considered to be a ‘work in progress’ 9 The author observes that: Anyone who has attended a rate case hearing recently is well aware that the debate over the rate of return now tends to focus on the implications for public utility investors of a largely unprecedented trend in the current capital markets – specifically, intervention by the Federal Reserve in the government bond market. The current capital market conditions are unique from a historical perspective. No US government policy intervention in recent history has had such an important effect on the risk-free rate relied upon by public utility analysts in their routine modelling of market and utility-investor behaviour. The author concludes that it is important to ensure that the rate of return somehow incorporates the current forward-looking investor expectations and does not rely solely upon unadjusted historic expectations. The article is available at: http://www.nera.com/nerafiles/PUB_Equity_Risk_Premium_Utilities_0614(1).pd f [accessed on 16 September 2014]. 10 Regulatory Decisions in Australia and New Zealand determinations for the seven regulated fixed-line services. The primary prices are the monthly and usage charges paid for the regulated services and include charges for access services (such as the unconditioned local loop service) and for resale services (such as wholesale line rental and wholesale ADSL). Telstra’s-fixed-line-services-andtransmission-services Australia Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) TPG FTTB Deployment – No Action On 11 September 2014 the ACCC announced that it has completed its investigation into a complaint that TPG Limited’s (TPG) plans to connect large apartment buildings in metropolitan areas to its existing fibre networks and to use fibre-to-thebasement technology to supply high-speed broadband services to residents of those buildings would be in breach of the ‘NBN level playing field provisions’ in the Telecommunications Act. The ACCC does not intend to take any action to prevent TPG implementing its plans, having concluded that TPG’s planned deployment is permitted under the Telecommunications Act. Media Release on TPG here Air Services Australia Prices On 26 June 2014 the ACCC announced that it had decided it had no objection to the proposed price increases by Air Services Australia. Airservices Australia provides air traffic control and aviation firefighting and rescue services to airports and airlines. ACCC-does-not-object-to-price-increases-byairservices-australia CBH Wheat Port Access Undertaking – Draft Decision On 26 June 2014 the ACCC issued a draft decision to accept Co-Operative Bulk Handling Limited’s (CBH) proposed 2014 Port Terminal Services Access Undertaking, subject to drafting amendments. The undertaking would govern access by third-party exporters to CBH’s port terminal services for bulk wheat export at CBH’s four port terminals in Western Australia. ACCC draft-decision-to-approve-cbhlong-term-arrangements GrainCorp’s Wheat Port Access Undertaking – Draft Decision On 21 August 2014 the ACCC the issued a draft decision proposing to consent to GrainCorp’s application to extend and vary its 2011 Port Terminal Services Access Undertaking. GrainCorp’s 2011 Undertaking governs third-party access to port terminal services at GrainCorp’s East Coast Australian bulk grain ports. The undertaking is currently set to expire on 30 September 2014 with a mandatory code of conduct anticipated to commence on 1 October 2014. Media Release on Graincorp Australian Energy Regulator (AER) National Electricity Law and National Gas Law – Quarterly Compliance Report Emerald’s Wheat Port Access Undertaking – Draft Decision On 1 August 2014 the AER released its quarterly compliance report on the National Electricity Law and the National Gas Law. Compliance Report here On 7 August 2014 the ACCC issued a draft decision proposing to consent to Emerald’s application to extend and vary its 2013 Port Terminal Services Access Undertaking. The 2013 Undertaking governs access to port terminal services at Melbourne Port Terminal and is currently set to expire on 30 September 2014. A mandatory code of conduct is anticipated to commence on 1 October 2014. Emerald MR here Individual Exemptions Electricity for the Sale of On 2 September 2014 the AER announced the grant of individual exemptions to supply electricity to: SE Solar 3; PPA Direct; PPA Energy; PPA Farm; PPA Electrical; PPA Now; PPA Solar; PPA Green; Pietermaritzburg; and Green Urban Group. On 29 July 2014 the AER announced the grant of individual exemptions to supply electricity to: Nue Pty Ltd; ET Solar Australia; Soly; Skycell; ePho; RF Industries; and SE Solar 1 and SE Solar 2. Fixed-line Services Inquiry Announced On 24 July 2014 the ACCC released a discussion paper seeking views on setting primary prices for the regulated fixed-line services supplied using Telstra’s copper network. This consultation is part of the ACCC’s inquiry into making final access On 3 July 2014 the AER announced the grant of individual exemptions to supply electricity to: RE Power Shoalhaven; Suntrix; Sungevity; Geits ANZ; 11 Solar Professionals; Zero Cost Solar; Infinity Solar; Applied Environmental Solutions; Solar Financial Solutions; and Voltaic Energy. Region (Rockhampton and Gladstone). The NCC received three submissions in response to its invitation