Human Geography – Population 1. Population Dynamics Fertility - Contemporary fertility differentials at global and national levels - Proximate variables affecting fertility Biological (years in marriage, IVF, sterilisation, contraception, abortions) Socio-economic (economic/social value of children, status of women in work) Institutional (government policies and religion) Mortality - Contemporary mortality differentials at global and national levels - Factors affecting mortality Demographic (age and gender) Medical technology (advances in medical care) Public health measures (sanitation, vaccination) Socio-economic changes (standard of living) Political (genocide, wars) Epidemics (Spanish flu) and pandemics (AIDS) Migration Concepts Time (short and long term movements) Distance (national and transnational, origin and destination) Transnational movement (skilled and unskilled labour) Issues in migration Labour migration and impact Identity and nationhood 2. Implications of Population Change Population Composition and Distribution Overview of world population growth and future projections in LDCs and DCs Population distribution across space and inequalities in distribution Need for and problems of population forecasting at national scale Problems of population prediction Future problems and opportunities resulting from population change and policies in different parts of the world Interpretation of population pyramids Interpretation of population pyramids and relationship to growth rates Dependency and its implications Coping with population growth (housing, work and services) Coping with population loss (maintaining viable communities) Value and limitations of population pyramids in prediction Socio-economic composition Ethnic diversity 1 Inequality between different populations and different sectors of the same population Indices used to measure inequalities in population Population Change and Planning Population growth in relation to Demographic Transition Model DTM and its usefulness Consideration of the 5th stage Anti-natal and pro-natal policies Role of governments in planning developments in light of forecasts of population change (in numbers and composition of national populations) Population forecasting and government policies affecting population growth and their implications Population-Resource Relationships Carrying capacity, optimum population, overpopulation and underpopulation Population-resource theories, origins and value Malthus Meadows I=PAT (Impact = Population x Affluence x Technology, Ehrlich and Holdren) Development and resource use Global variations in resource use Changes in society (technological, economic and political) result in changing appraisals of resources and environments, their use and management) Hedonist vs. conservationist views of population-resource relationship and their consequences Relationship of population growth to environmental conditions and the changing resource base Contrasting assessment of population-resource relationships Sustainable development 2 1. Population Dynamics Fertility Discuss the fertility differentials between LDCs and DCs. Discuss how the different proximate variables affect fertility in LDCs and DCs. Evaluate the impact of governments’ influence on the proximate variables in attempting to achieve a desired fertility rate. Key Terms Regarding Fertility Fertility: The natural capability of giving life, dependent on nutrition, culture, economics, way of life, sexual behaviour. Fecundity: The ability to reproduce – differs from fertility in that fecundity represents the potential to reproduce biologically, while fertility means actually reproducing. Crude Birth Rate (CBR): Measures total number of births over a unit of time per 1000 in any given population. CBR varies between countries, and is usually between 10-55 per 1000. ‘Crude’ is termed as such because factors such as age, sex and migration are not accounted for. Total Fertility Rate (TFR): Average number of children born to a woman throughout her reproductive years of 15-49. The sum of averages of number of babies born by age n/number of women age n gives a grand average. TFR in the US is 2.1, in 2008 Zambia was 5.8 and Singapore was 1.28. Age-Specific Fertility Rate (ASFR): The average number of children born to a woman in a specific year or age group concerned. Replacement Level: Measure of the extent to which a given population is able to produce enough offspring to replace itself. The ratio is approximately 2 per family, but to account for possible premature deaths, the replacement rate is a 2.1 TFR. Proximate Variables Affecting Fertility Biological Variables Biological variables are split into three sections: intercourse, conception and gestation. Intercourse Variables 1a) Age of Entry into Stable Sexual Unions – the socially acceptable age of entry into formal marriages. This, of course, differs over space and cultures. The earlier the age, the higher the chance of a higher fertility rate. For many LDCs, marriage is almost universal – there are many cases of children as young as 13 marrying due to specific cultures. For example, in India prearranged marriages are common. However, in DCs, the pattern is that marriages are late in life or non-existent. As education and opportunities for employment increase for people, they become more financially 3 and economically independent. There is more choice and freedom as to whether they want to get married or not, unlike in LDCs where marriage is almost bound by social and cultural norms. 1b) Interruption of Stable Sexual Unions – various factors which inhibit marriage, such as the death of a spouse, or divorce. For LDCs, death seems to be more common due to, generally, poorer health care systems. The key problem for DCs today is the increasing rate of divorce. One of the reasons is the increased status and choice of women in DCs due to higher education, thus they are more able to be financially independent than their counterparts in LDCs. The way which society views the family unit may have also changed, contributing to this phenomenon. 2a) Exposure within Unions: Postpartum Abstinence – where mothers do not get pregnant again immediately after giving birth due to various reasons. One reason is postpartum amenorrhoea, where women are generally less fertile while breastfeeding. This serves as a natural birth spacer between children, along with a social/cultural or natural inhibition of coitus and pregnancy during lactation. The spacing of births enhances the survival of the offspring. However, in recent years with infant formula on the rise in LDCs (the situation in DCs vary, depending largely on the choice of the women), this method is becoming less effective. 2b) Periodic Abstinence – for example seasonal abstinence when men/women migrate in search for employment. It is estimated that without seasonal migration, fertility could increase by 25%. This is especially so for LDCs, where many migrate to other countries and DCs to find jobs, leaving their families back in home countries. For example, in the Philippines, many women leave the country as domestic workers. For many other LDCs, it is largely the male population. Regardless, this leaves behind a skewed gender ratio as indicated by their population pyramids. On the other hand, this migration might be the reason that BRs in these LDCs have not been rising out of control, in comparison to other LDCs. Conception Variables 1) Voluntary Conception Variables – these include the use of contraception (mainly condoms and pill usage), affected by the accessibility, availability and affordability of such methods. For example, in most DCs contraception is widely used due to it being more accessible and more available due to more affluent conditions, in contrast to many LDCs. As such, contraception seems to have greater impacts in DCs. Some LDCs hold sexual education for females, and give out free condoms in an attempt to alleviate the problem of imperfect information. Contraception is also affected by cultural factors – some religions, such as Catholicism, prohibit contraception. Some Gulf States also require contraceptive measures to be prescribed. Another factor would be technologically-assisted pregnancies, such as IVF and artificial insemination, to boost fertility. Naturally, due to high costs and specialized technology and expertise required, this is more applicable to DCs than LDCs. 2) Involuntary Conception Variables – one of the key factors here would be the prevalence of diseases and health problems. Infectious diseases such as smallpox, as well as problems of malnutrition leads to lower health levels overall. This has the effect of lowering the fertility rate due to subfecundity, where the ability to reproduce is reduced. This naturally has greater impacts on LDCs due to poorer healthcare standards. 4 Gestation Variables Gestation refers to the period between conception and birth, approximately 9 months for humans. 1) Abortion Rates – abortion during pregnancy is a main problem – especially in some DCs where it might be seen as less of a cultural taboo, and there is safe technology for the operations. In some LDCs, such as India and China, the prevalence of ultrasound scans and a cultural preference for boys has resulted in gender specific births and a skewed gender ratio. This was exacerbated in China by the one-child policy. 2) Foetal Mortality – the chance of miscarriages. This risk depends on conception age, malnutrition, healthcare levels, but mostly differs between individuals. Generally, in DCs conception age tends to be higher due to career focuses, increasing miscarriage rate. Malnutrition and healthcare during pregnancy also seems to be lower in LDCs. Otherwise, there is no defining pattern in miscarriage rates between DCs and LDCs. Other Proximate Variables Value of Children – in LDCs, children are traditionally seen as a form of security in old age or a source of labour (such as helping out as farmhands). This is known as survival theory, where more offspring is key to survival. The cost of raising children in DCs is, however, rather high, due to education fees etc. Status of Women – with regards to both work and education. Due to greater and more equal opportunities nowadays, the cultural and social restraint on women is far less than it used to be. More women are employed, make independent decisions, and as such the age of marriage increases. Women who are highly educated with stable careers tend to have lower fertility rates, and with later marriages, fecundity is also likely to fall. In LDCs, the status of women is likely to be lower in comparison with their DC counterparts. Socio-economic/Political – factors needed to be taken into consideration include cost of living, degree of urbanisation, and the role of government demographic policies (pro-natal or anti-natal). For example, the one-child policy and China, and currently the benefits given to families with more children in Singapore. Governmental Influence on Fertility Variables In attempting to achieve a desirable fertility rate (which is usually towards replacement level of 2.1), governments have implemented various policies to either boost or reduce fertility levels. The extent to which governments have been successful largely varies. For a majority of LDCs, and in the history of many DCs, it is likely that governments are implementing or have implemented anti-natal policies in order to reduce the birth rate, worrying about future population booms and whether such booms will be sustainable by the country on economic, social and environmental fronts. Currently, when many DCs are experiencing falling fertility rates, governmental efforts have been targeted at boosting these flagging rates. The most infamous example of anti-natal policies is China’s One-Child Policy, restricting the number of children urban couples can have to only one. Flouting the policy incurred heavy fines of up to 30% of annual income. The main objective of the policy was to reduce the rapidly growing population with a TFR 5 of 3 in 1980 so as to alleviate its impact on future social services such as healthcare and education, as well as cutting off possible social impacts such as that of increased unemployment, slum development and poverty. It was extremely, and perhaps all too successful, with the TFR dropping to 1.8 in 2008. Problems caused by overpopulation have been solved to a great extent. Of course, many side effects were also caused, including the increased prevalence of infanticide of female babies. The imbalanced population is commonly called the 4-2-1 problem, forecasting a population with a high dependency ratio in the future. However, it is certain that the reduction in fertility rates was a success, due to forceful implementation and strict regulation – which may have been far too strict, as cases of alleged abuse of families who flouted the policy have surfaced. Also, India has attempted to target conception variables, by sponsoring the provision of contraceptives and family planning education. As a result, contraceptive use has more than tripled from 13% of married women in 1970 to 49% in 2009, and the TFR has halved from 5.7 in 1966 to 2.7 in 2009. However, the extent to which it is the government’s efforts that have played the main role in reducing fertility is questionable. Many of these successes in fertility reduction have been accompanied by economic growth, increasing education levels and an overall rise in affluence. This in turn has caused the cost of living to rise, as well as the social status of women to increase in standing, requiring smaller family units. Perhaps the governments’ anti-natal policies have only assisted in speeding up this trend which has been already underway. This can be seen due to two factors. For one, the impact of government policies on different areas of the country has varied in accordance with literacy levels and affluence. In India, while contraceptive policies and family planning have reduced TFR to 1.8 in Tamil Nadu (HDI of 0.736, one of the richest, most literate states of India (rate 80.3%), also the most urbanised), in Uttar Pradesh the TFR has been only reduced to 3.8 (literacy rate of 69.7%). This is, of course, assuming that government expenditure and implementation between states is roughly equivalent, and all other factors aside from socio-economic levels are similar. Secondly, when dealing with pro-natal policies, governments in DCs have seen significantly less success than when implementing anti-natal policies. Singapore’s efforts at increasing the fertility rate with “Have Three or More, If You Can Afford It” (maximum tax rebate of $20,000 per couple for third child, priority for housing choice for bigger families, priority for school enrolment for third child), along with Baby Bonuses, parental leave (8 weeks of paid maternity leave up to $20,000) and cash benefits have been largely ineffective, with the 2011 TFR estimated at 1.11. Japan in 1994 implemented the Angel Plan, emphasizing work-childcare compatibility, providing public support for childcare services. Cash benefits, abolishing of daycare waiting lists and allowing paid childcare leave of 50% of wages were implemented, but this has appeared to be ineffective, with TFR dropping further to 1.23 in 2008. For DCs, many have attributed this failure in pro-natal policies being due to the shift in mindset since urbanisation and increased affluence along with costs of living in these countries, leading the shift of focus onto the quality of life and smaller family units. This is of course not to suggest that government efforts to raise fertility levels have been largely useless in DCs. Such efforts can be successful if standards of living reach a high enough level, where, according to Maslow, social fulfillment becomes more important than economic growth. In France, extensive subsidies, tax breaks and concessions, along with high female participation in the economy and protection of their jobs, it now has the highest TFR in Europe (2.02), and is on an increasing trend. 6 Mortality Discuss the variations of mortality between LDCs and DCs. Discuss how different factors affect mortality in LDCs and DCs. Discuss why the infant mortality rate is regarded as one of the best measures of a country’s socio-economic progress. Key Terms Regarding Mortality Mortality: The incidence of death in a population, normally measured by crude death rate. Morbidity: The state of being diseased – can in turn be a factor for mortality. Crude Death Rate (CDR): Total number of deaths over a unit of time, normally a year, per 1000 persons in a population. In 2008, Singapore’s CDR was 4.4, Zambia’s was 17. Interestingly, Mexico’s CDR is lower than the US’ because of higher birth rates, leading to a smaller number of deaths per 1000. Potential for lapses in comparison. Infant Mortality Rate (IMR): Number of infants who die within the first year of age per 1000 live births, excluding aborted babies and still births. In 2008, Singapore’s IMR was 2.1/1000, and Zambia’s was at a very high 92/1000. A good indicator of the healthcare system of the country, as well nutritional intake and income. Life Expectancy: The average number of years a person is expected to live in his lifetime. It is calculated by sum of all ages of deaths divided by the number of deaths. In 2008, Singapore’s was 80.9, Zambia’s was 45, Japan’s was 83. Epidemic: Outbreak of a contagious disease that spreads rapidly, affecting large parts of the community. Pandemic: Epidemic occurring over a very wide area, across international boundaries and affecting large numbers of people. Mortality Differentials Overall Mortality Changes and Differences When looking at differences in mortality and the variations in factors leading to it, comparisons can be drawn between DCs and LDCs, as well as between rural and urban areas of the same country. Statistics used for comparison include life expectancy, CDR and IMR. Mortality rates largely depend on the availability, accessibility and affordability of medicine, healthcare, sanitation and hygiene. Medicine refers to technology and procedures such as chemotherapy, radiotherapy etc., pharmaceuticals such as pills, mixtures, genetic research and development, and surgical methods. Healthcare refers to the social institutions generally, such as public education, campaigns and health programs, nutrition, provision of geriatric facilities, old-age homes, palliative care, polyclinics, private and public hospitals and the provision of the quantity and 7 quality of medical workers. Sanitation and hygiene refers to knowledge of sterilization, heating, proper sewage and rubbish disposal systems, purifying and filtering systems. Generally, the trend worldwide is that generally, mortality is declining in both DCs and LDCs, the only difference being in rates of decrease. LDCs have a faster rate of decrease today, which only makes sense seeing as they come from a base of higher mortality rates to begin with. At a certain point in time, an LDC generally will have lower accessibility and availability of medicine and healthcare compared to a DC. Due to lower incomes, advanced technology and latest healthcare methods are also unlikely to be affordable for LDCs, also in part due to the likelihood of more corrupt governments. This is why mortality rates are at any point in time usually higher in LDCs. As such, the likely reasons for reductions in mortality rates for LDCs are that overall, due to increases in the accessibility, availability and affordability of medicine as a result of development. Such developments drastically decrease the IMR, because they directly affect the knowledge of childcare requirements, nutrition requirements and overall healthcare. Improvements in healthcare and medicine, along with improvements in social institutions and overall economic growth have a large impact on IMR, which is also why it is one of the best indicators of socio-economic development. With the level of healthcare in DCs already decently high, falls in mortality rates in DCs are more modest. Reductions are normally due to further increasing income levels, economic development and improving equity, requiring targeting the poorest in society, allowing more levels of society to afford healthcare by improving distribution. Focus on specific healthcare sectors such as palliative care, old-age pensions and health insurance also bring up the healthcare level in the country as a whole. Differences in Mortality between Certain Groups Socio-status Differentials Within a population there tends to be different strata of people, normally divided by income and/or social class. Mortality rates are higher among people on lower incomes and in manual occupations because they have less access to good healthcare and live in poorer environmental conditions than higher income groups. High rates of heart disease are concentrated in the old heavy industrial areas of the UK and in inner city areas. Lung cancer is also more prevalent in industrial and densely populated areas with higher than average levels of pollution. Race and Ethnicity Differentials Due to different ethnic groups in society and the tendency for bias to occur, minorities are normally economically disadvantaged when it comes to healthcare and have higher mortality rates. Studies in the USA have shown that while whites live up to 76.5 years in life expectancy, the life expectancy of blacks is 6 years lower at 70.8. Blacks are economically disadvantaged, as 31% of all black families live below the poverty line while only 9% of white families do. This stems from disadvantaged health, environmental and economic situations. 8 Gender Differentials In general, women have a longer life expectancy than men do. Factors that influence gender differences in mortality include biological factors such as hormonal influences on physiology and behaviour, and environmental factors, such as cultural influences on gender differences in health behaviours. The importance of specific factors may reflect the environmental context. How developed a country is can affect or shape the most important influences on gender differences in mortality. In developed countries, men's more risky unhealthy behaviours are a major reason they die younger. Their higher rates of cigarette smoking, heavy drinking, gun use, employment in hazardous occupations, and risk taking in recreation and driving are responsible for males' higher death rate due to lung cancer, accidents, suicide, and homicide. Men's risky behaviours also contribute to their having higher mortality rates in developing countries, but in developing countries the gender gap in mortality has been smaller than in developed countries. Environmental factors such as unsafe water and inadequate nutrition increase the death rate due to infectious diseases for both sexes. Women, however, face additional risks associated with childbirth. Maternal mortality is high in sub-Saharan Africa, and there are higher suicide rates for women than men in China. Another reason the gender gap in mortality is smaller in developing countries is because in many of these countries, women have much lower social status than men. As women's status catches up with men's in these countries, the gender gap is expected to increase in the developing nations. But in developed countries, the gender gap is expected to decrease as women adopt unhealthy behaviours similar to men's—drinking and smoking more, experiencing more job-related stress. Differences in what is expected of men and women and how they are taught to behave also contribute to variation in health-related behaviours. For example, many cultures encourage or condone men's heavy drinking, but discourage it in women. Also, in many cultures, women are not expected to work outside the home in the cash economy while men are expected to be part of the labour force. Because women are less likely to be part of the work force than men, they suffer less from the ravages of work. As a result, their health deteriorates less quickly. Changes over time can affect the gap in life expectancies. In most developed countries, men's widespread adoption of cigarette smoking during the first half of the 20th century was a major factor behind males' widening mortality disadvantage. Later, in the United States, the mortality gap narrowed as women began to smoke more and men smoked less than before. The difference in male and female life expectancy has narrowed in recent years, from at least 7.7 years from 1972-1979 to 5.2 years in 2004, according to the U.S. National Centre for Health Statistics. Changes in smoking patterns tend to affect men more than women, because more men have smoked and because smoking has elevated death rates more for men than for women. As smoking becomes even less common, mortality rates will probably decline further. Age Differentials The reasons and causes of mortality can also be divided into age strata. For children, infant deaths are susceptible if there is poor medical care and poor health of the mothers. This is largely to do with the individual family’s socioeconomics, but naturally IMR is higher in LDCs. The main causes of 9 mortality in young adults are due to accidents, homicides and suicides. The reasons for deaths for people of older age are normally major illnesses such as heart disease and cancer. Urban-Rural Differentials Up to a few decades ago, mortality rates were higher in cities due to overcrowding, poor sanitation and infectious diseases. This was especially true of most cities in LDCs and in DCs before healthcare was widespread and accessible. Due to the high population density of cities, along with poor sewage and garbage disposal systems, living conditions were squalid and similar to slums. Today, mortality rates are much lower in cities, with improved urban conditions and greater affluence. Epidemics and Pandemics Epidemics and pandemics are cases where contagious diseases are spread rapidly amongst a large population, with pandemics being on a larger and more global scale than epidemics. These diseases induce morbidity, which in turn has a high probability of leading to mortality. Epidemics: Dengue in Cambodia, 2008 Death toll was 407, mostly children. This was the highest toll in nearly a decade, and it infected nearly 40,000 people. Reasons for the outbreak: inadequate healthcare. Thousands of sick children sought free treatment at four Swiss-funded hospitals, but there were not enough resources to treat everyone. Overall, public healthcare is lacking. According to the World Bank, Cambodia spends only $3 per person on healthcare, with depleted funds after 30 years of civil war. Lack of public education. Public were unaware of prevention measures like cleaning of stagnant water, leading to widespread breeding of dengue carrying mosquitoes. After this experience, the Asian Development Bank gave $300,000 to fund an anti-dengue programme. Cholera in Zimbabwe, 2008 Swept across the country and spread to South Africa, Zambia and Botswana. 100,000 reported cases with a death toll of 4300. Factors affecting the outbreak: Lack of access to clean water in urban areas. Collapse of the urban water supply, sanitation and garbage collection systems along with the rainy season led to human waste with cholera bacteria washed into water sources and public drains. Spread of cholera from urban to rural areas. Infected city-dwellers visited their families’ rural homes during the holidays. Dead bodies infected with cholera buried haphazardly in rural areas. Collapse of Zimbabwe’s social and economic institutions. Failing health care system due to lack of medicine and staff. Due to hyperinflation, hospitals were unable to buy basic drugs and medicines, overstretching their resources. 10 Pandemics Avian Flu, H5N1 Seasonal in nature like most influenza viruses. The outbreak in Hong Kong garnered worldwide attention in May 1997. The virus is constantly evolving. 