for submissions on the application by interested parties. Further information is available here. ACTEW/AGL’s Regulatory Proposal – Issues Paper Australian Capital Territory On 25 July 2014 the AER issued an Issues Paper on ACTEW/AGL’s Regulatory Proposal. AER MR here Independent Competition and Regulatory Commission (ICRC) Annual Tariff Variations Accepted On 26 June 2014 the AER accepted annual tariff variations for: Envestra Queensland Gas Network; Dawson Valley Pipeline; and Allgas Energy Gas Network. ACT Electricity Feed-in Scheme Activity Summary: 30 June 2014 See ‘Notes on Interesting Decisions’ On 2 September 2014 the ICRC released the ACT electricity feed-in scheme activity summary for 30 June 2014. The ICRC has worked with ActewAGL Distribution and ActewAGL Retail to improve the quality of the data. The June 2014 report incorporates revisions to the data made since the September quarter 2009. The MR with access to the report can be accessed here 2014 Retail Competition Review Published New South Wales On 22 August 2014, the AEMC released its report on competition in retail electricity and gas markets for small customers in the National Electricity Market, along with new research on consumer experiences. The level of competition ranges from effective in South East Queensland, New South Wales, Victoria, and South Australia, to less effective in the Australian Capital Territory and is yet to emerge in Tasmania and regional Queensland. Competition in retail gas markets is at different stages of development between and within states and territories. Access the AEMC review through here Independent Pricing Regulatory Tribunal (IPART) Australian Energy Commission (AEMC) Market Distribution Network Prices – New Rules Proposed National (NCC) Competition Dawson Valley Pipeline Revocation Determination External Benefits to Public Transport On 26 August 2014 the IPART released an issues paper on benefits to the wider community when people use public transport. This is to determine how future fares should be set. Fares recover only a small proportion of the total cost of providing public transport in Sydney and surrounding areas – the NSW Government pays the bulk of the cost. When the IPART determines maximum fares it must decide how much of the total cost should be paid by those who use public transport (through fares) and how much by the NSW community as a whole (through the Government subsidy). The review will consider how much car use is avoided when people take public transport in Sydney, quantifying the net value of this avoided car use to the community. The IPART is also considering whether there are other things it might need to take into account. Information on the IPART review here Council – and Coverage On 8 September 2014 the NCC received Minister Macfarlane’s decision and statement of reasons. The Minister's decision was to make a coverage revocation determination for the Dawson Valley Pipeline. The Minister’s decision and statement of reasons are available here. Carbon Tax Repeal – Revised Regulated Gas Prices Envestra’s Queensland Gas Distribution Network – Application for Light Regulation On 15 August 2014 the IPART announced it had agreed to revised regulated retail gas prices for 201415 following the repeal of the carbon tax. The IPART has reviewed gas retailers’ proposals for revised prices, and is satisfied that savings from the carbon tax repeal have been appropriately passed through to On 18 August 2014 the NCC received an application from Envestra Limited under the National Gas Law for the light regulation of its covered Queensland Gas Distribution Network which distributes gas in the Brisbane Region (Brisbane CBD, Ipswich and suburbs north of the Brisbane River) and Northern 12 customers. IPART MR on Gas Price Effects of Carbon Tax Repeal NSW Rail Decision Access Undertaking – Gladstone Area Water Board for its 2015-20 prices. MR on Review-of-Gladstone-Area-Water-Board’s2015-2020-prices Final South Australia On 15 July 2014 the IPART released its final report on the rate of return and remaining mine life that will apply to RailCorp’s Hunter Valley Coal Network rail assets from 1 July 2014. This applies to the five sectors (21 kilometres) of track between Newstan and Woodville Junction. IPART Final Decision for NSW Rail Access Undertaking Essential Services Commission of South Australia (ESCOSA) Charter of Consultation and Regulatory Practice On 10 September 2014 the ESCOSA announced that it had completed its revised Charter of Consultation and Regulatory Practice. The revised Charter: includes revised Commission Values; provides additional guidance on the methods of engagement used; and reflects changes in the ESCOSA's functions in the electricity and gas industry, following the introduction of the National Energy Customer Framework and deregulation of energy retail prices in February 2013. Access Link to revised Charter Northern Territory Utilities Commission New Electricity Licence Granted On 11 August 2014 the Utilities Commission issued a licence for the selling of electricity to Rimfire Energy Pty Ltd in accordance with Part 3 of the Electricity Reform Act. MR on Rimfire Licence Report to the Minister on Retail Energy Prices Queensland Queensland Competition Authority (QCA) On 31 August 2014 the ESCOSA released its 201314 Report to the Minister on Retail Energy Prices in South Australia, covering gas and electricity prices to small residential and business customers. Energy Pricing Report here Regional Feed-in Tariff – Carbon-exclusive On 5 September 2014 the QCA reminded customers in regional Queensland that the 9.07 cents/kWh solar feed-in tariff paid by Ergon Retail will soon be reduced to 6.53 cents to align with the lower value of wholesale energy after repeal of the carbon tax. QCA MR on Carbon-exclusive-regional-feed-intariff Impact of Carbon Tax Repeal on Minimum Retail Feed-in Tariff (R-FiT) On 5 September 2014 the QCA released a Position Paper titled Long-term framework for SEQ Water Retailers – Weighted Average Cost of Capital (WACC). QCA SEQ Water WACC paper On 24 July 2014 the ESCOSA announced that the carbon-tax component of the minimum R-FiT payment amount will no longer apply from 1 July 2014. From 1 July 2014 the minimum R-FiT payment amount will be 6.0 cents/kWh, compared with 7.6 cents/kWh for the period that there was a carbon tax. All customers that export energy from qualifying solar photovoltaic (PV) generators are now entitled to receive at least 6.0 cents/kWh from 1 July 2014 until 31 December 2014. The ESCOSA will be conducting a review of the R-FiT to apply from 1 January 2015. Aurizon Network’s Draft Access Undertaking Withdrawn Water and Sewerage Pricing – Release of Draft Report On 11 August 2014 the QCA announced that Aurizon Network had withdrawn its draft access undertaking and had submitted a revised proposal. MR on Aurizon DAU On 16 July 2014 the ESCOSA released its Draft Report on Water and Sewerage Pricing Reform. Follow for Link to Draft Report Aurizon Network’s Draft Access Undertaking Withdrawn Gladstone Monitoring Area Water Board Price On 8 July 2014, at the direction of the Treasurer and Minister for Trade, the QCA announced that it has commenced a price monitoring investigation into the 13 introduce a carbon price-exclusive standing offer tariff without invoking enforcement action from the ESC. ESC Final Decision Tasmania Office of the Tasmanian Economic Regulator (OTTER) Western Australia Electricity Supply Industry Performance and Information Reporting Guideline Revised Economic (ERA) On 15 September 2014 the OTTER issued version 2.3 of its Electricity Supply Industry Performance and Information Reporting Guideline. This followed a review of the wholesale reporting requirements imposed on Hydro Tasmania under the Basslink Ministerial Notice (in force under section 36 of the Electricity Supply Industry Act 1995). The review identified a number of opportunities to streamline the reporting processes and remove duplication. Hydro Tasmania was consulted and supported the changes. Authority Goldfields Gas Pipeline – Revised Access Arrangements On 15 August 2014 Goldfields Gas Transmission Pty Ltd (GGT), on behalf of Southern Cross Pipelines Australia Pty Ltd, Southern Cross Pipelines (NPL) Australia Pty Ltd and Alinta DEWAP Pty Ltd, submitted proposed revisions to the access arrangement for the Goldfields Gas Pipeline (GGP) to apply from 2015 to 2019. GGT is the complying service provider for the covered pipeline. The ERA is seeking public comment on GGT’s proposed revisions to the access arrangement for the GGP. The ERA MR is available here. TasWater Price and Service Plan In September 2014, TasWater submitted its Price and Service Plan for 1 July 2015 to 30 June 2018. TasWater Plan here Microeconomic Released Victoria Essential (ESC) Regulation Reform – Final Report See ‘Notes on Regulatory Decisions’. Services Commission New Zealand New Zealand Commission (CCNZ) Minimum Feed-in Tariff for 2015 On 20 August 2014 the ESC announced it had determined the minimum energy value of embedded generation for 2015 to be 6.2 c/kWh with the carbon tax removed. Minimum Feed-in Tariff Final Decision for 2015 Commerce Court of Appeal Judgment on UBA – CCNZ Response On 8 September 2014 the CCNZ responded to the Court of Appeal judgment in relation to Chorus’s appeal against the CCNZ’s November 2013 decision setting benchmarked cost-based prices for the unbundled bitstream access (UBA) service. The decision upholds the previous High Court decision in April 2014. The Telecommunications Commissioner said that ‘the decision will allow the Commission and industry to focus on the cost modelling required to set the UBA price in accordance with the “final pricing principle”'. CCNZ response to Court of Appeal Standing Offer Tariffs – Variation following Carbon Tax Repeal On 21 July 2014 the ESC announced it had determined that it would allow retailers to vary their standing-offer tariffs one additional time. The Carbon Tax Repeal Act requires retailers to pass on to customers all cost savings resulting from the repeal of the carbon tax. In Victoria, the Electricity Industry Act 2000 and the Gas Industry Act 2001 restrict a retailer from varying its standing offer tariff more than once every six months. This statutory restriction could delay when a retailer can pass-through savings from the removal of the carbon tax to standing offer customers. The ESC has discretion on whether to pursue enforcement action against a retailer for possible breaches of Victorian energy laws. On 18 June 2014, the ESC released a Position Paper, and invited submissions from stakeholders on its preferred option, which was to allow retailers to vary