295 deaths worldwide as of June 2010, WHO estimates a 60% human mortality rate. Affects poultry prices, farmers suffer large financial losses. Tourism is also adversely impacted. Measures include culling over 200 million birds to attempt to contain the disease. Over $10 billion has been spent on vaccines and new poultry farming practices. Stocking up of medicines such as Tamiflu, and drills have been run to educate the public on what to do in case of epidemics. SARS (Severe Acute Respiratory Syndrome) The pandemic period was between November 2002 and July 2003. Guangdong province in China was the place of origin, and 37 countries were infected. SARS has been contained as of May 2006, but not eradicated yet. 774 deaths as of July 2003, no future deaths since then. Discrimination occurred to certain groups of people who were thought to be more susceptible to SARS, e.g. elderly. WHO’s travel advice caused tourism to dip sharply to affected countries. Patients were immediately isolated to prevent further spread. The HK healthcare system has been improved, and lab testing has been underway to look for better treatments. AIDS Over 40 million HIV Positive people in the world today, with over 90% in the developing world. The major countries are South Africa, Nigeria and India. The death toll in 2007 was 2.1 million. Reasons for the spread: Social stigma. On a national level, this stigma might deter governments from taking fast action, fearing repercussions in investment, tourism etc. due to declaring a HIV-positive population. On a personal level, individuals might be reluctant to test for HIV fearing discrimination. LDCs: Poor provision of healthcare. South Africa’s former president Thabo Mbeki’s denial of AIDS and refusal to address the problem resulted in ineffective governmental response to AIDS, increasing the already high death toll. DCs: Sexual promiscuity without protection. This leads to higher incidence and spread of AIDS due to a supposedly more liberal society. Social stigma: 27% of Americans would prefer not to work with a HIV-positive woman. 11 Migration Compare and analyse the extent of migration with reference to time, distance and transnational movements. Discuss the causes, process, patterns and results of recent migratory flows. Assess the consequences of migratory flows with reference to the feminization of labour and identity and nationhood. Key Terms Regarding Migration Migration is the movement of people from one administrative area to another, whether regional or international, usually involving a permanent change of residence for at least one year. (UN) Population predictions often do not include migration movements, as it is impossible to predict accurately. There are also issues with capturing data for migration, as there is still no universally accepted definition of migration, and data on internal migration within a country is hard to collect. Circulations are temporary, reciprocal flows of people over any spatial scale without any substantial long-term period of change in residence. This includes daily flows (commuting), periodic flows, seasonal flows, and long term flows such as expatriates working overseas. The difficulty with defining migration here is that for some long term flows such as maids and construction workers, they eventually return to their homeland. Mobility refers to both migration and circulation as an overall term. How mobile a population is depends on the extent to which they move both within the country and between countries. Reasons for Migration Voluntary Migration: When people are motivated by better economic or social opportunities in an attempt to increase their standard and quality of life. This is true of many rural-urban migrations. For example, in LDCs: In Indonesia, many migrate to Jakarta in search of opportunities. In Thailand, many go to Bangkok. It should be noted that for LDCs, most of these tend to be primate cities as well. This attractiveness of cities is also termed to ‘Bright Lights Syndrome’. There is also counterurbanisation in some DCs, with urban-rural movements, such as Slapton Village in Devon, UK, a retirement village. This can also happen internationally. Coerced Migration: When people are collectively pressurised by a larger institution to move somewhere else, or when large groups of people are self-motivated to migrate in large numbers. Examples for governmental pressure include the Indonesian Transmigration Programme and forced urban-rural migration in Cambodia during the Khmer Rouge regime. One example of voluntary movement is the Partition of India. Forced Migration: Driven by a need of self-preservation. The individual has no choice but to migrate due to reasons such as war and civil strife. Examples include the Vietnamese boat refugees during the Vietnam War in the 1970s and Rwandan refugees during the Rwandan Genocide. 12 Migration – Transmigrasi The Indonesian Transmigration Program (Transimigrasi in Indonesian), was an initiative of the colonial Dutch government, later continued by the Indonesian government, to move landless people from densely populated areas of Indonesia (Java, and also Bali and Madura) to less densely populated areas such as Kalimantan, Sumatra and Sulawesi, supposedly in order to reduce poverty and overpopulation on Java by freeing up jobs and creating a workforce to better utilize the resources on the islands. Under the Dutch, in the peak year 1929 in Sumatran east coast, more than 260,000 contract workers were brought, 235,000 of them from Java. Contract workers entered into a contract as coolie, if a worker asked for the termination of the contract in the company, he could be punished with hard labour. The mortality was very high among the coolies and abuse was common. After independence, under President Suharto, the program continued and was expanded to send migrants to more areas of the archipelago such as Papua. At its peak between 1979 and 1984, 535,000 families, or almost 2.5 million people, moved under the transmigration program. It had a major impact on the demographics of some regions; for example, in 1981 sixty percent of the three million people in the southern Sumatra province of Lampung were transmigrants. The program has resulted in communal clashes between ethnic groups that have come into contact through transmigration. For example, in 2001 the local Dayaks and the transmigrant Madurese clashed during the Sampit conflict resulting in hundreds of deaths and thousands of Madurese being displaced. Transmigration is controversial in the provinces of Papua and West Papua, where the majority of the population is Christian. Some Papuans accuse the government of Islamisasi, or Islamization through transmigration. Other Papuans support transmigration because transmigrants are perceived as disciplined and hardworking, and because through transmigration, Papuans can make friends with people outside of their home provinces. Migration – Partition of India The Muslim-Hindu conflicts in India in the early 20th century eventually led to the division of Pakistan from India on 15 August 1947. Pakistan came into being with two non-contiguous enclaves, East Pakistan (today Bangladesh) and West Pakistan, separated geographically by India. India was formed out of the majority Hindu regions of British India, and Pakistan from the majority Muslim areas. Massive population exchanges occurred between the two newly-formed states in the months immediately following Partition. Once the lines were established, about 14.5 million people crossed the borders to what they hoped was the relative safety of religious majority. Based on 1951 Census of displaced persons, 7,226,000 Muslims went to Pakistan from India while 7,249,000 Hindus and Sikhs moved to India from Pakistan immediately after partition. About 11.2 million or 78% of the population transfer took place in the west, with Punjab accounting for most of it; 5.3 million Muslims moved from India to West Punjab in Pakistan, 3.4 million Hindus and Sikhs moved from Pakistan to East Punjab in India; elsewhere in the west 1.2 million moved in each direction to and from Sind. The newly formed governments were completely unequipped to deal with migrations of such staggering magnitude, and massive violence and slaughter occurred on both sides of the border. Estimates of the number of deaths range around roughly 500,000, with low estimates at 200,000 and high estimates at 1,000,000. 13 Migration is both age selective and sex selective. People of working age (20-35) are more likely to migrate. Males also tend to migrate more than females, which is largely due to job opportunities. Types and Forms of Migration Internal/National Migration Rural-rural: certain farming types such as nomads and rural communities. Rural-urban: part of urbanisation. Villages to cities in LDCs (primate cities), also can be international, from a rural part of one country to a city in another. The most common in LDCs due to perceived socioeconomic opportunities in the city. Urban-suburban (suburbanization): a DC phenomenon, such as from Central to suburban London Urban-rural (counterurbanisation): largely a DC phenomenon, such as from New York City to rural Montana. Also can be forced: Indonesia’s transmigration programme. Urban-urban: looking for better opportunities in neighbouring cities. International/Transnational Migration International migration usually flows from LDCs to DCs, since DCs are the ones which normally have better opportunities for job seekers and a better environment and quality of life. Examples such as Chinese from mainland China migrating to Canada, USA, Singapore and so on to look for better and more well-paid jobs. Lesser cases would involve migration from DCs to LDCs. This is much less common, and is more likely to be due to personal reasons. Other Types of Migration Patterns Chain Migration: continuous flow of migrants into a place of destination from a similar place of origin, sustained primarily by kinship, such as Chinese ethnic communities in North American cities. This is motivated mainly by economic opportunities, with males migrating first, then bringing along their families. Step Migration: where migrants gradually shift closer and closer towards their intended destination, likely because they cannot afford this proximity immediately, thus locating their selves on the periphery temporarily, while they work to earn more money. The different types and forms of migration are affected by distance. Obviously, internal migrations take place over a far less distance than international migrations. The Impact of Distance on Migratory Flows In his survey of migration in developed countries, Greenwood (1997) identifies a few categories of explanations on the effect of distance on migration. 14 a) Distance is a proxy for transport costs of moving. In general, transport costs incurred in internal migrations are not large. Bihar is one of the poorest states in India. A third class railway ticket from Patna in Bihar to Delhi (over 500 miles) costs less than nine times the daily wage of an agricultural labourer in Bihar. For all but the very poorest households, saving for such an expense is not inconceivable and, in fact, many travellers manage to avoid buying a ticket at all. Transport costs alone seem unlikely to deter more distant internal migrations in most contexts. Admittedly there are other forms of monetary costs associated with relocating residence, such as the cost of establishing a new home. However, although these costs may be greater in a larger town, there is no apparent reason to anticipate that such settling in costs would be correlated with distance moved. Transport costs, and hence distance, may nonetheless be significant deterrents to moving in three contexts. First, when frequent return visits are intended by potential migrants, which may well be the case when the migrant wishes to sustain a close link with family left at the point of origin. Second, although costs of single journeys domestically may not be high, the price of international travel is significantly greater. Third, for very poor households who are credit constrained, ability to raise funds to pay the costs of moving in advance of reaping higher earning in their new destination may be a constraint. b) More distant moves require greater time and thus higher foregone earnings. Longer moves indeed normally require larger travel time (though even this depends upon the mode of travel), but the time involved is hardly extensive. Rather, the larger component of time commitment may involve job search. The limited evidence on job search among migrants in developing countries suggests that a significant portion of rural-urban movers have found their urban job before relocating and that spells of open unemployment among those who have not found a prior job are brief on average. Neither of these necessarily rule out significant foregone earnings: job search before moving may prove quite time consuming and involve loss of earnings; temporarily accepting a low paying job in town can keep open unemployment spells brief yet impose initial opportunity costs. c) The psychological costs of separation from home rise with distance. Psychological costs are a sense of alienation from one’s surroundings. Establishing a home in a context where a different language is spoken, where peoples of different ethnic groups are in the majority, where the life-style and institutions contrast with those at home, may be seen as a threat by some and as an exciting experience by others. Either way, geographic distance is often a very poor proxy for the changes which prevail. Under apartheid, moving from Soweto to Johannesburg was prohibited and would have meant entering a different world, while moving from white Johannesburg to Capetown presented far smaller contrasts. One can move 3,000 miles from one side of the US to the other and still find McDonald’s. There is also, surely, a large fixed psychological cost involved in simply leaving home, irrespective of the distance moved. d) Information about remote locations is more costly to acquire. If information about remote locations is more costly to acquire, then longer moves either involve higher costs or embody greater risks under less complete information. Information about job 15 opportunities and life-style in alternative locations may be transmitted in a number of ways. In some contexts, media coverage is no doubt important in shaping perceptions and distance may then be an important factor where media coverage is more parochial. Perhaps the most important mechanism for transmittal, however, is a network of previous migrants, especially if these include kith and kin. When prior migrants have moved short distances, information transmitted over this network will concentrate on nearby locations. Important as networks may be, there seems no inherent reason why their role should lead to more frequent short moves. Moreover, as communications improve one might anticipate that the effect of even an initial network of contacts in nearby locations should diminish. e) Extent of homogeneity of labour markets and skill transferability There is some evidence that unemployed migrants prefer a location in which the labour