their standing-offer tariffs one additional time to Transpower’s Allowances and Standards – CCNZ Final Decision Quality On 29 August 2014 the CCNZ released its final decision on the allowances for operating and base capital expenditure, quality standards, and reporting requirements that will be used to set Transpower’s price-quality path for the next five-year regulatory period which begins in April 2015. The price-quality path sets the maximum revenues Transpower can recover and will be finalised in late November 2014 14 Draft Price-Quality Distributors when the cost of capital for the regulatory period has been set and other components of the path finalised. CCNZ Transpower Final Decision CCNZ Draft Decision Average Cost of Capital on the Paths for Electricity On 4 July 2014 the CCNZ announced it was seeking submissions on its proposed average price limits and quality targets for 16 electricity distributors. The draft default price-quality paths cover the period 20152020, and will take effect from 1 April 2015. Following consultation, the CCNZ will make a final decision on the reset of the default price-quality path by 28 November 2014. CCNZ MR on Price-Quality Paths Weighted See ‘Notes on Interesting Decisions’. Chorus’s Proposed Changes to Regulated Broadband – CCNZ to Investigate Complaint On 22 July 2014 the CCNZ announced it will investigate a complaint that Chorus’s proposed changes to the regulated unbundled bitstream access (UBA) service are an enforceable breach under the Telecommunications Act. The CCNZ received a complaint from Telecom about the changes to the (UBA) service. MR on complaint about UBA Cost Modelling on UCLL and UBA – CCNZ Consultation On 9 July 2014 the CCNZ released a consultation paper seeking views on a number of decisions in relation to the cost models it will build to price the unbundled copper local loop (UCLL) service and the unbundled bitstream access (UBA) service. The paper sets out its views on: the regulatory framework; the type of hypothetical replacement network it will be the UCLL service, it will model a fibre-to-the-home network, with fixed wireless in remote areas; and for the UBA service it will model costs using Chorus’s copper-based inputs. In both models it proposes taking advantage of third-party assets where possible. CCNZ Cost Modelling Consultation Assessment of Unregulated UBA Services – CCNZ Releases Issues Paper On 7 July 2014 the CCNZ released an issues paper relating to its assessment of whether the two new unregulated UBA services, Boost HD and Boost VDSL, proposed by Chorus on 14 May 2014, fall within the category of regulated UBA service. The issues paper seeks to clarify Chorus’s proposed changes to the unbundled bitstream access (UBA) service and obtain views and information from industry participants for purposes of the assessment. Chorus is proposing a number of changes to the UBA service, including: offering two new unregulated UBA services, Boost HD and Boost VDSL; withdrawing the regulated VDSL service; and new bandwidth management settings for the regulated UBA service. Unregulated UBA Services 15 Interesting government. The ERA has developed a set of criteria for the Government to apply in reviewing the reasons for ownership of a business or asset. Access report here. Economic Regulation Authority Proposals on Microeconomic Reform in Western Australia Proposals to Amend Distribution Network Pricing Arrangements – New Rules Proposed by the Australian Energy Market Commission Notes on Decisions On 28 July 2014, the Western Australia Treasurer tabled the Economic Regulation Authority’s (ERA) Final Report on its Inquiry into Microeconomic Reform in Western Australia in Parliament on 28 July 2014. The objective of the Inquiry was to identify microeconomic reform measures that the Government could implement to improve the performance of the Western Australian economy. The ERA has examined a broad selection of areas of the Western Australian economy, broadly falling into the categories of: infrastructure; addressing disincentives for businesses; and removing barriers to competition. Areas were selected based on their potential to: improve the productivity and flexibility of the Western Australian economy; increase choice for consumers and businesses; increase opportunities for businesses to compete for national/international market share; and to reform unnecessary regulation. The ERA has made 46 recommendations for reform across the areas examined. On 28 August 2014, the Australian Energy Market Commission (AEMC) released its draft determination on proposals to amend distribution network pricing arrangements in the National Electricity Rules. The broad aim of the new rules is to enable consumers to make more informed decisions about how they use energy services. The AEMC observes that there are differences in the ways individual consumers choose to use electricity, due in part to new technology and changes in the way people live. The way consumers are charged for electricity has not kept pace with these changes. Under current price structures, all consumers pay the same network prices based on fixed charges and the volume of electricity consumed, regardless of how or when they are using it. Network prices are responsible for about 50 per cent of the electricity prices paid by residential consumers on average across Australia, and