market has some similarities to that at home, if only because this enables transfer of job or job-finding skills. To the extent that labour markets tend to be more homogeneous locally, this can encourage shorter moves; workers with prior experience only in agriculture may be less likely to make distant moves to find an industrial job in town or abroad. Certainly, the predominance of short moves shapes some common features of migration. For instance, in the low income countries the most common form of migration is frequently rural-rural. Though almost entirely neglected by economists, partly because of our preoccupation with a homogeneous rural sector, rural-rural migration actually offers many of the features normally modelled as the prerogative of rural-urban migration, such as the potential of earnings gain after job search, and of mutual insurance. Short migrations may also permit easier returns in the event of a crisis; in Indonesia during the financial crisis of 1998 massive return migration from towns to villages seems to have played an important role in the expansion of employment during the crisis, as the sharp currency depreciation enhanced profitability in agriculture (Fallon and Lucas). Step migration from village to town to city - also permits shorter moves and some authors have sought to explain this in terms of more complete information at close quarters. (Pessino, 1991). Whatever the cause, step migration may be one of the contributing factors to Ravenstein’s second law - that while cities attract migrants from nearby villages, these villages in turn attract people from more remote rural areas - a feature with important implications for trickle-down development. Skilled and Unskilled Labour Movements Skilled labour generally refers to any worker who has some special skill, knowledge, or (usually acquired) ability in their work, bringing some degree of expertise to the performance of a given job. Skilled workers are generally more trained, higher paid, and have more responsibilities than unskilled workers. Both skilled and non-skilled workers are vital and indispensable for the smooth-running of a freemarket society. According to Alan Greenspan, former Chairman of the Federal Reserve Bank, "...Enhancing elementary and secondary school sensitivity to market forces should help restore the balance between the demand for and the supply of skilled workers in the United States." Generally, however, individual skilled workers are more valued to a given company than individual non-skilled workers, as skilled workers tend to be more difficult to replace. As a 16 result, skilled workers tend to demand more in the way of financial compensation because of their efforts. According to Greenspan, corporate managers are willing to bid up pay packages to acquire skilled workers as they identify the lack of skilled labour as one of today's greatest problems. Education is an important factor in increasing people's skill level. The increase in number of people attending high schools and colleges contribute to the increase in the supply of skilled labour. Mass education, however, is not the only factor. Immigration is also a big contributor. Immigrants created a bimodal skill distribution, where most immigrants were either low skill or high skill workers. There were few who were in between. From this pattern, it can be deduced that it is the workers on the polar ends of the skill spectrum which have greater motivations to migrate. Migration of skilled and unskilled labour in today’s world may be deemed a more efficient and fundamental reallocation of human resource around the world, promoting efficiency – and yet, like other processes of globalisation, tends to result in unequal gains around the world. Major outflow of skilled professionals such as doctors from African countries is largely due to the socioeconomic differences between Africa and their intended destinations, such as lifestyle, economic gains etc. shaping the decisions of these people. As such, one of the main problems governments face today is the issue of educating and retaining skilled professionals. Education of people is largely a measure to improve the productivity of the workforce, but the gains from education have been shown by studies to be largely accruing to the individual. Thus the problem of brain drain is important to many countries. Retaining talent should be aimed at making the country attractive to such professionals, shaping their choices. Unskilled labour movements arise mainly from the lesser developed countries which lack proper education, and thus these migrants provide largely manual or repetitive labour, such as construction workers or domestic helpers. Motivations include poor job opportunities, social problems back at home, or better earnings abroad, but such movements are usually financially motivated, and repatriations to support families back in the home country are common. Unskilled movements thus last for a shorter period of time than skilled labour flows, because links with the home country are considerably stronger. However, this may result in a skewed population of dependents in the home country, which can potentially exacerbate dependency on repatriated profits and lack of actual economic development. UN Human Development – Skill Flow: A Fundamental Reconsideration of Skilled Worker Mobility and Development – http://hdr.undp.org/en/reports/global/hdr2009/papers/HDRP_2009_08.pdf Reasons and Consequences of Migration The sociological push-pull model is the most popularly used model for migration theory. Push factors are negative factors in the home country and pull factors are positive factors in the destination country. Both include environmental, social, economic and political reasons. Push Factors Environmental: Environmental degradation, natural hazards, epidemics, pollution, desertification, famine or droughts 17 Social: civil strife, wars, uncomfortable living environment, slavery or forced labour, poor medical care, no religious freedom, discrimination, poor chances of marrying Economic: crop failure, farm fragmentation, poor economic prospects, not enough jobs, loss of wealth Political: corruption of government, biased government, inefficient public systems, fear or persecution, lack of freedom Pull Factors Environmental: Attractive climates, healthier environment Social: Better living conditions, more religious freedom, better education, better healthcare, greater security, links to family, better chances of marrying Economic: Job opportunities, better industries Political: Increased political freedom, stable governments Migration, both internal and international, has positive and negative effects on both receiving and sending countries. Demographic Consequences Perpetuating unevenness in population: A general push-pull trend results in the destination being seen as very attractive, concentrating much of the population in one area. For example, primate cities in LDCs (such as Jakarta and Bangkok), sunbelts in the West Coast of US. Migration can have an effect on population distribution and density, concentrating growth in certain areas while possible neglecting surrounding declining areas (Myrdal’s model). Loss/Gain of human resources: Loss of human resources if brain drain occurs. Many professionals from Hong Kong migrated to Singapore and Canada to escape from China’s takeover in 1997. Africa loses over 20000 intellectuals annually – in 1988, 700 Ghanaian doctors are practicing in the USA. The receiving countries, in terms of manpower resource, gain # from this brain drain movement. Out migration can ease demographic pressures in the origin areas, lowering population density and its associated problems. For example, rural areas with overpopulation. Conversely, the receiving areas are affected by increased population pressure – especially shown in primate cities in many LDCs and their problems such as inadequate infrastructure. Age-sex selective migrations mean that men in their working age are more likely to migrate. Women also migrate in search of jobs, but less so than men. Rural areas may suffer from lack of labour and social protection. Environmental Consequences Pollution can result in destination areas due to massive amount of in-migrants to urban areas without the infrastructure to support them such as gas and water pipings. May result in slum-like 18 conditions, squatters and shanty towns with poor sewage and garbage disposal. For example, Los Angeles or many primate cities in LDCs (favelas in Brazil and bustees in India). Socio-cultural Consequences Culture Shock: Social disorientation can result when migrants migrate to larger cities, unable to adjust to urban life (e.g. rural-urban migrants to Latin-American cities). This may result in underemployment, unemployment or increased crime rates due to discontent. Racial/Cultural Clashes: Inevitably, a globalised world has caused individual groups, be it races or cultures, to come into contact with each other. This may result in friction, causing racial clashes and discrimination. Examples include Vietnamese migrants with native Australians in Australia and ethnic minorities who have migrated to Europe (Turks in Germany, Algerians in France, Pakistanis in UK). Social Polarisation: A separation of a distinct group of the population from others, preventing assimilation. Migration of retirees from London to Bournemouth, a retirement village, separates the two age groups, creating a perception of Bournemouth as a town for the old, deterring young people from moving there. Ethnic minorities forming their own enclaves and zones (ghettoes, Chinatown, etc) creates spatial and social polarisation. Cultural Exchange and Assimilation: A positive effect, where migrants and locals learn to live with one another and learn from each other. Impact on National Identity: Has impacts on both the nationhood and identity of the state, as well as on the individual. Economic Consequences Problems of unemployment in destination areas due to increasing supply of labour, competing for jobs. Ceteris paribus, in the short run this will depress wages and is not beneficial to individuals. Overall, it can increase competition in society. In the long run, the increased income may in turn create more jobs. Alleviate employment vacancies in destination areas if there are unemployment problems, which can be due to various factors (such as a decreasing workforce due to an aging population, or lower manual labour jobs which the locals do not want). Blue-collar jobs like construction industries and domestic workers in Singapore filled up by immigrants. Repatriation of profits from destination countries back to origin countries. For some LDCs, it is more beneficial for citizens to migrate and transfer cash back than stay in the country and earn little to no income at all. For example, over 8 million Filipinos work overseas, sending back $14 billion annually. The result is that the country is heavily dependent on this income, which may be both good and bad. Overall, on a societal level, migration cannot be classified as either beneficial or harmful, and it depends on the context. To the individual, migration is an individual desire to seek better opportunities elsewhere, outweighing the advantages of staying in the country of origin. The reality, 19 of course, depends on the migrant and his situation, although the act of migrating itself might be seen as beneficial to the individual anyway, if he rationally attempts to maximise his own utility. Migration – Identity and Nationhood Identity and nationhood refer to an individual’s sense of belonging to a nation. Nationhood focuses on how a citizen feels towards his country, while identity focuses more on the community aspect, how much the people of a nation are connected to each other. Migrants can have an impact on the identity and nationhood of the locals, and the act of migrating can have similar impacts on the migrants themselves. For one, the influx of migrants might dilute the unique culture and identity of the nation. Dubai boasts one of the fastest migrant flows (33 immigrants entered every hour in 2006). This has arguably resulted in the Westernisation of the Middle Eastern culture in Dubai. While it is still largely Muslim, standards of dress and conduct are more relaxed, and casinos are also being built. Practices such as wearing a hijab are being lost due to migrants from westernised countries like US and Australia. A large amount of immigrants may not necessarily change the unique culture of the nation, but rather such open policies may lead citizens to question whether their nation is made up of citizens or foreigners, as some Singaporeans feel. Singapore’s high immigration flow has led to a stigma against foreign workers who supposedly steal jobs from locals, and many question whether the government is prioritising foreigners at the expense of Singaporeans. As a result, some Singaporeans may feel alienated in their own country, dissatisfied with the status quo, forming an alarmingly strong push factor. The high emigration outflow of 26 emigrants per 1000 citizens (second only to Timor Leste’s 51/1000) may also contribute to this erosion of identity and nationhood. And yet, is has to be said that the assimilation of immigrants into their destinations is very possible. Looking at colonial Singapore in the 1800s, as well as the melting pot of the USA, there are many cases where migrants have assimilated into local cultures, strengthening it. The USA, known as the land of opportunities for many immigrants, provides them with a relatively more secure and higher quality of life, augmenting their sense of pride and nationhood for the nation. For migrants, often the very decision of migration itself is a personal choice – and thus would imply benefits to the migrant if they attempt to maximise their own utility. It thus follows that the pull factors in the destination country should outweigh that of the home country, or perhaps the push factors present in the home country are too strong, such as wars or famines. The extent to which migrants retain their sense of identity as a citizen of their home country, therefore, depends on their reasons for migration as well as the personal links which remain to their home country – which is of course empirical and on an individual scale. Crush et al. (2005: 25) report a survey of roughly 10,000 tertiary-level students from all disciplines in six southern African countries. Over half of these students predicted that they would emigrate within five years, mostly to rich countries. They were then asked why they felt this way. Though income and living standards were the most common responses, almost as common were concerns about the “HIV/AIDS situation”, “professional advancement”, “a level of fair taxation”, “personal safety”, “the future of your children”, and “quality upkeep of public amenities”. The motivations of 20 migration are linked to the socioeconomic background of the home and destination country, and are largely what determine whether migrants still retain a link to their home country. For migrants moving abroad purely to work (for economic reasons), psychological ties to family and friends remaining in the home country are also a major factor affecting identity, since such ties tend to retain connections and links to the home country. On the other hand, if migrants bring their family along with them, it greatly reduces the connections they retain with their home country. Regardless, psychological costs are largely inevitable, if the destination country is vastly different. It has been hypothesized that social adjustment in migrants may be influenced by the duration of the relocation, the similarity or dissimilarity between the culture of origin and the culture of settlement, language and social support systems, acceptance by the 'majority' culture, access and acceptance by the expatriate community, employment, and housing. If the individual feels isolated from his or her culture, unaccepted by the 'majority culture' and has a lack of social support, a consequent sense of rejection, alienation and poor self-esteem may occur. The loss of one's social structure and culture can cause a grief reaction, as has been described by Eisenbruch. Migration involves the loss of the familiar, including language (especially colloquial and dialect), attitudes, values, social structures and support networks. Grieving for this loss can cause significant distress or impairment for a certain period of time. Eisenbruch has defined cultural bereavement as "the experience of the uprooted person - or group - resulting from loss of social structures, cultural values and self-identity: the person - or group - continues to live in the past, suffers feelings of guilt over abandoning culture and homeland, and feels stricken by anxieties, morbid thoughts, and anger that mar the ability to get on with daily life". Psychosocial changes experienced by immigrants include assimilation, which can be viewed as a process by which cultural differences disappear as immigrant communities adapt to the majority or host culture and value system. An individual's cultural identity may be lost during the assimilation process as he or she moves within the host society. Acculturation, a process that may be voluntary or forced, requires contact between culturally divergent groups of people and results in the assimilation of cultural values, customs, beliefs and language by a minority group within a majority community. During the acculturation process, both the immigrant and host cultures may change. Changes in attitudes, family values, generational status and social affiliations can occur in both the majority and minority cultures as the two interact; however, typically one culture dominates. Cultural changes in identity can be stressful and result in problems with self-esteem and mental health. Contact between the immigrant, or minority, community with the dominant or host community may lead to assimilation, rejection, integration or deculturation. Rejection, in which the individual or minority group withdraws from the majority group, can lead to apartheid or segregation in extreme cases. Deculturation, in which the individual or minority group experiences a loss of cultural identity, alienation and acculturative stress, can lead to ethnocide. Post-migration stresses include culture shock and conflict, both of which may lead to a sense of cultural confusion, feelings of alienation and isolation, and depression. Host societies' attitudes, including racism, compounded by stresses of unemployment, a discrepancy between achievement and expectations, financial hardships, legal concerns, poor housing and a general lack of opportunities for advancement within the host society, can lead to mental health problems in vulnerable individuals. 21 Acculturation may help the culturally bereaved individual to gain a semblance of equilibrium. Migrants who experience the loss of their culture and guilt over leaving their homeland may find that, as the acculturation process proceeds, a sense of belonging in their new homeland occurs. The majority culture may seem less threatening and more inviting as the individual becomes more linguistically and socially fluent in this new culture. Social support can ensue in the forms of friendships, employment opportunities, and medical care. Integration and assimilation can help reduce feelings of loss and grief as the migrant starts to incorporate aspects of the majority culture. In acculturation, the interaction of the migrant's culture with the majority culture of the new homeland is a dynamic and reciprocal process that can result in changes in the broader cultural group, enhancing the ability of people of the dominant culture to better appreciate and understand aspects of the immigrant's culture and recognize some of the needs of those who have migrated. Migration, Cultural Bereavement and Cultural Identity: http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC1414713/ 22 2. Implications of Population Change Population Composition and Distribution Overview of World Population Growth and Future Projections in LDCs and DCs Discuss the reasons for changes and variations in population composition and distribution. Assess the economic, demographic, social and political implications of changes and variations in population structure and distribution. Compare the strategies used in LDCs and DCs in coping with population change. Population Distribution Population Composition An examination of the structure and social make up is known as the study of population structure or composition. Structure consists of three aspects, demographic, cultural and socio-economic facets. Population Projections and its Problems Population Projections It is the calculation of the number of people expected to be alive at some future point in time based on current fertility and mortality rates. This calculation can be based on local, regional levels, national levels or global levels. The length of prediction dates can vary, but normally ranging from 510 years, 20-50 years or 50-100 years. Short term forecasts are known as population estimates, and long term forecasts are known as population projections. How Population Projections are Done Projections and estimates are based on assumptions and principles which are normally most likely to happen. However, this often results in poor estimates if the time range is large, since variables are unlikely to be ceteris paribus. Assumption: BRs and DRs remain constant over time. This assumes the mostly likely course of events, or the medium projection. Assumption: Migration data is left out of population projections because of unavailability, inaccuracy of data and difficulty of defining what constitutes migration. Migration trends are also difficult to predict. If included, migration data will be left as an appendix. Assumption: Due to the high likelihood of any single prediction being inaccurate due to data problems and unpredictable variables, there will normally be three conditional futures calculated based on 3 constant BRs and DRs. This gives low, medium and high population projection figures indicating the smallest possible increase, most likely course of events, and the greatest possible increase in population size respectively. Each is based on different, likely assumptions of current and future variables. 23 Reasons for Population Projections On a global scale, projections allow people to assess balance between resources and population growth in order to achieve sustainable development practices in the long run. Important considerations for the future include the variations in population growth between regions (Asia, Europe, and America) and how this will affect future economies and policies, and the delicate balance between resource use and population growth. On a more localized scale, projections allow governments to plan and provide adequate socioeconomic provisions for their countries at each age structure, such as hospices and homes for an ageing population, or schools and childcare for a young population. Governments and Population Projections Economic Reasons: Planning fiscal policies – knowing the proportion of taxable and dependent population allows the government to decide how much to tax and how much to spend. Calculate future size of working population – helps in predicting future growth rates, the dependency of the population. Altering immigration policies – a shrinking working population may be a reason for relaxing immigration policies so as to boost the country’s economy and flagging workforce. Social Reasons: Predicting future dependency ratios and catering to needs of the population composition – creating suitable policies to deal with an increasingly dependent population, such as in Singapore and Japan due to low fertility rates and aging populations. For example, focusing on developing elderly facilities such as hospices, old age homes and better healthcare. Correcting gender imbalances – especially in Asian countries with a traditional preference for males: China, India. Distribution of Resources: Estimating future demand for food, water and energy – an increasing population will put additional strain on the country’s infrastructure and resources, such as healthcare, education etc. May be used to decide whether or not to implement anti-natal policies. Measuring Environmental Impacts: An increasing population size will result in more resources such as oil and fuel. Especially in DCs, this will mean more emissions and environmental impacts. For LDCs, increasing populations mean more waste produced, and for countries with poor waste management systems, this will greatly impact their environment. 24 Others Interested in Projections International Agencies – such as the UN, needed to assess the balance between resources and population growth and lend adequate support to various countries, normally LDCs, to assist their demographic policies. Problems with Population Projections The assumptions made in projections and the complexity of factors often make projections rather inaccurate, as too often the assumptions distort when they are meant to simplify, and many unexpected incidents do occur. 1) Social Change – the changing role of women and its effects on fertility and BRs, different levels and effectiveness of natal policies in different regions, rapid rise of fatal diseases, epidemics 2) Economic Change – unexpected recessions or booms which can affect fertility rates. Prolonged poverty, hunger and malnutrition in LDCs as well 3) Political Change – wars, civil strife, political unrest will affect BRs and DRs to some extent 4) Demographic Change – migration patterns, greater BRs of migrants, large changes in migration patterns due to events such as strife or natural disasters Overcoming Inaccuracies of Projections Some problems can be reduced if projection rates are continuously monitored and updated based on shorter time intervals or using differing BRs and DRs over time. Regardless, despite the fact that projections tend to be more inaccurate the longer the time period, long term projections are still needed for long term planning and analysis, and after all it is “better to be approximately right than precisely wrong”. Greater openness and cooperation between governments and planning agencies can be useful (e.g. more transparency regarding data) so that projection rates are able to be more accurate. 25 Interpretation of Population Pyramids Discuss the issues of population dependency. Discuss how population structure is affected by changes in family structure, economic change and gender imbalance. Critically evaluate the impact of changing population structures on issues related to the provision of leisure, employment and health and welfare services. Discuss the value of limitations of population pyramids in predicting population change. Population Pyramids Population pyramids show the demographic aspects of population composition. The age-sex composition of a country’s population tells us much about its history, socio-economic status etc., allowing us to infer much about its socio-economic level. Age-sex pyramids show two things: the percentage of males and females in a region on a horizontal scale, and the age groups of the population in the same region, normally marked at 5 year intervals on a vertical scale. A pyramid is a snapshot in time of the country’s population demographic structure, normally one year. By analysing a pyramid, we can infer and deduce about the region’s past and present development. We look at three things: the overall form and structure of the pyramid, looking at individual bars, or comparing between bars (either by age or by gender). Different Types of Pyramids There are generally 4 main types of population pyramids corresponding to the 4 stages of the Demographic Transition Model, but overall there are numerous variations of pyramids which do not conform to these 4 types. Stationary Pyramid Corresponds to the first stage of the DTM. The population as a whole is not really growing due to both equally high BRs and DRs, approximating zero population growth. Examples include 17th-18th century Europe. There are virtually no countries overall with this pyramid today, except specific, small regions within some of the poorest LDCs. This pyramid has a wide base, meaning that BRs are high. Depsite high DRs due to high IMR, compensation theory suggests that overall there are more babies being born. Due to the high IMR, the second bar is normally very short compared to the first bar – few ‘graduate’ to the next age group because most die within the first 5 years of their life. The overall shape is irregular, due to the presence of highly infectious and fatal