a key driver of these costs is peak demand. With respect to infrastructure, the ERA examines how the State can maximise the productivity of this important enabler of growth through: better decisionmaking; potentially divesting some public assets to the private sector; and providing incentives to use infrastructure efficiently through user charges. Existing network prices over-recover revenue for offpeak use of the network and under-recover for peak use. This means consumers who use most of their energy at off-peak times are paying more than it costs to supply network services to them – while those using energy at peak times are paying less than it costs. There are a number of areas in which existing infrastructure could be better utilised. The ERA recommends that, before considering new infrastructure expenditure, the Government should investigate demand-management tools that may obviate the need for such expenditure. For example, in many cases the more efficient use of existing infrastructure may delay or reduce the need for capacity enhancement. In this review the ERA considers time-of-use electricity charging and roadcongestion charging as measures that both reduce the need for infrastructure enhancement and provide significant productivity gains as a result of changing the behaviour of consumers. The amount of electricity used by individual households at different times of the day can vary depending on the appliances and technologies being used. But consumers are not being given the option of reducing their peak demand to save money, or continuing to use electricity at those times when the value they place on that use outweighs the costs. The AEMC draft determination details the impacts of different types of energy-use patterns on network prices. For example, a consumer using a large 5kW air-conditioner in peak times will cause about $1,000 a year in additional network costs compared with a similar consumer without an air-conditioner, but the consumer with the air-conditioner pays about an extra $300 under the most common network prices and the remaining $700 is recovered from all other consumers through higher network charges. A second example is of a consumer using an averagesized north-facing solar PV system, saving about $200 a year in network charges compared with a Divesting government assets, where appropriate, has the potential to increase the efficiency and productivity of the asset, which in turn may benefit consumers. It may also help to address conflicting objectives that arise from Government ownership (for example, trying to maximise profits from government business enterprises while also seeking to achieve social objectives). Greater private sector involvement in infrastructure also has the potential to reduce costs, given that the private sector often has a greater incentive to operate more efficiently than 16 similar consumer without solar. Because most of the solar energy is generated at non-peak periods, it reduces the network’s costs by $80, leaving other consumers to make up the $120 shortfall through higher charges. The AEMC consulted extensively with industry and consumers in the development of the draft determination. Further consultation is occurring before the final decision is made in late November 2014. Network businesses would need to start consulting on the development of new tariffs and submit draft proposals to the AER in mid-2015 for new prices to be phased in from 2017. AEMC Newrules-proposed-for-distribution-network-prices The AEMC expects that the majority of consumers would benefit from these changes through lower network prices in the medium-to-longer term. Some consumers would choose to respond to new network price structures by reducing their use of the network at peak times, which will reduce overall network costs. Those cost savings would be passed on to all consumers through lower future network charges. The Weighted Average Cost of Capital – New Zealand Commerce Commission Draft Decision On 22 July 2014, the New Zealand Commerce Commission (CCNZ) released its draft decision on the weighted average cost of capital (WACC). The WACC is used in the price-quality path and information-disclosure regimes that apply to businesses regulated under Part 4 of the Commerce Act 1986. Analysis undertaken for the AEMC estimates that up to 81 per cent of consumers would face lower network charges in the medium term under a costreflective capacity price; and up to 69 per cent would experience lower charges under a critical peak price. While different technologies impact on network use in different ways, the rules should be flexible enough to result in efficient outcomes regardless of the technology being used. The WACC reflects the cost of debt and the cost of equity, and the respective portion of each that is used to fund investments in the assets used to supply regulated services. The WACC cannot be observed; it must be estimated, so there is a risk that the estimate is higher or lower than the true (but unobservable) WACC. To mitigate this risk the CCNZ calculates a distribution around the mid-point WACC estimate based on the standard errors of some of the key parameters. This defines a WACC range. A percentile in this WACC range distribution is then chosen, based on what best meets the purpose of Part 4. It is a change to this percentile that the