diseases that the whole population is susceptible to. For example, in 17th century England, many diseases such as scarlet fever, typhus, measles, smallpox and cholera caused to life expectancy to be only about 33 years. Since diseases affect every strata of the population, dents can be seen across age groups in 26 the pyramid. The overall height is also very short due to low life expectancy. The pyramid is concave in shape, tapering rapidly as people die. Progressive/Expansive Pyramid Corresponds to the second stage of the DTM. The population is growing rapidly as BRs greatly exceed DRs, often due to a speedy reduction in DRs which is likely due to better affordability, accessibility and availability of healthcare. The pyramid has a wide base, like the stationary pyramid. However, it also has a wider second bar in comparison, as the IMR is drastically reduced. The pyramid is regularly tapering instead of rapidly or irregularly shaped, as the population in general can live longer and survive better as compared to the dents and bulges of the stationary pyramid. This regularity represents a declining DR. However, it shows that population is still susceptible to mortality as a whole, because the sides are not steep. The pyramid is also taller due to higher life expectancies. Most LDCs have already received some form of modern medicine, so most of them would already be in Stage 2 (Mozambique, Zambia) or Stage 3 of the DTM. Intermediate Pyramid This pyramid lies between progressive and regressive pyramids. The wide base is shrinking due to decreasing BRs, and the pyramid becomes steeper and less tapering due to decreasing DRs. More people are surviving across the entire population. This pyramid fits the third stage of the DTM, where many countries such as Singapore and China are in. Regressive/Contractive Pyramid The regressive pyramid fits with the fourth stage of the DTM. The population experiences low BRs, resulting in a narrower base. Lower DRs mean that the pyramid is generally the most steep, with most people living till life expectancy. The pyramid top is now high and wide because more people are living longer lives. This also means that DRs will increase slightly due to an aging population. Since women biologically live longer than men, it means that there might be an imbalance of gender towards the top of the pyramid. A regressive pyramid with low BRs and DRs also approximates zero population growth. ‘Early’ regressive pyramids have wider bases compared to ‘late’ regressive pyramids, due to falling BRs over time. Examples of countries with regressive pyramids are normally DCs, such as the UK and many European countries. Information Extraction from Pyramids Interpretation of population pyramids – There are at least 7 kinds of information able to be gleaned from pyramids. 27 1. Percentage of young, adult and aged populations, thus dependency ratios Adding up percentages of each of the 3 main groups: young dependent (0-14), economically active adults (15-64), old dependent (65 and over) Depends on the working ages of the country in question. Dependency ratio can thus be calculated from this information, both total dependency as well as young/old dependency 2. Current socio-economic levels based on demographic transition Looking at the percentage share of the 3 main groups, the stage of the demographic transition can be inferred Less developed, Progressive, Stage 2: {Young 45%, Adult 52%, Old 3%} Transitional, Intermediate, Stage 3: {Young 33%, Adult 59%, Old 8%} Developed, Regressive, Stage 4: {Young 20%, Adult 64%, Old 16%} 3. Birth rates/Fertility rates BRs can be estimated by looking at the bottom bar of the pyramid, the base. A wide bar indicating high fertility rates can be due to compensation theory, successful pronatal policies or baby booms due to healthy economic growth Look at: replacement level. A low BR might indicate an inability for the population to replace itself, which may result in underpopulation or under utilisation of resources Rate of natural increase. A high BR may indicate high increase, which may result in overpopulation, overcrowding etc. 4. Death rates When looking at DRs, there are two components – IMR and deaths other than IMR IMR – important indicator of a country’s development, healthcare and sanitation, derived by comparing the first two age bars Other deaths – Diseases, war and famine will cause the pyramid to taper rapidly since deaths are spread across all groups. This is so for most LDCs. For DCs, a broad top would mean more elderly, and thus more deaths from old age. 5. Life expectancy The taller the pyramid, the higher the life expectancy 6. Sex ratio The proportion of males to females. At the top of the pyramid, there might be an imbalance since females live longer If there is an imbalance at the base, it may indicate a preference for one gender, such as patriarchal societies in Asia (China, India). This might have implications such as lack of marriage partners, sex crimes, social imbalance, selective abortions, bride burnings, infanticides and so on. 7. Migration patterns By comparing two regional pyramids, migration patterns can be inferred. It could indicate internal migration, but not a definite. Migration can be implied if there is a significant dent, indicating emigration, in one pyramid, and a corresponding bulge, indicating immigration, in the other pyramid 28 Limitations of Population Pyramids 1. Does not show the cause of changes in BR and DR – needs specific details to understand their causes. Otherwise, they can only be inferred or suggested. 2. Problems of data collection – undercounting population, does not consider homeless and mobile people 3. Only divided by age-sex – other factors, possibly ethnicity and race 4. Does not indicate equity, quality of life, population density 5. Does not indicate racial and ethnic imbalances 6. Future predictions are still naturally limited by ceteris paribus assumption – pro/anti natal policies may be implemented, economic recessions may occur etc. The Dependency Ratio The dependency ratio is the age population ratio expressing the dependent population over the people active in the workforce. Dependency Ratio = _No. of people aged < 14 + No. of people aged > 65_ No. of people aged 15 to 64 Generally, the higher the dependency ratio, the larger the burden on the economically active workforce who pay income taxes and contribute to the economy to support the economically dependent, such as in public healthcare and expenditure. The ratio is a useful comparative indicator of the average number of people each working member of the population has to support. However, the age group definitions are arbitrary, subject to change when taking into account school leaving age, retirement age etc. Implications of Population Dependency There are in general two main types of dependency – child dependency and aged dependency, depending on the structure of the population. Both have different implications on policy making. For DCs with a high dependency ratio, such as Japan or the UK (50-55% ratio), the main cause is likely aged dependency due to an aging population. A combination of low birthrates and long life expectancy means that an increasing proportion of the population is expected to become elderly, meaning that each individual member of the workforce will have to support more dependents, such as via income taxes. Policy implications include the need for more and better geriatric care, healthcare for aged diseases, old age homes, pension schemes, insurance etc. Also, some countries may consider raising the retirement age, as Singapore has done from 62 to 65. Countries may also like to focus on long-term policies such as raising fertility rates via pro-natal policies, but these have rarely been successful. For dependent LDCs (with a ratio of 55-60%) such as India and Bangladesh, this is often caused by child dependency due to high birthrates. Reasons for this may include cultural reasons or other fertility variables. This implies a need for better education, more schools, childcare needs, parental benefits etc. Some countries have extremely high dependency ratios of above 80% such as Angola and Zambia, mainly due to their active workforce heavily impacted by diseases such as AIDS, along with a particularly high fertility rate as a result of the compensation effect. 29 Socio-Economic Composition Discuss the socio-economic differentials among various ethnic groups. Discuss the criteria used to measure inequalities in populations on a global or national scale. Discuss the level of inequality that exists between populations and between different sectors of the same population. Ethnic Inequalities Causes of Racial/Ethnic Discrimination and Inequalities The denial of equal rights is a central feature of discrimination. Most commonly, denial of equal rights comes from denial of equal access to basic rights, in particular, equal access to a share of society’s basic resources. Dominated groups frequently suffer poor basic amenities in the form of housing, health and educational facilities. This may not be the result of legislation discriminating against them but because of the way market forces and powerful pressure groups work to deny access. For example, it is said that in both the US and UK, ethnic minority groups are discriminated against in the housing market in terms of availability of mortgages and by agents being persuaded not to deal with ethnic minority families wanting to purchase homes in predominantly white neighbourhoods. Much more significantly, minorities are often forced to live in deprived areas, such as inner city areas and areas where provision of facilities is poor. Due to low incomes, it is difficult to move to better neighbourhoods and enhance standard of living. Active discrimination causes resentment and alienation into the mainstream of society. Solving Ethnic Problems Acts of discrimination based on ethnic differences may decrease over time due to a few reasons. The growing influence of international organization to find and address inequalities which exist within and between countries. Improved communication across the globe and increased contact between people is facilitated by personal mobility. Increasing realization of the interdependence between countries as more nations are integrated into a world system. Disputes arising from inequalities and exploitation of one group by another can spill over into other areas. Increasing emphasis on resolving disputes through discussion with the help of external mediators rather than through violence or armed struggle. 30 Population Change and Planning Discuss the links between the Demographic Transition Theory and age structure. Discuss the various stages of the Demographic Transition Theory. Apply the Demographic Transition Theory to population growth in LDCs and DCs. Evaluate the reasons for having pro- or anti-natal policies. Compare the effectiveness of pro-/anti-natal policies in LDCs and DCs. Analyse how population growth is affected by government planning. The Demographic Transition Model The demographic transition model (DTM) charts the change of a country’s population from high BRs and DRs to low levels over four stages. Recently, new trends have led to the proposal of 5th and even 6th stages to the DTM. The DTM was conceptualized in the 1950s based on the consistent demographic experiences of western European countries which underwent the Industrial Revolution. It attempts to explain a country’s current socio-economic development based on its current demographics. Stage 1: High Stationary Stage: High BRs (35/1000), High DRs (35/1000) In the first stage, population approximates zero growth as both BRs and DRs are high, canceling out each other. High BRs of approximately 35/1000 The high BRs are due to a few possible reasons: 31 1. An agrarian society and the need for familial labour in labour-intensive farms, which is true of medieval England, pre-industrial Europe, or rural regions in Africa. 2. For some communities, the social mindset is that a familial culture reigns, such as in China. 3. Ignorance, unavailability or low level of acceptance against contraception. Some rural areas either do not have access to contraception, cannot afford it or are unwilling to use it. 4. Inaccessibility of certain areas to education of family planning. 5. Compensation effect – where death rates are high, especially IMR, more are born to make up for this loss, so some children will survive. 6. Longer fertility rate due to earlier marriages – true of certain cultural beliefs, such as prearranged marriages in India and China. High DRs of approximately 35/1000 Normally due to poor healthcare and hygiene, rudimentary medicine and healthcare levels. Inaccessibility to medicine due to being rural. Not affordable due to being poor. There are almost no examples of countries today in Stage 1 of the DTM, as medicine and healthcare has become available to most. Ethiopia has a 39/1000 BR and a 20/1000 DR, showing that DR have also gone down in most countries worldwide. Only extremely rural and backward areas, such as in some parts of Africa and India, approximate Stage 1. Stage 2: Expansionary Stage: High BRs (35/1000), Declining DRs (35 to 20/1000) Rapid population growth occurs in Stage 2 as BRs remain high while DRs rapidly decrease, increasing the rate of natural increase. Rapidly declining DR from 35/1000 to 20/1000 The Industrial Revolution in Europe brought down DRs due to rapid improvements in technology, facilitating medicine, food production, transport and so on. The shift from an agrarian to an industrial society improved the standard and quality of life. There was mass employment due to the factory system and vaccinations greatly improved the situation against the epidemic-rife period. Generally, this fall in death rates is due to greatly improved healthcare. Today’s LDCs have greater accessibility to healthcare imports, greatly bringing down DRs. High BRs of 35/1000 The lag period between fall in DRs and the BRs was largely due to mindset. While decreasing DRs was easy through medicine and technology, shifting mindsets to reduce BRs takes time. BRs are driven by deep-seated social factors such as familial labour, community spirit, religion and biological compensation. Recent falls in DRs for LDCs were much more rapid than the falls in early Europe. This had the effect of exacerbating the overpopulation effect. Stage 3: Contractionary Stage: Declining BRs (35 to 20/1000), Low DRs (15/1000) At this stage, population increase starts to decrease as BRs fall. 32 Declining BRs to 20/1000 Socio-cultural changes in mindset, increasing affluence as well as cost of living, changing ideas of family life decreases the BR. This has happened in China and India, both rather traditional in mindset initially, but has since transformed in terms of social mindsets. Anti-natal policies may also have played roles in lowering the BR. Low DRs of 15/1000 DRs continue to fall at a slower, gradual pace as medicine and healthcare becomes more accessible and affordable to a larger section of the population. Present day China, Brazil, Argentina and other NIEs fall into Stage 3 today. Stage 4: Low Stationary Stage: Low BRs (16/1000), Low DRs (12/1000) Stage 4 also approximates zero growth and minimal population increase, as both BRs and DRs are low. Low BRs at 16/1000 and low DRs at 12/1000 Countries reaching Stage 4 of the DTM have completed the transition from high to low levels of BR and DR. BRs are low due to emancipation and changing roles of women, with women having more rights, liberalisation and education. Also, higher costs of living means children are seen as a liability instead of an asset (costs $260,000 to bring up a child in Singapore). Increased access to family planning, contraception, and a shift to a more urbane mindset in a capitalist society also lowers the BR. Low DRs are due to social medical advancements, such as increased availability of child immunization, advanced medical technology such as chemotherapy and biotechnology and better insurance. Most DCs are at least in Stage 4 today – some have even shown new trends which may justify the need for a 5th and 6th stage. Possible Stages: Stage 5 and Stage 6 Imaginary Stage 5 Stage 5 is a theoretical stage for many DCs now, as BRs are hovering extremely low around DRs, and can even go below DRs and replacement level. Countries like Germany and Singapore are experiencing natural decrease as socio-economic factors drive down BRs even further. This depicts an inverse relationship with HDI and fertility rates. Possible Stage 6 The UN discovered that for some countries, TFR increased slightly after HDI hit 0.9, showing a possible positive correlation at very high levels of development (Maslow’s hierarchy). This is tenuous at best, and maybe even limited by culture, as the only countries not conforming to this were Japan, 33 South Korea and Canada. Furthermore, the slight increase in TFR is ultimately not able to reverse the trend of decreasing fertility and is unable to stabilise the population. Application and Relevance of the DTM In general, the DTM is useful in classifying countries into categories and explaining their current socio-economic development with respect to BRs and DRs. However, it should be noted that different countries naturally have different, place specific explanations for their BRs and DRs that the DTM cannot explain. The DTM cannot be used to explain demographic histories specifically, since it is based on England alone. Also, it does not take into account other intervening factors like government policies. For most DCs, the DTM is largely relevant to countries completing the transition at the same time as the UK due to similar histories and migration trends. However, migration is not taken into account for the DTM, and is assumed to remain stable, while this is unlikely to be the case, due to changing immigration policies. Also, the possibility of Stages 5 and 6 may render the 4-stage DTM model outdated. An interesting point is that some DCs have DRs higher than BRs, and this is the basis of Stage 5. While it could be due to decreasing BR, it could also be due to increasing DR as a result of an aging population. For example, Italy’s DR is 10.2/1000, higher than its BR of 9/1000. Its death rate is higher than Indonesia’s at 6/1000. Better healthcare, medicine and nutrition, along with better education, affluence and infrastructure, increasing the quality of life and extending life expectancies. For LDCs, the DTM works only as a classifying tool, unable to reflect many aspects. For one, it does not indicate the time period the country took to reach their present stage – Singapore took only 30 years to complete the 4 stages, while the original UK-based model assumed that it would take 140 years due to the need for assuming status quo with regards to social and technological advancement. Also, it does not reflect how long a country will remain in that stage. Certain LDCs like Chad and Ethiopia have remained in Stage 2 for the past 30 years without much sign of change. Some countries don’t even fit into the DTM as it is generalized from European countries, while countries such as Pakistan and Egypt have very different demographics due to cultural differences (such as religions which forbid contraception, resulting in very high BRs yet very low DRs). It also does not take into account phenomena, such as HIV AIDS which actually reversed DTM progress in Sudan and Nigeria between 1975 and 2005, which greatly increased mortality and IMR. Different histories between DCs and LDCs also make it unable to apply the DTM to LDCs entirely. Migration policies were laxer in the past, allowing for Europeans to migrate easily, bringing down BRs quickly than LDCs today. DCs also had smaller population bases in the past compared to large LDC population bases today. It is more difficult for LDCs to reduce their BRs today. 34 Population Planning – Pro-natal Policies Country Singapore Reasons TFR dropped from 1.96 in 1988 to 1.42 in 2001 Rapidly ageing population (25% by 2025) Previous measures in “Have Three or More” were largely monetary and ineffective Policies Baby Bonus Scheme and Third Child Paid Maternity Scheme Maternity leave and baby bonuses $9000 for second child, $18000 for third child Children Development Account: government matches amount saved into account up to $6000 for 1st child, $12000 for 2nd-4th children and $18000 for 5th child 8 weeks of paid maternity leave for working mothers who give birth to third child up to $20000 Family friendly workplaces – initiatives e.g. Work-Life Unit, FamilyFriendly Firm Award Japan Emphasize work-child care compatibility Public support for childcare Ageing population (21% 65 and above) TFR low at 1.57 in 1989 France Ageing population Increasingly dependent population Angel Plan in December 1994 Cash benefits, work incentives, childcare incentives, work support for mothers Monthly child allowance of US$100 per child up to primary school children in 2006 “Zero Waiting List for Daycares” as a goal. Daycare enrolment rate rose from 15.6% in 2001 to 20.3% in 2007 Childcare Leave Law: 50% of wages (2006) paid during childcare leave Support Plan for Mother’s Re-entry into Labour Market (2004) – vocational schools to impart new skills to women, workshops to help start businesses Pro-natal Package Extensive subsidies and bonuses – families pay less tax in France than singles/childless couples Daycare costs a third as much as other countries Transport concessions for families with more than 2 children. 50% off train fares for 1.5 years, 1 year off work for the mother Strong support and protection for women’s jobs, high female participation in economy Effectiveness/Criticism Purely monetary policies are unlikely to work given as the main factor is changing social mindsets Even so, government attempts to change these mindsets are seen as overly controlling and decision limiting, making them seem artificial and worsening the situation SMEs not entirely accepting since small workforce means missing employees are important Apparently ineffective – TFR dropped further to 1.11 Appeared to be ineffective – TFR continued to fall to 1.23 in 2008 As usual, monetary policies were largely ineffective Childcare incentives only raised enrolment rate – previously un-enrolled children were enrolled by parents – no real increase in fertility rate Appears to be effective – TFR is highest in ageing Europe, increasing trend (now 2.02) Generally well-received by the public Key factor appears to be public acceptance of the government’s efforts – receptivity is ultimately what matters compared to other countries 35 Population Planning – Anti-natal Policies Country China Policies One-Child Policy (1979) Restricts urban Han couples to only 1 child Rural couples, ethnic minorities and parents who are themselves only children are exempted Flouting the policy results in heavy fines of up to 30% annual income India Largely government sponsored antinatal policies to deal with population increase Provision of contraceptives Family planning education Iran Effectiveness TFR fell from 3 in 1980 to 1.8 in 2008 Overpopulation problems e.g. epidemics and slums have been reduced in severity Improved healthcare – better health services for women, reduction in risks associated with pregnancy e.g. free contraception, pre-natal classes, ”Care for Girls” program eliminating cultural discrimination against girls Economic growth – reducing demand for natural resources, maintaining stable labour rate, reducing surplus labour, reducing exploitation Contraceptive use has more than tripled (13% of married women in 1970 to 49% in 2009) TFR halved from 5.7 in 1966 to 2.7 in 2009 Affords women a degree of choice Successful implementation relies on education – higher education levels and economic opportunities for women possible Late 1980s to TFR dropped from 6.5 from 1975early 1990s, 80 to about 1.71 in 2007 religious emphasis Usage of legislation to enforce Government was effective – mandatory declaration: Islam contraceptive courses before favoured families marriage license can be attained with 2 children and benefits doled out Nationwide Advertising/packaging of campaign with imported contraceptives introduction of contraceptives Criticism Violation of human rights bribery, coercion, compulsory sterilization, abortion and infanticide. Quota of 20000 abortions and sterilizations set for Huaiji County in Guangdong Province 4-2-1 problem: increasing dependency on the working population in the future – lower taxes and heavy burden on economically active, elderly at risk of little to no support after retirement Problems for the next generation – ‘Little Emperors’ due to overindulgence, imbalanced sex ratios may lead to social ills: 117:100 male to female births in 2000 A large ratio of illiteracy and the lack of accessibility to contraceptives limits the full potential and effectiveness of the policies Effectiveness varies across regions and states due to differing levels of literacy and affluence – Tamil Nadu’s TFR reduced to 1.8, Uttar Pradesh’s TFR to 3.8 Legislation was deemed to be extremely overbearing Lack of sustained usage – discontinued in 2006 by new president. Can result in returned problems of overpopulation and associated effects 36 Population-Resource Relationships Discuss the factors that characterize overpopulation and underpopulation. Discuss the relationship between population growth and resource utilisation. Compare resource use in LDCs and DCs. Discuss how changes in society result in the changing appraisal of resources and environments. Evaluate hedonist/conservationist approaches on the sustainability of resource use and how they impact population change and resource use. Resources are anything that satisfies human wants. Stocks are stores of resources which are currently unused. Reasons for stocks not being used could be that people are unaware of them (knowledge problem), don’t have the ability to obtain them (technological problem) or they don’t see the need to use them yet (socio-cultural situation). When stocks are translated into resources to satisfy human wants, the region’s resource pool generally increases, allowing it to better support its population. There are generally two types of resources. First, there are natural resources such as oil, gas, minerals and water. Within natural resources, there are renewable resources such as wind, solar energy and hydroelectricity and non-renewable resources such as coal, oil and natural gas. Renewable resources can become non-renewable if over-exploitation occurs. It is not so much the amount of natural resource as the means to tap on these stocks of resources. Secondly, there are human resources, which are the population. It is important to look at the quality and quantity of human resources. In order to increase aggregate supply and the productive capacity of the economy, it is important to improve the quality of the workforce, increase the size of the workforce or both. Singapore has focused much on supply-side policies such as education and retraining to improve the productivity of our workforce as we have little natural resources. Resource distribution varies greatly between countries. Some countries like the USA have high levels of both natural and human resources, others like Mozambique have good natural resources but poor human resources, and countries like Singapore and Hong Kong have little to none natural resources but high levels of human resource. Carrying Capacity, Optimum Population, Overpopulation and Underpopulation Carrying capacity is the population size the environment can sustain indefinitely, given the resources available in the environment, which can change over time due to changes in food availability, water supply and environmental conditions. When referring to population here, it must always be viewed in relation to availability of resources, both human and natural. Population density alone is not a good indicator of overpopulation. Something interesting to note is that due to increased globalisation and international trade, both natural and human resources are not restricted to any one country – oil can be imported, and 37 migrations can cause labour to shift from one country to another. Population stress may be increased or lowered in various countries as a result. Overpopulation Overpopulation is a situation where population growth exceeds current resource availability such that standards and quality of life fall. Overpopulation may be indicated by unemployment, congestion, pollution, poverty, famine and low levels of social provision, such as in SSA countries (Sudan, Ethiopia, Rwanda). High rates of natural increase result in depletion of natural resources