CCNZ is currently proposing. The AEMC proposals focus on establishing the right regulatory regime for the future so everyone can make clearly informed decisions about their energy use as new technologies emerge. Under the proposed rule change, consumers would have clearer incentives to consider how, when and where they use energy. The new approach to structuring network prices would help people see the value of different choices such as: investing in more efficient appliances or new technologies that can help manage their energy use at peak times; installing solar panels that point west so they can generate more energy at peak times; investing in batteries to complement solar panels; and choosing to locate their businesses in areas where network costs are lower. The draft decision proposes reducing the WACC used to determine price-quality paths for electricity lines and gas-pipeline services. The WACC used will be the estimate at the 67th percentile of the WACC range rather than the current 75th. The proposed changes would be introduced over the long-term. Network businesses would be required to minimise the impacts of price changes on consumers, for example, by gradually transitioning consumers to new prices over five years or more. The proposal was opened to submissions, with the CCNZ’s final decision due in October. The final decision will affect the prices electricity lines businesses can charge from April 2015, and from 2017 for gas pipeline businesses. While network prices would continue to be developed by the networks with oversight from the Australian Energy Regulator (AER), under the proposed new rules consumers would have greater influence on the decisions made and the prices they pay. There would be more consultation with consumers and retailers when networks develop their prices; and the process for setting prices would be more transparent. Network prices would be finalised earlier, giving consumers and retailers more time to prepare for price changes. The CCNZ’s work on WACC was in response to the High Court judgment in 2013 which questioned the WACC estimate. The Court considered that the use of the 75th percentile was insufficiently supported by evidence, and might be inconsistent with the Part 4 objective to limit the ability of regulated suppliers to earn excessive profits. The CCNZ’s draft decision also proposes that, under information-disclosure regulation, the 33rd to 67th percentile WACC range is used to assess the 17 profitability of electricity lines and gas-pipeline businesses. Part 4 of the Commerce Act 1986 regulates a number of markets where competition is limited, including electricity lines services, gas-pipeline services and specified airport services. The intention of Part 4 is to ensure that suppliers have incentives to innovate, invest, improve efficiency and produce quality services for consumers, while also limiting their ability to extract excessive profits. Some of the services regulated under Part 4 are subject to price-quality paths (electricity lines services and gas pipeline services). This means the CCNZ restricts the revenue a regulated business can make or sets the maximum average prices it can charge, in addition to setting service quality standards that must be met. Other regulated services (Wellington, Auckland and Christchurch airports) are only subject to information disclosure which means they must publish certain information about their performance. Part 4 also requires input methodologies to be set to promote certainty for regulated businesses and other interested parties. Input methodologies are a range of upfront regulatory rules, processes and requirements covering matters such as: the valuation of assets; the treatment of taxation; the allocation of costs; and the cost of capital. Part 4 of the Commerce Act requires the CCNZ to set input methodologies for specified airport services, electricity distribution and transmission, and gas pipelines. The CCNZ must review each input methodology no later than seven years after its date of publication and, after that, at intervals of no more than seven years. At present, the cost of capital input methodologies require that the CCNZ apply the 75th percentile estimate of the WACC range (‘75th percentile’) when setting default or customised price-quality paths applying to electricity distribution businesses and gas-pipeline businesses, or the individual pricequality path applying to Transpower. Electricity pricequality paths (excluding Orion) must be reset by the end of November 2014. The CCNZ intends to have the final decision released in time to be incorporated into its final decisions on price-quality paths for electricity lines businesses in late November 2014. Draft decision available here. 18 Regulatory News CCNZ Competition Conference 2015 and Regulation The CCNZ has confirmed that it will be holding a Competition and Regulation Conference in Wellington on 23 and 24 July 2015. View details on its website: http://www.comcom.govt.nz/thecommission/competition-and-regulation-conference2015/ Network is a quarterly publication of the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission for the Utility Regulators Forum. For editorial enquiries please contact Rob Albon (Robert.Albon@accc.gov.au) and for mailing list enquiries please contact Genevieve Pound (Genevieve.Pound@accc.gov.au). 19