such as fossil fuels, food and water, increase in pollution, inability of current infrastructure to support the growing population. Absolute overpopulation occurs when all existing resources have been exploited but there is no corresponding increase in SOL. This concept is largely an ideal because knowledge of all resources is always imperfect at any point in time. Relative population is more realistic, occurs when current resources are unable to support present population numbers i.e. a ceteris paribus situation. However, with increased productivity and better use of resources, standard of living can be improved. Countries deemed overpopulated are usually relatively overpopulated – under utilisation of factors of production, poor governance and instability are all factors leading to relative overpopulation. Underpopulation Occurs when population size is too small to fully utilize its resources effectively – increases in population will normally increase the standard of living of the country as a whole due to increased human resource. For example, New Zealand has about 3.5 million people, is self-sufficient in agriculture and also has a wealth of renewable energy resources. Underpopulation is not perceived to be a serious a problem as overpopulation due to having far less drastic consequences. However, the low BRs underpopulation implies may lead to an aging population in the long run (as it is in Canada, Australia and New Zealand), high dependency and being unable to maximize their welfare. Optimum Population A situation where there is maximum utilisation of resources available, achieving the highest SOL overall possible – a Pareto optimal situation. Since it is also difficult to quantify, optimal population also remains an ideal concept. Some countries approximate optimum population, such as Switzerland and other generally highly developed countries with high GNP per capita, high life expectancies and low IMR due to excellent medical advances, and an equitable wealth distribution. Malthusian Theory Main Ideas Thomas Malthus argues that: 38 1) Food supply/resources will grow arithmetically while population grows exponentially. There will eventually come a point where population outstrips food supply, hitting the food ceiling, resulting in overpopulation and famine. 2) The ‘doomsday’ situation Malthus predicts can be mitigated by preventive/negative checks as well as positive checks. Negative checks are decision made by people, such as postponing marriage or delaying having children. Positive checks are caused by environmental/external factors, such as natural deaths through diseases, malnutrition and famine. Limits to Growth Model Inspired by Malthus, neo-Malthusianists such as the Club of Rome came up with similar theories, like the Meadows Model or the Limits to Growth theory. It was devised in the context of spiraling oil prices in the early 1970s, emphasizing people’s dependence on oil and finite resources. The model is pessimistic and Malthusian in thinking, and claims that continued population growth will lead to dwindling resources. It believes that economic growth is the major cause of global problems such as environmental destruction. It claims that the solutions are economic and ecological policies which will shift countries to a zero-growth economy, instating global equilibrium. Applicability of Malthus’ Ideas Malthus and neo-Malthusianist ideas have some validity in some SSA countries like Ethiopia and Malawi, where population numbers exceed current resource pools. While fertility rates are extremely high (6% above the world average), subsistence farming gains have been unable to support the population growth. However, for the rest of the world in general, Malthusian ideas and assumptions can be challenged. For example, population growth may not grow exponentially due to increasing availability and accessibility of contraception, increasing costs of living and the changing social status of women. This is especially so considering the low BRs of many DCs today. Furthermore, Malthusian ideas do not take into account the exponential growth of technology, assuming rather unrealistically that technology grows arithmetically. Technology can lead to better use of resources such as the Green Revolution, increasing the productive capacity of the land and producing more food. This is the basis for Boserup’s rebuttal to Malthus’ ideas. Boserup’s Theory Esther Boserup’s views are anti-Malthusian and she claims that population growth and population pressure threatening overpopulation will force society to discover new agricultural methods to meet that increasing need. For example, the Green Revolution and terrace farming in China. High tech methods such as hydroponics and aeroponics were created to increase productivity. Overall, improvements in farming technology, accessibility in transport and communications, recycling, alternative fuel, power and water sources are areas which Boserupian views claim will continue to meet people’s needs. Julian Simon, an economist, claims that free market capitalism can solve overpopulation by creating jobs, stimulating production and joining international markets. 39 Of course, the key question is why resource pressures are still occurring in places like SSA if Boserupian views are correct, and also to what extent is production is truly unlimited, because resources are necessarily scarce. Neo-Marxist (Structuralist) Theory Structuralists claim that the fundamental problem between resources and population is a problem of unequal distribution. There are plenty of resources, just that they are distributed unequally, benefitting some privileged groups such as the rich or the governments. Although only 25% of the world’s population lives in DCs, DCs consume 75% of the world’s resources. The USA uses 30% of the world’s petrol and 35% of the world’s electricity, and is the largest polluter. Governments may channel resources into inappropriate areas such as military development when the country is undergoing famine, such as North Korea. Also, corrupt governments divert money from international aid to line their own pockets, such as the Marcos and Estrada regimes in the Philippines. Agricultural development of cash crops under colonialist rule in many LDCs continues today for export to TNCs. The land is not used for cultivating subsistence crops for the farmers, but cash crops to sell, of which the primary producers only gain a bit (inspiring the Fairtrade movement). Trade blocs and unfair protectionist policies like the EU CAP prevents an equitable distribution of food with the third world. Furthermore, geopolitical instability in terms of war and civil strife occur much more in LDCs, especially in African countries. Wars waste resources and refugees do not have access to proper nutrition. The problem here may be politics, not overpopulation. Development and Resource Use Key Terms Related to Sustainable Development Resource Appraisals are assessments or estimations of the worth, value, or quality of a resource, meant for the planning and monitoring land use and resource management. Resource Depletion occurs when raw materials within a region are being exhausted, consumed beyond their replacement rate. It can be caused by overpopulation, unsustainable resource extraction methods (slash and burn, deforestation, overmining for oil and minerals). Resource Management is the efficient deployment of resources when and where they are needed. The data required for effective management include demand for various resources over a time period and the ability for supply to match this demand. Resource management also refers to practices pertaining to maintaining the sustainability and integrity of natural systems and resources. Ecological Footprint is the measure of the impact of human demand for resources on the Earth’s ecosystems. It compares human demand with Earth’s ecological capacity to regenerate. It is possible to use this to estimate how many planet Earths it would take to sustain humanity given a certain lifestyle (e.g. in 2006 our ecological footprint was estimated at 1.4 Earths, or we use resources 1.4 times as fast as Earth can renew them). 40 Sustainable Development Sustainable development is meant to meet the needs of the present generation while leaving the same or an improved resource base as a bequest for the future. The needs of future generations are not compromised while satisfying those of the present. Both economic and environmental considerations must be covered when planning policies. The relationship between human development and environment is two-way. While the environment contributes to human welfare and well being and provides the essential resources, if in the process of economic progress the environment is damaged, future economic progress will be jeopardized. China faces a challenge of sustainable development. It faces increasing population pressure, rapid economic development with lagging environmental controls (3rd largest consumer of energy, land degradation and soil erosion) and an overuse of basic resources such as water, forests and fish (deforestation, overfishing, increasing demand for water in industrial and residential sectors). Agriculture has caused soil erosion and polluted water runoff, industries have resulted in urban pollution (26% of all deaths in China due to chest or lung illnesses) and a decrease in limited resources. Now, it is making conscious efforts to improve the situation. Population growth is largely under control due to anti-natal policies. Spending on environment protection has increased from 0.7 to 0.9% of GNP, but 1.5% is needed to control current degradation. Some management measures have been improved, e.g. replacing outdated coal boilers, rural use of windpower and biogas, sand break forests to reduce soil erosion. Regulation controls on industries are being introduced, such as potentially polluting industries being required to pay 30% of total construction costs. I=PAT Impact of Human Activity = Population Size x Affluence x Technology The formula I=PAT was introduced by Ehrlich and Holdren in the 1970s. It is used to understand some of the factors affecting human impacts on the environment, and originally used to emphasise the role of population growth on the environment. Population has been increasing exponentially since the Industrial Revolution. An increase in P will result in an increase in I, since a population increase will result in demand for greater land use, resource use and also pollution, ceteris paribus. This can result in habitat loss for other species, greater depletion of non-renewable resources, and perhaps climate change. Affluence is commonly measured in GDP/capita. An increase in A will increase consumption of goods, which can have a variety of impacts – for example, plastic packaging, Styrofoam, crude oil, rare earth minerals, water etc. Technology represents how resource intensive the production of affluence is. A reduction in technology can come about via improved methods, efficiency etc, reducing impacts on the environment (alternative energy sources etc.). T is likely to decrease over time as research and development continues. However, if P increases exponentially, then T needs to decrease at double the rate of population increase. Since P and A have both increased, the impact of a decreasing T has been lessened. 41 The model assists us in understanding the multiple causes of environmental impact and can help in projections for future environmental change. It is a useful framework for thinking about ways to reduce our environmental impact on the Earth and forms a useful policy development tool. However, the different factors are not necessarily independent of each other. Also, a simple multiplicative and an assumed linear relationship does not really hold in the real world (e.g. doubling population does not necessarily mean doubled impact). Also, there exist problems with measuring individual aspects (e.g. GDP per capita measures production, and consumption is assumed. Also does not take into account inequalities, distribution of wealth within countries and between countries). Importantly, it allows us to understand the factors which increase or decrease environmental impact, but not the level at which development is sustainable. Hedonist vs. Conservationist Based on population-resource relationships, two different approaches have been developed towards resource use. The hedonist approach is inherently Boseruptian while the conservationist approach follows a Malthusian concept. Hedonist Approach The hedonist approach seeks to utilize Earth’s resources to benefit mankind. They believe that “necessity is the mother of invention”, and as population densities increase, human populations are forced to adopt more intensive methods of food production and supply, often with technological innovations (e.g. the Industrial Revolution and the Green Revolution). There is no need to worry about limited resources. However, some argue that this theory cannot work indefinitely, and that at some point the population will get large enough that technology alone will not be enough to solve the problem, and that the environment will be unable to sustain such pressure in the long run. Conservationist Approach The conservationist approach seeks to minimize human impact on the earth at the expense of current development. This approach follows from a Malthusian viewpoint, that population will eventually outstrip resources, resulting in overpopulation, war and famine. Indeed, parts of SSA suggest that population growth have far exceeded ability to produce food, such as in Ethiopia. However, the theory seems too simplistic. Population rarely grows completely geometrically, and with recent trends growth seems to have slowed. Also, there is merit in the Boseruptian idea of technological growth, such as developing new farming methods and technology. Ultimately, while one seeks to maximize human development growth at all costs and the other wants to achieve minimal environmental impact at the cost of present growth rates, there are many methods which reconcile the two viewpoints, such as renewable energy resources, hybrid cars and organic products, which conserve our resources without diminishing development. Sustainable development seems to be the key here, where we use our resources only at a rate which can be replenished. 42